TJ Cheng, College of William and Mary Peter CY Chow, City university
Transcription
TJ Cheng, College of William and Mary Peter CY Chow, City university
Global Opportunities, Local and Transnational Politics: Taiwan's Bid for FTAs T.J. Cheng, College of William and Mary Peter C.Y. Chow, City university of New York I. Introduction I.1. The myth of the FTA and the apprehensions of being marginalized I.2. The emerging trade blocs in the region I.3. A Comparison between the TPP and RCEP I.4. The purpose of this study II. Hope for the Best: A Double Play II.1. Domestic politics in prioritizing the TPP vs. RCEP II. 2. The “China factor” in pursuing the trade pacts II.3. Sequencing order of applying for the TPP and RCEP II.4. Bilateral FTAs with dual membership countries first II.5. Political dividends of FTAs III. What if Both Doors Remain Shut? III.1. Multiple bilateral FTAs to reach the near hub-ness III.2.Looking beyond regional horizon: The Pacific Alliance IV. Economic Re-structuring Holds the Key IV.1. Agricultural sector: an economically weak yet politically strong sector IIV.2. Service sector: a socio-political complicated sector to be liberalized IV.3. Three points on industrial restructuring a. Branding and Enhancing value-added in OEM by functional and processing upgrading b. Innovate new production technology c. Exploit the untapped trade potential: Identifying the niche products in niche markets 1 I. Introduction I.1. The myth of the FTA and the apprehensions of being marginalized The proliferations of Free Trade Area ( FTA) in Asia since the 1990’s has generated many webbed trade blocs which were characterized as the “ Spaghetti bowl” ( Asian noodle bowl) of overlapping trading partners under different “ rules of origin” in various trade pacts. Chronically isolated from international community and affected by the “Beijing factor” in many of its wary trading partners, Taiwan has been blocked from signing FTAs with many of them. Except for its FTAs with 5 small economies in Central America which accounted for only 0.2% of its trade volume in 2010,1 Taiwan became an outlier of the emerging trade blocs in the Asia Pacific region.2The apprehension of being marginalized in the trend of economic integration and partisan politics on how to cope with China amid the drive for globalization have dominated Taiwan’s policy circles and academia research for decades. However, the overwhelming concern about being marginalized from the emerging trade blocs is not totally warranted; FTA benefits are not always reaped. A survey from Asian Development Bank Institute on the application of FTAs at the firms’ levels in many countries found that the percentage of applying the preferential trade rule is only 29 % in Japan, 24.9% in Thailand, 20.8% in Korea, 20% in the Philippines and 17.3% in Singapore (Kawai and Wignaraja, 2009. P.11). For Taiwan, even the utilization rate for the “ early harvest product list” under Economic Cooperation Framework Agreement (ECFA) with China is only about 20% for textile products, and about 50 to 60% in petro-chemical, machinery/parts and transport equipment in 2012. 1 They are Panama, Nicaragua, El Salvador, Guatemala, and Honduras. Taiwan signed a trade pact with New Zealand (ANZTEC ) in July 2013. But New Zealand is Taiwan’s 40 th largest trading partner with two- way trade totaled only $ 1.23 billion in 2012. Nevertheless, the ANZTEC is the first trade pact with the OECD countries. 2 2 Why have business firms in those countries not fully taken advantage of FTAs? Because of different rules of origin under various FTAs, the administrative cost of complying with the local contents requirement in conformity with the custom valuation is even higher than preferential rules. Hence, it is even more cost effective for business firms to apply the “most favored nation” clause under the WTO rather than the FTAs. Therefore, FTA is not a panacea at all for trade-inhibiting problems. We seem to be making a “sour grape” argument, but it really reflects that the transaction cost due to different rules of origin under various FTAs has undermined their effectiveness on actual trade performance. This argument also points to the necessity for consolidating and harmonizing various FTAs into a single framework. Integrating FTAs into uniform rules of origin is a very daunting task. Nevertheless, both the government and business enterprises in Taiwan have been eager to participate in the emerging trade blocs for both economic and political rationales to be analyzed below. Psychologically, participation or lack of it affects the incentive of investment domestically and from abroad. I.2. The emerging trade blocs in the region An overall review of the new development in the regional and global trade environment can be summarized as follows; a. Trade-investment nexus in Asia Pacific region became prevalent after the Plaza Accord in 1985 and accelerated after the 1990’s. Since then, trade in parts and components dominated the trade flows within Asia while most of their final products are destined to OECD markets, especially the U.S. In other words, intra-region trade in Asia is engaged more for intraindustry trade whereas that of inter-regional is more on an inter-industry basis. In general, trade for parts and components is much less distorted by protection policy than that for final products, thanks to interdependency among trading countries for the supply and demand for parts and components in the process of production. Hence, there are more 3 consensuses on liberalization on those sectors which are closely linked with the global supply chain than any others as reflected in the Information Technology Agreement (ITA) under the WTO framework. 3 b. The ASEAN has long been adroitly applying the ‘divide and rule’ tactic to expand the ASEAN-FTA to six economies using the formula of ASEAN plus 1’s (ASEAN plus China, ASEAN plus Japan, ASEAN plus Korea, ASEAN plus India, and ASEAN plus Australia as well as New Zealand) rather than ASEAN plus N. Hence, trade flows within ASEAN and between ASEAN and those six external economies are liberalized but not among those six economies outside of the ASEAN. Non-ASEAN economies thus have lately learned to take action collectively, rather than individually, viz., China-proposed ASEAN plus three (China, Japan, and Korea) and Japan-proposed ASEAN plus six (that is, ASEAN plus 3 plus Australia, India and New Zealand). Combining the ASEAN plus 3 and the ASEAN plus 6 led to the emerging Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership (RCEP).4 Meanwhile, China, Japan and Korea have launched the trilateral FTAs talk among themselves as well. c. The U.S. decided to join the four Trans-Pacific Partnership initiating members (TPP-4) for FTA talk in 2008. TPP-4 enlarged its member states to become TPP-12 by including Canada, Mexico and Japan, etc. As a major driver of the TPP talks, the U.S. is de facto extending the NAFTA to cover the Asia Pacific. Per the U.S. Trade Representative, the TPP is not meant to exclude China, but the bars for TPP membership are so high that China’s bid is not just in the offing yet, if it ever comes. By inviting Japan, one of its most important allies in the region, into the proposed TPP trade bloc, the U.S. has demonstrated its determination to empower its ‘pivot to Asia” initiative. Vowed to cover more members across the Pacific Ocean and liberalize deep by including service sector, labor and environment standards and regulatory governance on state3 The ITA provides for participants to completely eliminate duties on information technology products covered by the Agreement. The number of participating members has grown to 70, representing about 97 per cent of world trade in information technology products. WTO aims to finalize expanded information technology coverage by end July, 2013. From WTO website at: http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/inftec_e/inftec_e.htm. 4 RCEP was referred as the “Asian Track” in (Petri et al, 2011). 4 owned enterprises, the TPP will link Asia Pacific with Latin America and hopes to become the “Gold-standard FTA” in the 21st century. 5 d. The RCEP and the TPP can be a pair of rival trade blocs through the emerging China-centric and the U.S.-centric hubs with overlapping spokes. But both could be complementary to the Free Trade Area of Asia Pacific (FTAAP) if both pursue the ‘open regionalism” principle to entice more new member states to join in. In fact, both RCEP and TPP are considered by APEC Business Advisory Committee (ABAC) in 2013 as the pathways to Free Trade Area of Asia Pacific (FTAAP).6 I.3. A Comparison between the TPP and RCEP The TPP is proclaimed to be a high quality trade pact, going beyond tariff reductions on merchandise trade. It is therefore broader than the RCEP in terms of sector coverage and the degree of trade liberalization. In general, the impacts of TPP will be only about half as large as those of the RCEP to its member states because, except for Vietnam, most of the TPP economies have already relatively lower tariff barriers to start with. In terms of the impacts on the composition of world exports, the TPP will have no effect on trade in primary products, but will boost trade in manufactures by 0.8% and service sector by 1.1%. On the other hand, the RCEP will increase trade in primary products by 0.4%, manufactures by 2.3% and service sector by 2.1% from the base line of 2025 ( Petri et al, 2011, Table 9 Effects on the composition of world exports). Taiwan itself will benefit economically more by joining the RECP than the TPP. Applying the GTAP 8.1 version of the computable general equilibrium (CGE) model simulations, Hsu (2012) found that Taiwan’s GDP will increase by 1.98%, social welfare by $6.2 billion, and exports by $8.8 billion from its baseline if Taiwan joins the TPP-12. But, Taiwan will be benefitted more by joining the RCEP; its GDP will increase by 4.36%, social welfare by $11.6 billion and exports by $ 13.4 billion. Arguably, in terms of 5 The TPP is more conducive to the FTAAP by avoiding the risk of “drawing a line down the middle of the Pacific” in Asian regionalism. 6 The other pathway is the Pacific Alliance to be elaborated in the next section. 5 its political and strategic interest, Taiwan will have collateral benefits from its membership in the TPP (vs. the RCEP), namely, enhancing her economic-security nexus with the leading members in the club and further safeguarding her security. But it is much better if Taiwan can join both which are not mutually exclusive at all. Political feasibility, to be elaborated in Section II, would also suggest that Taiwan pursue its membership bids in both the TPP and the RCEP. I.4. The purpose of this study The purpose of this study is to analyze how Taiwan can do to cope with the rapidly evolving trade environment, why and how it can achieve that goal by pursuing both the TPP and RCEP, and, if neither agreement comes through, suggest some policy measures on improving economic structure to adapt to the new trading environment for further development. The thesis of this paper is based on the following assumptions; a. The TPP is very likely to succeed because it is the only trade pact undertaken by the Obama Administration to ‘return’ to a region of strategic and economic importance to the U.S. Without the TPP, the U.S. pivotal to Asia will be undercut substantially if not jeopardized because of the economic-security nexus (Cheng and Chow, 2013). The TPP has an accession clause which invites “ like-minded” states of APEC members to join in. Even if it does not fully implement the “open regionalism" to admit all APEC members as promised, the TPP will enlarge its members at various stages of its negotiations either before or after it is completed. Hence, a trade bloc with U.S.-centric hub is likely to emerge. b. A China-centric hub is likely to emerge as well. In spite of their territorial disputes, China, Japan and Korea are negotiating a trilateral FTA (CJK FTA). China has been pursuing its “good neighborhood” policy through preferential trade arrangements and has already wrapped its FTA deal with ASEAN (ASEAN plus China), and has another one with Central Asia (Shanghai Coop), and will probably get RCEP done to help generate China-centric hub.7 7 For the scenarios of the hub-spoke models in East Asia, see Chow (2013 a). 6 FTAAP NAFTA TPP RCEP Figure 1: Major trade blocs within the proposed FTAAP FTAAP includes all 21 APEC countries while excluding India which is a not a member of the APEC; it includes Russia, Taiwan and Papua New Guinea, which are not members of the either TPP or RCEP. Australia, Brunei, Japan, Malaysia, New Zealand, Singapore and Vietnam have dual membership in the RCEP and TPP. c. Both the RCEP and the TPP have the incentive to enlarge its membership to expand its sphere of influence before the completion of the FTAAP. Competitive trade liberalization will entice more non-member states to join either the TPP or the RCEP or both. 7 The rest of this paper is organized this way: Section II assesses the strategy by which Taiwan can maximize its opportunity to join both the TPP and the RCEP and minimize the odds for facing a trade-off between the two bids. Section III analyzes an alternative when Taiwan cannot join either club. Section IV discusses the relevant industrial re-structuring to cope with the new trading environment. The last section is for summary and conclusion. II. Hope for the Best: A Double Play The TPP and the RCEP may or may not be in rivalry. Regardless of the future relationship of the two pacts, Taiwan may not have the luxury of picking and choosing. In fact, based on internal and external rationales, Taiwan’s pursuit of both could help its bids for each. II.1. Domestic politics on prioritizing the FTA talks All politics, including political economy of trade, is local. Trade policy would inevitably involve domestic interest group politics in any democratic country. Taiwan is no exception. What is unique to Taiwan is that the pursuit of any FTA is entangled with national identity and partisan politics. While the government of Kuomintang (KMT), the ruling party in Taiwan today, has officially announced its interests in pursuing FTAs on all fronts, the Blue camp, a coalition consisting of the KMT, its affiliates, and their supporters that are not averse to political association with China in the future, is more enthusiastic about signing FTAs with China than with the US (Chiang et al, pp.106-107).8 Hence, it may well lead the Blue camp to favor the China-centric RCEP over the U.S.-centric TPP. But pursuing more agreements with China under the framework of ECFA has been upsetting most people in the Green camp, a coalition consisting of the main opposition party, DPP, its affiliates and their supporters. To this political camp, the ECFA clearly reveals China’s political intent to draw Taiwan closer into its orbit, as the former continuously packs economic sweeteners into a series of specific agreements. The Green camp believes that China, claiming sovereignty on Taiwan, has been enticing Taiwanese businessmen or Taishangs to become a strong pressure group by 8 In this study, Green camp refers to the supporters of the DPP and Taiwan Solidarity Union (TSU), whereas the Blue camp refers to those who support the KMT, the People’s First Party and China New Party. 8 which to leverage the KMT government to lean toward China. Moreover, the Green camp has learned from past elections that China did infiltrate into Taiwan’s electoral politics by, for example, supporting the presidential candidate from the ruling party of the KMT in 2012.9 The Green camp is not totally opposed to liberalizing trade with China, however. What many in this camp strongly favor is for Taiwan to become part of the TPP before seeing further cross-strait economic integration which would otherwise affect Taiwan’s autonomy and their cherished aspiration of a de jure independent Taiwan.10 The Green camp believes that further cross-strait economic liberalization can only, in real terms, incorporate Taiwan into the “Western Economic Zone across the Taiwan Strait” and blend Taiwan into Fujian, as intended by the Beijing leadership and stipulated in China’s 12th 5-year plan. In the words of an interviewee in the Chinese authorities, the ECFA “serves as an effective tool to enhance the formation of a ‘one China’ political identity and to suppress separatist, independence movements’” (Yuan, 2012.p.7). Given that the RCEP is a China-centric trade bloc, the Green camp probably prefers the TPP to the RCEP. As in any democratic country, interests groups in Taiwan, organized or not, are likely to face import competition through trade liberalization which could be a hindrance to any FTA negotiation. Taiwan’s trade with and investment in China has generated disproportional gains, more to big businesses, less to small and medium enterprises, and perhaps undesirable income redistribution effects as well. More KMT constituents have benefitted than DPP’s (if any) from cross-strait economic integration. Hence, constituents of the two political camps tend to harbor divergent attitudes on further expansion of the ECFA and deeper economic integration with China.11 The Green camp has alleged that, consciously or unconsciously, the China leaning policy undertaken by the incumbent KMT government is leading to such a stage that it is impossible for 9 During the finals weeks of campaign for presidential election in March 2012, several tycoons who invested in China stood out to declare their supports on the “92 consensus” –a policy initiated by the KMT administration. Moreover, the Director of Taiwan Affairs Office, Deng Li-Ching, visited during the period of president election in 2012 and contacted many Taishangs down to county levels. After the election, Deng came to Taiwan to thank those Taishangs for their supports as well. 10 It is noted that EFCA was signed under the “92 consensus” and “one China, self-interpretation” with Cross Strait characteristic rather than the WTO framework. The Green camp is not so much against liberalization on trade with China, but it opposes to trade off Taiwan’s de facto autonomy with plausible economic benefits. 11 Traditionally, the KMT has been in alliance with the big business and high rank professionals whereas the DPP is more supported by the SMEs, the low-skill labor. 9 any future government to reverse course, thereby dimming the hope for creating a de jure independent Taiwan. Given income and political effects of economic liberalization with China, the Green camp would be alienated if the ruling KMT government prioritizes RCEP over TPP.12 Warranted or not, many in the Blue camp are wary of joining the TPP not that they necessarily oppose it, but that they thought such an attempt would antagonize Beijing and jeopardize the next round of negotiation for an expanded ECFA with China as well as the negotiation for membership in the RCEP. While the Green camp is wary of asymmetric dependency on China’s market, the Blue camp does not think that this is a problem at all.13 For them, the real worry is that someday, China may not want Taiwan to continuously depend on its market, meaning that Taiwan no longer matters that much to China politically, and economic incentives to lure Taiwan begin to evaporate. The Blue camp’s preference of RCEP over the TPP is evidenced by the incumbent government’s persistent efforts to sign the trade pact in service sector with China without prior consultation with the enterprises, the industrial associations in service and even the legislators of its own party. Other than partisan politics, the civic society groups in Taiwan have been actively engaged in public (including trade-related) policy debates. Human rights, labor, environment, and other groups have long advocated that labor and environment standards be incorporated into public policies. The TPP includes the labor standard regulations which will fulfill the five principles of the International Labor Organization whereas the RCEP has not included labor clauses in its negotiation agenda. The TPP is led by the U.S. which is undoubtedly a democratic country whereas RCEP is led by China which is an authoritarian regime. Various civic society groups in Taiwan will be more enthusiastic about, and lend more support to their government’s participation in, TPP negotiations than RCEP ones. II. 2. The “China factor” in pursuing the trade pacts 12 A survey conducted by Chiang et al showed that among those who identify themselves as Taiwanese, 78% support to sign FTA with the U.S., but only 39% with China. The Blue camp is much in favor of signing FTA with China than with the U.S. But it was just the opposite in the Green camp. See Chiang et al (2013). 13 A statement made by P.K. Chiang, the chairman of Straits Exchange Foundation Foundation on the signing of the ECFA in 2010 is “There is nothing wrong (for Taiwan) to depend on China’s market. What matters is that China does not want Taiwan to depend on its market. ” 10 Externally, the single most formidable hindrance for Taiwan to ink free trade agreements is the omnipresent “China factor.” That China has minimal tolerance for Taiwan’s presence in international arena and for other countries’ assistance to help Taiwan to secure its place in the sun is too self-evident to warrant any elaboration here. It suffices for us to specify China’s preference order when it comes to Taiwan’s pursuit of FTAs. China's stand on this issue is as follows: first, expand ECFA which will further incorporate Taiwan into its orbit economically in the short term and political in the longer term; 14 second, delay its reply to Taiwan’s aspiration to join the RCEP, 15 then allow Taiwan to negotiate into RCEP only after its scheduled completion in 2015 under China's terms ;16 third, prevent Taiwan from flirting with the TPP by demonizing it as a device to contain China's economic and political influence, though the U.S. has repeatedly declared it is not, and if China cannot prevent Taiwan from bidding for TPP's membership, then it probably will try to draw some red line for the US which is the leading player of the TPP. Considering internal and external constraining factors, Taiwan does not seem to have a path of least resistance, as either pursuit is an uphill battle. It would then make sense for Taiwan to keep all the door opens, pursuing both the TPP and the RCEP, and indeed more bilateral FTAs with other economies as well. II.3. Sequencing order of applying for the TPP and RCEP Can Taiwan kill the two birds with one stone? Will the two pursuits be compatible or cross-cutting? First of all, one has to understand that pursing both the TPP and the RCEP does not necessarily mean Taiwan can officially apply for both memberships simultaneously; the sequencing order of application is dictated 14 Taiwan’s asymmetric trade dependency on China’s market, unless diversified by multiple trade pacts with its other major trading partners, would provide China with its leverage to infiltrate Taiwan’s elector politics. Any political party and politician running for public office cannot antagonize the interest groups benefitted from trade with and invest in China. It will limit the range of Taiwan’s ultimate political choice in its relation with China. 15 The incumbent ruling party, the Kuomintang (KMT) honorary chairman Wu Bao-Hsiung met with China’s president Xi Jianping on June 13, 2013, and expressed Taiwan’s aspiration of joining regional economic integration. Xi replied that it can be incorporated into the Cross Strait negotiation. It raise a great of controversies in partisan politics because Wu used “one China” framework on Cross Strait relation. Many regarded that the KMT moved from the “92 consensus” and “ One China, self-interpretation”, which at least intend to sell domestically that is the Republic of China in its mindset to “ one China” framework under which Taiwan is part of China. 16 Former Minister of Commerce Chen Der-Ming, now the president of the Association for Relations across the Taiwan Straits announced at the press conference on the 18th party congress of the Chinese Community Party on November 14, 2014. 11 by the application procedure and membership requirements for the trade pacts. The following reality check list helps to find a road map for Taiwan’s bids. 1. The TPP has an open admission policy for APEC members that are interested in joining, 17 whereas the RCEP mainly recruits those which have already FTA with the ASEAN as a group such as ASEAN plus Australia, China, India, Korea, Japan and New Zealand. Note that India is not even a member of the APEC. 2. ASEAN as a group is more interested in consolidating various FTA plus 1 and, in screening various RCEP applicants, will give priority to those that already have signed FTAs with the ASEAN. Moreover, China’s Minister of Commerce declared that the RCEP is not considering any new applicant until the negotiation is completed as noted before. 3. There is a double eligibility criterion for any country to join the TPP which includes the approvals from both individual member state and the TPP as a group. The sequencing order of pursuing the TPP and the RCEP probably is primarily shaped by the external factors of multilateral trade negotiations rather than domestic policy priorities. Taiwan can only prepare to apply, rather than apply, for entering the RCEP now, as the door is temporarily shut till the RCEP agreement is inked in 2015 by the founding members. As a member of APEC forum, Taiwan’s chance of being invited to the TPP talk is high, and it can be exploited right away. In 2012, Taiwan was the 11th-largest U.S. trading partner which was ranked higher than most those countries that the U.S. has signed FTAs, except for Canada, Korea and Mexico.18 Taiwan was the sixth-largest foreign holder of U.S. Treasury securities at $199 billion by the end of 2012. Taiwan’s quest for institutionalizing its trade liberalization with its trade partners in the region may coincide with U.S. “pivot to Asia”. If the US supports Taiwan’s bid,19 many of the other 11 negotiating parties probably can be persuaded to give Taiwan 17 Colombia’s application for TPP membership was rejected because it is not a member of the APEC. It is noted that the trade data has does not fully reflect the actual significance of the U.S.-Taiwan trade; U.S. imports from Taiwan in 2012 were $38.9 billion. However, U.S. export orders placed with Taiwanese firms in that year were $107.2 billion. The gap is due to the outsourcing and offshore production of Taiwanese firms, especially in China, see Kan and Morison (2013, p.38). 19 A pending bill in the US House of Representative, the H.R. 419 has a section which recommends that the U.S. government should invite Taiwan to join the TPP and sign a US-Taiwan FTA. 18 12 a chance, assuming that China is not too ferocious about the tricky moniker issue (discussed below). II.4.Bilateral FTAs with dual membership countries first Given the internal and external political realities, one feasible approach is for Taiwan to solicit more bilateral FTAs with those countries which have dual memberships in both the TPP and the RCEP. There are seven countries which belong to both: Australia, Brunei, Japan, Malaysia, New Zealand, Singapore and Vietnam. When more and more FTAs are signed with those countries which have dual memberships in the two blocs, it would be more conducive for Taiwan to join either or both. Bilateral FTA talks with individual ASEAN members, especially on the peninsular side of the organization, are something that Taiwan can initiate without anybody’s approval, though ‘the China factor’ may make it difficult to conclude these talks. II.5. Political dividends of FTAs Wallace (1982) argued that any format of economic integration, be it a FTA or a custom union, is basically a political establishment. For Taiwan, FTAs may come with some political dividends, if it can join under a proper name. Taiwan may be able to present itself as a negotiating party in the TPP under the name of “Chinese Taipei” (the so-called Asia Development Bank formula, which is also used in Taiwan’s ascension to the APEC) rather than the “Custom Territory of Taiwan, Penghu, Kinmen and Matsu” (CTTPKM), which is used in the WTO. The ADB formula, Chinese Taipei, connotes an official title for a Chinese national government with a capital in Taipei. The WTO formula is referred to a custom region, an economic jurisdictional unit that is clearly separate from China’s. China might have qualms with Taiwan using either formula for the TPP bid. Of the two formulae, the WTO one appears to be a lesser evil for China, as it denigrates Taiwan as an economic zone, while the ADB one puts Taiwan more or less on an equal footing with China. China being an outsider of the TPP negotiating body, and APEC membership being honored in the TPP talk, Taiwan stands a good chance defending its “Chinese Taipei” moniker, if it chooses to use this name. 13 Assuming that Taiwan under the banner of “Chinese Taipei” succeeds in joining the TPP within the next two years, it will be awkward, if not hard, for China to prevent Taiwan from using the same name in its application for admission to the RCEF in 2015. Should China insist that Taiwan use its WTO name, China could be roundly criticized for inconsistency and ‘snobbishness’ (China would ‘be snubbing’ TPP members, as well as ADB members), and China would be offending even the Blue camp in Taiwan, jeopardizing the prospect of further expanding the ECFA, and pushing Taiwan away from the RCEP and toward the TPP.20 Taiwan’s recent trade pact with New Zealand (ANZTEC) is a good start because New Zealand has dual membership in TPP and RCEP. The ongoing negotiation of trade pact with Singapore (ASTEP) is another big plus when it is completed. Taiwan’s pursuit for bilateral FTAs with those which have dual memberships in RCEP and TPP will not compromise or jeopardize its chance to be a negotiating party for either or both the TPP and the RCEP. On the contrary, it could help to create a window of opportunities to join both and enables Taiwan to kill two birds with one stone. III. What if Both Doors Remain Shut? While Taiwan should hope for the best, it should also prepare for the worst. The invitation from either the TPP or the RCEP to Taiwan may be slow in coming. The ‘China factor’ may push political cost of joining either trade pact far beyond what Taiwan’s domestic partisan politics could bear.21 The worst scenario for Taiwan is to find insurmountable high entry barriers to the negotiation rooms of the two trade blocs. If neither the TPP nor the RCEF is beyond the reach of Taiwan, will Taiwan be continuously marginalized? 20 A survey conducted by Wang in 2011 showed that when asked which name they prefer under PRC's pressure (which would make the use of either Taiwan or ROC impossible), then 4.6% would find Taiwan, China acceptable, 52.1% for Chinese Taipei, 9.7% could accept either Chinese Taipei or Taiwan, China, 28.5% would accept neither. See T.Y. Wang et al 2011 21 If China insisted on a full implementation of the ECFA and a political negotiation is need for Taiwan to join its FTAs with other countries, domestic partisan politics may reverse the negotiation of the next round of ECFA negotiations because it will polarize the society which has a great majority to remain the “status quo” whatever one perceives it. 14 The formation of TPP or RCEP may divert trade away from Taiwan if it is barred from joining the club. A study by Petri et al (2011) shows that trade diversion effect caused by the TPP to the exclusion of Taiwan would cost Taiwan a welfare loss of 0.2% of its baseline GDP in 2020. The welfare lost for a Taiwan excluded from the RCEP would be 0.95%. Should both the TPP and the RCEP leave Taiwan out in the cold, the combined welfare loss for this orphan would be 1.05% of its baseline GDP (Petri et al, 2011, Table 7), a nightmare figure indeed.22 It should be noted that the model simulation by Petri et al is based on the assumption that both the TPP and the RCEP are fully established without Taiwan’s participation and that Taiwan has signed no other bilateral or multilateral FTAs. The fact that Taiwan has recently signed the ANZTEC with New Zealand, has been negotiating with Singapore for a FTA (the ASTEP), and may go after FTAs with those countries with dual membership in the TPP and the RECP means that the worst scenario projected Petri et al can be avoided. III.1. Multiple bilateral FTAs to reach the near hub-ness If Taiwan can sign multiple bilateral FTAs (which can take many formats and are broadly referred as “economic cooperation agreements” or ECAs) with its trade partners,23 then the above-mentioned trade diversion effect created by the two emerging trade blocs can be mitigated. In the hub-spoke model of economic integration, Baldwin (2004) argued that small economy can reach the status of near hub-ness by emulating the following three models. The first is the Mexican model where a small economy not only signs a FTA with large economies (the U.S. and Canada), but also inks bilateral trade pacts with other small economies in its neighborhood (Latin American and Caribbean countries). The second is the EFTA model where small economies outside a sizable and growing trade and economic bloc (the European Union) set up their own shop (the European Free Trade Association). The third is the Singapore model where a small economy forges FTAs with as many trade partners far and near as possible. If both doors to the 22 It is noted that Petri et al (2011) did not include Japan in the TPP in their model simulation because Japan was yet to decide then. Moreover, one should note that model simulations on the impacts of FTAs are based on the assumption that the tariff reductions will be fully implemented. Hence, the simulation results could be deviate from the probable actual performances. 23 Taiwan’s Ministry of Economic Affairs defines an ECA as “an agreement signed by two or more economies for promotion of trade activities and economic integration with each other by reducing tariffs and fees, as well as by eliminating other trade barriers for goods and services.” see www.moea.gov.tw. 15 RCEP and the TPP will be slammed to Taiwan, then Taiwan should adopt both the Mexican and Singaporean models to not only escape marginalization, but also try to attain a near hub-ness status in the Asia Pacific region (Chow, 2013 a). Like Singapore, Taiwan certainly has set its eyes on many possible bilateral FTAs. If excluded from both the TPP and the RCEP, can Taiwan find a large, alternative trade bloc to mingle with? III.2.Looking beyond regional horizon: The Pacific Alliance An emerging trade bloc named the Pacific Alliance which includes Colombia, Costa Rica, Peru, Chile and Mexico with several observers from Japan, Canada, New Zealand, Panama, Guatemala and Spain, appears to be a promising alternative. The five member states of the Pacific Alliance accounted for one half of export and 36% of total GDP in Latin America. It is the 8th largest trade blocs in the world, and its total export in 2010 was $445 billion, almost 60% more than what Mercosur (Southern Cone Common Market), which is the main economic bloc in Latin America, exported in the same year. The Pacific Alliance, which is also the third pathway identified by the ABAC (the APEC Business Advisory Council) toward FTAAP, could be an alternative avenue for Taiwan to break its increasing isolation from an increasingly integrated East Asian economy. A bit like the Third Way, the Pacific Alliance does not have a hegemonic member and seems to be beyond the radar screen of the US or China. A study by Hsu (2013) showed that the full implementation of the Pacific Alliance without Taiwan could reduce its GDP by 0.39% to 0.51%, social welfare by $ 483 million to $ 1360 million under comparative static and dynamic model simulations respectively. Meanwhile Taiwan’s export will be reduced by $ 514 million to $ 741 million, and its terms of trade will deteriorate by 0.19% to 0.18% (see the third column on Table 1 below). But if Taiwan can join the Pacific Alliance, its total GDP will increase by 0.37%, social welfare will increase by $ 989 million, export will increase by $419 million, import will increase by $ 801 million and its terms of trade will improve by 0.17% (not shown in Table 1). The impact of the Pacific Alliance on Taiwan’s economy is too sizable to ignore. One additional reason to explore the possibility of entering the Pacific Alliance is that 16 Latin American and Caribbean is the home to the last significant bloc of countries that still maintain formal ties with Taiwan. The opportunity provided by the Pacific Alliance should be exploited before China seals more investment commitments and gains more soft power in Central America.24 Table 1: The impacts of major trade pacts on Taiwan’s Economy under comparative Static ( I) and Dynamic Scenarios ( II) TPP RCEP Pacific Alliance CJK FTA TTIP * Major trade pacts I II I II I II I II I II Nominal GDP (%) -0.54 -0.70 -1.51 -1.90 -0.39 -0.51 -1.27 -1.57 -0.49 -0.65 Social welfare ( $ million) -832 -2097 -2292 -5536 -483 -1360 -1772 -4316 -585 -1817 Export ($ million) -784 -1328 -2283 -3571 -514 -741 -1626 -2524 -517 -1006 Import ($ million) -1538 -1944 -4295 -5313 -942 -1154 -3167 -3867 -1048 -1512 Terms of trade (%) -0.31 -0.27 -0.89 -0.85 -0.19 -0.18 -0.68 -0.64 -0.21 -0.19 * Trans-atlantic Trade and Investment Partnership Source: Hsu (2013) IV. Economic Re-structuring Holds the Key Irrespective of which scenario is going to play out, Taiwan should try to upgrade its industrial structure and enhance its international competitiveness in the global market. Aimed at “elimination of all exemptions on tariffs,” the TPP has mandated any potential applicant including Taiwan to reduce their protective sectors in all industries including agriculture, manufacture and service sectors. Hence, Taiwan needs to re-adjust its economic structure to be 24 Reportedly, there are, at least, five states have been soliciting diplomatic ties with China. 17 ready for further economic integration. If Taiwan will be left out of major free trade bloc, it is equally necessary to shake off its remaining protective shell, overhaul its industrial structure, and improve its competitiveness in all sectors. IV.1. Agriculture: An economically weak but political strong sector A brief look at the tariff schedule on imports from the world, TPP-12 nations, and RCEP nations on Table 2 below showed that Taiwan has high tariff on imports of vegetable/fruit, fish, meats, milk, sugar, beverage/ tobacco and other agricultural products. On manufacturing products, wearing apparels and motor vehicles are the two most protective sectors. 25 Since the TPP negotiations are committed to setting “zero tariff “on all commodities including agriculture, Taiwan will have to prepare to face up to this challenge, especially in the area of agricultural imports. One should also realize that the TPP include three major agricultural exporters in the world; Australia, New Zealand and the U.S. The issue of “beef and pork’” import from the U.S. had recently triggered an intensive political battle in Taiwan, and caused a great deal of tension between Taipei and Washington, and postponed their TIFA (Trade and Investment Framework Agreement) talks. One can only expect more policy debate and fights within Taiwan over its agricultural liberalization, as the train of FTA talks moves on. If the TPP accomplishes its scheduled tariffs reduction on agriculture without discount, then Taiwan would need to resolve its domestic obstacles on liberalization of agricultural trade. This is a contentious issue on the political economy of trade which deserves for a full analysis that is beyond the scope of this study. Table 2: Tariff Schedule on Taiwan’s Imports from the world, TPP-12 nations, and RCEP area sector 1 pdr 2 wht 3 gro 4 vege,fruit 5 osd 6 c_b From RCEP(%) Global (%) From TPP12 (%) 0.12 0.00 0.00 6.49 6.50 6.49 1.59 1.60 1.33 17.23 17.16 17.36 3.89 3.88 3.24 0.00 0.00 0.00 25 The tariff rates are the trade-weighted average based on GTAP 8.1. The authors would like to thank Bo-Xian Hsu for compiling the tariff schedule. 18 7 pfb 8 ocr 9 ctl 10 oap 11 rmk 12 wol 13 frs 14 fish 15 coa 16 oil 17 gas 18 omn 19 cattle meat 20 other meat 21 vol 22 milk 23 pcr 24 sugar 25 other food 26beve.tobac. 27 tex 28 wearing apparel 29 lea 30 lum 31 ppp 32 p_c 33 crp 34 nmm 35 i_s 36 nfm 37 fmp 38 mor.veh 39 otn 40 ele 41 ome 42 omf 0.02 5.70 3.11 5.40 0.00 na 1.39 1.74 15.16 0.00 1.21 0.11 0.30 1.43 0.83 15.74 0.00 1.07 0.00 0.32 0.00 5.63 3.57 3.80 0.00 1.40 0.62 14.77 0.00 1.12 0.00 0.29 15.27 15.56 15.55 19.50 19.82 19.74 2.69 11.19 0.34 10.43 17.68 11.28 7.59 2.33 11.31 0.00 10.95 17.34 11.59 7.72 1.73 11.24 0.00 10.96 17.99 11.37 7.63 11.31 11.28 11.37 4.23 2.19 0.09 2.59 2.96 5.88 0.36 1.01 6.09 12.06 3.90 1.85 3.15 3.43 3.91 2.95 0.09 3.13 2.98 5.94 0.37 1.01 6.02 13.30 3.74 1.94 3.25 3.71 4.56 2.36 0.07 2.75 2.99 5.85 0.33 0.98 6.07 11.38 4.59 1.71 3.14 3.40 19 0.00 5.96 4.21 6.24 Source: calculated from the GTAP version 8.1 by Hsu IV.2. Service: a socio-political complicated sector for mature economy There are trade barriers in Taiwan’s service sector as well. In general, the first wave of development in service sector occurred in the traditional services which comprised wholesale and retail trade, hotels and restaurants, real estate, transport, personal services, and public administration. The second wave of development that occurred at the stage of high income level was dominated by modern services including information and communication, finance, and professional business services (Eichengreen and Gupta, 2009). From Lee and Itakura ( 2013), the tariff equivalents of non-tariff trade barriers on service sector in Taiwan is as follows; 10.8% in construction and utilities, 28.8% in trade, 12.6% in sea transport, 25.4% in airport, 26.1% in other transport, 23.6% in communication, 27.5% in financial services, 29.1% in government services and 26.7% in other private services.26 The TPP program includes liberalization of trade in service. Understandably, most of the TPP-12 nations, especially the U.S. and Japan, have a strongly competitive edge on trade in service. If Taiwan is to participate in the TPP, then it has to prepare well to open its service sector. Trade in service involves a) cross border consumption, b) cross border supply, c) commercial presence where the provider establishes a facility in the client’s country (i.e., investment and d) the temporary movement of personnel. Each of these four aspects involves complex socio-cultural factors between the service providers and consumers, a process that is much complicated than liberalization of merchandise trade. The trade pact in service that Taiwan recently signed with China under the umbrella of ECFA is already sparking a massive policy fight. Ratification of this pact is being put on hold. One can only wonder if Taiwan will be prepared to liberalize its service industry to face world competition. A closer look at this sector is in order here. Regarding the trade pact on service with China, Taiwan does have some competitive edge on the high end side of service industry where skills matter more 26 For comparison, the figures in the U.S. are 6.8% in trade, sea transport, air transport, other transport and communication, 7.8% and other private services and 6.3% in government service. 20 than labor cost, but is less competitive on the low end side where labor cost matters more than skills. The recent service trade pact is a bit biased for Taiwan, mitigating the cost of liberalization that Taiwan is expected to bear. If future service trade pacts will be truly symmetric, giving equal treatment to both sides, those in the high end of service trade will benefit from, whereas the less skilled will be adversely affected by liberalization of service trade with China. In terms of political spectrum of the constituents, those owners, managers and service persons in high end service (engineering service, high tech gadget testing and packaging, software development, financial product designs and transactions, fashion and cosmetic marketing, etc) are more in line with the KMT government for the expansion of ECFA into the service sector, while low end service people (beauty salons, transportation yeomen, etc) are, in contrast, more attuned to the Green camp. Those who oppose the trade pact in service with China are not necessarily from the Green camp. These opponents are against any further trade liberalization agreement with China for fear of opening the gate for China’s investors to infiltrate the Taiwan society, a development that, in the Green camp’s words, would “generate significant legacies on Taiwanese society”.27 To the opponents, not only would economic benefits of free trade pact in services accrue to big business and high skilled employees only, this service agreement, more importantly, would incur a high socio-political cost. Moreover, most investment from China are directly or indirectly sourced at or affiliated with huge state-owned enterprises whereas 99.7% of the 93,500 firms in Taiwan’s service sector are owned and operated by SMEs.28 China-invested service firms in Taiwan will be either monopolies or oligopolies whereas those local SMEs in Taiwan are highly competitive and can easily go out of business. Asymmetrical industrial organization and market power between the Chinainvested and local enterprises in service industry kept many service firms in Taiwan wary of and worry about unfair market competition once the door to China is open. 27 Other arguments against the trade in service are the lack of transparency, no advanced assessment prior to the negotiation, no prior consultations with the enterprises and industrial association and the legislative branch even with those belong to the KMT. 28 The total number of business firms in service industry is 93,500. Among them, only 2791 are large scale and the rest of the 92,809 firms are small scale with an average of employing 4.2 people per firm. In terms of skill intensity, 86% of the firms in service industry are classified as “no knowledge-intensive” industry. Data from Director General of Budget, Accounting and Statistics at www.dgbas.gov.tw. 21 The socio-political implications of liberalizing trade in service with the U.S. are quite different from those with China. High skilled services are leery of Taiwan’s signing on to the TPP, a bloc that includes the U.S., hereby opening up the floodgate for formidable American high services, while low end services in Taiwan are nonchalant about such an agreement. Moreover, Taiwanese people favor American investors more than those from China as the survey by Chiang et al (2013) indicated. Admitting chain stores of a fast food giant, McDonald restaurant caused fewer problems than licensing a single Peking duck house from China. The reason is simple and clear: the U.S. has no interest in claiming sovereignty on Taiwan but Beijing does. Considering the inevitable resistance from the interest groups for liberalization in finance, communication and transport services under the TPP, the government may use the leverage of external forces to induce more competition abroad through trade liberalization under various FTAs. Of course, many social remedy policies compensating the disadvantaged groups are needed to reach the “Pareto Optimum” of trade liberalization. IV.3. Three points on Industrial Restructuring Comprehensive study on industrial restructure for globalized trade liberalization is beyond the scope of this paper. But three major directions are highly recommended. a. First, promote Taiwan’s functions in the global production network and increase the value-added in the global supply chain. b. Second, re-structure production method from OEM (original equipment manufacturing) to newly innovative production methods such as the application of the “3 D printing” to manufacturing sector. c. Third, exploit the untapped trade potential by identifying the niche products in niche markets IV.3a. Branding and Enhancing value-added in OEM by functional and processing upgrading 29 Stan Shih’s famous “Smiling Curve” shows the value-added at various stage of production in ICT (information and communication 29 This section is derived from Chow ( 2013 b) 22 technology) sectors. Since the past decade, there is a significant development in the flattening out of the “smiling curve” shown in Figure 2 as argued by Chow (2013b). The dots on the right-hand side of the curve represent those firms with their own brands, as reported on Table 2, whereas those on the left-hand side are firms such as Acer, TSMC, etc. which engaged in chip designs. Figure 2: Breaking Through the Threshold by process and functional upgrading Source: author (Chow, 2013b) Table 3: Major brand names from Taiwanese manufactures Company Acer Brand Name Acer Products Notebook PC 23 Asustek ASUS, ASRock PC, PC motherboard, ODD, PDA, cellular phone BenQ BenQ Notebook PC, MP3 player, LCD TV Compal Palmax, Optorite Cellular phone, ODD Elite - PC motherboard, mini PC FIC Afina Mini PC Gigabyte AXPER PC motherboard, mini PC, notebook PC, LCD TV Hon Hai Foxconn PC motherboard hTC Dopod PDA Inventec Appliance OKWAP Cellular phone Mitac Mio Smartphone Quanta Nu, Gia ODD, cellular phone, display monitor, LCD TV Tatung Elio MP3 player TPV AOC Display monitor Sou rce: Aut hor (Ch ow, 201 3b ) L iter atur e on global value-added chain (GVC) suggests that there are two approaches to moving upward on the smiling curve: process upgrading and functional upgrading. Humphrey (2004) argued that once firms enter the GVC such as OEM, suppliers would gain valuable lessons from their partnerships with buyers. Specifically, they would be able to upgrade product development. In spite of the threshold on the smiling curve-this may become an obstacle for advancement, many Taiwanese firms managed to exploit their second mover advantage by expanding the bottom of the “smiling curve” through advancement in processing technology and product development. Hence, many Taiwanese firms made significant progress in processing technology, as reflected by the number of patents granted by the U.S. In terms of patents per capita, Taiwan was ranked third in 1997-2001, after only the U.S. and Japan. In 2009, Taiwan held 287 patents per million people, ranking it first among 139 countries, higher than Japan (279; rank 2) and the U.S. (262; rank 3). Among those patents granted to Taiwan, a great majority was in processing technology.30 On functional upgrading, one can find that many Taiwanese foundries and ICT industries have been moving vertically by engaging in the advanced stage of design and branding. Several firms served both as OEM manufacturers and IC designers. This tendency would increase the “value- added” on the segmented Data source from U.S. Patent and Trade Mark office at the website at: http://www.uspto.gov/. But it is noted that Taiwan still run into trade deficit in terms of trade in technology because much of its patent rights were in processed technology which could hardly market to foreign firms. 30 24 global production process, and improve the profit margin of Taiwanese enterprises. Taiwan should transform its role from what is being performed Faxcom to Tobisba does in Apple’s i-pad.31 On the other hand, the entry barriers of branding are high for most Taiwanese firms; In addition to the requisites of manufacturing, those barriers include innovative R&D and marketing channels, which impose their own cultural barrier as well (W.Chu, 2009).Taiwanese government did not support the branding of national champions of industry, as what the Korean government did to its chaebol conglomerates. Nevertheless, some Taiwanese firms such Acer, Asustek, and BenQ have developed their own brand names, as Table 3 reports. Though the extent of branding in Taiwan is much smaller than in Korea, which has its chaebol conglomerates, it demonstrates that Taiwan has followed a non-statist model of branding development. The progress in chip design, the specialization in wafer fabrication, and the brands of some firms show that the “smiling curve” has been flattening out in Taiwan in recent years. Taiwan would need to further increase its value-added and enhance its profit margin in the global supply chain to slow down the industrial migration and avoid further hollowing out of its domestic industries IV.3b. Innovate new production technology The other way to improve Taiwan’s industrial structure lies in innovation of production technology. While sector–specific industrial promotion policies undertaken in the past decades cannot be replicated the new socio-political environment,32 a more generic method of nurturing technology innovation is highly doable. One example is for Taiwan to ride the next big wave of 3D printing industrial revolution, which is based on computer design and additive manufacturing and which is what the U.S. is betting on to overhaul its economy to create high value jobs. The “3D printing” manufacturing technique can grossly reduce the time it takes from the drawing board to prototype making and testing. It has potential of revolutionizing the mode of production, transcending the Henry Ford type of large scale manufacturing of the standardized product, and ushering in an innovative, diversified, flexible, and diversified type of manufacturing in meeting quickly 31 Faxcom is the largest manufacturing sub-contractor whereas Tobishiba provided many strategic components for Apple i-pods. The profit margin in the Video i-pod 30 G is only 2% for the Taiwanese firm whereas it is 12% for Japanese firm. See Dedrick et al ( 2008). 32 For those who are nostalgia about the super performance of industrialization in the past, it is noted that there is a waning of the “developmental State” after the lift of the Martial Law in 1987. See Chow (2011). 25 changing market demand and satisfying a wide range of consumer references. This new mode of production is precisely what Taiwanese firms are good at. The 3D industrial revolution can transform Taiwan's industrial structure and enhance its position in global production chain to the extent that it can still do well in the world economy even without the benefits conferred by FTAs. Of course, just like microwave oven in the kitchen, the “3D printing” production technique can be complement with but not to substitute the long existing production techniques for mass production in all manufacturing industries. While the role of government on industrial policies is highly contentious, its role to internalize the externality to avoid the “ coordination failure” for multiple equilibriums along the line of the theory of “Big Push” is highly recommended. For economic transformation, the government can serve as a coordinator to transform the economic structure from the conventional OEM to newly innovative production technologies. Industrial policies using the government-funded enterprises to support sector-specific development are no longer regarded as desirable. New approaches to accelerating industrial transformation now center on “functional” support in R & D and incentives for research institutes to amplify technology spillover effects. Venture capital, be it private or public or joint, can be a good vehicle as it can socialize the risk of creating new production technology. The government in Taiwan has actually begun to use this device to promote the biotech and biomedical research and product development. IV.3c. Exploit the untapped trade potential: Identifying the niche products in niche markets Another potential big point is for Taiwan to exploit its untapped trade potentials by identifying yet-to-develop niche products in niche markets. Based on the TradeSim model which simulated the export performance for Taiwan’s exports, Chow and Ciuriak (2008) calculated the gap between the actual and the potential exports from a modified gravity model simulations. Export potentials for Taiwan were estimated for 15 sectors and 30 major trading partners in the world.33 Export potentials are interpreted as “potentials within the specified model set-up”.34 They 33 The top 15 sectors were ranked by the current export performances in 2002-2003. Obviously, the four sectors omitted were mostly in forestry / fishing products, mining/quarrying, petroleum and recycling. See Appendix 1 for more details. 34 “ The export potential is calculated on the basis of separate regressions for all 19 sectors, applying equation [1] (the variable ij Geo was only applied to sector P1 and P2). 26 represent the “relative trade potentials”, which are “independent of the absolute value of exports”. Hence, “highly untapped potential does not imply that this potential is high in absolute terms but that is high compared to the current export”. In spite of the caveats, 35 simulation results from TradeSim, in conjunction with a deeper sector-specific analysis, could capture the trade complementarities between countries. Export potentials for Taiwan were estimated for 15 sectors and 30 major trading partners in the world.36 The results are reported in Appendix I. Relative trade potential in each sector is ranked into 5 classifications in an ascending order of trading opportunities: 1. very strong current trade that is above predicted value; 2. strong current trade, that is also above the predicted value; 3. predicted values equal to current values or are low; X =αi k: +αj k +β0k +β1k D +β2k Tariff +β3k Border i j +β4k Language i j +β 5kConflict i j +β6k Geo i j +ε ( 1) where: i : the exporting country j: the importing country k: sector Xijk : trade in sector k from country i to country j Dij: distance between i and j Borderij: i and j are neighboring countries (=1) or not (=0) Tariffijk: bilateral market access measure (for trade from i to j in sector k) Languageij: bilateral measure of common language Conflictij: bilateral measure of conflict ij Geo : bilateral measure of geographical location ik jk α ;α : multilateral resistance terms in form of fixed effects. For each exporting country i and importing country j, we calculate the predicted values ijk Xˆ for sector k, i.e. export potentials are equivalent to the within-sample predictions, which are obtained through separate sector regressions. As we used fixed effects in the estimation, the application of an ‘a posteriori’ fixed effect Fi (as in TradeSim2) for the calculation of trade potentials in order to adjust the trade potential from systematic effects is not necessary. Hence, the trade potential TPijk is simply given by: ijk ijk TP = Xˆ .It is important to notice that the results obtained represent relative trade potentials, as the gravity specification employed is dependent on the sample specification. Hence, potentials should be understood as potentials within the specified model set-up, i.e. within the context of the specified 132 exporting and 154 importing countries, controlling for the variables included in [5] according to the sector analyzed, and the multilateral resistance terms. Any variation in the model or sample specification would necessarily entail different results”. 35 Export potentials are limited by the gravity model which is constructed on a general equilibrium model; hence it does not capture the dynamic effects and cross-industry linkages. Secondly, the model is very sensitive to changes in the sample due to the inclusion of multilateral resistance terms. Thirdly, the impacts of FDI on export were ignored due to paucity of bilateral data of FDI and finally, trade complementarity between countries is not sufficiently taken into account in the gravity model. 36 The top 15 sectors were ranked by the current export performances in 2002-2003. The four omitted sectors were forestry and fishing products, mining and quarrying, petroleum, and recycling. 27 4. untapped trade potential; and 5. highly untapped trade potential. In terms of trading partners and considering aggregate trade flows, the main simulation results are as follows: Taiwan has high untapped export potential in Korea, and moderate untapped potential in Japan, Malaysia and the Philippines. Predicted values are either in line with current levels or low for Hong Kong, Indonesia, Singapore, Thailand and the United States. Taiwan has strong current trade above the predicted values for China and Vietnam. Taiwan’s strong export performance in China and Vietnam may reflect the importance of Taiwan’s outward FDI in these destination economies in inducing exports. TradeSim model has two sets of sample countries where FDI data are available at aggregate (29 exporting and 165 importing countries) or disaggregate levels (7 exporting and 65 importing countries). Since the model of simulations for Taiwan’s export potentials does not belong to either set, the simulation results reported here may underestimate Taiwan’s trade potential by ignoring the contribution of its outward FDI on export potentials. As one can find from those tables in Appendix I, the significant untapped potential sectors and markets from the simulation can be summed up as follows: In the U.S. market, Taiwan has relative trade potentials in coke, petroleum and nuclear fuel, but the absolute potential probably lies in chemicals and chemical products. Taiwan’s trade potential in Hong Kong barely exists in one (residual) sector. Malaysia and the Philippines are two promising markets for Taiwan’s electrical and electronic products. For Japanese markets, there is room for expansion for Taiwan’s precision machinery, electric and electronic products, and to a less extent, textile goods. These simulation results help Taiwan to identify high value destination for its free trade negotiators, and, should no FTA is inked, the promise land for Taiwanese external trade. V.Summary and Conclusions Along with South Korea, Taiwan used to be a super exporter and a most often cited model of export-led industrialization before the advent of the spaghetti bowl of FTAs. During the past two decades or so, the two stellar economies seem to have parted the company, South Korea emerging as a member of the big league 28 in quite a number of mainstay industries (especially electronics, motor vehicles, and high-end, specialized vessels) and a much sought after partner for free trade agreements, Taiwan in contrast becoming an almost forgotten player at the risk of being marginalized, though still doing well in a number of industries (LCD, ICs, and …). Thanks to the “competitive trade liberalization’ between the TPP and the RCEF, Taiwan sees a glimpse of hope of returning to regional FTA blocs, as well as going for more bilateral FTAs. Given domestic partisan politics and external harsh reality (the whim of China, an economic power house), this study has contended that Taiwan cannot afford picking and choosing a regional FTA to join, but rather is obliged to knock on all doors that may be open to it. Prioritizing should not be on its menu. With fortuna and the support of TPP members, especially the U.S., Taiwan may be able to have a double play. But should Taiwan continue to be excluded from the two emerging free trade blocs, the TPP and the RCEF, it would not be the end of the world for Taiwan. The Pacific Alliance could be a good substitute, and an aggressive pursuit of bilateral FTAs can also keep Taiwan alive and kicking. Whatever scenario is going to unfold, Taiwan would be doing itself a big favor by overhauling its economic structure, with or without membership in major regional trade pacts. References Baldwin, Richard, 2004. The Spoke Trap: The Hub and Spoke Bilateralism in East Asian. Seoul: Korean Institute for International Economic Policy, CNEAC Research Series, 04-02. Cheng, Tun-Jen and Peter C.Y. Chow, 2013. “The Economic-Security Nexus in East Asia “ a paper to be presented at the American Association for Chinese Studies at Rutgers University in New Brunswick, New Jersey on October 12-14, 2013. Chiang, Chung-fan. Et al, 2013. “ Individual Preferences for Trade Partners in Taiwan”. Economics and Politics. Vol.25.no.1. pp. 91-109. 29 Chow, Peter C.Y., 2011” Economy of Taiwan after Lifting the Martial Law: A Waning Developmental State?” In David Blunder (eds) “Taiwan since Martial Law”. University of California-Berkeley and National Taiwan University Press. pp. 573-602. Chow, Peter C.Y. 2013a. “The Emerging Trade Bloc across the Taiwan Strait in Regional and Global Perspective “in Peter Chow (eds). “ Economic Integration Across the Taiwan Strait, Global Perspective” Edward Elgar. Chow, Peter C.Y. 2013b.” Taiwan’s Industrial Policy to Cope with Globalization” A paper presented at the East Association for Taiwan Studies in Lyon, Paris, May. 2013 Chow, Peter C.Y, and Dan Ciuriak, 2008” Taiwan Untapped Trade Potential” A paper presented at the Taiwan Economic Association in Taipei, December. Chow, Peter C.Y and Bo-Xian Hsu, 2012. “The Impacts of Economic Liberalization and Globalization on Income Distribution in Taiwan, 1985-2010” a paper presented at the International Conference at SOAS, University of London, September. 2012 Chu, Wan-wen, 2009. “Can Taiwan’s second movers upgrade via branding?” Research Policy 38 . pp 1054–1065 Dedrick, Jason et al , 2008.” Who Profits from Innovation in Global Value Chains? A Study of the iPod and notebook PCs”. A paper prepared for the Sloan Industry Studies Annual Conference Boston, MA. May 2008. Eichengreen, Barry and Poonan Gupta. 2009. “The Two Waves of Service Sector Growth”. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 14968. Cambridge, MA: NBER. Hsu, Bo-Xian, 2013.” The Impacts of Major Trade Pacts on Taiwan’s Economy and Their consequences” APEC Newsletter. June . No. 165. Humphrey, J. 2004.” Upgrading in Global Value Chains”. Geneva: International Labor Organization. 30 Kan, Shirley and Wayne M. Morison, 2013, “U.S.-Taiwan Relationship: Overview of Policy Issues” Congressional Research Service. R41952. P.13-30. Kawai, Masahiro and Wignaraja, Ganeshan, 2009, “The Asian ‘Noodle Bowl’: Is it Serious?” Asian Development Bank Working Paper No. 136. Lee, H. and K. Itakura (2013). "FTA Sequencing and the Extent of Structural Adjustments: Trans-Pacific Track, Asian Track and EU-Asia-Pacific Integration." A paper presented at the Ninth Annual Conference of the Asia-Pacific Economic Association, Osaka University, July 27-28. Petri, Peter et al, 2011.” The Trans-Pacific Partnership Integration: A Quantative Assessment”. East-West Center working papers. No. 119. Wallace, William, 1982. “Economic Divergence in European Community.” In John M. Letiche (ed.). International Economic Policies and Their Theoretical Foundation. New York: Academic Press. pp. 183-223 Wang, T.Y. et al . 2011. "Taiwan's Expansion of International Space: opportunities and challenges," Journal of Contemporary China, February. Yuan, W. (June 2012). The Trans-Pacific Partnership and China's Corresponding Strategies . Washington, D.C.: A Freemen Briefing Report, Center for Strategic & International Studies. Appendix I: In the U.S. market, untapped export potential is identified in the following sectors: Sector Level of Exports in Share of Tariff level in 2002-2003 (USD Taiwan’s the destination billions) exports in that market sector Chemicals and 1.2 8.3% 0 to 5% chemical products Coke, petroleum 0.1 4.5% 0 to 5% products and nuclear fuel 31 As can be seen, while there is relative untapped trade potential in coke, petroleum products and nuclear fuel, the absolute level of trade potential is small. In chemical and chemical products, however, the scale of existing trade is sufficiently large to warrant exploration of whether in reality some market expansion is possible. In the Hong Kong market, untapped export potential is identified in only one sector: Sector Level of Exports in Share of Tariff level in 2002-2003 (USD Taiwan’s the destination billions) exports in that market sector Other manufacturing 0.3 8.0% 0 to 5% Tariffs do not, of course, pose a barrier in the Hong Kong market but the scale of Taiwan’s exports to Hong Kong in this sector is sufficiently low to excite little interest. In the Malaysian market, untapped export potential is identified in only one sector: Sector Level of Exports in Share of Tariff level in 2002-2003 (USD Taiwan’s the destination billions) exports in that market sector Electrical and electronic equipment 1.9 2.9% 0 to 5% This would appear to be one area where Taiwan could explore possibilities to expand exports through trade promotion. In the Philippines market, untapped trade potential is identified in: Sector Level of Exports in Share of Tariff level in 2002-2003 (USD Taiwan’s the destination billions) exports in that market sector Electrical and electronic equipment 0.9 1.3% 0 to 5% 32 Metal and metal products 0.1 1.0% 0 to 5% Taiwan faces low tariffs in these two sectors in the Philippines market but the scale of potential trade expansion would be interesting only in the case of electrical and electronic equipment. In the Japanese market, high untapped export potential is identified in three sectors: Sector Level of Exports in Share of Tariff level in 2002-2003 (USD Taiwan’s the destination billions) exports in that market sector Chemicals and chemical products 0.9 5.9% 0 to 5% Precision instruments 0.5 8.0% 0 to 5% Textiles, clothing and leather 0.3 2.8% 20 to 25% The first two sectors face low tariffs from zero to 5% but the textile/clothing/leather products sector faced relatively high tariffs in the sample period between 20% and 25%. In several other Japanese sectors, moderate untapped export potential is identified: Sector Level of Exports in Share of Tariff level in 2002-2003 (USD Taiwan’s the destination billions) exports in that market sector Electrical and electronic equipment 6.4 9.5% 0 to 5% Machinery and equipment 0.6 5.8% 0 to 5% Rubber and plastic products 0.4 8.7% 0 to 5% Motor vehicles and other transport equipment 0.4 7.0% 0 to 5% Wood and wood products 0.1 10.8% 0 to 5% Coke, petroleum products and nuclear 0.1 5.9% > 50% 33 fuel In each of these markets, Taiwan faces low tariffs from zero to 5% implying that it may not have yet fully exploited its trade potential. The scale of trade would point to electrical and electronic equipment as being the major sector on which to focus. In the Korean market, three sectors are identified as having high untapped trade potential: Sector Level of Exports in Share of Tariff level in 2002-2003 (USD Taiwan’s the destination billions) exports in that market sector Chemicals and chemical products 0.4 2.6% 5 to 10% Metal and metal products 0.2 1.7% 5 to 10% Machinery and equipment 0.1 1.3% 5 to 10% In all three sectors, Taiwan faces moderate tariffs from 5% to 10% which could represent a significant factor in diverting trade away from Taiwan. Taiwan also has moderate untapped trade potential in several other Korean markets. Sector Level of Exports in Share of Tariff level in 2002-2003 (USD Taiwan’s the destination billions) exports in that market sector Electrical and electronic equipment 2.8 4.2% 0 to 5% Metal and metal products 0.2 1.7% 5 to 10% Precision instruments 0.2 3.6% 5 to 10% Machinery and equipment 0.1 1.3% 5 to 10% Rubber and plastic products 0.04 1.0% 5 to 10% Food, beverages and tobacco 0.04 2.4% 35 to 40% Motor vehicles and other transport 0.02 0.5% 5 to 10% 34 equipment Wood and wood products 0.02 1.5% 5 to 10% Tariffs are an issue in most of these sectors, especially in the food, beverages and tobacco sector in which Taiwanese exporters face tariffs of 350%. The scale of existing trade in electrical and electronic equipment makes this an important sense on which to focus. In the Singapore market, five sectors are identified as having untapped trade potentials: Sector Level of Exports in Share of Tariff level in 2002-2003 (USD Taiwan’s the destination billions) exports in that market sector Chemicals and chemical products 0.2 1.4% 0 to 5% Metal and metal products 0.2 1.5% 0 to 5% Machinery and equipment 0.2 1.4% 0 to 5% Precision instruments 0.1 1.2% 0 to 5% Motor vehicles and other transport equipment 0.1 1.5% 0 to 5% As can been seen, the scale of trade is low despite low tariffs, implying little in the way of quantitatively significant gains in these sectors. 35