PDF Available - IPSA Online Paper Room
Transcription
PDF Available - IPSA Online Paper Room
Damien J. Wirths 1 A critical examination of the policymaking process and of the lawmakers’ motivation for evaluations A theoretical framework DAMIEN JAMES WIRTHS*1 Abstract: There is strong evidence showing the rise of a culture of public policy evaluation in Switzerland, and as a result, a huge amount of money is spent on more and more evaluations. It triggers the need to know how to best make use of this investment. Nevertheless, the existing literature on public policy evaluation is not able to satisfactorily explain why policymakers require mandatory evaluations only in certain cases. Recently, scholars, lawyers, and practitioners claim, under the label of evidence-based policy making, that efficiency evaluations are related to policymaking improvement and that it would be a panacea leading to better laws. However, evidence shows that most of the time evaluation results are not addressed to the policymaker and the legal basis of the evaluation (evaluation clause) is not precise enough to implement the evaluation. Using a game theoretic framework from the actors of the policymaking process, I consider the most important forms of institutionalized evaluation, the so-called evaluation clauses, to highlight the necessary conditions under which they have appeared. The solutions of the games yield two empirically testable hypotheses, distinguishing the policymakers’ willingness to adopt an evaluation clause. The policymaker’s motivation to evaluate the policy could be either to actually improve the policy efficiency (instrumental use of knowledge) or to expand their power and legitimacy (symbolic use of knowledge). The paper assesses how well the theory and hypotheses fit the actual “raison d’être” of evaluation clause, proposing a case study of Swiss policymaking process using several lines of cases. KEYWORDS: Evaluation, Legislature, Game theory, Policymaking. 1 * Phd Student at the Swiss Graduate School of Public Administration involved in the research project SynEval, funded by the Sinergia program of the Swiss National Science Foundation. SynEval analyzes the relationship between different attributes of political systems and the practice and institutionalization of policy evaluation. Therefore, SynEval addresses the fundamental questions of how policy evaluation in Switzerland is influenced by the Swiss political system, and how policy evaluation in turn influences the Swiss political system. These questions are answered with an innovative and fruitful research track, as attributes of policy evaluation are linked with policy, polity, and politics in a comprehensive approach. More information about SynEval: http://syneval.ch/index.php/en/ 2 Critical examination of lawmaker’s motivation for evaluations Introduction Evaluation of public policies is growing and evaluation is currently a well-established, systematic and institutionalized information instrument (Bussmann, 2008; Eliadis, Furubo, & Jacob, 2011; Mader, 1990). A key aspect is to consider the legal basis requiring mandatory evaluation, the most important form of evaluation institutionalization (Hans-Ulrich Derlien, 1998). Because evaluation is not a fixed term, I have to define that: The notion of ‘Evaluation clauses’ is introduced to describe a legal basis added since the draft or during the negotiation process into a law and asking for an evaluation of the impact of the public policy. It is an information instrument related to the implementation of public policy only focused on evaluation in a strict sense (FOJ, 2005) meaning the investigation of policy efficiency2 (Evaluation) – in contrast with other kinds of information instruments highlighting process efficiency (controlling) or providing statistics (monitoring) (FOJ, 2004, 2007). Evaluation is, above all, related to the causes of the social transformation (impact) and not only to the measure of effects produced by the law (outcomes). What happens after a bill becomes a law? Are legal dispositions implemented? What are the impacts and the outcome produced for a given law? Are the legislator’s goals reached? Following Luzius Mader, I consider these fundamental questions of public policy evaluation in a multidisciplinary framework named “legislative evaluation”, defined as a scientific analysis of the implementation and effects of laws (Mader, 1985, 1994). The evaluation clauses are considered as an indicator of legislative evaluation demand and their characteristic is to have been established without standards (FOJ, 2007). A recent study (Wirths 2014) has showed that the evaluation clauses can be classified into two categories according to their normative density: the weak clauses (very lacunar regarding the evaluation implementation) and the strong clauses (more precise regarding who has to evaluate what, when, under which criteria and to whom send the report). Most of the time, the clauses is introduced since the draft of the bill (FAO, 2011; Wirths, 2014). The aim of this paper is not to provide legislative evaluations but, on the one hand, to raise the question of the reasons why mandatory legislative evaluation is sometimes required, and sometimes not and, on the other hand, to identify the necessary 2 Excluding the analysis of human resources, IT, products and supply (FOJ, 2005). Damien J. Wirths 3 conditions explaining why strong or weak evaluation clauses are introduced. Despite a huge literature on the importance of public policy evaluation, little attention has been paid to the actual lawmaker’s motivations for evaluation. However, in Switzerland, a recent study from the Federal Audit Office highlighted several tricky findings. On the one hand, evaluation clauses are most of time not enough clearly formulated to be well implemented and that “these clauses tend to be very inconsistent and often imprecise, leading to many ambiguities during implementation” (FAO, 2011). On the other hand, they found that the addressees of evaluation results were mainly not specified. At the international level, I can also highlight the Bush Administration's Program Assessment Rating Tool (PART), that assessed all programs “to make sure they are working well for the American people”3 but whom the results were used by congressional chambers on a limited basis (Frisco & Stalebrink, 2008) and that have been criticized “as overly political and a tool to shift power from Congress to the President” (Brass, 2004). Hence, when politicians are not the addressees of the evaluation results and when these results are not reinjected in the policymaking process, how could policy improvement be the reached purpose? The absence of rigorous theory of lawmaker’s motivation for evaluation has made difficult to explain the actual meaning of such a kind public expenditures. Nevertheless, the question is of great practical relevance because either the evaluation is a necessary requirement whom the success of the law is depending on, or the evaluation serves private or organisational interest thanks to public money. This paper would like to help policymakers to identify, when an evaluation clause is proposed in the draft of a bill, if the related expenditure serves the public policy or an other purpose. At the Swiss federal level, a first evaluation clause has been introduced in 1984 (Bussmann, 2005), which has been followed by 114 clauses according to a monitoring provided by the Federal Office of Justice4. Moreover, “The Swiss Federation is, at the international level, a pioneer in the use of this technique. No other country has established an evaluation requirement as a constitutional norm, such as Article 170 of the Federal Constitution” (Jacob, 2005, p. 299) which 3 www.expectingmore.gov (consulted on May 2014) http://www.ejpd.admin.ch/content/bj/fr/home/themen/staat_und_buerger/evaluation/materialien_/uebersic ht.html (consulted on August 2013) 4 Critical examination of lawmaker’s motivation for evaluations 4 stipulates that “The Federal Assembly shall ensure that effectiveness of the measures taken by the Confederation is subject to evaluation” 5. The crucial issue is to determine the roots of evaluation clauses. Even if several studies have studied institutionalization of public policy evaluation, until now, this question has not yielded an extensive literature (Jacob, 2005) an no studies have been devoted to the reasons why public authorities have specifically institutionalized evaluation through legal basis. A multidisciplinary topic This paper deals with legislative evaluation considering the field of law with the unusual perspective of a political scientist. The specific question of who is allowed or abled to study laws or legal basis has been a big disciplinary issue. From the 80’s, Pierre Bourdieu challenged the jurist monopoly, highlighting that they are not the only professionals allowed to deal with law and to analyse them - criticizing the illusory monopoly of law interpretation and their tendency to hide how laws reflect existing balance of power (Bourdieu, 1986, 1991). I don’t want to open up the debate here and I prefer adopting a more consensual perspective than opposing juridical science to political science. Following Jacques Chevalier (2004), I focus on the interdisciplinary of the study of laws. In this paper, I focused on the political dimension of the juridical phenomenon (Chevallier, 2004, p. 48) considering that the legal norm is not the product of a spontaneous generation due to juridical field without any political input. This paper speaks about what Chevalier would call “the political begetting of law”, and more specifically of legislative evaluation. Concerning this specific aspect of the study of law, Charles-Albert Morand (1999) recognized that, since science of law is only focused on law implementation, legislative evaluation (focused on law production and evaluation) adopted mainly its knowledge and its method to political science, and specifically to public policy study. Basically, legislative evaluation is now merged with public policy evaluation. Mainstream conception of evaluation For Jacques Chevalier, beside the distinction between political science and juridical science, the legislative evaluation issue would be related to a law managerialization since law is perceived through the lens of its efficiency instead of its regularity (Chevallier, 2008). Raising this question, considering the law under the criteria of its 5 RS 101, art. 170. Damien J. Wirths 5 reached results would be synonymous of a penetration of the managerial thinking in the field of law (Chevallier, 2008). Currently, bills would be submitted to a quality control and they have to demonstrate their necessity, opportunity, and practicability (Ost, 1999, p. 13). For scholars working on legislative evaluation (mostly considered as an evaluation institutionalization), evaluation is mainly considered as a neutral and scientific activity, supporting parliamentarian oversight, building strong knowledge bases for policymaking or helping agencies develop improved capabilities for politics and program planning, implementation and analysis of results (Chelimsky, 2006, p. 39). In the policymaking process, evaluation demand is perceived as a panacea leading to a more rational policymaking (Mader, 1985, p. 119), increasing law quality (evidencebased policymaking, legitimizing the law and supporting implementation oversight. Evaluation is also seen as a response to the complexity of the post-modern State (FOJ, 2004), promoting accountability and improving governmental management (Davies, Newcomer, & Soydan, 2006, p. 165). Most scholars consider evaluation demand as a means of improving the quality of public policy outputs and they reduce evaluation demand either as incorporating information of evaluations into the legislation process, or as fulfilling the legislature’s oversight function. Nevertheless, these studies do not consider sufficiently the fact that, during a policymaking process, decision-makers can, in every step of the policy cycle, mobilize institutional rules and resources (such as the introduction of evaluation clauses) to impact the content of the concerned step in their favour (Knoepfel, Larrue, & Frédéric, 2002). The notion of symbolic use of knowledge The recent findings regarding the formulation weakness of evaluation clauses tend to contradict the assumed willingness to improve laws and policies (FAO, 2011). It can be related to the research question developed by Christina Boswell (2009). She noticed that “the typical explanation given for this increased demand for expert knowledge is proffered by what is termed the ‘problem-solving’ or ‘instrumentalist’ approach. According to this account, governments and civil servants recognize that expert knowledge is crucial for improving the quality of their outputs (Boswell, 2009, p. 4). Such a kind of consideration can be found in the stakeholder argumentation, related either to a juridical approach (Aubert, 2003; Bussmann, 2005; Mader, 1985; Charles-Albert Morand, 2001), highlighting clause significance, or to a functionalist Critical examination of lawmaker’s motivation for evaluations 6 approach (Bussmann, Klöti, Knoepfel, & Varone, 1998; Chelimsky, 2006; Hans-Ulrich Derlien & Rist, 2002; Mader, 1985), giving a framework related to the governmental need for evaluation results (Davies et al., 2006)6. Christina Boswell highlighted that ”it has frequently been observed that in many policy areas, political debate and decision systematically fail to take into account research findings” (Boswell, 2009, p. 5). In her book, she challenged what she called an instrumentalist account of evaluation. My starting point is that, under certain cases, evaluation clauses are related to such a kind of political use, or, using Boswell’s terminology, “symbolic use” (rather than an instrumental one). Even though “research is in fact highly valued by policymakers, and it plays a crucial role in policymaking and political argumentation”, she considered that “the value of expert knowledge does not lie exclusively, or even predominantly, in its contribution to policy. Research does (indeed) play an important political function, but this is not necessary an instrumental one” (Boswell, 2009, p. 7). For the purpose of this paper, the following terminology is adopted. On the one hand, the instrumental use of knowledge considers the evaluation clause as a means of “improving the quality of the outputs or adjusting the social impacts of the public actions” (Boswell, 2009, p. 61) through legislative revisions (Frey, 2010). On the other hand, the symbolic use of knowledge considers rather evaluation clauses as a means of “enhancing the legitimacy of an organisation or as a way of lending credibility to its policy preferences” (Boswell, 2009, p. 61). Bussman and Knoepfel (1998) recognized already in the 90’s that evaluation can be strategically used by politicians to strengthen a strategic position or at least to neutralize an opponent position. In their text, Bussman and Knoepfel presented cases where administration required an evaluation to motivate credit request, and where interest groups tried to influence decision-makers’ knowledge. More recently, Karsson and Conner (2006), in their chapter on the relationship between evaluation and politics, highlighted how far evaluation is inextricably linked to the phenomena of 6 Even though the first category of works does not investigate the cause of evaluation clause introduction, the second is also insufficient. On the one hand, they do not present empirical evidence to support their claims and, on the other hand, they do not propose independent variables involving a causal link between political behaviour and evaluation clause introduction. Moreover, most of these studies focused on the use of evaluation results rather than evaluation demand. However, research has consistently shown factors that have fostered evaluation institutionalization (whose evaluation clauses are a form). In this paper, I will consider these highlighted factors as control variables, exogenous to the policy-‐making process as the fiscal situation, the political constellation and the constitutional features (Derlien/Rist 2002, Derlien 1990, Derlien 1998) as well as the federalism (Mader 1994). Damien J. Wirths 7 conflict and consensus. They claim that “this context means that there are multiple actors and institutions with power and interests to influence the evaluation, from the choices of criteria, standards, and methods, to the choice of an evaluator” (Karsson & Conner, 2006, p. 237). They proposed three views on the relationship between evaluation and politics. One of them sees politics as driven by many influences other than evaluation, protecting its own interests, and harmful to evaluation. Moreover, in a paper devoted to factors influencing the introduction of evaluation demand in the United States, Hamm and Robertson (1981) have shown that conflict between government and parliament was a key factor. Consequently, this paper considers that sometime the required evaluation is necessary for the good implementation of the law (which will otherwise suffer implementation-failures or programme-failures), represented as an instrumental use of knowledge, and sometimes the evaluation aims to support a symbolic use of knowledge and is not necessary to the law implementation. Research question The existing literature on legislative evaluation is not able to satisfactorily describe the causes of evaluation clauses in a particular law and why they ask sometimes for a weak clause, and sometimes for a strong clause. The two investigation purposes of this paper are (1) to understand why public authorities have introduced mandatory evaluation, and (2) to explain the great heterogeneity of the clauses (which have a very variable normative density) and the fact that, most of the time, their formulation is incomplete and not enough precise (too low normative density) to be well implemented (FAO, 2011; FOJ, 2012; Wirths, 2014). Considering that the evaluation clauses are most of the time introduced since the draft of the bill, the paper has as a priority to address the question of: which causal factors are necessary conditions for explaining why administration proposed strong or weak evaluation clauses into a draft? The question is of great practical relevance since when Parliament is facing a bill containing an evaluation clause, how can it know if the induced costs are justified to guarantee the correct implementation (instrumental use of knowledge) or are rather serving the administration’s or government’s interest? This is the point of this article that aims to determinate if the evaluation clauses could be an indicator of the administration’s motivation. Since all collectable data will contain an evaluation clause (constraint on the case selection), the causal links will highlight necessary conditions to infer evaluation Critical examination of lawmaker’s motivation for evaluations 8 clause instead of sufficient conditions (Dion, 1998). Thus, the paper aims to highlight factors that always exist when the dependant variables occurs (weak or strong evaluation clauses), event if these factors do not necessarily lead to the introduction of evaluation clauses. The findings are of great theoretical significance for political science, public administration theory and law because, until now, empirical research on the relationship between politics and the practice and institutionalization of policy evaluation has been missing. The evaluation clause dilemma I begin by presenting a game theoretic analysis of the strategic environment affecting interactions between the administration and politicians in the policymaking process. This theoretical framework yields empirically testable hypotheses thanks to the identification of logical scenarios (equilibria) leading to the introduction of an evaluation clause (dependent variable) and of conditions under which such equilibria are possible (independent variables). Hence, game solutions ensure the plausibility of the causal argument and the logical validity of the theory. Asserting the policymaking process is strategic is no longer controversial and it is well established that game theory models, considered as rigorous deductive analytical tools, have been successfully deployed in all the subfields of political science. In political interactions no actor can alone determine the outcome of the situation and all actors must think about what the other actors will do when choosing their own actions (Morrow, 1994). A game is generally thought of as a situation in which individuals are aware that their actions affect one another. This is particularly relevant for policy formulation analysis. Recent works have considered “evaluation games” (Eliadis et al., 2011) but it was mostly a misuse of language rather related to the balance of power due to the interaction between evaluators, mandators, and evaluated. These scholars have too focused on the evaluators and underestimate the keyplayer of the evaluation: the ones who ask for it. This paper does not deal with the game of the evaluators who try to maximize his room for manoeuvring, but about the evaluation clause dilemma of deciding to require an evaluation, or not. Scholars working on evaluation often explain why people should ask for evaluation, but they have never demonstrated why they actually do it. Consequently, the model proposed here is a game between the policymakers, and the presence of the clause into the draft of the bill is considered as a signal (Cho & Damien J. Wirths 9 Kreps, 1987) emitted by the drafter. Signalling games allow for representing a situation when some players are better informed about variables than other players (Osborne, 2004, p. 331). Hence, the informed players (the sender) will take action (the potential signal) observed by the uninformed parties (the receiver) before the latter take actions. For the receiver, the main issue is to determine if the signal is relevant and, if so, how to interpret it. In signalling games, one can identify two kinds of scenarios (pure strategy equilibria): first, whatever the information is, the signal doesn’t inform the receiver about the variable (pooling equilibrium). Second, observing the sender’s action will clearly signal the sender’s information (separate equilibrium). Basic component of the game The present modelling (fig. 1) of the policymaking tends to be as robust as possible in the setting of the game and to avoid baroqueness (Allan & Dupont, 1999). Basically, the model is related to an important class of game, named “signalling game” (McCarty & Meirowitz, 2007, pp. 214-250) between two players involved in a dynamic noncooperative game where players choose strategies sequentially on a single issue (the debated policy). The first player (the sender) is the administration7 (S) which drafts a bill that he will later implement (at least partially). As highlighted above, the law can either require additional knowledge to be well implemented or not. In the first case, requiring efficiency evaluation is considered as a willingness to do an instrumental use of knowledge (t1). In the second case, evaluation is considered as a willingness to do a symbolic use of knowledge (t2). Hence, S is type t ∈ {t1 , t2} and p represents the probability for S being t1, and 1-p the probability of being t2. The parliament is the receiver (R). Before the parliamentary phase, the administration drafts the bill and moves first. During this first opportunity, (preparliamentary phase) the administration knows his type and chooses whether to include an evaluation clause (strong or a weak), or not8. This first move represents a message m ∈ {strong, weak}. When the parliament has the opportunity to play, he does not know what administration’s type is and has simply the choice between refusing the bill (N) adopting it with a clause (Y) and, adopting it without clause (Λ). 7 Even if we know that the government leads administration, the term “administration” will be used to globally represent this player whom we consider the same interest. 8 Here I simplify the model and I do not take this action into account because the empirical corpus available is focused on laws with evaluation clauses. Critical examination of lawmaker’s motivation for evaluations 10 Fig. 1 : Extensive form of the evaluation clause dilemma Concerning the measurement of sender’s utilities, according to the setting of the game, I distinguish between type t1 which have no interest in the adoption of the bill (and which is indifferent regarding the payoff, always equal to 0) and type t2 which have an organisational interest in the adoption of the bill (payoff = ΠS in case of adoption rather than 0 if the bill is rejected), and more particularly with a weak evaluation clause that will allows for a reward9 (payoff = ΠS + a). It means that playing weak clause is a dominated strategy for type t210. Even though type t1 is insensitive to his own payoff, the fact to propose an evaluation clause is not for free and is logically related to a perceived risk of implementation-failure (that would be decreased thanks to the evaluation results). This risk doesn’t exist with type t2 since he has an interest in the success of the law. This potential failure impacts the measurement of receiver’s utilities. On the one hand, one has to consider that the evaluation implementation will be costly (payoff reduced by – c). On the other hand, either there is a risk for the law implementation (and the evaluation clause is justified), or there is no risk and the clause is useless. If the implementation required additional knowledge (t1), the parliament runs a risk of implementation failure 9 Because the room for manoeuvring allowed : « Because the phrasing of the evaluation clauses is often imprecise, the responsible federal authorities tend not to critically question their activities, but to use an evaluation to try and legitimise them » (FAO, 2011) 10 Introducing a strong clause is always at least as good as and some times better than introducing a weak clause. Damien J. Wirths 11 adopting the law without evaluation (payoff = 0). If the law implementation does not require additional knowledge to be performed (t2), the parliament would earn the best payoff without evaluation clause (payoff = ΠR) rather than paying for a useless evaluation (payoff = ΠR - c). In any case, all is better than refusing the bill, in other word the status quo (payoff = S), as long as ΠR > S. Separate equilibrium? The first scenario is very intuitive: the type t2 administration will propose weak clause to maximise its payoff and type t1 administration will propose strong clause to maximise the implementation efficiency. The inverse is not plausible (since strong clause is a dominated strategy for t2). Hence, the scenario assumes that each administration type chooses a different message. The first question is: can the parliamentarian logically identify the administration type observing the clause type? More specifically, can we assume a first strategy σ1, so that weak clauses are related to willingness to do a symbolic use of knowledge, and that strong clauses are related to the willingness to do an instrumental use? In other words, !! (!) !"#$%& !" ! = !! !"#$ !" ! = !! Regarding the beliefs for Parliament, let µ (ti|A) be the probability receiver assigns to type i after observing action A. If Parliament sees that administration plays strong, he will assign probability 1 to t1 (and 0 to t2). In contrast, seeing a weak evaluation clause, he will assign probability 1 to t2 (and 0 to t1). Bayes’ rule applies and the resulting Parliament’s beliefs are: µμ (!! | !"#$%&) = (!! | !"#$) = 1 µμ (!! | !"#$) = (!! | !"#$%&) = 0 In these conditions, Parliament’s expected utilities (EUP) from playing A, Λ or R against weak are: !"! !, !"#$ = 0 • 0 − ! + 1 • Π − ! = Π − ! !"! Λ, !"#$ = 0 • 0 + 1 • Π = Π !"! !, !"#$ = 0 • ! + 1 • ! = ! Since, Critical examination of lawmaker’s motivation for evaluations 12 !"! Λ, !"#$ > !"! !, !"#$ > !"! !, !"#$ Hence, the best response11 against weak is !" !"#$ = Λ. In contrast, Parliament expected utilities (EUP) from playing A, Λ or R against strong are: !"! !, !"#$%& = 1 • Π − ! + 0 • Π − ! = Π − ! !"! Λ, !"#$%& = 1 • 0 + 0 • Π = 0 !"! !, !"#$%& = 1 • ! + 0 • ! = ! And since, !"! !, !"#$%& > !"! !, !"#$%& > !"! Λ, !"#$%& Thus the best response against strong is !" !"#$%& = A. Nevertheless, his strategy (type t1 plays strong and type t2 plays weak) is an equilibrium (in other word, a credible scenario) if and only if neither type of administration has an incentive to deviate considering the best responses calculated. Type t1’s payoff is always the same (whatever is the receiver response) and it has no incentive to deviate. Along the equilibrium path, type t2’s payoff Π + a. Playing strong instead of weak, receiver’s response will be A instead of Λ and his payoff becomes only Π. Since it is less than the payoff earned along the equilibrium path, type t2 has no incentive to deviate. It means that at least one type of administration has an incentive to deviate, and that this is not equilibrium. Consequently, the following hypothesis can be made: H1: A strong evaluation clause is proposed when the administration’s willingness is an instrumental use of knowledge; otherwise, the evaluation clause is weak. Pooling equilibrium? In this case, the scenario assumes both administration types choose a same message and their willingness (instrumental or symbolic) cannot be distinguished on this basis. Since only two possibilities exist (everybody play weak or everybody play strong) and since (as explain above) playing strong is a dominated strategy for type t2, the only plausible pooling equilibrium would be both administration type play weak. !! (!) !"#$ !" ! = !! !"#$ !" ! = !! As previously, let µ (ti|A) be the probability the receiver assigns to type i after observing action A. If Parliament sees that administration plays weak, he will assign 11 The action that gives the highest payoff against the first player’s strategy Damien J. Wirths 13 probability 1 to t1 and to t2. Bayes’ rule applies and Parliament’s beliefs are: ! (!! | !"#$) = ! !"# ! (!! | !"#$) = 1 − ! If, however, government plays strong, which shouldn’t occur along the equilibrium path related to the pooling equilibrium (weak, weak), Bayes’s rule does not apply and beliefs have to be assigned. However, since type t2 will not deviate (because strong is a dominated strategy) and since type t1 is insensitive (payoff always equal 0), we do not need to take this possibility into account. ! (!! | !"#$%&) = ! !"# ! (!! | !"#$%&) = 1 − ! This time, Parliament’s expected utilities (EUP) from playing A, Λ or R against weak are: !"! (!, !"#$) = ! • (Π − !) + (1 − !) • (Π − !) = Π − ! !"! Λ, !"#$ = ! • (0) + (1 − !) • (Π) = Π − !Π !"! (!, !"#$) = ! • ! + (1 − !) • ! = ! ! And, as long as Π > ! , !"! !, !"#$ > !"! Λ, !"#$ > !"! !, !"#$ Hence, the best response against strong is !" !"#$ = A and the strategy (weak, weak) is a pooling equilibrium. Hence, following hypothesis can be deduced: H2: A weak evaluation clause is introduced whatever the administration’s willingness is (instrumental or symbolic use of knowledge). The Swiss context The Swiss political system is well known to be ideal for within-system comparisons thanks to his high degree of internal heterogeneity. The 26 cantons of Swiss Federation have retained state sovereignty, far-reaching competences and rights of self-determination. Since they dispose of their “own territories, constitutions and legal systems, organisational sovereignty and sovereignty to employ and dismiss staff, the division of the political institutions into executive, legislature and judiciary and their extensive legislative and fiscal competences, the cantons dispose of numerous properties and characteristics of a State” (Vatter 2006: 198) and are equivalent to small nations with its own policy-making agenda which is not set by the central government (Wälti/Bullinger 2000). In every canton, the process can be described in four formal steps: (1) Critical examination of lawmaker’s motivation for evaluations 14 preparlimentary, (2) parliamentary, (3) referendum and (4) implementation. This paper focuses on the first two involving basically, two kinds of players are involved: (1) the implementing actors (mainly the government and the administration) and (2) the parliamentarians. Thanks to the median voter concept (Downs 1957), given that every step is under the majority rule, we can consider that each actor represents the median position of its body and we are allowed to simplify the choice of each body to that of a single actor. Preparliamentary phase The Government has a two main function in the process (1) drafting the bill and (2) leading implementing actors. The «State Council» (Conseil d’Etat) is the highest executive and administrative authority of the canton and is in charge of implementing the laws. The citizens directly elect it and each member leads a department. The number of departments depends on the size of the canton, on how developed the administration is and on how professionalized the government work is (full-time or part-time) (Felder 1993: 23). The divisions (offices) are the administrative units subordinated to the departments, and on average we can find 48 divisions in a canton (Vatter 2006:206). Switzerland has a very decentralized administration (by international comparison), since 39% of the civil servants work at the cantonal level (Linder 2005). Nevertheless, one has to keep in mind that the implementation phase can involve several kinds of other actors, either public or private. Most of the time, the decision-making process starts with the drafting of a bill by the administration and the cantonal government (who leads the departments). The parliament itself has the possibility to draft a bill (through a parliamentary initiative proposed by an individual or a group of parliamentarians) but, for instance, at the federal level, the administration takes the lead over the Parliament in the legislative process and initiates almost half of the bills (Sciarini & al., 2002: 11). During a consultation procedure, which usually consists in a written reply, principal parties and interested organizations are consulted to express their point of view on the draft and on the policy aims. Opinions are gathered, eventually integrated into the legislative act, and a final draft is submitted to the parliament with an explanatory note. Parliamentary phase At the cantonal level there is only one parliamentary chamber named « Grand Council » (Grand Conseil). The significance of interest groups is less formalized and Damien J. Wirths 15 the political relationships between parties are more homogeneous, simpler and clearer than at the federal level (Vatter 2006: 200). According to Vatter (2006: 208), the size of the cantonal legislatures varies between 49 (Appenzell Innerhoden) and 200 seats (Bern until 2006). Being a parliamentarian on the legislative level is a volunteer job that involves attending meetings, most of the time for , less than 200 hours per year (with the exception of Ticino, Vaud and Geneva) (Bolchsler et al. 2004: 45). Half of the cantons have between five and nine permanent commissions but this number of ad hoc committees may vary between 0 (Appenzell Innerhoden and Lucerne) and 450 (Vaud) within one legislative period (Heierli 2000:32). In the policymaking process, the draft is discussed by the responsible legislative committee (parliamentary commission). Under a majority rule it proposes either accept or reject the proposal, or to accept it with certain modifications. The committee have the possibility of suggesting dismissing the proposal without debate or to send it back to the government. If the parliamentary commission modifies the draft, the floor adopts on average 95% of the committee proposals. If a parliamentarian is outvoted in the committee, he has the possibility to state his opinion writing a minority request addressed to the floor. Afterwards, during the plenary session, each parliamentarian has the right to call for modifications. It could be minor corrections and, for instance, at the federal level, the parliament modified only 44% of the proposals submitted by the Federal Council and only 3% of the cases concerned questions of principle. As far as we are concerned, evaluation clauses introduced in these steps are clearly not questions of principle and can be considered as minor corrections. Research design Working progress References: Allan, P., & Dupont, C. (1999). International Relations Theory and Game Theory: Baroque Modeling Choices and Empirical Robustness. International Political Science Review, 20(1), 23-47. Critical examination of lawmaker’s motivation for evaluations 16 Aubert, J.-F. (2003). Art. 170 Évaluation de l’efficacité Petit commentaire de la Constitution fédérale de la Confédération suisse du 18 avril 1999 (pp. 12891293). Zürich ; Bâle ; Genève: Schulthess. Boswell, C. (2009). The political uses of expert knowledge: immigration policy and social research: Cambridge University Press. Bourdieu, P. (1986). La force du droit. Actes de recherche en sciences sociales, 64, 3-19. Bourdieu, P. (1991). Les Juristes, gardiens de l’hypocrisie collective. F. Chazel y J. Comaille (direc.) Normes juridiques et régulation sociales, Paris. LGDJ, coll. Droit et société, 95-99. Brass, C. T. (2004). The Bush Administration's Program Assessment Rating Tool (PART) RL32663: Library of Congress. Congressional Research Service. Bussmann, W. (2005). Typen und Terminologie von Evaluationsklauseln. LeGes (Gesetzgebung und Evaluation), 16(1), 97-102. Bussmann, W. (2008). The emergence of evaluation in Switzerland. Evaluation, 14(4), 499-506. Bussmann, W., Klöti, U., Knoepfel, P., & Varone, F. (1998). Politiques publiques: évaluation: Economica. Chelimsky, E. (2006). The purposes of evaluation in a democratic society. In SAGE (Ed.), The handbook of evaluation (pp. 33-55). Chevallier, J. (2004). Science politique et science juridique. In O. P. E. Darras (Ed.), La science politique une et multiple (pp. 41-59): L’Harmattan. Chevallier, J. (2008). Management public et droit. Politiques et management public, 3, 93-100. Cho, I.-K., & Kreps, D. M. (1987). Signaling games and stable equilibria. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102(2), 179-221. Davies, P., Newcomer, K., & Soydan, H. (2006). Government as structural context for evaluation. In SAGE (Ed.), The handbook of evaluation (pp. 163-183). Derlien, H.-U. (1998). Le développement des évaluations dans un contexte internationale. In W. Bussmann, U. Klöti, P. Knoepfel & F. Varone (Eds.), Politiques publiques: évaluation: Economica. Damien J. Wirths 17 Derlien, H.-U., & Rist, R. C. (2002). Policy evaluation in international comparison. In N. B. a. L. Transaction Publishers (Ed.), International Atlas of Evaluation (pp. 439-455). Dion, D. (1998). Evidence and Inference in the Comparative Case Study. Comparative Politics, 30(2), 127-145. doi: 10.2307/422284 Eliadis, F. P., Furubo, J.-E., & Jacob, S. (2011). Evaluation: Seeking Truth Or Power? (Vol. 17): Transaction Publishers. FAO. (2011). Umsetzung der Evaluationsklauseln in der Bundesverwaltung. FOJ. (2004). Rapport du Groupe de contact interdépartemental "Evaluations de l’efficacité" à la Conférence des secrétaires généraux de la Confédération suisse. FOJ. (2005). Guide de l'évaluation de l'efficacité à la Confédération. Berne: Widmer, Thomas. FOJ. (2007). Evaluations rétrospectives Guide de législation (3e ed., pp. 163-174). Bern. FOJ. (2012). Recommandations pour la formulation des clauses d'évaluation. Frey, K. (2010). Performance information in legislative revisions in Switzerland. Governance, 23(4), 667-690. Frisco, V., & Stalebrink, O. J. (2008). Congressional use of the program assessment rating tool. Public Budgeting & Finance, 28(2), 1-19. Hamm, K. E., & Robertson, R. D. (1981). Factors influencing the adoption of new methods of legislative oversight in the US states. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 133-150. Jacob, S. (2005). Institutionnaliser l'évaluation des politiques publiques: étude comparée des dispositifs en Belgique, en France, en Suisse et aux Pays-Bas: Cambridge Univ Press. Karsson, & Conner. (2006). Relationship between evaluation and politics. In SAGE (Ed.), The handbook of evaluation (pp. 33-55). Knoepfel, P., Larrue, C., & Frédéric, V. (2002). Analyse et pilotage des politiques publiques: Genève/Bâle/Munich, Helbing & Lichtenhahn. Mader, L. (1985). L'évaluation législative: Pour une analyse empirique des effets de la législation: Payot. Mader, L. (1990). Institutionnalisation de l'évaluation dans une perspective suisse. In K. Horber-Papazian (Ed.), L’évaluation des politiques publiques en Suisse (pp. 185-196). Lausanne: PPUR. Critical examination of lawmaker’s motivation for evaluations 18 Mader, L. (1994). L’évaluation legislative en Suisse. Revue de la recherché juridique. Droit Prospectif, 1994(4), 1354-1360. McCarty, N., & Meirowitz, A. (2007). Political game theory: an introduction: Cambridge University Press. Morand, C.-A. (1999). Formes et fonctions de l’évaluation législative Élaborer la loi aujourd’hui, mission impossible? (pp. 207-227). Morand, C.-A. (2001). L’évaluation des effets des mesures étatiques. In Schulthess (Ed.), Droit constitutionnel suisse (pp. 1119-1129). Zürich. Morrow, J. D. (1994). Game theory for political scientists: Princeton University Press Princeton, NJ. Osborne, M. J. (2004). An introduction to game theory (Vol. 3): Oxford University Press New York. Ost, F. (1999). La régulation: des horloges et des nuages Élaborer la loi aujourd’hui, mission impossible? (pp. 11-34). Wirths, D. (2014). A new typology of evaluation clauses. not yet published.