Book PDF - Employee Benefit Research Institute
Transcription
Book PDF - Employee Benefit Research Institute
Employee Benefit Research Institute The Employee Benefit Research Institute (EBRI) is a Washington-based, nonprofit, nonpartisan public policy research institution. EBRI's overall goal is to promote the development of soundly conceived private and public employee benefit plans. Through research, policy forums, workshops and educational publications, EBRI contributes to the expansion of knowledge in the field and to the formulation of effective and responsible health, welfare and retirement policies. This work is intended to complement the research and education programs conducted by academia, the government and private institutions. EBRI's educational and research materials aid the public, the media and public and private sector decision makers in addressing employee benefits issues before policy decisions are made. The Institute seeks a broad base of support among interested individuals and organizations as well as those sponsoring employee benefit plans or providing professional services in the employee benefits field. DR. SYLVESTER J. SCHIEBER is the Research Director of the Employee Benefit Research Institute. Dr. Schieber previously served as Deputy Director, Office of Policy Analysis, Social Security Administration and the Deputy Research Director, Universal Social Security Coverage Study, Department of Health and Human Services. He has also held other government and academic positions, and has authored numerous publications in the employee benefit field. More information on the Employee Benefit Research Institute can be obtained by writing: Executive Director, EBRI, 1920 N Street, NW, Suite 520, Washington, DC 20036 (202) 659-0670. SOCIALSECURitY.. Perspectives on Preserving the System By Sylvester J. Schieber _'._1982 Employee Benefit Research Education and Research Fund 1920 N Street, NW, Suite 520 Washington, (202/659-0670 Institute DC 20036 All rights reserved. Reproduction is granted provided proper attribution is given. The ideas and opinions expressed in this publication are those o[ the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the Employee Benefit Research Institute, its trustees, members or associates. Library Schieber, Social o[ Congress Sylvester Security, Cataloging Data oll preserving the system. J. perspectives Includes bibliographical I. Social security--United nance. I. Title. HD7125.$33 1982 ISBN 0-86643-028-8 Printed in Publication in the United States references. States. 2. Social 353.0082'56 of America security--United States--Fi82-21046 Table of Contents List of Illustrations List of Tables ................................................... .......................................................... Executive Summary Foreword ............................................................. Introduction Chapter I The Evolution ix xi .................................................. xxi xxxvii ........................................................... of the Social Security Program 1 ................... 7 The Early Development of Retirement Programs .............. Environment in the United States Prior to Enactment of Social Security .................................................. Development of the Social Security Act ........................ The Provisions of the Social Security Act ....................... Social Security Coverage; Retirement Age; The Benefit Structure Financing Social Security ......................................... Growth of the Social Security Program ......................... Chapter II Income Security for the Elderlv: The Role of Programs Than Social Security ................................................. 7 10 14 17 33 37 Other The Role of Pensions ............................................... Growth in Pension Programs; Growth in Beneficiaries; Growth in Benefits Individual Savings and Asset Income ........................... Special Retirement Savings Programs; Homeownership; Business Assets; Other Financial Assets Employment Income of the Elderly ............................. Cash Assistance Programs ......................................... In-Kind Benefit Programs ......................................... Continuing Evolution of the U.S. Retirement System ........ 45 46 61 70 71 73 74 V Chapter III Retirement Benefit Levels Under Current Policy ................. A Framework for Evaluation ..................................... Pension and Retirement Income Simulation Model; Assumptions for the Base Case Simulations Current Policy Simulation Results ............................... Sources and Levels of Income; Earnings; Social Security; Pensions; Individual Retirement Savings; Relationship of Pensions and IRAs; Supplemental Security Income; Projected Income Levels for the Elderly; Retirement Program Income Levels; Replacement of Earnings by Retirement Programs Implications of the Results ....................................... Chapter IV Social Security Financing Problems ............................... Measurement of Social Security's Financing Status .......... The Short-Term Problem; The Long-Term Problem Changing Perspectives ............................................. Increases in Benefits ............................................... Introducing Basic Changes ........................................ Recognition of a Structural Problem ............................ The Effect of Short-Term Economics; The Effect of LongTerm Demographics Modification of the System ....................................... Continuing Problems .............................................. Chapter V The Mathematics of Social Security's Financing Problems and the Short-Term Policy Options ................................ The Mathematics of Social Security Financing ................ Short-Term Imbalances; Long-Term Imbalances Stabilizing the Financing of Social Security ................... General Policy Considerations Short-Term Policy Options ....................................... General Revenue Financing; Raising Payroll Tax Rates; Expanding Coverage; Redefining Taxable Wages; Social Security Benefit Adjustments; Indexing; Taxing Benefits Selecting Short-Term Policies .................................... vi 77 77 83 102 103 103 116 116 ! 18 122 128 131 135 136 145 151 158 Chapter VI Social Security Beyond the Short Term ........................... Social Security Benefits Under Current Law The Earlier Debate ................................................. 161 ................... 161 163 Options for Modifying Social Security's Benefit Calculation Procedures .......................................................... Index Earnings by Price Increases; Index Formula Bend Points by Price Increases; Options for Limiting Replacement-Rate Reductions; Rapid Bend-Point Adjustment for Limited Period; Slow Bend-Point Growth Gradually on a Limited Basis 167 Options for Changing Work and Retirement Patterns ........ Increase Normal Retirement Ages; Change Actuarial Adjustment Factors; OASDI Savings with Later Retirement Ages Distributional Implications of Benefit Formula Adjustments on Income Levels ................................................... Implications of Modifying the Benefit Formula; The Response of Pensions and Other Resources; Distributional Considerations 171 Implications of Taxing Benefits .................................. Implications of Raising the Retirement Age .................... Comparing the Alternatives ....................................... Selecting Options .................................................. 186 187 194 198 Chapter VII Universal Social Security Coverage and the Alternatives ....... Problems with the Status Quo ................................... Inadequate Protection for Persons Not Covered; Inequities Inherent in Exemption from Participation in a Mandatory Redistributive Program; Benefits Afforded Partial Participants in Social Security Providing a Perspective on the Bonuses ......................... Measuring the Cost to Social Security of the Bonuses ........ Options for Resolution of the Problems ......................... Universal Social Security Coverage; Modification of the Benefit Computation; Offsetting the Noncovered Pension Benefit The Effect of Eliminating the Unintended ients .................................................................. Benefits The Cost of Coverage ...................... for Federal Workers 177 201 202 206 209 212 on Recip224 225 vii The Cost of Coverage for State and Local Workers ............ Mandatory Social Security Coverage of Nonprofit Organizations .................................................................. Other Issues Associated with Mandatory Social Security Coverage ................................................................. Chapter VIII Other Policy Considerations ......................................... Redefining Evaluating Maintaining Maintaining Security ....................................... Income Simulation Model Appendix B Calculating Social Security Benefits Under the curity Formula ........................................................ viii 244 249 255 256 261 265 275 the Goals .............................................. Specific Options ...................................... Incentives for Private Programs .................. Flexibility ............................................ Appendix A Pension and Retirement 243 249 Horizontal and Vertical Equity in Social Security ............ The Earnings Test .................................................. Trust Fund Accumulations ........................................ General Revenue Financing ....................................... Reorienting the Social Security Program ....................... The Family Plan; Personal Security Accounts; The Freedom Plan Chapter IX The Future of Social 234 275 278 284 286 ............. 1977 Social 289 Se297 List of Illustrations Figure 1 2 I-1 I-2 Page Future Average Family Social Security Age 65 ................................................... Total Civilian Employment and Workers Social Sccuritv ......................................... Workers Covered bv Social I-4 I-5 II-I IV-1 V-1 VII-I A-1 Ratio of Workers tal Beneficiaries Social at xxxi Future Average Disposable Family Income A_c 65 ................................................... Over 65 Receiving I-3 Benefits at xxxii Covered bv 39 Security and Persons Security .................. Covered bv Social Security ........................................ 40 to To41 Year End Average Monthly Social Securitv Benefits Retired Workers,and All Beneficiaries .............. 42 Combined Taxable 43 OASDI Taxes Paid on Average Earnings ...................................... Reported Total Number of Tax-Qualified Plans in Effect Selected Years .......................................... for 48 Legislated OASDI Payroll. Tax Rate and Projected Cost Rates Under Ahernative Assumptions ........ 113 Replacement of Preretircment Earnings Worker Retiring at Age 65, bv Year of Retirement ........................................... 149 Flow of Funds Related ment System, 1980 for Average to the Civil Service .................................... Retire228 Data Sources Used to Create the PRISM Database ................................................ Baseline A-2 PRISM Work History .............. A-3 PRISM Retirement Simulation Benefit Model Simulation 290 Model ........ 293 296 ix List of Tables Table I-1 Page Percentage of the Population Over Age 65, 18701940 ...................................................... 10 I-2 Labor Force 11 I-3 Five-Year Variations in Unemployment Rates for Civilian Labor Force and Nonfarm Workers, 19001939 ...................................................... 12 Replacement Rates for Workers Retiring at Age 65 Under 1935 Social Security Act and 1939 Amendments .................................................... 23 Replacement Rates for Single Workers Retiring at Age 65 Under Various Social Security Amendments .................................................... 26 I-4 I-5 I-6 II-1 II-2 1870-1940 ............ Comparison of Combined OASI Taxes Accumulated with Interest and Present Value of Retirement Benefits I-7 and Employment, for Persons Age 65 ........................... Annual Maximum Taxable tion Rates Under Social Earnings Security 30 and ContribuAct ............... 38 Wage and Salary Workers in Private Sector Nonagricultural Establishments and Pension Participation ...................................................... 50 Private Pension Plan Creations, Terminations, Net Plan Increases ..................................... 52 II-3 Plan Qualifications II-4 Working Participants Per Beneficiary in Defined Benefit Pension Plans .................................. 55 Working Participants Contribution Plans 57 II-5 and Participants and ................... Per Beneficiary in Defined ..................................... 53 xi I1-6 II-7 II-8 II-9 II-10 II-11 Private Pension Plan Participants, Benefit Recipients, and Average Benefits for Selected Years ..... 59 Percentage of Families with Individuals Ages 65 to 69 Eligible to Receive Employer Pension Benefits. 60 Pension Benefits in a Hypothetical Two-Class ety: Period I ............................................ Soci60 Pension Benefits in a Hypothetical Two-Class ety: Period 2 ............................................ Soci60 Earnings and Age Characteristics of the U.S. Civilian Work Force and Workers Participating in a Pension Plan in May 1979 ............................ 63 Percentage Income 64 of Eligible Persons Who Have IRAs, bv Class, 1977 .................................... II-12 IRA Assets by Financial II-13 Distribution of Household Assets and Liabilities Current Prices for Selected Years, 1950-1979 in ..... Labor-Force Participation Rates for Individuals 65 and Older for Selected Years ..................... Age II-14 Benefits ................... 71 III-I Assumed Consumer Price Index Increases Used in Retirement Simulations .............................. 81 III-2 Assumptions 81 III-3 Assumptions about covered Workers the Annual Probability of NonAdopting an IRA ................... 82 III-4 Assumptions IRA Contributions 83 1II-5 Worker's Reach about Savings 1979 67 Federal about for the Elderly, 65 II-15 xii In-Kind Institutions Plan Participation ................. Ages in 1979 and Years When Cohorts Age 65 ........................................... ....... ....... 74 84 Ill-6 Age in 1979 and Projected Family Earnings 65 ........................................................ Elderly Families 111-8 Elderly Employment III-9 Age in 1979 and Projected Famih' Social Security Benefits at Age 65 ...................................... 88 Past and Future Social Security Benefit 1952-2054 .............................................. 89 III-1 l Rates in 1979 85 III-7 III-10 with Earnings at Age in March ............... 1980 ........... Benefits 90 III-12 Age in 1979 and Projected III-13 Age in 1979 and Projected Benefits from IRAs and Pensions Combined at Age 65 ........................ II1-14 III-15 Age in 1979 and Projected Preretirement Earnings at Age 65 ... by 97 Estimated Average Family Benefit Levels from Social Security or Pensions and IRAs .................. Age in 1979 and Projected SSI Benefits aI Age 65 III-17 Age in 1979 and Projected Annual Familv Income Lcvels from Selected Sources at Age 65 ............ Estimated Net Retirement Program Replacement Preretirement Family Earnings ...................... III-19 Estimated Replacement Rates for Median IV-1 Actuarial Status of OASDI on "Closed and "Open Group, Limited Period" 1980 ................................................... Earnings. 93 96 IRA or Pension Benefit ............................... III-16 III-18 86 Levels, Age in 1979 and Projected Family Pension at Age 65 ................................................ IRA Benefits 86 98 ... 99 100 of 101 102 Group" Base, 1971104 xiii IV-2 IV-3 IV-4 IV-5 IV-6 IV-7 IV-8 IV-9 IV-10 IV-I 1 IV-12 IV-13 xiv Operations of the OASI Trust Fund During Selected Calendar Years, 1940-1981 and Estimated Future Operations .......................... 107 Operations of the DI Trust Fund During Selected Calendar Years, 1960-1981 and Estimated Future Operations ..................................... 109 Operations of the Hospital During Calendar Years, Trust Fund ............... 110 Economic Assumptions Used in the Projections for OASDI and HI in the 1982 Trustees Report.. 112 Insurance 1966-1984 Cost and Tax Rates of the Hospital Insurance Program, as a Percentage of Taxable Payroll ... 115 Payroll Tax Schedule in Effect in 1971 and Schedule Recommended by 1971 Advisory Council to Finance OASDI Benefits .............. 119 Payroll Tax Schedule to Finance OASDHI Benefits Established by Legislation in 1971 and in June and October 1972 ............................. 121 Projections of OASDI Reserve Ratios and LongTerm Financing in Successive Trustees Reports ............................................... 122 Primary Insurance Amount Computation for Selected Years ................................... 123 Replacement Rates for Successive Cohorts Retiring at Age 65 .................................. Factors of Men 124 Comparison of Five-Year Economic Assumptions in the 1972 OASDI Trustees Report with Actual Experience ........................................... 126 Birthrate, 127 United States, 1940-1979 ................ IV-14 IV- ! 5 IV-16 V-I Actual and Assumed Total Fertility Rates lected Years .......................................... Effects of Changing OASDI Actuarial Fertility Balance Estimated Cost Rates V-3 OASI Average Beneficiary V-7 VI-2 VI-3 132 for OASDI 139 Per 100 Workers Monthly Benefit Levels ........................................... Number of Beneficiaries and Beneficiary lents ................................................... .. 140 by Class of 142 Equiva143 Projected OASI Dependency Ratios, Cost Rates, and Relationships Between Average Benefits to Average Wages for Selected Years ................ 144 Social Security Cost-of-Living 156 Additional Outlay Savings Under Different Adjustments ........................ Trust der Various VI-1 130 ............................................. OASI and OASDI Beneficiaries V-6 Assumptions on .......................... and Tax Rates V-2 V-5 129 A Comparison of Five-Year Economic Assumptions in the 1977 OASDI Trustees Report with Actual Experience ................................... Programs V-4 for Se- Fund Revenues Policy Adjustments for OASDI Un................... 159 OASDI Financing Surplus and Deficit Under II-B Assumptions and Net Savings from Moving to Price Indexing of Earnings and Bend Points .... 167 OASDI Financing Surplus and Deficit Under II-B Assumptions and Net Savings from Indexing PIA Formula Bend Points by 75 Percent of Wage Growth for Specified Periods .............. 171 National Commission on Social Security Proposal for Phasing in Later Retirement Ages ............ 173 XV VI-4 VI-5 VI-6 VI-7 VI-8 VI-9 VI-10 VI-I 1 VI-12 xvi PIA Adjustment Factors During Transition to Normal Retirement Age of 68 with Early Retirement at Age 62 .................................. 175 OASDI Financing Surplus and Deficit and Net Savings as a Percentage of Covered Payroll Following Raising of the Normal Retirement Age .................................................... 176 Social Security Benefits in 1982 Dollars at Age 65 Under Current Policy and Three Alternate Policies for Future Benefit Determinations .......... 179 Average Pension and IRA Benefits in 1982 Dollars Under Current Social Security Policy and Alternate Policies ...................................... 182 Average Family Income in 1982 Dollars at Age 65 Under Current Social Security Policy and Alternate Policies ................................... 184 Estimated Average Family Income from Selected Sources at Age 65 for Persons Aged 25 to 34 Under Current Social Security Policy and by 75 Percent Wage Indexation of PIA Formula Bend Points for 16 Years .................................. 185 Average Disposable Income at Age 65 in 1982 Dollars Under Current Policy and Alternate Formula and Taxing Provisions ................... 188 Average Family Income from Specified Sources 1982 Dollars at Age 68 Under Current Policy and Alternate Policy Raising Social Security's Retirement Ages by Three Years .................. in Average Family Income from Specified Sources in 1982 Dollars at Age 68 Under Current Policy and Alternate Policy Raising Social Security's Normal Retirement Age by Three Years ......... 190 191 VI-13 VI-14 Distribution of Relative Change in Present Value of Lifetime Social Security Bcnefits at Age 62 Under Alternative Policv Scenarios .............. Distribution of Relative Change in the Present Value of Lifetime Social Security Benefits for Men and Women Policy Scenarios VII-1 VII-2 VII-3 VII-4 VII-5 at Age 62 Under Alternate ..................................... VII-7 VII-8 198 Wage Assumptions for Three Hypothetical Workers .............................................. 207 Percentage of Total Employee Social Security Taxes Paid and Primary Benefits Accrued in Covered Employment .............................. 208 Earnings Credits, Present Low Benefits, and Estimated Windfalls for Workers with Identical Wage Streams ....................................... 211 Estimated Additional Benefits Payable Under Alternative Coverage Options for the Calendar Years, 1985-1988 .................................... 215 Additional OASDI and HI Tax Collections Coverage of Federal, ment, and Nonprofit VII-6 196 from State and Local GovernEmployees .................. 217 Estimated Amount by Which OASDI Taxes Exceed Expenditures, as a Percentage of Total Taxable Payroll, after Extension of Coverage ... 220 Effect of Economic Assumptions on CSRS Cost Estimates ............................................ 227 Federal Agency and General Revenuc Expenditure Projections for the Current CSRS and Modified System in Conjunction with Newly Hired Workers Under Social Security ........... 231 xvii VII-9 VII-10 VII-l I Change in Total Expected Retirement Income Under Constant-Benefit Formula Using Two Inflation Assumptions .................................... 236 Normal Cost of Current Plan Compared with Normal Cost of Constant Benefit Step-Rate Plus Social Security Payroll Taxes ..................... 240 Present Plan Normal Cost Versus fit Plan Normal Cost Plus Social Taxes ................................................. VII-12 VIII-l VIII-2 VIII-3 IX-l B-l B-2 B-3 xviii Constant-BeneSecurity Effects of Expanded Coverage for State Workers on Social Security Revenues 1985 and 1990 ....................................... 241 and Local Between 243 Monthly Social Security Benefits for Specified Individuals and Couples Retiring at Age 62 in Early 1982 ........................................... 253 Estimated Costs of OASDI System as a Percent_ age of Covered Payroll and as a Percentage of GNP ................................................... 261 Fiscal Budget Receipts, Outlays, and Surpluses Deficits by Fund Group ............................ or 264 Projected Expenditures of OASDI with Universal Coverage and with Hypothetical National Pension Plan ............................................. 285 Indexing Average Wage Series, Annual Maximum Taxable Earnings, and Wage Indexes Used in Calculating Social Security AIME, for 19791982 ................................................... 298 PIAs and Replacement Using 1979 Benefit 300 of AIME in Selected Cases Formula ....................... Social Security Benefit Formula Bend Points Selected Years ....................................... for 301 B-4 Maximum Family Benefit Bend Points lected Years .......................................... for Se302 xix Executive Summary The public discussion of the Social Security financing problem throughout most of 1982 has been broad and serious but not focused on detail. In its 1983 session, Congress will have to tackle the details of Social Security financing. In November 1982, the largest Social Security trust fund, the Old-Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) program, will be in the unprecedented position of having to borrow from the Disability Insurance (DI) and Hospital Insurance (HI) programs. Without new legislation, the OASI program will not be able to make the benefit payments on schedule in July 1983. The legislation that evolves must do more than merely extend the inter-trust-fund borrowing provisions that permit OASI to meet scheduled payments for the next half-year. If the current borrowing authority is extended, the combined trust funds will be depleted during 1984 or 1985 at the very latest. Beyond the immediate short term, the HI program faces financing problems during the latter half of the 1980s, and OASI will encounter new problems shortlv after the turn of the century. This report provides the details for an evaluation of the status of the United States retirement income securitv system in general, and the Social Security system in particular. The analysis particularly addresses the scope and mathematics of the financing imbalances of Social Security, several options for balancing the system in both the short and long terms, and implications of various options for the income security of the elderly. The analysis goes beyond Social Security alone, however, because other elements of the retirement income security system modify the implications of various policy adjustments in the Social Security program. The Evolution of Social Security The Social Security Act of 1935 has proved to be one of the most significant pieces of legislation--if not the most significant piece-ever passed by the Congress of the United States. The act itself evolved quite rapidly in the midst of the Great Depression, but its roots can be traced to the changing socioeconomic structure of thc country dating back to the Civil War. Chapter I examines the origins and evolution of the Social Security system. xxi There is a widespread misconception that Social Security today is somehow radically different from the program that began paying benefits in 1940. It is true that disability and hospital insurance benefits have been added, coverage has expanded, the level of benefits has grown in real terms, and the tax liabilities of workers have increased over the years. But the fundamental elements of the program--the financing basis and the general redistributive structure of the benefit formula--have changed minimally over the years. It is the combination of the maturing of the program and the growth of real benefits that has led to the increased tax burden on workers. In 1950, only 20 percent of the people over age sixty-five received Social Security benefits; today more than 90 percent do so. In 1950, the average monthly benefit, adjusted for inflation, was equivalent to about $125 in 1980 dollars. By the end of 1980, the average benefit was $300 per month. The combined employer and employee payroll taxes on average earnings rose from $200 per year in 1950 (in 1980 dollars) to slightly more than $1,000 in 1980. In the face of financing shortfalls, the maturity of the Social Security program limits the options for adjusting the program to raising revenues or for slowing benefit growth, or for a combination of the two. The Role of Income Sources Other Than Social Security In addition to Social Security benefits, the elderly receive income from pension programs, returns from individual savings and asset holdings, earnings and welfare programs. The changing role of these additional sources of income should not be overlooked in the discussion of Social Security policy; this role is discussed in chapter II. When the Social Security Act was passed in 1935, there were about 750 private pension plans in operation. At the end of 1981, there were nearly 700,000. As a result of this growth, an increasing share of the work force is participating in at least one pension program other than Social Security. In 1979, about 70 percent of the civilian wage-earning and salaried workers outside agriculture between the ages of twentyfive and sixty-four who worked at least half time, participated in a pension program. And the number of pension plans continues to grow. New plans that met the Internal Revenue Service tax qualification standards in 1980 and 1981 had 6.3 million participants. Yet, the pension system in this country is relatively young. Nearly two-thirds of all private-sector tax-qualified defined-benefit plans in 1977 were less than ten years old. Clearly as these plans mature, the proportion of the population receiving a pension will increase markedly. xxii Not only have pension plans burgeoned, but also recent changes to the federal income tax code encourage workers to save for their own retirement. The Keogh program for the self-employed began in 1962; at that time, the program allowed tax-deductible contributions to a retirement program of 10 percent of income up to $2,500 per year. By 1983, the self-employed will be able to contribute to such programs 15 percent of earnings up to $30,000 per year. In 1974, the Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) allowed workers not covered by a pension plan to establish Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs). The 1981 Economic Recovery Tax Act extended this option to all workers, who can now take tax deductions on earnings of up to $2,000 per year for contributions to an IRA. In the case of one-earner couples, the limit has been raised to $2,250. In addition, thanks to modifications to the tax code in 1978, workers now may establish cash or deferred arrangements (CODAs) under qualified profit-sharing or stock bonus plans. CODAs allow workers to divert part of their current earnings into a tax-qualified retirement program; this portion of their salary is not taxed until cash distributions are made to the worker. In addition to having access to special retirement savings programs, about 70 percent of the elderly own their homes at retirement, and nearly 80 percent of these have no mortgage. At retirement, some people liquidate their home equity, but the majority continue to reside in their long-term residence, enjoying the benefits of familiar surroundings and lower housing costs than they would have if they were renting. Besides retirement savings and home significant amounts of additional wealth ticularly true for the self-employed, who that, by retirement, often make them the ciety. equity, many people have at retirement. This is paraccumulate business assets wealthiest members of so- A significant number of people over age sixty-five continue to work. Although the labor-force participation rates of older people have been declining for more than a century, in 1979 nearly half of all families with a member sixty-five years old reported some earned income during the year. The rates decline with age, but were still slightly above 25 percent for persons seventy years old that year. Finally, for those segments of the elderly population who meet the eligibility criteria, there are a variety of means-tested cash and inkind assistance programs: the Supplemental Security Income program, food stamps, housing and energy assistance, and Medicaid. XXlll Often, older Americans are characterized as being solely or largely dependent on Social Security for retirement income. While this is regrettably the case in too many instances, the situation is changing. In the future, the relative contribution of various sources of income will be significantly different from the situation today. Retirement Benefit Levels Under Current Policy In the past, policymakers have often focused on one component of the retirement system at a time, with little regard for the role of other programs. The changes in Social Security that might be considered in upcoming policy deliberations can be expected to affect the distribution of total income for the elderly differently from the way they affect the distribution of Social Security benefits. To assess the implications of current and various policy alternatives, the Employee Benefit Research Institute (EBRI) has developed an in-depth analysis to evaluate a range of policy options. This analysis is based on a microsimulation of a sample of the United States population. It uses a model developed by ICF Incorporated called the Pension and Retirement Income Simulation Model (PRISM). PRISM was enhanced under contract to EBRI specifically for this project. The simulation procedure generates representative work and earnings histories, including periods of retirement program coverage. These work histories are used to estimate retirement benefits under various policy scenarios, policies. and to show the comparative effects of alternative Chapter III of this book provides a detailed description of this model, the base-case assumptions, and the results of the current policy simulation. The results of the simulations are generally consistent with the intuitive expectations based on the evolutionary analysis in chapters I and II. Average Social Security benefits, in dollar values adjusted for inflation, increase for each successive cohort of retirees, in line with assumptions that wages will grow somewhat more rapidly than prices in the future. Both the proportion of the elderly receiving pensions and the average levels of pension benefits are projected to increase steadily; by the second decade of the twenty-first century, three out of four married couples and two out of three single persons are expected to be receiving a pension at age sixty-five. IRAs are also expected to become progressively more important as a source of retirement income in the future. The continuing historical trend of declining labor-force participation rates among the elderly will further reduce the significance of earnings as a source of income xxiv for younger groups of today's workers as they reach normal retirement age. On the whole, the simulation results estimate that average family incomes in constant dollars will roughly double between now and 2015. Social Security Financing Problems The most sensible way to assess Social Security's funding status, given the current structure of the program, is to examine the extent to which currently legislated revenue provisions will be adequate to meet the benefits provided by current law. This evaluation is complicated by the fact that the assessment has to be made on a prospective basis. As was stated at the outset, the OASI trust fund is now depleted, so there is no reserve other than short-term borrowing capability that expires in December 1982. To give a range of potential outcomes, the Social Security actuaries base their estimates of the program's future financing status on a range of assumptions. Chapter IV considers various sets of assumptions, but this summary will consider the financing situation under an "intermediate" set of assumptions referred to in the 1982 Social Security Trustees Report as the Alternative II-B assumptions. Under these assumptions, which may prove to be optimistic, tax collections for the OASI program will fall about $99 billion short of benefit payments between 1982 and 1986. At the end of 1981, the OASI trust fund held $21.5 billion in assets, an amount insufficient to meet the shortfalls in 1982 alone. Just to stay even during the 1982-1986 period, the OASI program would require an increase of 9.0 percent in revenues or a reduction of 8.3 percent in disbursements. The long-term situation is no better. Even if the short-term deficits could be handled, the OASI program would not accumulate enough excess revenues over the next twenty years to pay off the deficits now occurring. Beyond the turn of the century, OASI {aces a deteriorating situation under current program provisions. For the twenty-five-year period beginning in 2007, the Social Security actuaries estimate that the legislated tax rate will fall 21.9 percent short of meeting average annual benefit obligations. In the twenty-five years following that, the actuaries project that the shortfall will be nearly 50 percent short of meeting scheduled benefits. As was mentioned at the outset, the OASI trust fund can supplement its own tax revenues with enough funds borrowed from the DI and HI trust funds to meet the benefit schedule through June 1983. The DI program is solvent and could continue to lend monev to the OASI XXV program, or part of the DI tax collections could be reallocated to the OASI program. The DI program is much smaller than OASI, however, and cannot by itself provide sufficient reserves to resolve the OASI problem. Meanwhile, the HI program is facing its own financing shortfalls, and the HI trust fund is expected to be depleted over the next ten years. Beyond that time, the HI program faces funding shortfalls that are of even greater magnitude than those projected for OASI. Although this report concentrates on the resolution of the OASI financing problem, it is important to note that resolving this problem alone will not solve the funding problems in HI. The 1983 Social Security Advisory Council is focusing primarily on those HI funding problems. The HI and OASI problems are somewhat different, and they do not necessarily have to be resolved simultaneously. Resolving the OASI problem first, in fact, may help to define the range of policy options for addressing the HI program. The Mathematics of Social Term Policy Options Security Financing and Short- The cash benefits provided by Social Security are, for all practical purposes, financed on a pay-as-you-go basis. This means that the revenues collected from current workers and their employers are paid out almost immediately as benefits to retirees. Given the small balances in the trust funds, revenues must closely match benefits during any particular time period for the program to be solvent. The socioeconomic factors that affect both revenues and benefits become extremely important in determining the stability of the system. Through the use of some simple equations, chapter V explores these factors and their effects on the system. Basically, four crucial variables determine the tax rate (t) required to support Social Security over time. These are: (1) the number of covered workers (Nw); (2) their average covered earnings (W); (3) the number of beneficiaries (Nb); and (4) the average level of benefits paid to them (B). For the program revenues to equal benefits paid for a given time period, the tax rate has to equal the ratio of the number of beneficiaries to the number of workers (i.e., Nb/Nw) times the ratio of average benefits to average covered earnings (i.e.i B/W). Focusing on these crucial ratios can clarify some of the problems and potential solutions for balancing Social Security. The primary reason that Social Security has been experier_ciiag financial declines during the past ten years is that both of these .ratios have been unxxvi stable. Because of variations in employment levels, the beneficiaryto-worker ratio will always be somewhat unstable over the economic cycle. During economic downswings, unemployment rises, reducing the number of workers contributing to the program and increasing the number of beneficiaries, as older workers retire rather than become unemployed. In recent years, unemployment has been higher than anticipated in the regular cost projections of the Social Security actuaries. Underestimating unemployment has meant tax collection shortfalls and increased benefit burdens on the system. In the long term, the beneficiary-to-worker ratio will increase significantly as the baby-boom cohort of workers ages and begins to retire after the turn of the century. The ratio of average benefits to average covered wages (B/W) also has been unstable in recent years. A technical error in the 1972 amendments, when automatic benefit indexing was introduced, caused benefits to grow faster than wages did. Although this error was largely resolved for future retirees by the 1977 amendments, retirees who benefited from the earlier error will continue to receive higher benefits throughout their retirement. Even after enactment of the 1977 amendments, however, the continued indexation of retirement benefits by the consumer price index (CPI) has meant further increases in the B/W ratio, because wages have not grown more rapidly than prices, as had been expected. This unforeseen sustained growth in the B/W ratio has meant that the cost of the program has been higher than anticipated in the annual valuations. In the long term, the benefits-to-earnings ratio might be expected to decline as real wages grow. The projected recomposition of the beneficiary population in the future, as a result of the increased prevalence of women in the work force, will stabilize this crucial determinant of the system's long-term cost. Both these ratios for determining the tax rate required to finance Social Security have been moving toward increasing the cost of the program. In combination, their effects are multiplicative of each other. In the short term, a number of policy options can help to ameliorate this situation. The 1977 amendments eliminated much of the problem of the growing benefits-to-earnings ratio. The remaining instability in this ratio can be eliminated by linking postretirement benefit increases to wage growth rather than to price increases. The linkage does not have to be direct if productivity increases are not to be passed on to retirees. For example, indexing retirement benefits by the rate of wage growth minus 1.5 would provide the same benefits as the current price indexing of benefits under the II-B assumptions for the xxvii long term. It would B/W ratio to occur. not, however, allow the recent instability in the There are basically two ways to decrease the ratio of beneficiaries to workers. The first would be to quickly raise the eligibility criteria for benefits. This course would inflict considerable hardship on people who are near retirement, causing extreme disruptions in some instances. The second alternative is to expand coverage to some or all of the roughly 8 percent of current workers not now participating in the program. This course would garner significant revenues in the short term without causing comparable benefit increases in the future, since 80 to 90 percent of current nonparticipants will ultimately get highly subsidized benefits under the current system as a result of taking covered employment at some time before they reach retirement age. The combination of modified benefit indexation and expanded coverage probably would not provide enough savings or increased revenues to meet the short-term deficits, so additional revenues or benefit adjustments would have to be considered. On the revenue side, there are basically two options. The first would be an infusion of general revenues; however, because federal deficits of $150 to $170 billion are projected for each of the next three years, no general revenues are readily available. Because Social Security is in the unified budget, general fund infusions would not worsen the deficit in the short term, but they could prolong or worsen the situation in the long term. The second option for raising additional revenues would be to move forward payroll tax increases already scheduled in law for 1985, 1986, and 1990. Moving forward any of the tax increases would produce new revenues and help to ameliorate the overall budget deficit problem to some extent. On the benefit side, a range of short-term options can be considered. The cost-of-living adjustment (COLA) for one year could be eliminated. For one or several years, the adjustments could be provided only at fifteen-month intervals, rather than annually. They could be capped in either dollar or percentage terms. A somewhat different approach would be to treat some part (e.g., 50 percent) of Social Security benefits as regular income for income tax purposes and earmark the increased revenues for the trust funds. The reason for considering taxation rather than significant COLA modifications is that the taxation alternative would affect only upper-income elderly people who are also receiving income from alternate sources. Eliminating a COLA, on the other hand, would increase poverty rates among the elderly. None of these options would be considered xxviii in the context of Social Security financing if the program were solvent, but the public now widely perceives that the svstem is going bankrupt. Elderly retirees fear for a major portion of their income; young workers do not believe the system will be there when they retire. Without solvency, the program will not have public support; without public support, the svstcm cannot be preserved. The shortterm crisis can be resolved if the burden of balancing the svstem is widely shared. The combination of mandatorv universal coverage, moving forward the 1985 and 1986 tax increases to 1984, and treating half of benefits as regular income would resolve the short-term problem. Other options and combinations can be considered, but unless there is a broad public perception that the problem is being solved through an equitable sharing of the burden, preserving the svstem will be much more difficult. Social Security Beyond the Short Term Chapter VI of this book presents a variety of proposed long-term modifications to Social Security that would help to balance the system's financing. These range from modifications in the benefit formula to adjustments to Social Security's retirement age. To assess the implications of each of the options on the future level and distribution of Social Security benefits and other income sources, several of these options were simulated using the Pension and Retirement Income Simulation Model. (The options themselves are spelled out in the chapter.) The simulation results from each of the policy options were compared with the simulation results from current policy; then the results of the various options were compared with one another. Because PRISM simulates the life and work patterns of individuals, the effects of each option could be compared for individuals with different characteristics. Each of these options has been widelv interpreted as a benefit reduction, but this interpretation is only partly correct. What is not alwavs understood is that there is inherent growth built into the Social Security benefit structure that will increase the purchasing power of average benefits in the future. For example, figure 1 shows the growth in average benefits under the current policy simulation in 1982 dollars as the solid upper line. (Table III-10 in the report shows a similar pattern of benefit growth projected bv the Social Securitv actuaries.) The broken lower line in the figure shows future average Social Security benefit levels under an option that would xxix slow the growth of initial benefit levels through a modification of the benefit formula. The adjustment to the benefit calculation procedure considered here, for the sake of discussion, would begin in January 1984 and, would index the benefit formula "bend points ''_ by 75 percent of wage growth instead of the full wage indexation that is now used to adjust the formula annually. This procedure would be continued for sixteen years under the II-B assumptions, although a shorter or longer period could be used depending on actual economic experience. The net ultimate effect of this benefit formula modification under the II-B assumptions would be to reduce average Social Security benefits by about 11 percent, when compared with the current policy benefit levels. Yet, over the period, average benefits would continue to grow steadily. This option can be perceived as providing a real cut in benefits only if the benefits under the current policy to potential retirees decades hence are considered to be firmly committed--on the way to the bank, so to speak. It is tenuous, at best, to assume that the exact level of Social Security benefits to be paid ten, twenty, or thirty years from now is broadly perceived as that firmly committed. A more important commitment should be to the assurance that the benefits will be there when people need them and that those benefits will provide a reasonable base of support for the elderly's retirement income security. It is also important to remember that there are other sources of income that will help to mitigate the effects of modifications in Social IRetirees' Social Security benefits are based on their lifetime covered earnings. First, the earnings from each year of the workers' careers are adjusted to account for historical growth in average earnings throughout their working lives. A specified number of years of the lowest earnings are dropped; then the remaining lifetime earnings are added together and averaged over the number of months in the years included on the workers' benefit calculations. Benefits are then calculated on the basis of this earnings calculation, referred to as the average indexed monthly earnings (AIME) in technical jargon. The benefit formula established by the 1977 amendments has three replacement rate thresholds that are then applied to the AIME to calculate the basic monthly benefit. If a worker retires prior to age sixty-five, the benefit is adjusted to account for early retirement. In 1981, the Social Security benefit formula replaced 90 percent of the first $211 of AIME plus 32 percent of the next $ 1,063 and 15 percent of any remaining AIME. These different AIME dollar amounts to which benefit calculation factors are applied are often referred to as the formula "bend points." The amount of AIME that is subject to each factor increases each year by the rate of average wage growth in the economy. For example, in 1982 the formula replaced 90 percent of the first $230 of AIME, plus 32 percent of the next $1,158, plus 15 percent of any AIME over $1,388. xxx FIGURE 1 Future Average Family Social at Age 65 Security Benefits In 1982 Dollars $10,000, 9,000 ..... Current Policy Benefits Modified Benefit Formula • 1985 Average Benefit Level / e • _ 8,000. . ...*'°'... e. ee °e eeeeeeeee 7,000 ee - ••"°" eee " e* ee°e 6,000 ........... "" 5,000 I 1985 I 1990 I 1995 I 2000 Year I 2005 I 2010 I 2015 Source: Social Security benefits estimated from the Pension and Retirement Income Simulation Model. Security. By the time any of the long-term options being seriously discussed is fully implemented, the portion of the elderly population receiving pension and IRA annuities will be significantly higher than is currently the case. Figure 2 shows the estimated average disposable income for future cohorts of retirees from the PRISM simulations under three different Social Security policy scenarios in 1982 dollars. The top line in the figure represents estimated average disposable family income under current Social Security policy. The middle line shows the projected path of average income under the Social Security benefit formula modification that would slow bend-point growth to 75 percent of wages for a defined period. The bottom line shows the projected path if the formula were modified and half of Social Security benefits began to be treated as regular income. The difference between the current policy and the combined alternatives may be considered as a 9 percent reduction in income at age sixty-five by the year 2015. Another way of expressing the difference is to say that under current policy, average real disposable income is projected to xxxi FIGURE Future Average Disposable 2 Family Income at Age 65 In 1982 Dollars $22,000, -• ...... ...... 20,000 ! 8,000 Current Policy Modified Benefit Formula Modified Formula and Tax 50% _ ....... of Benefits _'_... • • """ _.-. .... 1985 Average Fam,ly Income /'_,---"_-.--'''- 16,000 .." s S oe ° 14,000 ..._ _..* 12,000 Source: s S • • _-"" °_ I I I ° 1985 1990 1995 I 2000 Year ss I 2005 I I 2010 Disposable family income estimated from the Pension and Retirement Simulation Model. 2015 Income rise by 1.9 times between 1985 and 2015, whereas it might go up only 1.8 times under the modified policy• The combined effects of modifying the formula plus treating half of benefits as regular income would ',:lose at least 90 percent of the projected long-term deficit in the Social Security cash benefit programs. This particular set of options has been chosen not to represent a preferred policy option, but rather to put the discussion in a proper context• Each of the other options discussed in chapter VI would have distributional results somewhat different from those associated with this particular option, in the aggregate. but most would not be significantly different Universal Social Security Coverage and the Alternatives In 1939, Congress realized that there was a long-term problem in the benefit formula adopted at that time--a problem relating to people who moved back and forth between covered and noncovered emxxxii ployment. amendments The House stated: of Representatives' report on the 1939 An average wage formula will also have the effect of raising the level of benefits payable in the early years of the system, but it will reduce future costs by eliminating unwarranted bonuses payable under the present formula to workers in insured employment onlv a few years. These bonuses result from the greater weight now given to the first $3,000 of accumulated wages. They are justified, if a total wage formula is used, in the case of older and low-paid workers who retire in the early years of the system and have not had time in which to build up substantial benefit rights. In the long run, however, such bonuses are unwise and endanger the solvency of the system by permitting disproportionately large benefits to workers who migrate between uninsured and insured employment and accumulate only small earnings in insured employment. 2 Today, these "unwarranted bonuses," as Congress called them, are costing Social Security at least $2 billion per year. In the long term, the net savings from mandatory universal OASDI coverage would be 0.5 percent of payroll, or slightly more than one-quarter of the projected long-term deficit in the Social Securitv cash benefit program. If Congress had mandated universal coverage in 1977, the last time they dealt with the Social Security financing crisis, there would be no short-term problem today. The coverage issue is a political lightning rod, however, and has been successfully opposed on several occasions by the groups now exempted. Only about 8 percent of all current workers are not participating, but as many as 90 percent of these people will ultimately receive benefits as a result of taking covered employment sometime in their careers. If the current exemptions are extended and the "unwarranted bonuses" are perpetuated, both the short- and long-term adjustments for full participants will have to be more severe. Other Policy Considerations As Congress takes up the task of preserving the Social Security system, it may wish to reconsider several other controversial or troublesome Social Security policy issues that have been discussed over the years. These include: (1) the equity of Social Security's treatment of women; (2) the elimination or modification of the earnings test; (3) the financing of some portion of the Social Security program through general revenues; (4) the development of a mechanism for dealing 2House of Representatives, 76th Congress, First Session, Act Amendments of 1939 (June 2, 1939), p. 10. Report no. 728, Social Security xxxiii with trust fund accumulations, should they occur, which could help to prefund a portion of the benefit liabilities for the baby-boom generation; and (5) a fundamental reorientation of the whole system of social insurance for the contingencies of old-age, disability, and survivorship. Chapter VIII deals with each of these issues in some detail. The Future of Social Security Historically, Social Security policy has attempted to balance the countervailing goals of adequacy and equity through its financing and benefit structure. Until recently, this process has been relatively uncontroversial because virtually all beneficiaries have received, or could expect to receive, benefits that substantially exceeded the value of their contributions. The days are quickly passing when all members of each retiring group of workers can expect to receive more than the value of their combined employer-employee payroll tax contributions. The future balance of adequacy and equity has to be considered in the framework of a broader set of priorities. Two equally important policy goals for Social Security are solvency and public support. If these goals are not met, adequacy and equity considerations will become moot. Questions about Social Security's solvency have substantially shaken the confidence of old and young alike. Without confidence that the program is solvent, continued support will wither. Intergenerational concerns about Social Security link the shortand long-term considerations. Policymakers cannot seek solvency with total disregard for either adequacy or equity. There is general agreement across the entire political spectrum that retirees must not be ravaged by program modifications. At the same time, the national commitment to the income security of the elderly must be perceived as a burden equitably shared by all elements of society. The story that the numbers throughout this book tell is that the future may not be so dismal as a narrow focus on Social Security's current financing projections would suggest. While no one can predict the future with great accuracy, some trends can be observed and their outcomes predicted. For example, American society is aging, and it will continue to do so. In addition, pensions and private retirement savings are growing in importance as sources of retirement income security, and they will continue to do so in a favorable policy environment. Although the aging of society is bound to put extra stress on Social Security, the growth of pensions can help to relieve some of that burden. xxxiv These two countervailing trends suggest that Social Security can adjust in the future to meet the needs of society. The uncertainty of the extent of changes in the economy, productivity, birthrates, life expectancy, and a host of other factors suggests that Congress should adopt a Social Security policy that allows some margin for error. In essence, this means that any policy changes Congress makes in the current environment should not promise more for the future than we are sure we can provide. One has to assume that future Congresses will be better equipped in ten or twenty years hence to assess appropriate benefit and taxing provisions in their respective times. Policymakers then will be better able to .judge the relative needs and capabilities of their society and economy than anyone in Congress can judge today. It we cannot trust the future political process in this society, we should be seeking not to insure ourselves against that process, but to change it fundamentally. XXXV Foreword Since its creation in the 1930s, Social Security has been at the center of national public policy debates. In 1945 there were twenty workers for every retiree and few sources of retirement income security outside the extended family. Today, there are only three active workers to support each retiree, and extended families are almost nonexistent. More than 50 percent of new retirees receive pension income other than Social Security. Increasingly, workers are gaining access to these additional pension income sources. Preserving Social Security is a national goal that requires thoughtful attention and bipartisan action. In this study, Svlvcster J. Schieber carefully analvzcs the development of Social Security and complementary retirement income systems. He thoroughly reviews both the short-term and long-term financing issues; and he demonstrates the effects of various solutions to Social Securitv's financial problems. As Dr. Schicbcr points out, concern over benefit adequacy and equity dates back to Social Security's inception. Debate about the benefit adequacy and equity goals has led to the consideration of alternative social insurance systems. For example, there were proposals for replacing the current system with a "double-decker" system as long ago as the 1940s. This study discusses questions such as the basic reorganization of the Social Security system today. Schieber stresses that while the existing structure of the system has been the subject of continuing policy debate, the program generally has enjoycd widespread public support. This is in part because retirees have traditionally received more in benefits than they paid in Social Security taxes. Many young taxpayers now perceive that they will not receive as great a return on their investment in Social Security as their parents received. The widespread public confidence in the system has been shaken bv recent events. The elderly live in fear that their benefits mav run out, while young workers who are contributing to the program fear that the program will not be there when they reach retirement age. Public support can no longer be considered automatic. To maintain the integrity of the system, public confidence must be restored. Policvmakers should deal with both the short- and long-term problems in the system now. This should be done through decisive, fair action rather than bv asking future generations to pay higher taxes than we are willing to pay. xxxvii This study developed out of Dr. Schieber's work as Research Director of the Employee Benefit Research Institute. Computer work was provided under contract by David L. Kennel[, John F. Shiels, and John Castner of ICF Incorporated. Priscilla Taylor edited the manuscript. Appreciation is expressed to the many people who commented on drafts of the study and to those who prepared the manuscript. Dwight K. Bartlett, Robert J. Myers, and A. Haeworth Robertson, all former chief actuaries of the Social Security Administration, are owed special thanks for their review and comments. The views expressed in the study are those of the author and should not be attributed to officers, trustees, members, associates, or other staff members of the Employee Benefit Research Institute, its Education and Research Fund, or to any of those who were consulted with or commented on the manuscript. DALLAS Executive November xxxviii L. SALISBURY Director 1, 1982 Introduction A front-page article in the New York Times on October 18, 1982, broke the story that within a month, Social Security's largest program, the Old-Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) program, would have to borrow money from the Disabilitv Insurance (DI) and Hospital Insurance (HI) programs to meet scheduled benefit payments. The news spread quickly. For several years, analysts who have been tracking the Social Security program have known of the pending financing problems. Moreover, innumerable accounts of the situation have appeared in the media, some of them thoughtful and informative, others anecdotal and confusing. The political discussion of the issue has also been somewhat uneven. Rather than an attempt to educate the public and dispel confusion, the public discourse has often been described bv the politicians themselves as "demagogic." As a result of the conflicting information, the public has been generally skeptical about the seriousness of the problem. Skepticism about the existence of a "crisis" in Social Security on the one hand, is a striking counterpoint to numerous analyses that Social Security is unsalvagcable on the other. It is not surprising that the public is confused bv the wide range of opinions about the Social Security program. For example, Dr. Henry Aaron, an economist at the Brookings Institution, argues that the situation can be resolved with moderate adjustment, while Dr. Michael Boskin, an economist at Stanford University, argues that the social insurance system known as Social Securitv has to be radically reconfigured. This book was written to clarify some of the issues that are central to the Social Security debate now beginning in the public policy arena. The discussion presented here analyzes a wide range of policy options and their implications for Social Security financing, as well as their potential effects on the economic security of elderly people. The analysis does not conclude with a definitive list of policy prescriptions that need to be implemented in order to assure Social Security's financial solvency. There are actually several ways that the OASI program can be balanced in both the short and long terms. It is not a question of whether it can be done, but rather how it should be done. This analysis seeks to intorm the public and to help policymakers who evaluate the ramifications of various alternatives. Background To some extent, Social Security can be thought of as a savings program. Workers, along with their employers, pay taxes to the system based on their earnings. This participation in the program "earns" workers a benefit they are "entitled" to receive when they have met certain eligibility criteria of the program. In other words, workers give up part of their current income while working, in return for an income that will be provided to them after they retire. Social Security is different from traditional savings programs, however, because the contributions of each individual worker are not put aside into an account that is specifically his or hers. For the most part, the aggregate tax collections from all employers and workers are put together each month to pay the benefits as they come due. In this sense, Social Security is not a savings program, but rather an intergenerational transfer program. This simply means that the program collects revenues from one generation (i.e., workers) and passes them on to another (i.e., retirees). American society consists of a broad range of individuals and families which can be thought of as economic units. The activities of these basic economic units tend to follow a pattern over their lifetimes, with some variation among groups and individuals. If these economic units are observed over time, it becomes apparent that for the majority, individual members typically spend a portion of their lifetimes in the work force, earning a living. Prior to work-force participation on an intensive and sustained basis, the typical person is born, reared, and educated through a complementary set of privately and publicly financed family and educational institutions. During their working years, most people are relatively self-sustaining. They meet their own consumption needs and those of their children, if they have them. In addition, many people also save part of their earned income during their working lives to help meet their needs during periods when they cannot provide sufficiently for themselves and to supplement the income that they can expect from Social Security. Prior to the development of the broad set of programs that have come to be known as social insurance in this country, the private accumulation of savings and dependence on one's own grown children or other relatives were the chief mechanisms for providing economic sustenance to people who could no longer make their own way because of old age or disability. This approach to economic security seemed to meet society's needs during the early years of the nation, 2 but as the economic structure ures became noticeable. became increasingly urbanized, fail- Retirement programs began to develop in the United States in the latter half of the nineteenth century when it had become clear that circumstanccs could arise which were beyond workers' control and for which they could not or would not prepare. People often cannot anticipate the occurrence of disability or premature death, and they need some sort of insurance protection against income loss for themselves and their dependents when either does occur. People must also provide for themselves in their old age; they cannot depend solely on being able to work until they die. Each of these contingencies could be provided for through private insurance and savings mechanisms. The evidence of the early 1900s, before the advent of the Social Securitv Act, however, was that these mechanisms were not sufficiently developed to meet the challenge. Today, private insurance and pensions are more prevalent and secure and new tax incentives exist to encourage private retirement savings, but participation in these programs is still not universal. Even if it were, low-wage earners would be unable to provide adequate protection for themselves, and some kind of public subsidy would be necessary to prevent widespread economic deprivation. The fact is that if Social Security did not exist in the United States today, there would still be many people who would not be protected by alternative provisions. When the contingencies requiring income support arose, these people would suffer hardship or require public support or both. In a society as diverse as ours, there has to be a social insurance mechanism to support people in the event of earnings loss. Scope of the Current Analysis In 1935 when the Social Security Act was passed, its primary architect, President Franklin D. Roosevelt, did not intend for it to be the sole source of support for large segments of the United States population. Since that time, significant changes have been made in Social Security and in other elements of the retirement income security system. The analysis in this book attempts to clarify some of the issues relating to those changes and their significance for the current deliberations. Chapter I describes the historical development of the Social Security Act and its evolution, in a structural sense, into the program 3 that we know today. The time devoted to the historical perspective may seem inordinate. The chapter is included, however, because it seeks to dispel some broadly held myths that Social Security is a radically different program from the one originally conceived. Chapter II describes the evolution of other organized and individual retirement, savings, and income transfer programs that provide income support to people during their old age. This chapter may also seem to dwell on history, but the purpose is to show that these programs evolve over time and that the expectations from them tomorrow should be quite different from the level of benefits they are providing today. Chapter III provides a set of estimates of what future income levels would be for retirees if we were to continue current policies and programs without change. This chapter serves primarily as a baseline for detailed analysis of a host of alternative policies later in chapter VI. Chapter not focus the short problem changing IV discusses the Social Security financing problem. It does solely on where we are today and what we can expect in or long terms but explains how the Social Security financing crept up through a process of program modifications and socioeconomic circumstances. Chapter V focuses on the intrinsic elements of the Social Security program that gave rise to the financing problem and describes a series of options that might stabilize the program in the short term. While chapter IV focuses on the magnitude of the problem and its recognition, chapter V explains why there is a problem. For anyone wanting to understand the nature of the financing problem, chapter V is one of the most important sources of information in the book. Chapter VI describes several proposals that have been widely considered as ways to deal with the long-term Social Security financing deficits. The first part of the chapter describes these proposals and their long-term effects on the program's financing. The second part of the chapter looks at what the implications of each of the proposals considered would be for future beneficiaries. The last part of the chapter compares the distributional implications of the various options. Chapter VII discusses the issue of mandatory universal Social Security coverage and the various alternatives that have been proposed. The noncoverage of about 8 percent of the work force gives rise to serious equity questions that Congress should consider. This chapter describes and analyzes these equity questions. The chapter also explains how extending coverage to remaining noncovered workers would have significant, beneficial financing effects on Social Security in both the short and long terms. Chapter VIII discusses a range of other issues that are mentioned elsewhere in the book but deserve further consideration. Five issues are discussed at length: (1)the equity of the current treatment of women under Social Security spouse and survivor benefit provisions; (2) the problems with maintaining the earnings test in Social Security; (3) the potential of financing some portion of the program through general revenues; (4) the problem of OASDI trust fund accumulations to unmanageable levels under certain policy options; and (5)three proposals that would change the Social Security system more fundamentally than any of the other incremental changes considered throughout the analysis. The last chapter summarizes the prospects for the future of Social Security and for the retirement income security of elderly people. I. The Evolution Program of the Social Security The Social Security Act, signed into law on August 14, 1935, was undoubtedly one of the most significant pieces of legislation ever passed bv the United States Congress. The original act and subsequent amendments established a number of programs that arc beyond the scope of this discussion. This chapter will focus on those programs that are financed primarily by Social Security payroll taxes, including the Old-Age (OA), Survivors (S), Disability (D), and Hospital (H) Insurance (I) programs (OASDHI) which constitute what the public usually thinks of as Social Security. I When thc initial act was passed in 1935, it included only Old-Age Insurance and was limited to private-sector workers in commerce and industry. Traditionally, the program has been financed bv the payroll tax, first levied in 1937. The first old-age benefit check was issued in January 1940 to Ida M. Fuller of Ludlow, Vermont.2 Benefits for dependents and survivors were added in 1939, disability benefits in 1956, and health insurance in 1965. Before we examine this evolution in detail, it is important to review the context in which the Social Security Act was developed and passed in 1935. Then the actual development of the initial Social Security Act is described in some detail. This includes a description of the developmental process, the substance of the original act, and the subsequent modifications. This chapter seeks to provide a broad historical and conceptual framework that defines the Social Security structure as we know it today. The Early Development of Retirement Programs The earliest retirement program in this country can be traced back to 1636 when the settlers at Plymouth Colony decreed "that any man sent forth as a soldier and returned maimed should be maintained by the colony during his life." The colonies made similar provisions for men who were disabled and for survivors of men who were killed in military expeditions against the Indians. The first national pension IThis discussion will not generally focus on the Supplementary Medical Insurance (SMI) program, "Part B" of Medicare, which is tinanced by' premiums paid by people who elect to be covered and subsidized through general revenues. 2W. Andrew Achenbaum, Old Age iu the New Land (Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1978), p. 126. 7 law, which dates back to 1776, provided half pay for life, or during disability, for soldiers disabled during the Revolutionary War. Military provisions based on service date back to 1780. Gradually, service pensions came to be provided separately for veterans of each war. In 1861, the first major nondisability program provided for voluntary retirement of military officers after forty years of duty. In 1885, nondisability retirement was extended to Marine and Army enlistees, providing voluntary retirement after thirty years of service. 3 Civilian retirement programs in this country date back to the end of the eighteenth century. In 1794 Albert Gallatin established the first recorded profit-sharing plan in his glassworks in Pennsylvania. New York City established a pension system for its policemen in 1857. A smattering of additional local public pensions were started during the remainder of the nineteenth century. In 1911 Massachusetts established the first state retirement program for public employees. About a dozen private pension plans existed in 1900; the number grew to about 60 by 1910, 270 by 1920, and 420 by 1930. 4 The federal Civil Service Retirement System began in 1920. Early on, pensions were established for many of the same reasons they still are being established today, including employers' desires to encourage retirement of older workers, so younger ones could move up the organizational ladder, and employers' desires to entice superior workers and discourage excessive turnover by providing an attractive compensation package. Most of the early pension plans provided no benefits prior to age sixty-five, and they often required twenty or more years of continuous service prior to retirement. Some of the early plans included restrictions prohibiting the hiring of workers over forty-five to fifty-five years of age. Many of the early pension plans were "final-pay" plans, which provided annual benefits equal to 1.0 to 1.5 percent of final average pay for each year of service. The growth of organized retirement programs was not an isolated American phenomenon. In Europe, interest in providing security for old age dates back to the nineteenth century. In fact, European mining communities had established miners' funds as far back as the Middle Ages. These funds provided income replacement for men who could _Office of the Actuary, Del_ense Manpower Data Center, Valuation o[ the Military Retirement System: Fiscal Year 1980 (Washington, D.C.: U .S. Government Printing Office, 1981), p. 2. 4M. W. Latimer, Industrial Pensio_t Systems in the United States and Canada (New York: Industrial Relations Counselors, Inc., 1933). no longer work in the mines because of age or disability. 5 Horlick, an American authority, notes that as early as 1832 German employers were beginning to establish old-age retirement programs; he suggests that these employer programs were the precursors of Germany's social security program adopted in 1889. 6 Two types of public programs for the aged evolved in Europe: noncontributory old-age assistance programs aimed at deserving elderly poor, and contributory types to cover the working population. The first of the noncontributory plans was established in Denmark in 1891. During the first decade of the twentieth century, France and Great Britain established similar programs. By the beginning of World War I, New Zealand, Austria, Newfoundland, and Iceland had oldage assistance programs in operation. After the war, the trend continued around the world with several more national programs being established .7 Two objections arose in connection with these programs: (1)the "means-tested" basis of the programs conflicted with the general desire to make benefits available as a right upon attaining old age, and (2) as the number of needy recipients increased, the old-age assistance programs put an increasing fiscal strain on the sponsoring governments .8 These concerns encouraged the rapid growth of the contributory type of old-age income support program that actually preceded the establishment of the early assistance programs. The contributory program established by Bismarck in Germany in 1889 covered all wage and salary workers and provided disability (then called invalidity) and old-age benefits. In 1911 the German program was amended to provide survivor benefits. Prior to World War I, Luxembourg, Rumania, Sweden, and the Netherlands had enacted contributory programs. Between the end of World War I and 1927, an additional fifteen countries, mostly European, enacted contributory old-age programs. These included France and Great Britain, which had established oldage assistance tems.9 programs prior to setting up their contributory 5Committee on Economic Security, Social Security in America (Washington, Government Printing Office, 1937), p. 181. 6Max Horlick, Private Pensions in West Germany and France (Washington, Security Administration, 1980), p. 3. 7Comrnittee on Economic Security, Social Security in America, p. 181. Slbid. 91bid., pp. 181-182 and 470. sys- D.C.: U.S. D.C.: Social 9 Environment in the United Social Security t° States Prior to Enactment of More than forty-five years passed between the time that the first contributory programs were established in European countries and the Social Security Act was passed in the United States. There are many reasons to explain this significant time lag. At the end of the Civil War the elderly constituted about 3 percent of the U.S. population, as shown in table I-1. Declining birthrates in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, increasingly restrictive immigration policy, and gradual improvement of life expectancy all contributed to an aging population. The elderly as a percentage of the United States population doubled during the lifetimes of persons who reached age sixty-five by 1935. Furthermore, actuarial projections at that time estimated they would again roughly double, to make up 11.3 percent of the population by 1980.11 TABLE I-I Percentage Year 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 of the Population Over Age 65, 1870-1940 Percentage of Population Over Age 65 3.0 3.4 3.9 4.1 4.3 4.7 5.4 6.3 Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975),p. 14,Series 91-104. Not only was the country's population aging, but the nation's economic fabric was changing as well. During the 1880s, the economy was still predominantly agrarian with more than half the labor force engaged in agricultural employment (see table 1-2). By 1910 agricultural employment had declined to 31.4 percent of the labor force. In the decades since 1910, agricultural employment has declined in ab_°For a detailed discussion of changing retirement policy in the United States, see Achenbaum, OM Age in the New Land. lICommittee on Economic Security, Social Security in America, p. 141. It is worth noting that forty-five years later this estimate has proved to be correct. 10 solute terms as well as relative size. This shift from an agricultural economy to an industrial one was accomplished largely bv the movement of younger workers to urban .jobs. According to the 1910 census, 29 percent of farm operators were under age thirty-five, while not quite 24 percent were over age fifty-five. The 1930 census showed that farm operators under age thirty-five had declined to 23 percent while those over age fifty-five had risen to 29 percent of the total. 12 TABLE I-2 Labor Year Force and Employment Labor Force (Thousands) in Agriculture, 1870-1940 Employment in Agriculture Number Percentage of Total (Thousands) Labor Force 1870 12,930 6,790 52.5 1880 17,390 8,920 51.3 1890 23,320 9,960 42.7 1900 29,070 11,680 40.2 1910 37,480 11,770 31.4 1920 41,610 10,790 25.9 1930 48,930 10,560 21.6 1940 56,290 9,575 17.0 Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics o[ the United States (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975),p. 139, Series D 182-232. Historically, agricultural employment has been far less sensitive to recessions and depressions than nonfarm employment has been. The decline in agriculture was important because it increased the sensitivity of employment to the general level of economic activity. A comparison of the rates of nonfarm unemployment and unemployment in the total labor force shows this relationship. Between 1900 and 1940, the unemployment rate showed greater variation for nonfarm workers than for the total labor force (see table I-3). More significant is the consistent decline in the ratio of the nonfarm to total unemployment rates. During the early 1900s, nonfarm unemployment was consistently double that for the total labor force; swings in unemployment also were twice as high in the nonfarm sector as in the total labor force. During the dust bowl period in the late 1920s and early 1930s, when natural disaster wrought havoc in the Plains states and dislocated many farmers, agricultural unemployment levels _2u.s. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics o[the UnitedStates (Washington, D.C.: U,S. Government Printing Office, 1975). p. 465, Series K 82-108. 11 rose. As growth in the nonfarm sector of the economy grew, the effects of cyclical swings in the economy were exacerbated. At the turn of the century, the nonfarm unemployment rate was consistently at least twice that of total labor-force unemployment. When nonfarm unemployment reached all-time high levels in the Great Depression of the 1930s, it was only 50 percent higher than unemployment in the total labor force. TABLE 1-3 Five-Year Period 1900-1904 1905-1909 1910-1914 1915-1919 1920-1924 1925-1929 1930-1934 1935-1939 Variations in Unemployment Rates for the Civilian Labor Force and Nonfarm Workers, 1900-1939 Civilian Labor Unemployment Rate High Low Difference (Percent) (Percent) (Percent) 5.4 8.0 7.9 8.5 11.7 4.2 25.2 20.3 3.7 1.7 4.3 1.4 2.4 1.8 8.9 14.3 1.7 6.3 3.6 7.1 9.3 2.4 16.3 6.0 Nonfarm Worker Unemployment Rate High Low Difference (Percent) (Percent) (Percent) 12.6 16.4 14.7 15.6 19.5 6.9 37.6 30.2 8.6 3.9 8.2 2.4 4.1 2.9 14.2 21.3 4.0 12.5 6.5 13.2 15.4 2.0 23.4 8.9 Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics o[the United States (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975),p. 126, Series D 1-10. Industrialization of the United States changed the status of older workers. In an agrarian society, elderly people could choose to continue to work at their own enterprises or to pass the reins on to subsequent generations. Retirement was often a gradual process, with the older farmer first taking on less strenuous activities in the production process as the sons undertook the heavier tasks. Opportunities for gradual retirement were more limited in the industrial workplace. The increased mechanization of production processes required vigorous, competitive workers. "In such competition the position of older persons tends to become more and more unfavorable."13 Hence large employers had begun establishing pension programs to provide retirement income for superannuated workers in public as t_Committee on Economic Security, Social Security in America, p. 143. 12 well as private employment. At the end of the nineteenth century, nearly 70 percent of the men over sixty-five continued to work; by 1920 tewer than 56 percent did so. 14 The various factors affecting the elderlv's ability to provide for themselves converged during the early 1930s. The transition from an agrarian society was far enough along that significant numbers of older workers were being retired. Demographic factors were increasing the size of the elderly population to more noticeable levels. Finally, the Depression, which raised unemployment levels among nonfarm workers above 35 percent, had a particularly devastating effect on the elderly. Not only did the Depression eliminate many employment opportunities for older workers, but also the stock market crash of 1929 and the rash of bank failures during the early years of the Depression wiped out the limited resources that many older workers had accumulated. Furthermore, many of those who had pension protection lost it when businesses collapsed. Achenbaum reports: "Forty-five plans, covering one hundred thousand employees, were discontinued between 1929 and 1932; other plans, lacking an adequate fiscal base, curtailed benefits. ''_s In this environment, a host of proposals for supporting the aged were put forth. Arizona enacted the first publicly supported old-age assistance bill in the United States in 1915, but that bill was later declared unconstitutional. By the end of 1928, six states had established old-age assistance programs that counties within the states could adopt if they so chose. These programs provided benefits to slightly more than 1,000 people over sixty-five years of age in 1928. By the end of 1934, twenty-eight states had established old-age assistance programs. Many of the programs became mandatory for all counties within the states that established programs after 1929. Bv the end of 1934, nearly 250,000 people were benefiting from these old-age assistance programs. 16 High unemployment levels, particularly among the elderly', led to a couple of revolutionary policy prescriptions. Francis E. Townsend, a retired California doctor, proposed that every citizen over sixty years of age who was not employed be entitled to receive $200 per month on the condition that the recipient spend the benefit within thirty days of its receipt. This proposal was aimed at simuhaneouslv _4U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics o['the U_zited States (Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975), p. 132, Serics D 29-41. ISAchenbaum, O/d Age i_z the New La_ld, p. 129. 16Committee on Economic Security, Social Security m America, pp. 159-163. D.C.: 13 providing for the elderly and stimulating the general economic demand for goods and services. The program was to be financed by a 2 percent sales tax on all transactions, which most policy analysts at the time estimated to be grossly inadequate. Also early in the Depression, Senator Huey Long of Louisiana was beginning a run for the presidency with a campaign based on the policies he outlined in his book, Eve_. Man a King, published in 1933. Among other things, he proposed free college educations for everyone, a homestead worth $5,000 for every family, veterans' bonuses, and old-age pensions for the elderly with less than $10,000 in cash. During Franklin D. Roosevelt's first year in office, more than onequarter of the U.S. work force and more than one-third of the nonfarm workers were jobless. The Townsend plan was gathering widespread support and the Democratic party was concerned that Senator Long's campaign could garner enough votes to result in the election of a Republican president in 1936. In this context FDR proposed a program to assure the economic security of the United States and its population. On June 8, 1934, the president sent a message to Congress indicating his desire to establish a long-range, contributory social insurance program. He opposed financing this system through general revenues on two grounds: (1) he believed a contributory system would be more fiscally secure, and possibly more important; (2) he felt that personal contributions to the system would build in a political safeguard, because the benefits would be perceived as an earned right, t7 Development of the Social On June 29, 1934, President Security Act Roosevelt issued Executive Order 6757 which established a Committee on Economic Security to study the problems related to the economic security of individuals and to develop recommendations to promote greater economic security. The Committee consisted of the Secretary of Labor as chairman, the Secretary of Treasury, the Attorney General, the Secretary of Agriculture, and the Federal Emergency Relief Administrator. The committee was to report its recommendations to the president by December 1, 1934. In addition to establishing the committee, President Roosevelt's executive order also created an Advisory Council on Economic Security, a Technical Board on Economic Security, and a staff to assist the 17Arthur J. Altmeyer, The Formative Wisconsin Press, 1968), pp. 10-11. 14 Years ofSocial Security (Madison: University of Committee on Economic Security. Edwin E. Witte was selected as executive director of the staff on July 24, 1934. The staff was to work under the immediate direction of the executive director but at the general direction of the technical board, which was composed of people then in government service designated by the committee. Arthur J. Altmeyer was appointed chairman of the technical board. The advisory council, which was made up of people outside the federal bureaucracy, was initially to include fifteen representatives: five each from business, the labor movement, and the general population. Because of various special interest additions, the council ultimatelv included twentv-three members. The Committee on Economic Security concentrated on major policy issues, resolving questions in accordance with the president's policy positions. I_ The technical board was to help the staff develop a concrete program while apprising committee members of the issues important to their policy deliberations. The advisory council was not to make a formal report but rather to advise the committee of the views of interested outside groups and individuals. The advisory council did submit a final report that included several recommendations somewhat different from the final recommendations of the committee itself. Dr. Witte's diary of the proceedings of these various groups suggests that the advisory council had little influence on the deliberations by the committee or on the development of the ultimate proposal. 19 The major players then were the president, his Cabinet-level committee, their designees as technical advisers, and the staff that Dr. Witte organized. On Januarv 17, 1935, the president transmitted a message to both the House of Representatives and the Senate recommending legislation on economic security. 2° At the same time he transmitted the report of the Committee on Economic Security that provided the analytical basis for the various titles in the act. On Januarv 21 and 22, the House Ways and Means Committee and the Senate Finance Committee began hearings on the proposed legislation. According to Witte, both committees focused on the o/d-age assistance (title I) provisions in the act. In the Ways and Means Committee, the old-age insurance (title II) provisions provided the most contro- _The intended functions of the various bodies have been described in ibid., p. 8. I_Edwin E. Wittc, The Developme_zt of the Social Security Act (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1963), p. 63. 2°Ibid. The discussion of the legislative consideration of the act is based on Witte's diarvaccount, pp. 75 108. 15 versy, and were nearly stricken at one point. Ultimately, the House committee completely redrafted the legislation, making several substantive changes in the provisions. The committee also changed the title of the legislation from the "Economic Security Act" to the "Social Security Act." The committee favorably reported out the bill on April 5, and the House began debate on April 11. Roughly fifty amendments were offered to the bill but none passed. On April 19, 1935, the House passed the Social Security Act by a vote of 371 to 33. The legislation's opponents concentrated their strongest opposition on the Senate Finance Committee. Witte suggests that it was the adroit management of the committee chairman, Senator Pat Harrison of Mississippi, that salvaged title II, the old-age insurance provision, in the bill. The real fight in the Senate Finance Committee was over the Clark amendment, which would have exempted employers with pension programs from participation in the old-age insurance program. In committee, this amendment was defeated on a tie vote. On May 20, the Senate Finance Committee filed a report in favor of the legislation. Debate on the bill in the Senate began on June 14. When the Clark amendment was reintroduced on the Senate floor, it became the subject of extended acrimonious debate. On June 19 the amendment was finally adopted by a vote of 51 to 32, and the Senate then approved the legislation 77 to 6. The Conference Committee did not begin deliberations until the end of June. All differences in the two legislative versions, with the exception of the Clark amendment, were reconciled by July 16. The conferees reported back to their respective bodies recommending adoption of agreed-upon facets of the bill and seeking further instruction on the Clark amendment. On July 17, both the Senate and House accepted this conference report but the chambers instructed their respective conferees to hold firm to their different positions on the Clark amendment. The Conference Committee set about having the amendment redrafted. After several weeks, the legislative drafters indicated to the committee that their work would extend beyond the end of the legislative session. The conferees then recommended that the Social Security Act be adopted without the Clark amendment, with the understanding that a joint committee be formed to develop such legislation for the next session of Congress. The conference report was accepted by the House on August 8 and by the Senate on August 9. The Social Security Act became law on August 14, 1935, when President Roosevelt signed it. 16 The Provisions of the Social Security Act The Social Security Act passed in 1935 was basically a retirement annuity program. Coverage was mandated for private-sector wageearning and salaried workers under age sixty-five engaged in commerce or industry, with the exception of railroad employees. In 1937 this group of covered workers included roughly 58 percent of all paid employment in the United States. The program was to be financed by a payroll tax, shared equally by employers and employees, initially set at 1 percent on the first $3,000 of covered annual earnings. Tax collections began in 1937; the first benefits were scheduled for January 1942. Benefits were to be paid to retired workers on the basis of cumulative earnings credits, and were to be weighted to favor lowincome earners. Contributors who died before receiving a benefit were to have their contributions plus an allowance for interest returned to their estates. The Social Security Act was substantially modified before the first retirement benefit was paid. In 1939 the first amendments to the act: (1) expanded Social Security's retirement provisions to include benefits for dependents of retirees and survivors of active workers and retirees; (2) eliminated the provision for contribution rebates and the age restriction for participation; (3) significantly altered the benefit computation formula; and (4)provided for the first benefits to be payable in January 1940. The 1939 amendments were the precursors of many additional changes to Social Security. The institutional role that the Social Security Administration has played and the political process involved in the development of Social Security policy have been discussed at length in a Brookings study by Martha Derthick. 21 Another study, bv Robert J. Myers, provides a comprehensive description of the actual changes to the program over the years. 22 While it is unnecessary to repeat those analyses here, it is important to understand the effects of the changes on the program and its participants over time. The following sections discuss the evolution of Social Security coverage, retirement age provisions, benefit structure, and financing provisions of the program. Social Security tee on Economic Coverage--The proposal developed by the CommitSecurity limited the scope of coverage for various 21Martha Derthick, Polic_vmaki_lg [or Social Security (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1979). 22Robert J. Myers, Social Security, 2nd ed. (Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1981). 17 practical reasons. Self-employed people were excluded because they were assumed to earn no wage or salary and because including them would have complicated administration of the program. State and local workers were excluded because of constitutional limitations on federal taxing power. Federal employees and railroad workers 23 were already largely covered under other federal retirement programs and thus were also excluded. Farm laborers, domestic servants, and other widely dispersed workers were not included for administrative reasons. Finally, the tax exemption provided to religious and charitable organizations was deeply imbedded in tradition; therefore, Social Security coverage was not extended to employers in the nonprofit sector primarily because of constitutional considerations. Once the Social Security Act had been enacted, there was consistent pressure to expand coverage under the program. Social Security coverage was first expanded in 1939 when workers above the age of sixtyfive were covered. In 1950, the program was expanded to include regularly employed and domestic workers; federal civilian employees not covered by the federal retirement program; Americans employed outside the United States; and nonfarm, nonprofessional, self-employed people. In 1954, self-employed farmers and professionals, except lawyers, dentists, and medical professionals, were included. In 1956 the military and the remaining self-employed people, except physicians, were included. In 1960, Americans employed by foreign governments or international organizations and parents working for their children were included. In 1965 interns and self-employed physicians were included and tip income for the employee tax only was covered. Finally, in 1967 ministers and members of religious orders not under the vow of poverty, who had been able to elect coverage on a voluntary basis beginning in 1956, were included unless they claimed a conscientious exemption. In addition to mandating expansion of coverage to the group just described, the government has offered several groups the option of becoming covered voluntarily over the years. In 1950, employees in nonprofit organizations and state and local employees not covered by a retirement system were extended coverage on an optional basis at the election of the employer. In 1954, state and local employees, except policemen and firefighters, could be covered by Social Security even if they were already covered by a pension plan; such coverage was available if both employers and employees elected it. In 1956, 23Actually railroad workers were included for a short period until the Railroad Retirement Act was enacted on August 29, 1935. 18 optional coverage was extended to all police and firefighters under a retirement plan in selected states; in 1967 optional coverage was extended to all firefighters. There were various other optional provisions for individuals in religious professions and orders in 1954, 1965, 1967, 1972, and 1977. Today, slightly more than 90 percent of the nation's workers have Social Security coverage. Of those now covered, roughly 2.5 million are federal civilian workers, about 3 million are state and local government workers, and about 500,000 to 1 million are employed bv nonprofit organizations. Most public employees not covered bv Social Security participate in retirement programs sponsored by their employers, but nonprofit workers not covered by Social Security are less likely to be covered by private programs. Other people without Social Security coverage include quasi-workers such as casual laborers who do not earn enough in a year to meet the coverage criteria. Also some conscientious objectors, such as the Amish, are not covered on the basis of self-employment. Retirement A_e--Thc recommendation of the Committee on Economic Security and the 1935 Social Security Act provided benefits for workers retiring at age sixty-five. The committee never articulated its reasons for selecting this age, although it was a common retirement age in private pension plans and foreign social security programs. For example, Germany', Great Britain, and Italy had contributory programs then in effect that paid benefits to people aged sixty-five or over. The staff analvsts for the Committee on Economic Security who developed the Social Security Act in 1935 argued that, as workers grow older, they became less and less able to maintain sufficient earnings to sustain themselves. Thev showed that unemployment stemming from the Great Depression was higher among workers over age forty-five and increased with age. Their analysis, however, does not provide any svstematic rationale for selecting age sixty-five. In fact, at the time of the passage of the Social Security Act the federal civil service retirement age for most classes of employees was seventy, 24 although civil servants with thirty years of service could retire at age sixty-eight. There were also special classes of workers who could retire at age sixty-five or sixty-two. While there appears to be no gerontological, physiological, or other basis for settling upon age sixty-five, all of the initial published actuarial cost estimates for the proposed system assumed that the pro24Committee on Economic Security, Social Security i_t America, p. 179. 19 gram would provide retirement benefits at that age. Over the years, the retirement age in many public retirement programs has been reduced; this process dates back to 1916 when Germany reduced its retirement age from seventy to sixty-five. In 1956 the U.S. Social Security retirement age for women was reduced to age sixty-two, primarily on the basis that wives were, on average, three years younger than their husbands. The extension of this early retirement "privilege" to men in 1961 was justified on the basis of unemployment in the short term. Early retirements under Social Security are coupled with benefit reductions at a rate of five-ninths of 1 percent for each month or 6.67 percent for each year short of attaining age sixty-five. During 1981, to discourage early retirement and save money when it occurred, the Reagan administration proposed reducing early retirement benefits at age sixty-two from 80 to 55 percent of the full benefit payable at age sixty-five. The proposed reduction in early retirement benefits which was to have taken effect in 1982 was widely criticized because it allowed too little time for workers to adjust their retirement planning. Congress never seriously considered the proposal. The Benefit Structure--One of the most complicated elements of the Social Security program over the years has been its benefit structure. From the outset, policymakers have attempted to balance countervailing goals. In its statement of basic principles on the design of Social Security, the Committee on Economic Security held that benefits should bear a "definite relationship to the previous earnings of the beneficiary. ''25 They attempted to find a set of factors that would determine the proper and feasible relationship of benefits and earnings. The first factor related to the start-up problem. The committee believed that although it was socially desirable for benefits eventually to approximate 50 percent of previous earnings, it was fiscally impossible to meet that goal during the early years of the system. The committee recommended that benefits should rise gradually over a generation to correspond with the duration of covered employment. As a counterweight to their basic principle that benefits be related to earnings, the committee stated that benefits must be of sufficient magnitude to "prove a considerable item of income to the recipient and to warrant the administrative costs of distribution. ''26 Hence the 2Slbid., p. 202. 2¢'lbid. 20 committee concluded that no benefits should be paid for five years; it would take longer than this for "earned" benefits to meet the goal, so the committee recommended that initial individual benefits should be not less than 15 percent of the beneficiary's average wages. The committee also believed that benefits should be graduated so that low-wage earners and people who entered the system late in life would receive proportionately higher benefits. The committee believed that the goal of preventing dependency dictated that benefits be adjusted to meet "the relative needs of various classes of beneficiaries even though need is not a determinant in the individual case. ''27 To enhance the redistributive nature of the program, the committee recommended that a maximum wage-base standard should be established as the basis for benefits and contributions. A fourth factor the committee considered in designing the benefit structure was the treatment of persons who continued to work beyond the age at which they became eligible to retire. The committee believed that benefit payments to persons who continued to work would be a wage subsidy that would put younger workers at a disadvantage. The committee therefore recommended that benefits to regularly employed individuals be suspended on the basis "that the social advantages of encouraging retirement at age 65 far outweighed the objective that individual equities would be reduced when benefits were thus suspended."28 Finally, because the original legislative proposal included only retirement benefits, the committee proposed lump-sum refunds for covered persons who died if their contributions plus an interest allowance exceeded benefits. The refunds were to be paid to the estate of the deceased. If the person had received no benefit prior to death, total contributions plus the interest allowance were to be refunded. If the person had received benefits, the refund was to be reduced by that amount received. The benefit provisions in the original Social Security Act paralleled the recommendations of the Committee on Economic Security, but there were some significant differences. The original bill provided that benefits would be paid to persons with five years of coverage under the act. Since tax collections began in 1937, benefits would not have been payable until 1942. The benefit formula enacted in 1935 applied to cumulative creditable wages; it provided proportionately higher benefits to low-wage workers but would have increased ben27Ibid., 28Ibid. p. 203. 21 efits, on average, for each successive cohort of retirees as the duration of coverage increased. The Committee on Economic Security designed an annuity program aimed primarily at lower-income workers. The committee recommended that workers other than manual workers earning more than $250 per month be exempted from paying taxes and excluded from credit for benefits for such years. The committee's proposal would not have provided benefits "unless 200 weekly tax payments had been made in his behalf within a 5-year period prior to his attaining age 65." To deal with low start-up benefits, a minimum benefit of 15 percent of the worker's average wage was proposed for workers entering the system during its first five years. Subsequently, the committee recommended paying relatively larger benefits for the first $15 of a worker's average wages per month. 29 The proposed weighting of benefits toward people earning lower wages would have made the program income redistributional, but the proposed exclusion of white-collar workers earning more than $3,000 per year would have excluded higher-salaried workers from participating in the redistributional aspects of the program. The Social Security legislation enacted in 1935 included all workers in covered employment with the provision that only the first $3,000 in annual earnings would be used in computing benefits and determining tax liabilities. This change made the program considerably more redistributive than the original proposal would have because higherincome workers were included. Although this change was significant, Witte indicates it was made with relative ease: The new benefit rates were still geared to average contributions of S per cent during an industrial lifetime, but a new principle was introduced to give relatively larger benefits to workers receiving low wages. This idea had been discussed favorably by the staff on old age security, but never had been worked out. This revision of the benefit rates was never seriously questioned by any member of either congressional committee. 3° Myers has described the characteristics of the benefit structure established in 1935 by showing the earnings replacement capacity of the program. Table I-4 shows the replacement-rate estimates for various workers under that act, where the replacement rate is the per- 2_Ibid., pp. 211-214. 3°Witte, Tile Development o[ ttle Social Security Act, p. 152. 22 centage rep[aced of annual earnings in the year by the Social Security benefit. argued to the contrary, from high- to low-wage act. prior to retirement that Although it is sometimes the redistributive workers was firmly is nature of Social Security established in the original The modifications incorporated in the 1939 amendments significantly altered the redistributional characteristics of the program. These amendments maintained the principle that benefits should increase on the basis of the number of years of coverage, but the relationship became much less pronounced than it was in the original act. First, benefits became payable in 1940 with only three years of coverage. Second, short-term beneficiaries received higher replacement of their earnings than originally, while long-term replacement rates for single workers were reduced. These changes were accomplished by moving from a formula that based benefits on lifetime, cumulative, covered earnings to one based on average monthly covered earnings. TABLE I-4 Replacement Rates for Workers Retiring at Age 65 Under the 1935 Social Security Act and 1939 Amendments Earnings Level a Low (Percent) Average (Percent) Maximum (Percent) 1935 Social Security Act Minimum (5 years of coverage) Maximum (43 years of coverage) 30.0 73.0 20.0 58.0 10.0 34.0 1939 Ame_tdments SingLe Worker Minimum (3 xears of coverage) Maximum (43 years of coverage) 41.2 57.2 28.9 40.0 16.5 22.9 1939 Amendme_zts Worker with Dependent Spouse Minimum (3 vears of coverage) 61.8 43.2 24.8 Maximum (43 years of coverage) 85.8 60.0 34.4 Source: Robert J. Myers, "History of Replacement Rates for Various Amendments to the Social Security Act,;' Memorandum no. 2 (Washington, D.C.: National Commission on Social Security Reform, 1982), p. 3. _The annual average earnings level is assumed to be $1,000 under the 193S act and 1939 amendments. The actuarial projections at that time assumed wages would remain stable. The low earnings level is approximately S0 percent of the average level, and the maximum level is based on maximum taxab[e wages. 23 The redesign of the program in 1939 further redistributed benefits through the provisions covering spouses. Under the modified program a sixty-five-year-old wife was entitled to 50 percent of her husband's basic benefit; this change more than doubled the replacement rates for early retirees with spouses provided for in the original act. At the same time the 1939 amendments increased the potential long-term benefits for those workers, as well. The 1939 amendments also established a new category of beneficiaries, survivors. Finally, the lumpsum distributions provided in the 1935 act were eliminated, although a small, residual lump-sum benefit justified as a funeral expense allowance was maintained. The net effect of these provisions, as with dependent benefits, was to redistribute benefits toward nonworkers. The 1939 amendments profoundly changed the goals of the program. Instead of being heavily weighted toward equity (i.e., benefits based on cumulative wages) albeit income redistributive, the program after 1939 included much broader protection against hardship. Over the years, debate has continued over the relative weight that the "equity" and "adequacy" goals of the program should receive. Early critics of the Social Security system argued that the adequacy and equity components should be separated. This argument led to various proposals to substitute for Social Security a "double-decker" system, under which a universal "demogrant" for all elderly persons (i.e., the first deck) would have been supplemented by a benefit proportional to average covered earnings. For people with no covered earnings, the demogrant would be the total benefit. Some proponents of a modified system argued that only the bottom deck should be provided through government transfer mechanisms; employers could provide the top tier of benefits through pension programs. There were several arguments in favor of the double-decker system. First, it was clear that early beneficiaries under Social Security received benefits on a highly gratuitous basis. By 1950 only about 20 percent of all persons over age sixty-five were receiving benefits, and critics argued that such selective subsidization under a publicly supported program was highly inequitable. Furthermore, critics said, those receiving the greatest subsidy were the least needy to begin with. Representative (later Senator) Carl T. Curtis of Nebraska articulated this criticism in a dissent to legislative amendments to the Social Security Act being considered in 1949. He argued that benefit differentials between high- and low-wage workers could not be justified on the ground of individual equity: Primary insurance benefits which would be awarded in 1950 under the bill proposed here by the majority, for a worker 24 who has been steadily employed at an average of $250 a month, are $16 a mont_a greater than the benefits for a worker steadily employed at $100 a month. Yet, less than $2.47 differential in primary benefit amounts can be justified actuariallv bv the higher contributions of the $250-a-month man. In other words, the higher-paid man has paid for $2.47 more in benefits but receives $16 more in benefits. 31 Proponents of the double-decker system argued that inclusion of all the elderly could be accomplished quickly. Furthermore, such coverage would immediately present the svstem and taxpayers with the cost of supporting a full cohort of retirees and thus relieve some of the pressures to increase benefits under the partially mature Social Security system. Finally, unwarranted redistribution toward higherincome individuals could be eliminated. The Social Security Board acknowledged that Old-Age and Survivors Insurance benefits would greatly exceed the value of contributions for early beneficiaries. But, according to Altmeyer, the board feared that the uniform benefit under the double-decker system would be raised over time, and this would erode and eventually destroy "the rationality of a contributory social insurance system under which benefits, contributions, and wage loss were interrelated. ''32 The pressure for a double-decker system was so intense that the Social Security Board did develop a double-decker proposal and President Roosevelt himself, in a speech to the Teamsters Union during 1940, seemed to support such a measure. 33 Although the debate over this proposed alternative to Social Security continued throughout the 1940s and beyond, it has never received sufficient support to have been seriously considered in Congress. It did result in special "age seventy-two" benefits that were payable to men reaching that age before 1972, and to women reaching that age prior to 1970 who could not otherwise qualify for benefits. Nonetheless, the double-decker option still receives serious consideration and was advocated by several members of the 1979 Social Securitv Advisory Council. 34 The 1939 benefit formula increased benefits significantly for workers with short periods of coverage by using average monthly wages as the computational basis. Benefits also were to increase bv ! percent for each year of coverage, thus maintaining the linkage of benefits to _Carl T. Curtis, "Additional Minority Views," Social Secm'ity Act Ame_Mme_ltso/1949 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. House ot-Representatives Report no. 1300, 1949), p. 176. 32Altmeyer,The Formati_,eYears ofSocial Secl_rit)',pp. 125-126. 3_Ibid., p. 126. 34Report of the 1979 Advisory Council on Social Security, Social SeczlriO"Fi_zanci_lg a_ldBene/_ts (Washington, D.C., 1979), pp. 68-71. 25 duration of coverage. The 1950 amendments further benefits to short-term covered workers by eliminating increments related to length of covered service and exclusion of earnings before 1951 in computing average The 1950 amendments further raised benefits in the the program while simultaneously reducing benefits the system fully matured (see table I-5). TABLE redistributed the benefit permitted the monthly wage. early years of payable when I-5 Replacement Rates for Single Workers Retiring at Age 65 Under Various Social Security Amendments Earnings 1939 Amendment Level a Low (Percent) Average (Percent) Maximum (Percent) b Minimum Coverage (3 years) 41.2 28.8 16.5 Maximum Coverage (43 years) 57.2 40.0 22.9 Subsequent 1950 Amendments 44.7 30.0 26.8 ! 952 45.2 30.3 28.3 1954 47.5 34.0 31.0 i 958 46.7 34.2 3 ! .8 1965 44.2 33.5 30.5 1967 46.9 36.3 33.5 1969 51.7 40.3 38.6 ! 971 1972 53.5 62.7 43.0 51.2 39.4 42.7 70.2 55.9 42.6 52.5 41.2 27.6 1975 1977 Source: (present law)" Robert J. Myers, "History of Replacement Rates t0r Various Amendments to the Social Security Act," Memorandum no. 2 (Washington, D.C.: National Commission on Social Security Relorm, 1982), p. 3. aThe average annual earnings level is assumed to be $1,000 [or the computations under the 1939 amendments (because wages were relatively stable in the late 1930s), and equal to average earnings in the economy for subsequent computations. The low earnings level is approximately 50 percent of the average level, and the maximum is equal to the applicable maximum taxable wage base. bThe minimum coverage was 3 years ["or the 1939 amendment: the length of coverage for steady workers generally has no effect on benefits under subsequent amendments. The maximum coverage was taken as forty-three years (from age twenty-two to age sixty-five) for the 1939 amendment (actually, forty-three years was the maximum creditable under the maximum-earnings case under the 1935 act). "Ultimate replacement rates shown. Alternative II-B assumptions used in the 1981 OASDI Trustees Report. 26 Subsequent amendments, particularly those during the late 1960s and the early 1970s, gradually increased benefits across the board. By the mid-1970s, Social Security began to face serious financing problems. The 1977 amendments substantially reduced benefits for future beneficiaries, but the effects of the 1977 act were delayed) s Because of the way Social Security was started, virtually all beneficiaries with normal life expectancy at retirement could expect to get back more from the program than they had paid in. Because of benefit enhancements over the years, this situation has persisted until now, although it is diminishing. One way of showing this phenomenon is to compare the value of contributions at retirement to the value of expected benefits. The value of contributions is estimated by accumulating the value of contributions workers make over their lifetimes plus interest they would have received if they had invested the monies in their own behalf instead of paying taxes to Social Security. The value of expected benefits at retirement can be similarly derived by determining how long people can expect to live and receive benefits, on the basis of detailed studies of death rates among individuals at various ages. To estimate the amount of lifetime benefits, the annual benefit that will be paid during each year of the expected lifetime must be calculated. Benefits payable in future years have to be discounted because a dollar paid in the future will be worth less than a dollar in hand. For example, investing ninety-one cents today at l0 percent interest will be worth one dollar a year from now. Stated alternatively, if interest rates are l0 percent, one dollar a year from now is worth only ninety-one cents today. Using life expectancy, estimated annual benefits, and a discount factor, it is possible to estimate the present value of Social Security benefits at retirement. Myers has described the technical considerations in estimating the value of contributions and benefits under Social Security. 36 He has developed estimates that show the value of contributions and benefits strictly related to the OASI program for workers retiring at various times. His calculations assume that workers retire at age sixty-five. He also assumes, for the cases considered, that the workers were steadily employed between 1937 or their twenty-first birthday, whichever is later, and age sixty-five without any periods of unem- 3SThe Social Security financing problem is discussed in chapter llI. X6Robert J. Myers, "Money's Worth Comparison for Social Security Benefits," Memorandum no. 45 (Washington, D.C.: National Commission on Social Security Reform, August 12, 1982). 27 ployment. Myers' analysis considers workers at two levels of earnings. The first worker is assumed to have had "average" covered earnings during each year of employment. For years prior to 1980, this average earnings level is based on empirical data maintained by the Social Security Administration. For 1980 and beyond, earnings were estimated using Alternative II-B assumptions contained in the 1982 Trustees Report. The second worker is assumed to have had maximum taxable earnings in each year. For years prior to 1980, savings are based on the historical maximum levels; for 1980 and beyond, the calculations arc based on the Alternative II-B assumptions. Myers makes separate calculations for male and female single workers and for married couples with one earner. His work indicates that in the long term, two-earner couples are better represented in the calculations by combining single-worker cases than by using the oneearner married-couple example. His analysis assumes that there are no children who receive benefits in any of the examples. Myers' analysis for future retirees is based on current law tax rates and benefit computation methods. His assumptions for future growth in wages and the Consumer Price Index (CPI) are consistent with the Alternative II-B assumptions in the 1982 Trustees Report. For purposes of calculating the value of benefits at retirement, Myers uses a 2 percent real (i.e., 2 percent in excess of inflation) discount rate. To value contributions, he uses the average yearly interest rate on new special-issue investments of the trust funds for 1951 to 1981. For 1937 to 1950 he uses an assumed interest rate of 2.25 percent; beyond 1981, he uses the Alternative II-B assumptions from the 1982 Trustees Report. Table I-6 shows the results of Myers' analysis and compares the cumulative value of combined employer and employee contributions for earnings throughout the careers of workers to the present value of benefits for persons retiring in selected years. The top section of the table shows the results for workers earning the average wage, while the lower section shows the results for workers earning the maximum covered earnings. The table shows that the ratio of benefits to total taxes paid for full-career workers has been declining for workers at both earnings levels--and that ratio will continue to decline because of the nature of the program. The workers retiring at age sixty-five in 1960 were forty-two years old in 1937 when tax collections started. These people paid no taxes for twenty years of their careers, and they paid very low taxes throughout most of the remaining years. 28 The table also indicates that workers with different characteristics have fared and will continue to fare quite differently on a benefit-tocontribution basis. Virtually all analyses of this kind show that workers with normal life expectancy who have retired under Social Security up to now could expect benefits exceeding the value of their contributions. Myers notes in his analysis, however, that the present value of benefits as a percentage of contributions shown in table I-6 is probably too high for future retirees under OASI. Cost projections for the OASI indicate that if Social Security's current cost-financing basis is to be maintained, future tax rates will have to be raised or benefits lowered, or both. Either change will lower the value of benefits in relation to contributions. The maturing of Social Securitv has raised questions about the redistributive nature of the program and the competing adequacy and equity goals. Because even high-wage workers up until the present could expect to receive more in Social Security benefits than the value of the total taxes paid on their earnings, there has been a peaceful coexistence of the countervailing goals of adequacy and equity. Balancing these goals in the future may be more difficult because many current workers will receive less than their "money's worth" from Social Sccuritv if the combined employer-employee taxes are considered. It is argued that in order for Social Security to be a "good buy" (i.e., equitable) for workers, they should expect benefits roughly equal to their contributions. If "their contributions" are interpreted to include their employers' contribution, this is virtually impossible to accomplish in a program that strives to accomplish income redistribution (i.e., adequacy). The nature of this problem is reflected most clearly in the part of table I-6 that relates to maximum-wage earners. For the high-income, single male worker, OASI, as now structured, will provide less than a full return as of the end of this century. For the single female, this situation will occur somewhat later because women, on average, live longer than men and thus have higher expected lifetime benefits. Changes to the program could cause this less-than-full-return phenomenon to occur sooner and to filter further down the income spectrum. This characteristic of Social Security has given rise to various criticisms of the benefit structure, and several modifications to the system have been proposed. Some critics of the system support the concept that the program should give low-income workers more in proportion to their earnings than it gives high-wage workers, but they are critical of what Professor Laurence Kotlikoff of Yale University calls the 29 _-_ _ _ - _ "_ 3O °_ _ 31 "capricious redistribution of economic resources among individuals in the same income class. ''37 Kotlikoff points out that "under the current system two families making the same contributions to Social Security may expect to receive dramatically different benefits, and two families that expect to receive the same benefits may make radically different contributions. ''3_ To a certain extent this phenomenon can be demonstrated by comparing the single average-wage earner in the top section of table I-6 with the one-earner, high-wage married couple in the lower section of the table. Consistently the one-earner, high-wage couple has received and can expect to receive a better return from Social Security than is the case for the unmarried single worker with only average earnings. The question that some Social Security analysts raise is whether this type of redistribution is socially desirable. Some critics even question the desirability of any income redistribution at all in a work-related retirement program. These latter critics argue that such redistributions could be carried out more equitably and efficiently through a means-tested transfer program supported by the general income tax system. These criticisms could change the public's perspective and undermine the overall popularity of Social Security. Thus far the program has been tremendously popular in America because people have perceived that they are getting a fair return on their contributions. In fact, retirees until now have received a much better return on their payroll tax contributions than they could have gotten from almost any alternative investment. To argue that current beneficiaries have "paid for" their benefits is correct in a statutory sense but not in economic terms. The economics of Social Security is changing, however, because of the interaction of the benefit structure and its maturity relative to its financing provisions. The evolution of the financing provisions is discussed in the following section. The discussion will follow the time path presented in this section on the description of the benefit structure; that is, it begins with the financing structure developed at the conception of the program and describes its subsequent evolution. _TLaurence J. Kotlikoff, "Personal Security Accounts: A Program ot Social Security Ret0rm" (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1982),p. 2. _SIbid. 32 Financing Social Security The Committee on Economic Security also developed the basic financing structure of Social Security, considering various potential sources of revenue. The committee decided that even with sharply higher tax rates, personal income taxes would be insufficient to meet the program's funding requirements. Corporate income taxes and inheritance taxes were dismissed for the same reasons. Sales-tax financing was not proposed because the committee feared the potential fiscal and economic effects and worried about the incidence of such taxes. President Roosevelt himself had very strong ideas about the financing of Social Security. He wanted the system to be contributory, partly because he thought that design was economically sound, but also because it provided political insurance for the program: I guess you are right on the economics, but those taxes were never a problem of economics. They are politics all the way through. We put those payroll contributions there so as to give the contributors a legal, moral, and political right to collect their pensions .... With those taxes in there, no damn politician can ever scrap my Social Security program. 39 The Committee on Economic Security responded with a financing proposal that called for taxes on a percentage of employees' earnings, taxes on a percentage of employers' payrolls, and "subsidies from the Federal Government financed through taxes not borne by workers. ''4° The rationale for the employee tax was that benefits would be provided as a "matter of right without a test of means." To obtain this "virtual equity," the committee believed that workers had to share the burden of making it possible. To avoid disproportionate hardship on workers earning lower wages, a proportionate formula was selected in lieu of a fiat tax. Since the benefit design was redistributive, the committee did not feel a progressive tax structure was called for. The committee also reasoned that "Just as industry, generally, has become accustomed to meeting charges for the depreciation and replacement of its material equipment, many employers have developed programs for the payment of retirement allowances for their 39Arthur M. Schlesinger, Jr., The Age ofRoosevelt, vol. 2, The Coming of the New Deal (Boston, Mass.: Houghton Mifflin Co., 1959), pp. 309-310. _°Committee on Economic Security, Social Security m America, p. 204. 33 superannuated workers. TM They believed that such costs were related to production, and that employers should contribute to the social insurance program designed to protect their workers. To assure a direct relationship between the labor services provided to the employer and the cost of Social Security, the committee recommended a tax on earnings covered by the system, to be computed on the same basis and at the same rate as employee contributions. To minimize the initial shock, the committee recommended that the initial tax rate be set at 1 percent (0.5 percent each on employee and employer) and that the joint contribution rate should be raised by one percentage point at five-year intervals until a maximum combined rate of 5 percent was reached. The .joint 5 percent payroll tax would meet the system's cost for twenty-five years; the committee proposed that the financing deficits that would arise beyond that time should be subsidized by "the Government." The committee reasoned that as Social Security matured, the federal budgetary costs of old-age assistance would decline. They believed that the savings in federal costs that resulted from an expanding Social Security program should not be realized at the expense of Social Security participants, but that the old-age retirement program should be subsidized. 42 This subsidy was projected to reach 67 percent of combined employer and employee contributions by the time the program fully matured in 1980. When President Roosevelt discovered that after 1965 a large deficit would develop in the proposed program because benefits would exceed employer and employee taxes, he insisted that the proposal developed by the committee be changed. But the committee's report had already been distributed to Congress and the press by the time FDR made his discovery. Rather than reworking the financing proposal that was in the original bill, the committee modified its report to indicate that general revenue financing was merely one means of dealing with the deficits that would result as the program matured. 43 During the legislative development of the act, the financing schedule was amended to include an initial payroll tax of 1 percent each on employers and employees, with scheduled increases of 0.5 percent on each (1 percent combined) every three years. The tax rate was scheduled to increase to a combined rate of 6 percent in 1949 and 411bid.,p. 205. 421bid.,pp. 206-207. 4_Witte, I'he Development o[ the Social Security Act, p. 74. 34 remain level thereafter. This revised schedule of tax collections, it was thought, would make the program completely self-supporting until at least 1980. It was also understood that this financing mechanism, which was included in the Social Security Act, would result in establishment of a large trust fund during the early years of the program, and with positive balances in the trust fund persisting through 1980 and beyond. The Committee on Economic Security had proposed the development of a trust fund to assure the availability of resources to meet benefit payments. The committee believed that such a fund could help to meet gradual changes that would affect the program such as declining retirement ages, increasing wages, and variations in mortality rates. The committee also thought that in the event of a depression, a trust fund might mitigate the effects of accelerating benefit claims. Under the committee's original financing proposal the trust fund was expected to accumulate to roughly $15 billion by 1960. 44 Under the modifications made in the Social Security Act, it was expected to grow to three times this magnitude. During the early days of the program, many policymakers expressed various concerns about the projected magnitude of the trust fund. One concern was that the accumulation of such a large trust fund would rcsuh in politically motivated benefit increases that would sharply incrcasc the program's cost in the long run. A second set of concerns focused on the central government's control of such a large pool of assets. Senator Arthur Vandenberg argued, "It is scarcely conceivable that rational men should propose such an unmanageable accumulation of funds in one place in a democracy. ''45 The third set of concerns related to the fiscal implications of a government program in which tax collections would exceed benefit disbursements for such a sustained period. Arthur Altmeyer believed that the trust funds should be allowed to accumulate to help defray the long-term cost of the program. He argued that "if there were no reserve to earn interest and no government subsidy in lieu of interest, the schedule of contribution rates would have to be raised, so that the eventual combined employeremployee contribution rate in 1980 would have to be 10 percent instead of 6 percent. ''46 He also thought that the accumulation of the trust fund would provide a better perspective on the long-term cost 44Committee 4SAltmeyer, _01bid. on Economic The Formative Security, Social Security i_zAmerica, Years ofSocial Security, p. 89. p. 212. 35 of the system and benefits. and an appreciation of the relationship between costs In the short term, the 1939 amendments resolved the concerns over trust fund growth. As was discussed previously, benefit payments were moved up two years, to begin in 1940, and heavily weighted to the advantage of early retirees. At the same time, the increase in the payroll tax scheduled for January 1, 1940, was delayed; the tax had been scheduled to rise at that time to 1.5 percent in the first of four increments. The 1939 amendments did retain the 1943, 1946, and 1949 scheduled increases to 2.0, 2.5, and 3.0 percent, respectively. Throughout the 1940s Congress continued to defer tax increases under Social Security, and the method of financing continued to be debated. While FDR had come down strongly in favor of a system that paid for itself, the 1937-1939 Advisory Council had argued for partial financing from general revenues. During the 1940s the Social Security Board also advocated federal subsidies for the program and the 1947-1948 Advisory Council again forwarded the recommendation. The benefit increases incorporated in the 1950 amendments finally brought the financing issue to a head. As Derthick notes, Congress came down firmly on the side of a self-supporting program in which benefits were clearly tied to payroll collections: This link made taxes easier to raise because the public could see that it would get something for its money. The link also disciplined the demand for benefits, because congressmen in general and their constituents could be admonished that they must pay the costs, and this in turn relieved the committees of the need either to raise general revenues for the program, a relatively unpopular course, or to accept responsibility for increases in the national debt. Perceiving these advantages at an early stage of the program's development, the committee committed themselves unequivocally to the payroll tax. 47 The 1950 amendments modified the future payroll tax schedule on both employers and workers and increased the level of maximum taxable earnings from $3,000 to $3,600 per year. When the 1950 amendments were passed, the tax rate was scheduled to rise to 2.0 percent in 1954, 2.5 percent in 1960, 3.0 percent in 1965, and 3.25 percent in 1970. Since the passage of the 1950 amendments, there 47Derthick, Policymaking [br Social Security, p. 239. 36 has been no fundamental change to the financing for Social Security. The actual increases in tax rates and those currently scheduled for the future are shown in table I-7. These data show a consistent increase in Social Security costs as the program has matured. Part of that increase is attributable to the addition of disabilitv and hospital benefits. The actual OASI contribution rates of 4.5 percent in 1980 w;ere not far off the rates predicted bv the Social Security actuaries in 1935 when the first projections were made. 4s Growth of the Social Security Program Although the basic benefit and financing structure of Social Security was established during the early years of the program, the system has not been static. Moreover, although the program has bad its critics over the years, it has also been one of the most popular public endeavors ever undertaken in this country. Since 1940 Social Security has expanded to touch nearly every element of society. Figure I-l traces the growth of civilian employment in this country and the corresponding covered employment under Social Security. Initially the program covered slightly less than 60 percent of all workers. The gap between total and covered employment narrowed considerablv following enactment of the 1950 and 1954 amendments. Since the late 1950s there have been no major changes in Social Security's coverage provisions, and covered employment has continued to closely parallel total civilian employment. Figure I-2 shows the percentage of workers covered by Social Security and the percentage of the U.S. population over age sixty-five receiving benefits. This picture of Social Security's development is important in several respects. First, it clarifies the criticism of the early program that heavily subsidized benefits were being provided to only a small segment of the elderly. In 1950, less than 20 percent of people over age sixtv-five were receiving Social Securitv. As the program has matured, nearly all old people are receiving benefits. Although the program's inherent redistributive features are still criticized, the redistribution takes place on an economic rather than class basis. 4_Robert J. Myers, "Actual Costs of the Social Security System Over the Years Compared with 1935 Estimates," Social Security Bulleti_t,'vo(. 45, no. 3 (March 1982), pp. 13-15. 37 TABLE I-7 Annual Maximum Taxable Earnings and Contribution Rates Under the Social Security Act and Amendments Employer Year Beginning Annual Maximum Taxable Earnings 1937 1950 1951 1954 1955 1957 1959 1960 1962 1963 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983_1984 J 1985 _ 1986-1989 _ 1990 and beyond _ $ 3,000 3,000 3,600 3,600 4,200 4,200 4,800 4,800 4,800 4,800 6,600 6,600 7,800 7,800 7,800 7,800 9,000 10,800 13,200 14,100 15,300 16,500 17,700 22,900 25,900 29,700 32,400 _b_ Ib_ _b) lh_ Total OASI 1.000 1.500 1.500 2.000 2.000 2.250 2.500 3.000 3.125 3.625 4.200 4.400 4.400 4.800 4.800 5.200 5.200 5.850 5.850 5.850 5.850 5.850 6.050 6.130 6.130 6.650 6.700 6.700 7.050 7.150 7.650 1.000 1.500 1.500 2.000 2.000 2.000 2.250 2.750 2.875 3.375 3.500 3.550 3.325 3.725 3.650 4.050 4.050 4.300 4.375 4.375 4.375 4.375 4.275 4.330 4.520 4.700 4.575 4.575 4.750 4.750 5.100 and Employee (Each) DI 0.250 0.250 0.250 0.250 0.250 0.350 0.350 0.475 0.475 0.550 0.550 0.550 0.550 0.575 0.575 0.575 0.575 0.775 0.750 0.560 0.650 0.825 0.825 0.950 0.950 1.100 Tax Rates HI 0.35 0.50 0.60 0.60 0.60 0.60 0.60 1.O0 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.90 1.00 1.05 1.05 1.30 1.30 1.30 1.35 1.45 1.45 Source: Social Security Btdletbz: Ammal Statistical Supplement, 1980 (Washington, Social Security Administration, 1982), p. 35. _'Currently scheduled tax rates in existing law. bSubject to automatic increase with growth in average wages. 38 D.C.: FIGURE I-1 Total Civilian Employment and Workers Covered by Social Security Millions 100 / Civilian Workers Covered Workers / 80............ 60- _... ...._ SF / ._..°._.- 40 / / • ,, .-'-.• ! / 2O 1940 Source: I 1945 I 1950 I 1955 I I I I 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 Year Data for 1940-1970 period, from U .S. Bureau of the Census, HistoricalStatistics o[the United States (Washington, D.C., 1975), p. 348; for 1971-72, from U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract o[ the United States 1079 (Washington, D.C., 1980), p. 331; for 1973-79, fi'om U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract o[ the United States 1981 (Washington, D.C., 1982), p. 326. A second and more important point illustrated in figure I-2 is the relationship between the percentage of workers covered and the percentage of beneficiaries over time. The Old-Age Insurance system is a work-related retirement program. Because benefits are tied to earnings and contributions, albeit not directly, it takes time for succeeding waves of covered retirees to make up a dominant share of all elderly. Coverage can be expanded very quickly in a retirement system, but it is only the gradual aging of covered workers that can raise the rates of receipt of benefits. Another way to show the maturing of Social Security is through the direct relationship between workers and beneficiaries, in other 39 FIGURE I-2 Workers Covered by Social Security and Persons Over 65 Receiving Social Security Percent 100 60. 80 _ s j'S" . o.. _..y,f .... "- s# 40 /" sS 8S iI so ° 20, / ooo o" 940 Source: ............ I I I 1945 1950 1955 I Percent Percent I of Workers Covered Over 65 Benefiting I I 1960 1905 1970 1975 Year Coverage data for 1940-1970, from U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics o[ the U_tited States (Washington, D.C., 1975), p. 348; for 1971-1979, from U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract ol the U_tited States 1979 (Washington, D.C., 1980), p. 331; for 1973-1979, from U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract o[ the United States 1981 (Washington, D.C., 1982), p. 326. Beneficiary data t0r 1940-1969, [rum U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics o[the United States (Washington, D.C., 1975), p. 357; for 1970, from Social Security Bulletin (March 1981 ), p. 73; [or 1971-74, from Social Security Btdleti_l (December 1978), p. 75; for 1975-79, from Social Security Bulletiil (March 1982), p. 66. words, the number of workers in covered employment for each person receiving a benefit, which is often referred to as the dependency ratio. Figure I-3 shows how the Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance dependency ratios sharply declined and then leveled off in the 1960s. This leveling off at a very low ratio has important implications for the financing of Social Security especially as it relates to benefit increases. Since Social Security is financed on a pay-as-you-go basis, each dollar in benefits paid has to be spread across contributors. For 40 FIGURE I-3 Ratio of Workers Covered by Social Security to Total Beneficiaries Workers Per Beneficiary 120 100 8O 60 40 2O 1940 Source: 1945 1950 1955 1960 Year 1965 1970 1975 1980 Coverage data t0r 1940-1970, _rom U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics oi the Umted States (Washington, D.C., 1975), p. 348; for 1971-1979, from U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract olthe United States 1979 (Washington, D.C., 1980), p. 331; for 1973-1979, from U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract o[ the U_zitedStales 1981 (Washington, D.C., 1982), p. 326. Beneficiary data f0r 1940-1969, from U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics o/ the United States (Washington, D.C., 1975), p. 357; for 1970, from Social Security Bulleti_t (March 1981), p. 73; for 1971-74, from Social Security Bulletin (December 1978), p. 75; lbr 1975-79, from Social Security Bulletin (March 1982), p. 66. example, in the early 1940s there were a hundred or more workers for each beneficiary. In this period, significant benefit increases could be provided with relatively small effects on the taxpayers supporting the program. In the early 1950s there were still ten workers per beneficiary. A onc-dollar increase in average benefits would still have cost workers earning the average wage and their employers together an additional dime in tax. Bv thc 1970s a much closer linkage between 41 benefit increases and their financing impacts was being felt. By the end of the 1970s there were only 3.5 workers per beneficiary, meaning that an added dollar in benefits would cost average workers and their cmployers an additional thirty cents in tax. The growth in Social Security benefits over the years has improved the economic status of the program beneficiaries. Figure I-4 plots average monthly benefits in 1980 dollars. The upper line shows the average benefits paid to retired workers; the lower line reflects average benefits paid to all Social Security beneficiaries. The declining benefits during the 1940s show the effect that inflation had on stable nominal benefits during that decade. While the 1940s could be characterized as a decade of declining benefits, the 1950s showed substantial growth, with the most significant increases resulting from FIGURE I-4 Year End Average Monthly Social Security Retired Workers, and All Beneficiaries Benefits, In 1980 Dollars J $300- i Retired Workers ............ All Beneficiaries _"_'__, /_-"'"" 250. I 200•......... I"" .... '£"/ 150 100 ..o_a 1940 I I | t I I 1945 1950 1955 1960 Year 1965 1970 i 1975 1980 Source: 1980 dollar adjustments calculated by the author based on data for 194070, from Social Security Bulletin Annual Statistical Supplement 1970, p. 89; for 1971-1980, from Social Security Bulletin (June 1978),p. 43; and Social Security Bulletin (February 1982),p. 50. 42 enactment of the 1950 amendments. In the 1950s average benefits increased by more than one-third in real terms. Throughout most of the 1960s, the purchasing power of average benefits remained relatively constant. At the end of 1960, retired workers' average benefits (measured in 1980 dollars) were just under $215 per month; at the end of 1969 they were just under $226 per month. During the next three years, ad hoc benefit increases of 15, 10, and 20 percent raised average benefits for retired workers to nearly $320 per month by the end of 1972. Benefits continued to grow in real terms throughout the remainder of the 1970s, although not at the precipitous rates of the 1970-1972 period. Between 1950 and 1980, the proportion of people over age sixtyfive who were receiving benefits jumped from less than 20 percent to more than 90 percent. During this period, benefits also became Combined Average In 1980 Dollars FIGURE I-5 OASDI Taxes Reported Taxable Paid on Earnings $1,000 80(> 600 400, 2O0_ 1940 I 1945 I 1950 I 1955 I 1960 I 1965 I 1970 ! 1975 Year Source: Calculated from data provided in Social Security Bulletin Annual Statistical Supplement 1980, p. 35 and p. 88. 43 payable to persons retiring at age sixty-two, and disability benefits were added as well. At the same time the real value of average monthly benefits for retirees rose more than 125 percent, and the real value for all beneficiaries more than 140 percent. The declining dependency ratio in combination with increased benefit levels meant that both the tax base and tax rate had to expand to meet the pay-as-you-go cost. In constant dollars, the taxes paid by workers earning the average wage covered under the system increased by more than 500 percent. The annual combined employer and employee OASDI taxes paid by average workers are shown in figure I5. Workers' tax liabilities under Social Securitv will probably continue to increase. Under existing law, payroll tax rates are to continue to rise until after 1990. Growth in average wages also will raise the base against which these rates are applied. Furthermore, the Social Security system now faces a serious financing shortfall in both the short and long terms. If Social Security is to remain a pay-as-you-go system, bencfi ts will have to be cut, additional revenues will have to be raised, or some combination of the two will have to be implemented. These are not pleasant choices for anyone, especially politicians, but there are no alternatives. One factor that policymakers should keep in mind is that Social Security does not exist in a vacuum; there are other elements o[ retirement income security that are maturing. These other programs could help relieve the financial burden and allow some restructuring of the Social Security system. 44 II. Income Security for the Elderly: The Role of Programs Other Than Social Security Although Social Security retirement benefits have had a dramatic effect on the economic well-being of the elderly over the past four decades, rnanv other facets of federal law have also enhanced the elderly's income security. Today the elderly receive income from an amalgam of publicly and privately organized programs that aim to provide them with adequate income, as well as from their own private provisions. All the major components of this loosely configured system have developed in the past forty-five years, but they have not evolved at the same rate. It is important to understand this point, because the various income sources will play different roles for future groups of elderly people. In 1930, 54 percent of the men in the country over age sixty-five continued to work; by 1940, the employment rate of men over age sixty-five had fallen below 42 percent. 1 Much of the decline related directly to the escalated unemployment rates during the Great Depression. Although it was widely understood that the U.S. economy's collapse had diminished the extent and value of individually held assets, there was little precise statistical evidence to support the premise. When Social Security (OASI) and the Old-Age Assistance (OAA) programs were established in 1935, there were approximately 750 private pension plans in operation. Nonetheless, for many years after the two government programs began paying benefits, they were the only source of income support for many elderly persons. As Social Security matured, it became the predominant source of retirement income support. Today, the reliance of elderly people on public income support programs is diminishing in relative terms, and in the future it will probably decline even further. The elderly now have four major sources of income in addition to Social Security: pension programs, individual savings and asset income, employment earnings, and welfare programs. Because the current debate on Social Security financing and future benefit levels should be conducted in this broader context, this chapter discusses the history of these four sources of retirement income. _u.s. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics o/the U_litedStates (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1976),p. 132, Series D 29-41. 45 The Role of Pensions The expansion in the role of pensions can be traced through growth in pension programs, beneficiaries, and benefits. the Growth in Pension Programs--Pension programs have been publicly regulated, in one way or another, almost since their very beginnings. Dan McGill, who has written extensively on pension programs and policy, notes that even prior to the enactment of regulatory legislation, reasonable employer pension payments to retirees or contributions to trust tunds were tax-deductible expenses. 2 However, the funding of prior service credits and amortization of unfunded liabilities were not tax deductible. Furthermore, income accruing to either the employer or employee in an established trust fund was taxable. The 1921 Revenue Act eliminated current taxation of income for stock bonus "some and profit-sharing plans or all" of their workers. established by employers to benefit Through an administrative ruling, pension trusts also were accorded preferential tax treatment, and the 1926 Revenue Act established this treatment of pension trusts as law. The 1928 Revenue Act permitted reasonable deductions in excess of currently accruing liabilities, in effect allowing funding of past service credits. The 1928 Revenue Act allowed the continued provision of pensions for "some or all" of the employees of a sponsoring employer, which allowed owners and officers to establish plans under which they received preferential tax treatment while excluding rank-and-file workers. Also at that time pension trusts were revocable. That is, a sponsor could establish a plan in a high-income year, make tax-free contributions to the plan, and revoke it in an unprofitable year. The 1938 Revenue Act modified the revocability provisions and required that a retirement trust be for the exclusive benefit of the employees covered until all liabilities were met under the plan. In 1940 a sharp increase in corporate income tax rates greatly expanded the incentives to establish pension programs, particularly because the 1938 Revenue Act had not changed the provisions allowing selective coverage of the sponsor's work force. The 1942 Revenue Act and amendments to it in the 1954 Internal Revenue Code modified the tax qualification standards and changed the tax code to preclude plan sponsors from discriminating in favor of a sponsor's owners and officers. 2This paragraph Private Pensions, 46 and the next four rely heavily on Dan M. McGil[, Fundamentals 4th ed. (Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1979), pp. 23-28. o[ Organized labor also played a major role in the evolution of pensions in the United States. When Inland Steel Company initiated mandatory retirement at age sixtv-five in 1946, the union filed a grievance with the National Labor Relations Board (NLRB) arguing that the company's unilateral decision on this issue violated a provision in its negotiated contract dealing with separation from service. The employer argued that the mandatory retirement provision was an essential part of the company's pension program and that pensions were outside the realm of collective bargaining. The 1948 NLRB ruling, based on the 1947 Labor Relations Management Act, held that pensions were negotiable. The NLRB based its ruling on two principles: ( 1) that pensions fell under the term "wages" as defined in the law, and (2) that pensions could be considered "other conditions of employment," which were negotiable. When the company appealed the ruling, tile Seventh Circuit Court of Appeals found that the employer had reasonably argued that pensions were not wages but that premiums were clearly included in the "other conditions of employment" clause. Inland Steel's original disagreement with the union over the negotiabilitv of pensions linked to its mandatory retirement age provision indicates that employers do use their pension programs for manpower management. Over the years the unions themselves have negotiated vigorously ['or pensions that help provide new jobs for younger workers as older ones retire. The Social Security Act's provision of a bottom tier of retirement income has further increased awareness that economic security for the elderly is of paramount importance. The policy focus on income adequacy since the 1960s has especially highlighted the needs of the elderlv. Thus, pensions have grown as a result of a combination of preferential tax treatment, employer and union interest, and social consciousness. Figure II-I depicts the dramatic increase in tax-qualified plans which rose from 659 at the end of 1939 to 696,000 at the end of 1981. Growth has been steady over most of the mid-1970s, when the Employee Retirement (ERISA) was implemented. ALthough enactment in a shift toward defined-contribution plans, 3 fined benefit plans have been established in just the period except for Income Security Act of ERISA did result more than 46,000 dethe past three vears. 4 _Svlvestcr J. Schicbcr and Patricia M. George, Retirellze_zl h_co.te Opportz.Hties i_*aH .4_i_zg America: ('o_wraRe a_M Be_wl)'t E_tlith'me_tt {Washington, D.C.: EBRI, 1981 ), p. 66. 4S_,]_,csIcF J. Schicber, Tremls m PeplsioH £'overa,_e a_ul Be_wlit Receipt (Washington, D.C.: EBRI, 19821, p. 5. 47 FIGURE Total Number II-I of Tax-Qualified Plans for Selected Years in Effect Thousands of Plans 600- 500- 400 - 300- 200 - 100- 0 I 1940 Sources: I 1945 I 1950 I 1955 i I I I 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 Year Charles D. Spencer & Associates, Inc.. EBPR Research Reports (Chicago, I11., 1980), section 101.1; and periodic IRS press releases. As a result of this growth, an increasing share of the work force is participating in at least one pension program other than Social Security. The May 1979 Current Population Survey (CPS) provides the most recent available statistics on recent pension participation levels. 5 This survey, based on a sample of households representing the U.S. civilian work force, estimated that outside agriculture, 68.3 percent of all civilian wage or salary workers between the ages of twentyfive and sixty-four, working at least half time, who had been with _For a description of the Current Population Survey, see the U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, "The Current Population Survey--A Report ot Methodology," Technical Paper no. 7 (Washington, D.C., 1963); U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, "The Current Population Survey--A Report of Methodology," Technical Paper no. 40 (Washington, D.C., 1979); and Marvin M. Thompson and Gary Shapiro, "The Current Population Survey: An Overview," Amtals o/Ectmomic a_td Social Management (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department ot Commerce, Bureau of the Census, 1973). 48 their plan. employer for a year or more, were participating in a pension Because private employment constitutes 85 percent of all U.S. employment and because lower coverage rates prevail in the private sector, pension policy is often focused on this segment of the economy. [n fact, most noncovered workers are in private sector employment. The federal government provides pension coverage to virtually all its civilian employees in permanent positions; the approximately 10 percent of federal civilian workers who are in temporary positions receive only Social Security coverage. At the state and local levels, 85 to 90 percent of full-time employees are covered by a pension plan. 6 The growing prevalence of private pension plans has led to a marked increase in pension participation, as table II-1 shows. The growth of private pension participation is indicated bv the steady growth in the number of participants. In addition, and perhaps more important, over the years participation has grown more rapidly than privatesector employment has. Private-sector employment grew 15.4 percent from 1950 to 1959, 27.0 percent from 1960 to 1969, and 26.8 percent from 1970 to 1979. Over the same three periods, pension participation increased by 85.7, 39.0, and 36.8 percent. Some analysts have suggested that the stabilization of the participation rate during the 1970s indicates that the private pension system has stagnated. According to previous research by the Employee Benefit Research Institute (EBRI), more reasonable explanations of stable pension participation rates during the 1970s are the rapid growth in employment as the postWorld War II babv-boom generation entered the work force, the rapid rise in female labor force participation rates during the 1970s, and the implementation of ERISA. 7 Private-sector employment grew as much between 1975 and 1979 as it had in the previous eleven years. Most of the new workers were young people who were just embarking on a career. Nearly 58 percent of the spurt in private-sector employment during the late 1970s occurred in firms with fewer than 100 employees, and almost 55 percent of the growth occurred in trade and service firms. Pension coverage is known to be lowest in smaller firms and in the trade and service industries, s _House Pension Task Force, Pension Task Force Report on Public Employee Retireme_zt Systems (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978), p. 59. 7See Schieber and George, Retirement l_wome Opporttotities i_zat_ Agitzg America, chapter 3. qbid., p, 49. 49 TABLE II-I Wage and Salary Workers in Private Sector, Nonagricultural Establishments and Pension Participation, 1950-1979 Year P_vate-Sector Wage and Salary Worke_ (Thousands) Workers Participating in P_vate Pensions (Thousands) Participation Rate (Percent)" 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 39,171 41,430 42,185 43,557 42,239 43,727 45,091 45,237 43,485 45,185 45,836 45,405 46,659 47,427 48,687 50,691 53,117 54,412 56,058 58,189 58,326 58,333 60,342 63,059 64,095 62,260 64,511 67,345 71,025 73,966 9,800 10,800 11,300 12,600 13,400 14,200 IS,S00 16,700 17,200 18,200 18,700 19,200 19,700 20,300 20,900 21,800 22,700 24,300 24,800 26,000 26,100 26,400 27,500 29,200 29,800 30,300 30,700 32,000 33,700 35,200 25.0 26.1 26.8 28.9 31.7 32.5 34.4 36.9 39.6 40.3 40.8 42.3 42.2 42.8 42.9 43.0 42.7 44.7 44.2 44.7 44.7 45.3 45.6 46.3 46.5 48.7 47.6 47.5 47.5 47.6 Sources: 50 Employment data are from the U.S. Department ofLabor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, presented in the 1981 Eco_to,tic Report o/ the President, table B35, p. 273; pension participation data are h'om Alh'ed M. Skolnik, "Private Pension Plans, 1950-1974," Social Sec,ritv Bttl_titt, June 1976, vol. 39, no. 6; and Martha Remv Yohalem, "Employee Benefit Plans, 1975/' Social Security Bul_tin, November 1977, vol. 40, no. 11. Estimates Ior 1979 were derived from the May 1979 Current Population Survey. Estimates tot 19761978 were derived by interpolation between 1975 and 1979. The stabilizing pension participation rate was the result of the simple mathematical calculation of participation rates bv which the numerator (pension participation) did not keep up with the denominator (workers) during a period in which the latter was growing at unprecedented rates. During the 1980s, private-sector employment is expected to grow at only one-half to one-third the rate during the latter half of the 1970s. The slowdown in the expansion of the work force means that continued pension expansion should result in higher pension participation rates during this decade. Also, because of the decline in birthrates toward the end of the 1950s, a smaller proportion of the work force will be under age twentv-five and excluded from pension participation on the basis of ERISA's standards. Another important factor that can contribute to further growth in pension participation rates is the continued establishment of new pension programs. Table II-2 shows net growth of 51,607 tax-qualified plans during the three years 1975 to 1977. The average annual growth in plans was less than one-third the rate ['or the years immediately prior to the passage of ERISA. This slowdown in plans created in the mid-1970s obviously slowed participation growth as well. However, the number of tax-qualified programs increased by 220,592 plans between January 1978 and December 1981. The number of participants affected bv new pension programs is less well documented than plan growth. Table II-3 includes the number of new plan qualifications bv plan type for 1976 through 1981, and the number of participants in newly qualified plans for each year. There are two problems in interpreting these data, however: First, the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) does not publish participant levels in terminating plans, so it is impossible to estimate net participant growth. Second, many of the new plans being created either replace coverage for persons previously covered bv terminating plans, or represent supplemental coverage for workers who are already pension participants. The data in table II-3 appear to suggest that 1977 and 1978 were far more expansionary (8.8 million participants in newly qualified plans) than the subsequent two years (only 5.8 million participants in newly established plans). The problem is that the 1977-1978 period _The participation rates are tot all private-sector workers regardless of age, tenure with employer, or hour's worked per year. If only workers who met ERISA participation standards were considered, the participation rates would be much higher. For example, if the work torce were narrowed to include only those people between the ages of twenty-five and sixty-four, working at least half time, and having one or more years of tenure with their current employer, the 1979 participation rate would rise to 65 percent. 51 52 TABLE Plan Qualifications Defined Contribution Year Plans 1976 Number Percentage 1977 Number Percentage 1978 Numbcr Percent age 1979 Number Percentage 1980 Number Percentage 1981 Number Percentage Source: II-3 and Participants, Participants 1976-1981 Defined Benefit Plans Participants Total Plans Participants 18,891 87.9 780,708 85.3 2,595 12.1 134,462 t4.7 21,486 100.0 915,170 100.0 28,463 80.4 3,315,205 66.9 6,953 19.6 1,639,719 33.1 35,416 100.0 4,954,924 100.0 55,956 85.2 2,754,635 71.0 9,728 14.8 1,125,498 29.0 65,684 100.0 3,880,133 100.0 41,122 72.3 1,050,595 51.9 15,755 27.7 972,062 48.1 56,877 100.0 2,022,657 100.0 50,493 72.8 1,997,285 52.8 18,849 27.2 1,784,280 47.2 69,342 100.0 3,781,565 100.0 57,748 70.8 1,302,089 37.3 23,789 29.2 2,185,551 62.7 81,537 100.0 3,487,640 100.0 EBRI tabulations o[ periodic IRS press releases. is misleading. The Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation found that about 40 percent of the participants in plans during the early days of ERISA were recovered bv newly (PBGC) has terminated established defined-contribution plans. 9 It is important to note that 18,857 defined benefit plans were terminated between 1975 and 1977, compared with 15,514 such terminations during the previous nineteen years. The surge in defined-contribution plan participants in 19771978, therefore, probably did not represent a comparable increase in total participation levels. These caveats aside, the combined information in tables II-2 and II-3 indicates that pension participation has grown significantly in recent years. The rate of plan qualifications has consistently exceeded terminations indicating real growth in plan availability. Furthermore, the average number of participants in newly established plans indicates manv of these plans are being established in small and 9Pension Benefit Guarantv Corporation, Analysis o[ Single Employer Delined Benefit Plan Terminatio_t, 1976, 1977, 1978, 3 vols. (Washington, D.C.: PBGC, 1977, 1978, 1979). 53 intermediate size firms. For example, the newly qualified definedbenefit plans in 1981 had an average of eighty-five participants, while defined-contribution plans averaged twenty-three participants. This fact is particularly significant when one considers that more than two-thirds of nonagricultural workers between the ages of twentyfive and sixty-four, working at least half time who were not covered by a pension plan in 1979 were in firms with fewer than 100 workers. I° Growth in Benefi'ciarie3"--Increased pension participation ultimately means higher rates of benefit recipiency, but these rates do not rise instantly. It is misleading to judge the effectiveness of pension programs on the basis of the number of current retirees receiving benefits. A newly established pension plan does not provide benefits to workers who have already left the sponsoring firm. Depending on the nature of the program established and the characteristics of the employer's work force, it could take several years before retirements under the program occur. Table II-4, based on tabulations o[' information that plan sponsors filed with the [RS (form 5500) in compliance with ERISA [or the 1977 plan year, indicates a clear relationship between plan age and beneficiaries in defined-benefit plans. Among other things, torm 5500 requires reporting the "effective plan date" or date the plan was set up, the number of active participants in the plan, and the number of beneficiaries. The age o[ the plan can be calculated from the eflcctive plan date. As expected, most of the young plans have more workers per participant than older plans do. Less than 10 percent of the plans that had been created in the previous five years reported fewer than five workers per retired beneficiarv. For plans operating twenty-five years or longer, nearly 49 percent had fewer than five active participants per beneficiary. The changes in this relationship with increasing plan age are too consistent to be coincidental. At the other end of the participant/beneficiary range, the pattern is comparably consistent. More than 55 percent of plans less than live years old had twenty or more active workers per beneficiary, while less than 11 percent of the oldest plans reporting had as many as twenty participants per beneficiary. Undoubtedly many of the older plans with high participant/beneficiary ratios are in firms that are expanding. High participant/beneficiary ratios will continue as some plan sponsors continue to expand in the future, but such sponsors will still have increasing numbers of I°Schieber 54 and George, Retirement Income Opportmlitie._ m an Aging America, p. 49. N •,. I _ r-_ - _ _ _r--:_ ....... - ._ _ dmd° 55 beneficiaries over the vcars. This relationship of plan age and beneficiary rates becomes particularly significant in comparison with the defined-benefit plan creation data shown earlier in table II-2. If we use 1977 as the reference year, because it corresponds with the ERISA data, we find that the universe of private defined-benefit programs grew by 218,487 plans in the previous twenty years; 32.0 percent of this growth occurred between 1973 and 1977 and 72.7 percent between 1968 and 1977. If all 28,169 tax-qualified plans in existence at the end of 1955 were assumed to be defined-benefit plans, which is certainly not the case, 62.7 percent of all defined-benefit plans would have been less than ten years old at the end of 1977. The definedbenefit pension system in this country today is still quite young. As the system matures, the ratio of workers to beneficiaries will markedly decline, much as the ratio of workers to beneficiaries in the Social Security program declined during the 1950s and 1960s. The ratio will decline not because of fewer covered workers, but because of more beneficiaries. The data on defined-contribution plans are more difficult to interpret but equally revealing. Table II-5 shows the participant/beneficiary ratio for defined-contribution plans with more than 100 active participants in 1977 based on ERISA filings. With the exception of plans more than twenty-five years old, less than 20 percent of the plans in any other age category reported a ratio of working participants to beneficiaries below twenty to one. This may seem particularly peculiar in comparison with the defined-benefit plan statistics, because defined-contribution plans often have more lenient vesting requirements than their counterparts. The most significant category in the table is the "unknown" category, which indicates that benefits were paid during the year but that there were zero beneficiaries. Most defined-contribution plans are not themselves annuity programs; at withdrawal or retirement, vested participants are generally given a lump-sum distribution. In many instances the employer will arrange for conversion of the distribution into an annuity program, but the plan itself seldom pays pension benefits in the traditional sense. Some defined-contribution plans also report the number of cash distributions in this reporting period as the number of beneficiaries--hence, the consistent percentage of plans reporting worker-to-recipient ratios above twenty to one. It is unlikely that many employers would experience turnover of vested employees in excess of 5 to 10 percent of their total work force each vear. This lump-sum distribution phenomenon also results in undercounting of the number of pension beneficiaries on population 56 _1 _ __ 57 surveys. For example, the Census Bureau's annual March Income Supplement to their Current Population Survey gathers information on the prevalence of the receipt of pension and the annual levels of benefits. Interviewers' instructions and training specifically direct that only regular income is to be recorded in the interview; one-time income is to be ignored. Unless defined-contribution plan lump-sum distributions are converted to an annuity, they never show up on the survey as retirement program benefits. Historical data on the growth of private pension beneliciaries over the years are scarce. Table II-6 includes the data that are available. The phenomenon of declining numbers of active participants relative to beneficiaries noted in the age analysis of the defined-benefit plan also prevails for all plans as the pension system ages. This phenomenon will continue to some extent as the younger plans now in the system continue to mature. Ultimately, it is reasonable to expect that this ratio will approximate the Social Security dependency ratio and vary directly with the demographic swings of the population. The aging of the pension system has also increased the receipt of benefits among the elderly. Table II-7 shows the percentages of families with persons between the ages of sixty-five and sixty-nine eligible to receive employer pension benefits in 1967 and in 1979. Over that period, the recipiency rates for couples increased more than 80 percent, while for single persons the rates more than doubled. Again, the further maturing of the pension system should result in additional increases in pension recipiency. Growth in Bene[its--The data in table II-6 indicate that average benefits paid by private plans have steadily increased. EBRI's previous research has shown this to be true among public plans as well. a_ Some analysts have argued that the relative stability of average benefits in constant dollars indicates that the income-replacement capacity of the private pension system is not growing. It is important, however, to distinguish between average benefits per recipient and average benefits for all the elderly. The following example demonstrates this point. Assume there are two groups of elderly people consisting of fifty persons each in a two-class society. Assume that forty people in group 1 each receive a pension of $1,000 per month and ten people in group 2 each receive $100 per month. Table II-8 shows the outcome of this example. _JEmployee Benefit Research Institute, Retirement America: Income Levels arid Adequacy (Washington, 58 hwome Opportunities D.C.: EBRI, 1982). in an Aging q_ _° _ 5 59 TABLE Percentage of Families Eligible to Receive II-7 with Individuals Ages 65 to 69 Employer Pension Benefits 1967 1979 29 15 22 53 33 42 Married Couples Single Persons All Families Source: Note: 1967 values from U.S. Social Security Administration, Demographic and Eco_umtic Characteristics of the Aged (Washington, D.C.: Office of Research and Statistics, 1975), p. 184. March 1980 and May' 1979 Current Population Survey data fur 1979 values. Values for 1979 arc higher than the percentage ot elderly persons currently receiving benefits because some persons ages sixty-five to sixty-nine have a vested right to employer pension benefits but have not vet received them. TABLE Pension Benefits Then Calculated assume in a Hypothetical Period 1 Total People Number Receiving a Pension 50 50 100 40 IO 50 Group 1 Group 2 Total Source: II-8 Two-Class Society: Monthly Benefit Total Benefits $1,000 100 $40,000 1,000 $41,000 by the author. that some time later, this society still consists of two groups of elderly persons, but conditions have improved for both. Assume that lorry-five persons of group 1 each receive a monthly benefit of $1,200, while thirty-five people in group 2 each receive $200 per month. Table II-9 shows the outcome. TABLE Pension Benefits Group 1 Group 2 Total Source: 60 Calculated II-9 in a Hypothetical Period 2 Total People Number Receiving a Pension 50 50 100 45 35 80 by the author. Two-Class Society: Monthly Benefit Total Benefit $ 1,200 200 $54,000 7,000 $61,000 The example suggests that things have generally improved for both groups in the interval between the periods depicted. The total level of benefits and recipiency rates improved for both groups, and average benefits for all elderlv increased from $410 to $610; the average benefit per recipient, however, declined from $820 to less than $763. Basically this same phenomenon has been occurring among private pensions. Many early pension plans provided benefits only to longcareer workers who stayed with the sponsoring firm until retirement. Also pension plans were most prevalent in firms and industries with higher-than-average salary and wage structures. The combination of these factors meant that average benefits were often large. During the 1950s and 1960s, sponsors began to establish vesting standards allowing workers to acquire pension entitlements based on shorter periods of service. When ERISA mandated vesting standards in 1974, it reduced the average service required to earn a benefit. At the same time that service requirements were being reduced, pensions were being extended to an increasing segment of the work force, including workers in the lower- and middle-earnings range. These improvements in the pension system are responsible for the extension in the number of people receiving benefits. Enhancing the general welfare of the elderly has meant stable average benefits per recipient, howcver. The growth in pension plans will mean expanding exposure of American workers to these programs in the future. The maturing of the baby-boom generation also should contribute to increased participation in these programs. The standardized vesting requirements established bv ERISA in combination with the aging of the pension plans themselves will assure higher rates of benefit recipiency as today's workers reach retirement. Thus, the pension system is expanding its role in the retirement income security system. Individual Savings and Asset Income Several recent studies have analyzed personal savings behavior, basing the analysis on a life-cycle consumption model which assumes that consumption in any given time period is not based solely on current earnings. I_ The model takes account of financial markets _Albert Ando and Franco Modigliani, "The Lite Cycle ot Hypothesis of Savings," America_z Ec'ommtic Review, vc_l. 51, no. 1 (March 1963), pp. 55 84: and Franco Modigliani and Richard Brumberg, "Utility Anah'sis and the Consumption Function: An Interpretation of Cross Section Data," Po.sl k'evl_esiau Ec'ouomics (New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press, 1954). 61 which permit wealth and debt accumulation that can be used to adjust consumption patterns over time. People are assumed to make consumption and savings decisions by comparing current and future resources with current and future needs. The theory suggests that people would save or accumulate wealth during their working years and liquidate those resources to meet retirement consumption needs. In this context, savings become a crucial element in the retirement income security system. Special Retirement Savings Programs--The U.S. tax code specifically recognizes the desirability of private retirement savings. People who are self-employed or in unincorporated businesses can establish a retirement program for themselves called a Keogh plan. Keoghs were initially authorized by the Self-Employed Individuals Tax Retirement Act of 1962, often referred to as H.R. 10. Initially, contributions were limited to the lesser of 10 percent of earnings or $2,500 annually. Today, Keoghs permit deductions from taxable income for retirement contributions up to $15,000 or 15 percent of earnings annually, whichever amount is smaller. The Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 increased the Keogh deduction limits to $30,000 for plan years beginning after 1983. In the future these limits will increase in step with contribution limits in incorporated business plans. The last year for which comprehensive information is available on the utilization of Keoghs is 1977. At that time there were 649,456 plans in operation with 907,403 participants. At the end of the year, according to filings with the IRS, these plans held $6.5 billion in assets. Individuals can also establish tax-deferred retirement savings programs for themselves. When ERISA was enacted, the tax code was modified to allow persons not covered bv a pension plan to establish individual retirement accounts (IRAs). The 1981 Economic Recovery Tax Act (ERTA) made IRAs available to all workers beginning in 1982, regardless of their pension coverage status. ERTA allows individual IRA contributions annually up to $2,000 to be deducted from taxable earnings. If an individual worker has a spouse who does not work, the limit is $2,250. Based on individual tax return data for 1980, the IRS estimates that $3.4 billion was contributed to 2.6 million IRA accounts that year. It is too early to estimate the actual response to the new IRA provisions included in ERTA, but there is some concern that IRAs may not be a particularly effective element of the retirement income security system. During 1977, roughly 50 million workers were eli62 gible to establish an IRA, but less than contributed to them. I_ There were several 11 percent of those eligible reasons for low utilization rates under previous law, however. The major reason was that the people most likely to take advantage of the IRA provisions were excluded prior to 1982. The expansion of IRA availability to workers covered bv a pension plan completely changes the economic and demographic characteristics of the eligible population. Table II-10 shows the earnings and age distribution of workers in May 1979 and their pension participation status. Anyone who was a plan participant at that time was excluded from contributing to an IRA during 1979. Some additional workers also were excluded because they had changed .jobs and thereby had become plan participants at some time during 1979. The table shows that more than three-fourths of workers with TABLE II-10 Earnings and Age Characteristics of the U.S. Civilian Work Force and Workers Participating in a Pension Plan in May 1979 Estimated Earnings in 1979 Total Work Force (Millions) Workers Participating in a Pension Plan (Millions) (Percent) $ I -$ 4,999 $ 5,000-$ 9,999 $10,000-$14,999 $15,000-$19,999 $20,000-$24,999 $25,000 or more 11.97 23.42 19.66 12.49 5.95 5.70 1.20 8.62 12.10 9.45 4.74 4.63 10.0 36.8 61.5 75.6 79.7 81.2 Unestimated 16.18 2.81 17.4 21.18 25.41 18.56 16.04 7.00 4.33 2.85 95.37 4.65 12.84 10.05 9.23 4.08 2.20 .49 43.54 21.9 50.6 54.7 57.6 58.2 51.0 17.2 45.7 Age Less than 25 25 34 35 44 45 54 55-59 60-64 65 or older Total Source: EBRI tabulations of Mav 1979 Current Population Survey data. I_Dallas L. Salisbury and Susan E. Click, "IRAs: An Expanding Opportunity Retirement Provisions" (Washington, D.C.: EBRI, 1981 ). for Private 63 annual earnings over $15,000 were excluded. Also, most members of the prime age groups between twenty-five or thirty-five and sixtyfive in which retirement savings are most likely to occur were largely excluded. Seventy percent of prime-age, regularly employed wage and salary workers were covered by pension plans. If the work force were narrowed to include only workers employed at least half time, IRA participation rates would probably be higher. The population eligible for IRAs roughly doubled in 1982. Table |I11 indicates that the use of IRAs has expanded with income of workers. Because the expansion in eligibility occurred primarily among higher-income workers, the use of these savings vehicles should increase more than proportionately. While the long-term effects of IRAs on the income security of future retirees has not yet been adequately analyzed, this analysis is important if IRAs are to be a vital part of the retirement system. Information on the early response to expanded IRA availability is sketchy but encouraging. The increase in IRA assets invested in selected financial institutions, shown in table II-12, suggests that total IRA assets could easily double and possibly triple this year alone. A recent survey by the Life Insurance Marketing and Research Association found that one-third of all eligible households intend to open an IRA this year. Furthermore, the survey found that about 60 percent of those opening an account intend to fund them, at least in part, from current income.14 TABLE II- 11 Percentage of People Who Are Eligible and Who Have IRAs, by Income Class, 1977 Family Adjusted Gross Income Percentage of Eligible People Who Have IRAs $ 0-$ 5,000 .2 $ 5,000-$10,000 1.3 $10,000-$15,000 3.3 $15,000-$20,000 5.5 $20,000-$50,000 21.7 Over $50,000 52.4 Source: President's Commission on Pension Policy, Co_ni_lgo/Age: Towarda National Retiremettt Income Policy (Washington, D.C., 1981),p. 35. 14WallStreet Journal, July 1, 1982,p. 2. 64 TABLE 11-12 Assets in IRAs by Selected Financial Institutions Percentage Increase 12/31/81 (Millions) Commercial Banks Mutual Savings Banks Savings and Loan Associations Credit Unions Mutual Funds $7,000 _ 3,400 9,200 _ 205 2,600 3/31/82 (Millions) $11,660 6/30/82 (Millions) 12/31/81 to 6/30/82 $14,905 b 112.9 4,200 5,764 69.5 15,493 447 3,800 NA NA 4,285 68.4 _E 118.0 d 64.8 Source: EBRI calculations from data provided by the Federal Reserve Board, National Association of Mutual Savings Banks, National Credit Union Administration, U.S. League of Savings Associations, Investment Company Institute. _IRA and Keogh deposits. bEstimated. _Preliminarv. dTo March .31, 1982. In addition to Keoghs and IRAs, changes in the tax code in 1978 allow employers to establish tax-deferred "salary reduction" programs. Section 401(k) of the Internal Revenue Code sanctions "cash or deferred arrangements" (CODAs) under qualified profit-sharing or stock-bonus plans. Although the enabling legislation was part of the 1978 Revenue Act and was effective for the plan year beginning on or after Januarv 1, 1980, IRS did not publish proposed regulations until November 10, 1981. Under these rules, qualified plans may offer participants the choice of immediate or deferred compensation taxable in the year actually received. Participants can choose to receive as cash the part of the employer compensation that would otherwise be contributed to the plan, or the participants can choose to defer receipt of the part of their compensation that would normally be received in cash. The employer pays the deferred amount, or salary reduction, into the qualified plan. As with all qualified plans, nondiscrimination requirements must be met. In addition, any employer contributions deferred at an employee's individual election under a CODA must vest immediately. The nondiscrimination ing provision will assure pants. This test separates test in conjunction with the immediate vestbenefit distributions for all CODA particithe eligible employees into those in the top 65 third of the salary scale and those in the bottom two-thirds, and calculates an average deferral percentage for each group. To be qualified as nondiscriminatory, a plan has to meet either of two tests. Under the first test, the average deferral percentage in the top salary tier cannot exceed that in the lower by more than 1.5 times. Under the second test, the higher tier may contribute at a rate of 2.5 times the lower group but the higher group's average deferral rate may not exceed the lower group's rate by more than three percentage points. Little information is available yet on the ultimate potential of these programs. Early marketing surveys indicated that as many as threefourths of firms being surveyed were seriously considering implementing a CODA program.15 The availability of CODAs and their need to be tax qualified may have some offsetting effects on IRA utilization. Under ERTA, employers can establish voluntary programs that allow workers to make their IRA contributions through payroll deductions. The problem for an employer who establishes both a payroll deduction IRA and a CODA is that IRA contributions may lower the contribution limits in the CODA or endanger its tax qualification altogether. Many perceive CODAs as the more effective retirement savings device because they are not subject to the IRA contribution limits. Moreover, because CODA contributions are not subject to the payroll tax, CODAs provide an added tax incentive to individuals with current compensation below the Social Security taxable maximum. Salary reductions for such workers, however, will reduce their Social Security entitlements. Home Ownership--The current prevalence of pension plans and worker participation in them are relatively recent phenomena. The multiplicity and extent of tax incentives for retirement savings are even more recent. Public programs and tax incentives that encourage people to buy a house, however, have a much longer history. Table II-13 shows the significance of home ownership in an aggregated distribution of assets and liabilities for selected years. Home or residential property ownership makes up nearly a third of all household assets and nearly two-thirds of household liabilities. The nature of the home purchase and mortgaging process is such that for many retirees today, the owned home constitutes the largest share of personal wealth. In 1978, more than 71 percent of housing I_Philip M. Alden, Jr., "Where Less Means vo[. 18, no. 4 (April 1982), pp. 43-44. 66 More--See. 401(k) Plans," Pe_tsion World, TABLE Distribution Current II-13 of Household Assets and Liabilities Prices for Selected Years, 1950-1979 in 1950 1960 1970 1980 $1,014.9 $1,661.2 $3,028.4 $8,178.1 Assets Total Assets(Billio_ls) Percentage of assets held as: Financial assets Owner-occupied housing Owner-occupied land Equity in noncorporate business 71.7 14.6 2.0 53.1 18.8 4.3 55.7 18.6 6.0 46.1 23.3 7.2 27.7 23.7 19.7 23.5 $77.0 $228.1 $502.0 Liabilities Total Liabilities (Billio_ls) Percentage of liabilities held Home and other mortgages Installment credit Other consumer credit Bank and other loans Security and other credit $1,493.5 as: 57.2 20.1 13.2 3.8 5.7 Net Wortt¢'(Billio_s) $937.9 Assets/Liabilities 63.9 19.7 8.8 3.2 4.3 61.7 21.0 7.5 5.7 4.1 $1,433.0 13.2 $2,526.4 7.3 65.0 20.9 4.8 5.6 3.7 $6,684.6 6.0 5.5 Source: Note: Federal Reserve Board: Flow of Funds Accounts. This table 11-13 does not include pension fund reserves or privately held consumer durables other than housing. "Excludes reproducible assets o[ nonprofit institutions, nonprofit plant and equipment, and land owned by nonprofit organizations. units with an Social Security clderlv head Administration home owners their rcsidencc. At retirement, aged sixtv-four 17 home owners generating financial were owner occupied, j6 A study found that in 1975, 77 percent to sixty-nine can convert reported their no homes for the of the mortgage into on income- assets, or they can continue living in them, enjoying the and personal advantages resulting from owning residential I_u.s. Dcpartmcnt of Housing and Urban Development, Ammal Housing Sun'ev. 1978, Part A: Gowral ttousml4 Characteristics (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Gmernment Printing Office, 1980), table A-I. _rJoseph Friedman and Jane Siogren, "The Assets o[ the Elderly as The,,' Retire," (Washington, D.C.: Abt Associates, Inc., 1980), p. 108. 67 property. On the financial side, the prevalence of mortgage-free home ownership among the elderly reduces the portion of monthly income that must be spent to provide shelter. The Retirement History Survey conducted by the Social Security Administration has been used to compare the housing circumstances of persons aged sixty-six to seventy-one in 1977. The analysis found that elderly home owners were spending about 23 percent of their income to meet these shelter costs, whereas older renters were spending about 33 percent on average. Is Part of this differential can be attributed to higher incomes among the home-owning elderly, but the prevalence of subsidized rental arrangements for low-income elderly offsets their higher housing costs to some extent. Not only do elderly home owners pay a smaller share of their income to meet their housing needs, but also they live in quarters that are somewhat larger on average than those of their counterparts who rent. The elderly are not particularly mobile as a group, and home ownership allows them to reside in housing that is familiar to them, often in the setting of communities where they have spent many years of their lives. It provides them financial as well as personal security. There is some concern that many elderly people today are not efficiently using this substantial asset to assure their retirement income security. Reverse annuity mortgages (RAMs), which allow the elderly to annuitize their home equity while continuing to live in their own homes, are available on only a limited basis, but as the programs become established RAMs may prove to be a valuable retirement income resource. Although the value of home equity should not be considered a substitute for pensions or Social Security protection, it is a potentially valuable resource that can augment the effectiveness of retirement programs. Business Assets--In addition to saving specifically for retirement and household equity, a small but significant number of households accumulate business equity during their lifetimes. This group is important because traditionally these people have been less likely than wage and salary workers to acquire pension protection. During 1979, less than 15 percent of the self-employed were participating in a pension program. 19 Based on the Social Security Administration's I_Sally R. Merrill, "Home Equity and the Elderly," prepared for The Brookings Institution's Conference on Retirement and Aging, Washington, D.C.,October 21, 1982,p. 12. t_Schieber and George, Retirement hwome Opportunities in a_lAging America, p. 83. 68 Retirement History Survey, Michael Hurd and John Shoven, of the National Bureau of Economic Research, found that among households headed by a person aged fifty-eight to sixtv-three in 1969, 10.6 percent possessed wealth in the form of farm equity, 8.3 percent held business equity, and 17.2 percent held property other than their own residences. By 1975, among the surviving persons studied in 1969, these respective rates had declined to 6.9, 4.2, and 14.8 percent, z° As this group aged into their mid- to upper-sixties, the most significant declines in real assets occurred among farmers and people with buMncss equity. Using separate data, Peter Diamond and Jerry Hausman, economics professors at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, found that "farmers and businessmen form a disproportionate share of those with consistently high wealth (top decile year after year), particularly in the oldest age group. ''21 The results of these two studies, using entirely different data, are totally consistent. Professor Joseph Quinn of Boston College has noted that among the elderly who continue to work there is a relatively heavy preponderance of self-employed workers. Using data from the Retirement History Survey, he found that self-employed people nearing retirement age were less likely to be out of the labor force than were people who worked in wage or salary positions. He attributed this situation to the less constrained environment of the self-employed, as well as to the absence of institutional rules that affect the elderlv's work behavior, x2 This combination of studies suggests that people who accumulate business wealth tend to continue to rely on business income beyond normal retirement age. And business people who do retire often find that liquidation of their equity provides substantial assets for their retirement income security. Hence, for business people, accumulated business assets appear to substitute to a considerable extent for organized retirement savings. Other Financial Assets--During 1980 more than half of household asset holdings were either residential properties or business assets. Table II-13, presented earlier, indicates that financial assets as a percent of total assets held by households have steadily declined over 2°Michael D. Hurd and John B. Shoven, "The Economic Status of the Elderly," NBER working paper, forthcoming, 1982. 2t Peter Diamond and Jerry Hausman, "Individual Savings Behavior," paper prepared for the National Commission on Social Security, Washington, D.C., 1980, p. 22. 22Joseph F. Ouinn, "Labor Force Participation Patterns of Older Self-Employed Workers," Social Security Bulletin, vol. 43, no. 4 (April 1980), p. 17. 69 the past thirty years, as a result of inflation, which has driven up the value of real property assets more rapidly than financial assets. Although these asset distributions do not separately show private retirement savings such as those in IRAs, and pension assets are specifically excluded, it is unlikely that a large share of the financial assets represented in table II-13 would fall into one of the other categories of retirement savings (IRAs, CODAs, etc.) discussed earlier. Financial assets did account for 46 percent of household wealth in 1980, but these assets are less unilormly distributed than property or pension wealth. Liquid assets, such as funds in checking accounts, savings accounts, stocks and bonds, are the most common assets held by the elderly. Friedman and Sjogren tound that 81 percent of households headed by a person aged sixty-four to sixty-nine reported some liquid assets on the 1975 Retirement History Survey. However, the average value of held assets by this group was more than five and one-half times the median amount, which indicates that the wealthier elderly hold a disproportionate share of assets. 23 The long-term effects of tax incentives aimed at individual retirement savings are, of course, uncertain at this point. If these programs have their intended result, they will raise the level of savings, possibly increase the share of financial assets in household portfolios, and cause a wider distribution of private savings in general. Employment Income of the Elderly Most analyses of income security tor elderly people do not address their employment income, chiefly because relatively few older people participate in the labor force. On the basis of the historically low labor-force participation rates of elderly women, it is safe to conclude that, thus far, most women have not relied on earnings to meet a large share of their income requirements. Elderly men, in contrast, have traditionally had higher labor force participation rates than women although the male rate has been declining steadily for nearly a century (see table II-14). This decline was relatively slow around the turn of the century; the single greatest decline occurred during the 1930s, when the United States experienced the highest unemployment rates in its history. That more than half of the elderly men and more than nine out of ten elderly women did not work during 2_Joseph Friedman and Jane Sjogren, "Assets o[ the Elderly as They Retire," Social Security Bulletin, vol. 44, no. 1 (January 1981),p. 26. 7O TABLE Labor-Force Source: Participation and Older II-14 Rates for Individuals for Selected Years Age 65 Year Men (Percent) Women (Percent) 1890 1900 1920 1930 1940 1950 ! 960 1970 68.3 63.1 55.6 54.0 41.8 41.4 30.5 24.8 7.6 8.3 7.3 7.3 6.1 7.8 10. 3 10.0 U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics o]the U_lited States (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975), p. 132, Series D 29-41. the 1930s retirement a pension. tinues to is remarkable, considering program and that only that there was no Social 10 to 15 percent, at most, Security received Today fewer than one in five men over age sixty-five conwork. The historical reliance of the elderly on earnings suggests that it might not be unreasonable in the future to expect a greater portion of the elderly's income to come from wages and salaries. For this to happen, though, a trend dating back a hundred years would have to be reversed. Cash The Assistance 1935 Social Programs Security Act established the Old-Age Assistance (OAA) program and the Aid to the Blind (AB) program in addition to the Old-Age Retirement Insurance program. The OAA program offered states grants-in-aid on a matching basis to enable the states to help needy aged persons. The federal government reimbursed states for expenditures under the program using a matching tormula that generally resulted in higher federal matching to low-income states. The states designed, implemented, and administered the programs through district or county offices, or through local agencies under state supervision within minimal federal requirements. Federal financing came from general revenues while state financing came from either state or local funds. Later, the Aid to the Permanently and Totally Disabled (APTD) as OAA under the Social program Security was established Act. on the same basis 71 The 1972 Social Security amendments established the Supplemental Security Income (SSI) program, which was implemented on February 1, 1974. SSI replaced the OA, AB, and APTD programs and completely altered the federal-state relationship in providing assistance to needy persons in the adult aid categories. The Social Security Administration administers SSI and regulations are established at the federal level. The states were left with only a supplementary role. In January 1974 the federal guarantee for a person without other income and living in his or her own household was $140; an eligible couple in similar circumstances was guaranteed $210. Individuals or couples living in someone else's household were eligible for one-third less. The federal program is financed from general revenues. States were given the option of supplementing the federal benefit. This supplement could be administered either by the state itself or by Social Security in the state's behalf. Eligibility is determined on the basis of income, resources, and status as aged, blind or disabled. SSI was intended to provide a nationally uniform income floor for people eligible to receive benefits. It sought to raise benefits in states where payments were traditionally low. The higher guarantee levels in conjunction with uniform assets tests, lien, and provisions for relatives' responsibility expanded the coverage to a broader base of the needy. The program also sought to limit or decrease the fiscal burden of adult welfare programs at the state and local levels. Finally, the federalization of this program sought to provide uniform and efficient administration. The program has been relatively successful in meeting its goals. Participants in one of the predecessor programs were automatically converted to SSI and generally achieved a significantly higher economic status because of the increased benefit levels. The poorest of people automatically transferred benefited most. 24 The program also extended assistance to more needy people. One concern about the program is that significant numbers of people who appear to be eligible for SSI do not participate. While this is probably the case, empirical analysis has found that individual perceptions of need and actual benefit eligibility are significant in explaining nonparticipation in SSI. People who perceive they have adequate resources to get by on and those who are entitled to small monthly benefits are less likely than others to participate in SSI. 24Sylvester Assistance 18-46. 72 J. Schieber, Populations," "First Year Impact of SSI on Economic Status of 1973 Adult Social Security Bulletitz, vol. 41, no. 2 (February 1978), pp. Lack of information about the program and concerns about social stigma also help explain why some eligible people do not participate in SSI. 2_ SSI benefits are indexed to increases in the consumer price index. Since 1974, the basic federal guarantee has doubled, reaching $284.30 for a single person and $426.40 for a couple in July 1982. SSI cash benefits administered by Social Security rose from $5.1 billion in 1974 to $8.5 billion in 1981. According to published Social Security data, the number of elderly SSI recipients has decreased from 2.3 million in 1974 to !.7 million at the end of 1981. 2_ But, the Social Security Administration classifies SSI recipients according to their initial basis of entitlement. Thus, at the beginning of 1974, 87,000 recipients over age sixty-five were classified as blind or disabled, but by the end of 1981, the number of elderly blind or disabled SSI recipients had climbed to 433,000. 27 The total number of elderly SSI recipients has remained relatively constant over the period. There is substantial overlap in the SSI and Social Security retirement for the elderly. At the end of 1980 about 70 percent of aged SSI recipients were also receiving an average monthly Social Security retirement benefit of $198.56. 2_ It is hoped that the future income security role of SSI will diminish as other components of the retirement system mature. Although the percentage of all elderly people receiving cash assistance benefits has steadily declined over the past three decades, it is unlikely that the need for a cash assistance program for the elderly will ever be totally eliminated. In-Kind Benefit Programs Beginning in the mid-1960s and accelerating through the 1970s, public policy has moved toward meeting individual needs through in-kind benefits. Bv far the largest of these is the Medicare program. Except for Medicare, which is targeted at Social Security and Railroad Retirement beneficiaries over age sixtv-five and disabled persons who have been receiving Social Securitv or Railroad Retirement 2_John ipation 21. 2_U.S. 1982), 271bid., 2sU.S. plement, A. Mencfee, Bea Edwards, and Svlvester J. Schieber, "Analysis of Non-particin the SSI Program," Social Security Bulletin, vol. 44, no. 6 (June 1981), pp. 3Social Security Administration, table M-19, p. _27. table M-18, p. 29. Social Security Administration, 1980, table Social Social Security Security Bulletin, Bulletin vol. 45, Ammal no. 4 (April Statistical Sup- i63, p. 226. 73 benefits for two years or more, the remaining benefits are granted on a needs-tested basis. 29 Table II-15 shows the totals for various kinds of federal benefits to the elderly in 1979. By 1981, annual Medicare costs had increased to $42.5 billion. 3° Health care programs have continued to grow more rapidly than other benefits programs, but there has certainly been significant growth in each of these categories over the past couple of years. The Medicare program has to be considered in the general context of Social Security and broader retirement policy issues. The remaining programs are important parts of what has come to be called the social safety net. Although programs will continue to have an important role, retirement policy should be developed with the goal of minimizing the need for these programs. The nature and magnitude of these programs can be assessed only in the context of perceived needs and budgetary constraints at any particular time. To a large extent, these needs and constraints are determined politically, and thus they defy projection. Continuing Evolution of the U.S. Retirement System The programs that now provide retirement income security continue to evolve. Although it is possible to focus on separate components of the programs when deliberating policy, it is necessary to TABLE II-15 Federal In-Kind Benefits for the Elderly, 1979 In-Kind Benefits Value (Millions) Medicare $24,647 Medicaid 4,329 Food Stamps 512 Subsidized Public Housing 1,634 Other In-Kind 59 Total In-Kind Benefits $31,181 Source: The Budget o[ the United States Government, Fiscal Year 1981 (Washington, D.C., 1980),p. 267. 2_Amore complete description of these programs can be found in EBRI's Coverageand Benefit Entitlement and Income Levels and Adequacy studies. _°Budget of the United States Governme_lt,Fiscal Year 1983 (Washington, D.C., 1982), pp. 5-161. 74 understand where current policies may lead us before we consider various options that will change the mix of program components. EBRI has undertaken a major retirement policy research project to evaluate the long-term implications of present policies and the potential effects of various policy alternatives. Chapter III presents an analysis of future income levels for the elderly by projecting current policies into the future. The remaining chapters take up the Social Security problems being broadly discussed by politicians, the news media, and policy analysts concerned with retirement and economic policy issues. 75 III. Retirement Benefit Current Policy Levels Under Chapters I and II described the evolution of various programs and resources that provide income security to elderly people. The modifications to the Social Security program now being considered have far-reaching implications not only for beneficiaries and taxpayers, but for other income security programs as well. Before we consider the Social Security financing situation and various policy options for changing the mix of program components, it is necessary to understand where the current policies would lead and how the results of current policies would compare with the results of alternative policies. This chapter, therefore, begins with the development of a framework for evaluating the potential of current programs and policies that will provide income security for the elderly of the future. The analysis in the chapter is based on a microsimulation model that projects into the future the patterns of work, earnings, marital status, retirement, and death for a sample of the United States population between the ages of twentv-five and sixty-four in 1979. The model simulates people's working careers, their retirement, and the level of income they receive from various sources throughout their lives. The analysis in this chapter focuses on the sources and levels of income that today's workers might expect at the present Social Security normal retirement age if current policies are continued. The model is also the basis for analysis in chapter VI. There the model is used to evaluate the implications of various potential changes to the Social Security program. A Framework for Evaluation One way to evaluate policy changes is to make the changes and then observe the response. For example, the Social Security retirement age could be raised and the effects of that change monitored as the new age criteria were implemented. If factors other than Social Security's retirement-age criteria are important in determining actual retirement behavior, however, this policy change may not have the desired result. In other words, the policy prescription for solving the problem may be frustrated bv the way workers and their employers act in response to it. Another way to evaluate policy is to construct a model--a mathematical abstraction that embodies a behavioral theory--which would 77 approximate the workings of the system being analyzed. Although it is impossible for such mathematical tools to completely capture realworld phenomena, models help in understanding current events and in guessing the likelihood of future events under alternative assumptions and policies. The use of quantitative economic models dates back to Jan Tinbergen's 1939 analysis of the macroeconomic structure of the United States economy. I An alternative approach to modeling macroeconomic structures was developed by Wassily Leontief in the early 1950s. 2 The latest approach for explaining economic behavior through modeling was originally developed by Guy Orcutt, 3 who devised a microanalytic model that could be used to analyze socioeconomic behavior. Macroeconomic models are used to project aggregate economic flows on the basis of alternative assumptions; they can deal with the total economy or selected segments. Microeconomic models, in contrast, use the individual or the household as their basic unit of analysis. While the micro unit has always been the basic building block for economic behavioral theory, microanalytic modeling has become popular only in recent years, as household survey data have become available and computer technology has advanced. The Employee Benefit Research Institute has undertaken a large retirement policy research project, based on a microsimulation of a sample of the United States population, to evaluate the long-term implications of present policies and the potential effects of various policy alternatives. Estimating the distribution of future retirement income requires the development of representative work and earnings histories that include periods of coverage under retirement plans. This information can then be used to calculate retirement benefits, earnings replacement rates, and the like. In addition, the level of income from programs such as Supplemental Security Income can be estimated to obtain a more comprehensive picture of the elderly's income security over time. To perform these tasks, ICF Incorporated has developed a model that uses recent data on pension plan characteristics, labor-force participation, and pension coverage. A version of this model was develIJan Tinbergen, Statistical Testing o[ Business Cycle Theories (Geneva, Switzerland: Society of Nations, 1939). 2Wassily Leontief et al., The Structure o[ the American Economy (New York: Oxford University Press, 1951). _Guy Orcutt, "A New Type of Socio-Economic System," Review o] Economics and Statistics, vol. 58, no. 5 (May 1957),pp. 773-797. 78 oped in 1980 for the Office of Pension and Welfare Benefit Programs at the U.S. Department of Labor and for the President's Commission on Pension Policy. + During 1981, ICF substantially enhanced this model for the American Council of Life Insurance. For the project discussed here, ICF, under contract for EBRI, has further revised the model so that it can better measure the impact of changes in Social Security policy. Pension and Retirement Income Simulation Model--The Pension and Retirement Income Simulation Model (PRISM) has three basic components: an input database, a work history simulation, and a retirement benefit simulation. The input database contains survey and earnings histories on 28,000 persons. The work historv simulator uses dynamic aging simulation techniques to generate work, wage, and family histories for records used in the simulation from the population database. The work history element of the model assigns a set of actual plan characteristics to each person covered bv an employer retirement program. The model is linked to the ICF MacroeconomicDemographic Model in order to produce long-term estimates consistent with the macroeconomic and demographic projection of the U.S. economv. The retirement benefit simulator calculates the retirement benefit payable from each of the plans in which each person participated, plus that person's Social Security entitlement and benefits from IRAs established bv individuals. Finally, the model calculates benefits for low-income individuals from the Supplemental Security Income program. A more detailed description of the model is presented in appendix A. Assumptions [+orthe Base Case Simzdations--To actually carry out the simulation, analysts must make certain assumptions about the work histories and retirement benefits of families. To the extent possible, the assumptions used in the current policy simulation parallel assumptions used in the intermediate Social Security valuations, known as the Alternative II-B assumptions (from the section in the 1982 Social Security Trustees Report in which they are stated). A brief description of various key assumptions follows. Patterns of employment bv industry, age, sex, hours worked per year, and part-time/full-time status do not change over time. The level aJames Schulz and his colleagues at Brandeis University pioneered the initial development ot microanalytic pension simulation models. The model presented here draws on Schulz's work and extends it for application to policy analysis. 79 of employment is constrained to match the ICF macroeconomic-demographic model forecasts of employment rates by age and sex during each year of the simulation. Current patterns of wage growth based on age, sex, and job-change status are assumed to remain constant. In the aggregate, real wages are assumed to grow at the rates forecast by the ICF macroeconomic-demographic model by age and sex. While the wage growth of an individual or even of a particular cohort may vary from the average, overall real wages grow in a pattern close to that assumed in the Alternative II-B scenario. For each person, simulation of job change is a function of age, part-time/fulltime status, and job tenure. These probabilities are assumed not to change over time. The model uses the Social Security Administration's "Alternative II-B" assumptions on mortality and fertility, which reflect projected improvements in mortality as well as projected changes in fertility rates. These assumptions are also consistent with the ICF macroeconomic-demographic model forecasts. Disability rates are assumed to remain constant by age and sex over the simulation period. The current cross-sectional patterns of marriage, divorce, and remarriage by age and sex arc assumed to continue over the simulation period; the assumptions are consistent with the assumptions about marital status used by the Social Security Administration in its population forecasts. Prices are assumed to increase at the rate specified under the Alternative II-B assumptions. Table III-1 shows these rates of increase in the CPI. In the current policy simulation of retirement benefits, 70 percent of married men with an annual pension benefit of less than $3,000 in 1980 dollars are assumed to elect not to take the postretirement joint-and-survivor option in their plan; 30 percent of married men with annual pension benefits of $3,000 or greater are assumed not to take it. For married women, it was assumed that 75 percent with annual pension benefits less than $3,000 in 1980 dollars do not take the postretirement joint-and-survivor option; 50 percent of married women with annual pension benefits of $3,000 or greater in 1980 dollars are assumed not to take the option. Table III-2 summarizes the assumptions used to estimate participation in supplemental thrift and savings plans for people eligible to participate in them. People who are vested in a defined-contribution plan and then change jobs are assumed to roll their lump-sum payment over into an IRA if the value of the lump-sum distribution is $1,750 or more in 1980 dollars and if they are age thirty or older. People who have lump-sum distributions with a value less than $1,750 8O Assumed Calendar TABLE III-1 Consumer Price Index Used in Simulations Increases Consumer Price (Percent) Year 1979 _ 1980" 1981 '_ 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 199O 1991 - 1994 1995-1999 2000 and later Source: _Actual Index 13.3 12.4 10.3 6.9 7.9 7.4 6.6 5.8 5.5 5.3 4.9 4.5 4.0 4.0 4.0 1982 Annual Report o[Trustees o[the Federal Old-Age a_d Suta,ivors lnst_ra_ce and Disability l_zsura_we Trust Funds (Washington, D.C.: Social Security Administration, 1982), p. 29. consumer price index data are used for these years. TABLE 111-2 Assumptions about Savings Plan Participation Employer Hourly Wage Level (1980 Dollars) Less than $4 $4-$7 More than $7 Low (Percent) 20 4O 60 Match Medium (Percent) 25 50 75 Rate a High (Percent) 30 60 90 Source: Developed by the author and project staff of ICF Incorporated. ;'Plans that match one dollar of employee contributions with less than fifty cents of employer contributions are low-match plans. Plans that match one dollar of employee contributions with fifty to ninety-five cents are medium-match plans. Plans that match one dollar of employee contributions with one dollar or more of employer contributions are high-match plans. in 1980 dollars or who are younger than age thirty arc assumed to cash these benefits out. People with deferred vested benefits from defined-benefit plans are assumed to start receiving payments in the 81 first year they are eligible. Similarly, widows of vested men who chose the joint-and-survivor option are assumed to draw on these benefits in the first year they are available, provided the widow is eligible under the rules of the plan. The initial benefit in defined-benefit plans was indexed to changes in wages for flat and unit benefit formulas. Defined-benefit plan formulas based on final pay and all defined-contribution plan formulas were held constant. No changes in participation, vesting, or other standard provisions of plans were assumed. Table III-3 summarizes the assumptions used in modeling the adoption of IRAs by noncovered workers. These estimates do not include workers assumed to roll over vested benefits into IRA arrangements. Ninety percent of noncovered workers who adopt IRAs are assumed to contribute to them annually. The proportion of persons assumed to adopt tax-deductible IRAs in 1982 under the provisions of the Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 is equal to 80 percent of the proportion of uncovered persons who contributed to IRAs in 1979 on an age and earnings basis. In future years, it is assumed that 80 percent of the people who adopted IRAs will contribute to them. New IRAs were assumed to be established using the assumptions in table III-3. Table III-4 shows the contribution levels assumed for these IRAs. Pension coverage is assumed to increase at rates consistent with the moderate growth assumptions used in EBRI's Income Levels and Adequacy study, s No growth in pension coverage is assumed in the mining industry, the federal government, state or local government, or agricultural sectors. Coverage is assumed to grow at an annual rate of 0.33 percent in the manufacturing industry; at 0.44 percent TABLE III-3 Assumptions about the Annual Probability of Noncovered Workers Adopting an IRA Family Earnings Level (1980 Dollars) Less than $12,500 $12,501 -$25,000 More than $25,000 Percentage of Workers by Age 25-39 40-54 55-59 60 or Above 0.40 0.60 3.75 0.80 1.20 3.25 1.00 1.40 3.50 1.00 1.80 5.00 Source: Developed bv the author and project staff of ICF Incorporated. SEmployee Benefit Research Institute, Retirement Income Opportunities in an Aging America: htcome Levels and Adequacy (Washington, D.C.: EBR[, 1982), p. 104. 82 TABLE III-4 Assumptions Family Earnings Level (1980 Dollars) about IRA Individual IRA Contributions Spousal IRA Less than $13,500 70% of the smaller of 80% of the smaller of (1) 15% of earnings or (1) 15% of earnings or (2) $2,000 (2) $2,250 $13,500 $25,000 70% of $2,000 80% of $2,250 More than $25,000 90% of $2,000 95% of $2,250 Source: Developed by the author and project staff of lCF Incorporated. in the transportation industrv and among the self-employed, 0.57 percent per year in the finance industry; and at 0.87 percent per year in the construction, trade, and service industries. Current Policy Simulation Results The model was used to simulate the work histories and retirement income resources available to a representative sample of persons between the ages of twenty-five and sixty-four in 1979. This analysis focuses on the sources and levels of income estimated through the simulation when the sample persons reach age sixty-five. In this way, income levels and composition can be viewed as they change over time for successive cohorts of people when they reach the current normal retirement age under Social Security. PRISM estimates earnings and benefits from Social Security, pensions, IRA accruals, and Supplemental Security Income. This discussion will use the family as the unit of analysis, so the receipt and level of income are reported on that basis. The two types of families that are considered in the analysis are: (1) single persons, including persons who have never married, those whose spouses have died before reaching age sixty-five, and divorcees; and (2) married couples, including intact couples generally at the point the older spouse reaches age sixtv-five. The presentation of the results breaks the prime working-age population in 1979 into four age cohorts, based on age in 1979 (see table III-5). The assignment of single persons to their respective cohorts was straightforward. As for married couples, when both husband and wife were in the same cohort, the sources and levels of familv income were estimated at the point when the older person reached age sixty-five in the simulation. When husband and wife were in separate cohorts, the sources and levels of income were estimated 83 TABLE 111-5 Cohorts for Analysis by Ages in 1979 and Years When Cohorts Reach Age 65 Individual Ages in 1979 25-34 35-44 45-54 55-64 Years Reaching Age 65 2010 2019 2000-2009 1990 1999 1980-1989 Source: Computed by the author. as each person reached age sixty-five and were reported in both cohorts. Because the date of death is simulated, some persons who are included as married in one cohort are treated as single in a later cohort when they reach age sixty-five because their spouses are assumed to have died. Sources and Levels o/Income--The elderlv are often characterized as being primarily dependent on Social Security, although Social Security was never intended to be the sole source of retirement income for all Americans when it was established. EBRI's previous research has shown that significant numbers of elderly households also depend on earnings, pensions, and income from other assets as major sources of cash income:' Chapter II of this report suggests that the maturing of the pension system in the United States and the increased incentives tor individual retirement savings will change the mix of cash resources available to the elderly in the future. The results of the current policy simulation also suggest that this will bc the case. Earnings--Table III-6 shows the estimated percentages of families with earnings and the level of average simulated family earnings for the various age cohorts. The trend of declining receipt of earnings for the elderly in the future was consistent with long-term retirement patterns and expectations. The gradual increase in average family earnings in 1982 dollars was consistent with assumed real wage growth. While labor force participation rates are low for all people over age sixty-five, the labor torte participation rates decline steadily beyond that age. The treatment of married couples also tends 1o raise the estimated receipt of earnings because the analysis generally focuses _Ibid. 84 TABLE 111-6 Age in 1979 and Estimated Percentages of Families to Have Earnings, and Average Family Earnings in 1982 Dollars, at Age 65, by Marital Status All Families Cohort Age in 1979 25-34 35-44 45-54 55-64 Source: Percentage with Earnings 36 38 40 44 Tabulation Average Amount of Earnings $19,754 19,384 15,825 13,331 Married Couples Single Persons Percentage Average with Amount of Earnings Earnings 46 $22,377 49 21,198 48 18,479 55 15,498 of PRISM current policy simulation Percentage Average with Amount of Earnings Earnings 20 $10,635 22 13,039 27 8,486 28 6,917 results. on the year in which the older spouse reaches age sixty-five. Aworking wife of a sixty-five-year-old retiree who is more than three years younger than her husband would not be eligible for Social Security retirement benefits and in many instances might reasonably be expected to work until at least age sixty-two. The plausibility of the projections can be judged against estimated earnings levels reported by the elderlv for a recent year. Table III-7 shows the 1979 earnings for elderly single persons and married couples estimated from the March 1980 Current Population Survey. The rates of receipt of earnings at age sixty-five estimated by PRISM are slightly lower for the group of people aged fifty-five to sixty-four than the rates for people right at the normal retirement age for Social Security when the March 1980 CPS was conducted. However, they are very close. One factor that could account for the difference in the CPS and simulation results is a slight variation in the measurement period. The March CPS earnings data are gathered on the basis of prior year experience. So persons who were sixty-five in March 1980 would have been reporting earnings in the year in which they were sixty-four. The receipt of earnings for sixty-six-year-olds on the CPS closely correlates with the PRISM results for the oldest cohort at age sixty-five. It should also be kept in mind that earnings during the year do not necessarily indicate full-time or year-round employment in either real life or the simulation. For example, the employment rates of the elderly in March 1980 shown in table III-8 are consistentlv lower than the earnings receipt rates in table III-7. The elderlv as a group are more likely than younger workers to work only part time or peri85 TABLE III-7 Estimated Percentages of Elderly Families with Earnings, and Level of Earnings in 1982 Dollars for Elderly Families, by Marital Status in 1979 Age of All Families Elderly Person in Percentage Average March with Amount of 1980 _ Earnings Earnings 65 66 67 68 69 70 7i 72 or over 51.1 46.2 39.6 35.2 32.2 30.7 27. l 12.3 Married Couples Single Persons Percentage Average with Amount of Earnings Earnings Percentage Average with Amount of Earnings Earnings $14,832 11,566 10,573 i 1,091 l 0,482 9,168 7,906 7,888 62.6 56.3 51.6 49.4 43.0 46.2 37.4 23.8 $17,554 12,989 12,803 13,197 13,419 l0,244 9,675 9,316 36.5 33.0 25.7 18.4 21.0 16.8 17.7 6.5 $8,607 8,732 5,675 4,913 5, i02 6,570 4,469 5,298 Source: EBRI tabulation of the March 1980Current Population Survey. _'In the case of married couples, the age is the age of the older spouse. TABLE Employment Married and Living with Spouse Men Women (Percent) (Percent) Age 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 or over Source: III-8 Rates of the Elderly 33.0 29.3 27.9 25.9 23.9 26.9 19.3 11.5 Single Persons Men Women (Percent) (Percent) 15.3 9.2 I 0.2 9.7 4.2 6.0 6.9 2.9 EBRI tabulationsot in March 1980 25.3 27.1 17.3 26.1 17.2 15.4 13.4 8.1 25.0 23.1 18.9 10.8 16.5 12.6 12.5 3.7 the March 1980 Current Population Survey. odically. It is not surprising, thcrciorc, that cross-sectional employment rates measured in a particular week of the year would be somewhat lower than annual rates of employment [or the elderly, either 86 part or lull time, measured over the whole year. In the long term, the simulation projects a declining rate for the receipt of earnings, as a result of the continuing trend toward earlier retirements. The early retirement phenomenon will be exacerbated as more people become eligible for pensions. In fact, early retirement may become more pronounced than the simulation suggests if employers continue recent trends of liberalizing early retirement provisions in their pension programs. Ahernatively, it may turn around as life expectancy improves, and if the retirement age for Social Security were to be adjusted upward. In the simulation of the pension system, PRISM does not provide for liberalization of early retirement provisions. While the long-term trend is toward a reduced rate of receipt of earnings, the rate projected for married couples is relatively stable for the three younger, ten-year cohorts. The primary explanation lies in the increased labor-force participation of married women. Because married women today are more likely than their counterparts in earlier generations to have careers that are comparable to men's careers, they are also likelv to have somewhat higher labor-force participation rates in their older years than married women have traditionally had. So the stable levels of receipt of earnings projected for the younger cohorts of married couples are partly a transitional phenomenon resulting from modified work patterns of married women over the past ten to fifteen years. There is a steady increase in average earnings at age sixty-five, particularly for the three oldest cohorts simulated. This is a result of real wage growth that is assumed in the simulation. This increasing earnings phenomenon persists into the youngest cohort for the married couples. For single persons, average earnings at age sixty-five peak for the thirty-fiveto forty-four-year-old cohort. They decline somewhat thereafter, because of early retirements among those participating in pensions and because of the shift from full-time to parttime employment among older cohorts. Social Security--Table III-9 presents the estimated rates of receipt of Social Security and average family benefit levels for each of the four decennial cohorts. The estimates are made at the point at which people attain age sixty-five, in the same way that earnings estimates were developed. For some persons, of course, this means that they had been receiving benefits for some period prior to the point at which the estimate was made. Under the current policy simulation, the early retirement provisions in the present law are simulated over the full period. At the same time, some people will not vet be receiving ben87 efits because they are continuing to work at earnings levels where the earnings test reduces their benefits to zero. The effects of the declining prevalence of earnings reported earlier are evidenced by the increasing rates of receipt of Social Security for each successive cohort as these people reach age sixty-five. The average annual benefit levels shown in table III-9 are all in 1982 dollars. There is a steady pattern of increasing benefits, in real terms, for each successive cohort. This phenomenon is the result of the benefit structure now in place that bases initial benefits on the level of real wages. Because the model assumes real wage growth, consistent with expectations for the future of Social Security, initial benefit levels are driven upward by the inherent growth in the system. This benefit growth phenomenon was expected and the growth in average benefits estimated here is consistent with prototypical workers often described by the Social Security Administration. Table III10 shows annual initial benefit entitlements for three such prototypical workers developed by the Office of the Actuary at the Social Security Administration. The benefit levels cannot be directly compared between tables III-9 and III-10 because they are derived on different bases. The average benefit estimates in table III-10, for example, assume that the beneficiary has earned exactly the average covered wage during each year after 1937 or their twenty-first birthday, whichever is later, and the year the person reaches age sixty-five. It is unlikely that anyone would have a forty-four-year career with no breaks for unemployment or sickness and be right at the average earnings level every year throughout that career. This is not meant to criticize the TABLE III-9 Age in 1979 and Estimated Percentages of Families to Receive Social Security Benefits at Age 65, and Average Annual Benefits in 1982 Dollars, by Marital Status All Families Cohort Age in 1979 Percentage to Receive Benefit Average Amount of Benefit Married Percentage to Receive Benefit 25-34 93 $9,868 94 35-44 92 8,128 92 Couples Average Amount of Benefit Single Percentage to Receive Benefit $11,546 9,530 45-54 88 6,394 91 7,410 55-64 85 5,775 88 6,819 Source: Tabulations of PRISM current policy simulation results. 88 93 Persons Average Amount of Benefit $7,300 90 5,933 84 79 4,662 4,040 TABLE III-lO Past and Future Social Security Benefit Levels, in 1980 Dollars for Individuals Retiring at Age 65, 1952-2054 Annual Initial Benefit Amounts Calendar Year 1952 1955 1960 1965 1970 Low Earner Average Earner Maximum Earner a $ 2,600 3,600 2,900 3,1 O0 3,200 $ 3,500 3,600 4,000 4,200 4,600 $ 4,000 4,000 4,500 4,700 5,200 1975 1980 1990 2000 2010 3,400 3,900 3,700 4,400 5,200 5,000 5,900 5,600 5,700 8,000 5,900 7,400 7,500 9,500 12,000 2020 2030 2040 2054 6,1 O0 7,200 8,600 11,000 9,500 11,200 13,200 17,000 14,700 17,400 20,600 26,400 Source: Office of Actuary, Social Security Administration, Note: Benefits are rounded to nearest $100. _'Earnings equal to the Social Security earnings base. estimates over time in table III-10, under a stated because they do set of assumptions. show November how 19, 1980. benefits grow The average benefits in table III-9, in contrast, are derived on the basis of large numbers of simulated work histories, including a great deal of variation from the norms applied in the example shown in table III-10. PRISM simulates periods of unemployment, variations in individual that affect wage benefit growth, levels. early retirement, The important techniques, the estimated growth pected. In both cases, benefits are the future. and many other factors point is that under both in benefit levels projected to grow behaves as in real terms exin Pensions--Chapter II provided a fairly detailed discussion of the maturing of the pension system in this country which implied that the rates of receipt of pension benefits may be considerably higher in the future than they are today. 89 Table III-11 presents the simulation estimates of rates of receipt of pension benefits and average benefit levels for each of the four cohorts considered in this analysis. The oldest cohort, persons aged fifty-five to sixty-four in 1979, has by far the lowest estimated rates for recipiency among the four cohorts. The estimates for receipt of pension benefits for that cohort may be somewhat below the actual rates. By 1979, a substantial number of people in the cohort would have already retired. Some of them would have been covered under a definedcontribution plan and would have received a substantial cash distribution prior to the beginning of the simulation period. As chapter II discussed at length, such cash distributions do not get recorded on surveys such as the Current Population Survey, which served to define the baseline population for the simulations conducted here. In subsequent cohorts, asset accumulations under defined-contribution plans are converted to a level life annuity, in nominal dollars, at retirement. The benefit recipiency rates are projected to increase fairly rapidly between the oldest and second oldest cohorts attaining age sixty-five. Beyond the retirement of the second cohort these rates continue to grow steadily but slowly, especially between the retirement periods of the third and the youngest cohorts. For workers aged twenty-five to thirty-four, between two-thirds and three-fourths of the family units were projected to be eligible for a pension by the time they reach age sixty-five. Because there is a fairly direct linkage between the growth in wages and individual pension entitlements, the average family pension benefits in 1982 dollars are estimated to rise steadily over time. For defined-benefit plans that base benefits on years of service and final TABLE III-I 1 Age in 1979 and Estimated Percentages of Families to Receive Pension Benefits at Age 65, and Average Benefits in 1982 Dollars, by Marital Status All Families Cohort Percentage Average Age in to Receive Amount of 1979 Benefit Benefit Married Couples Single Persons Percentage Average to Receive Amount of Benefit Benefit Percentage Average to Receive Amount of Benefit Benefit 25-34 71 $12,417 35-44 65 11,190 45-54 52 8,656 55-64 37 5,315 Source: Tabulations of PRISM current 90 75 $14,541 65 67 12,563 60 58 9,621 41 44 5,548 26 policy simulation results. $8,701 8,823 6,496 4,718 average salary, the effect of growing wages is direct. In unit-benefit plans, especially prevalent in union-negotiated pensions, increases in benefit levels are generally negotiated in accordance with negotiated wage levels. In defined-contribution plans there is also a direct link between the annual contribution (and, therefore, total retirement asset accumulation) and wages. In each instance, the assumed growth in future average wage levels portends substantial growth in pension benefits for successive cohorts of retirees. The results of these simulations run counter to the conventional wisdom that often influences the development of retirement policy in general or pension policy in particular. For example, Alicia Munnell, a Vice-President at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, concludes: Because of the influence of industrv structure on pension coverage, the percentage of the work force covered by pension plans is not expected to increase significantly in the future. Industries with traditionally high pension coverage, such as manufacturing, are expected to employ a declining share of workers, while employment in industries with low pension coverage, such as retail trade is projected to increase. Moreover, small businesses, which employ the bulk of noncovered workers are unlikely to adopt pension plans. 7 Setting aside the question of future growth in pension coverage for the moment, a basic question is whether the current prevalence of pensions will mean higher, lower, or constant rates of receipt of benefits in the future. The analysis of Social Security in chapter I, referring to figure I-2, showed that rates of receipt of benefits for elderly people under Social Security did not approach rates of coverage of workers until thirty-five years after the program began paying benefits. The analysis of active participants in pension plans relative to beneficiaries in chapter II showed a clear pattern of increased recipiency rates for defined-benefit plans as they matured. The analysis in chapter II also showed that most pension plans in this countrv are relatively young, so even if there is no future growth in pension coverage, the maturing of existing plans can be expected to result in higher rates of receipt of pension benefits in the future. This conclusion is consistent with that of analyses that assume no future growth implications in pension coverage. In the simulation work evaluating the of a mandato_ pension system proposed by President 7Alicia H. Munnell, The Economics ofPrivate Pensio_ls(Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1982). p. 200. 91 Carter's Commission on Pension Policy, there were explicit assumptions that there would be no future growth of pension programs. 8 Yet under these assumptions, the commission estimated that the proportion of workers aged twentv-five to twenty-nine in 1979 who would receive pension benefits at age sixty-five would be 80 percent for married couples and 66 percent for single persons. _ More than half the wage and salary workers aged fifty-five to sixtyfour in 1979 working at least half time on a regular basis had already acquired a vested right to a pension on their current jobs. More than two-thirds were participating in a plan. Richard Ippolito, Assistant Administrator for Policy, Planning, and Research at the Department of Labor, estimates that at least two-thirds of the current full-time private-sector work force will retire with a pension. Based on a study in which the Department of Labor examined the administrative records from a sample of private pension plans, the average annual benefit of retirees during 1978 was $6,100 in 1982 dollars. I° In comparison with other estimates, the simulation results presented here are not out of line and may be relatively conservative. Analysts like Munnell may be correct in their predictions that pension coverage will not grow in the future, but such predictions either ignore both long-term and short-term trends (discussed in chapter II of this report) or assume that current incentives to establish and maintain plans will be eliminated. Moreover, even if coverage should not continue to grow, the future rates of receipt of pension benefits will be higher than current rates. Individual Retirement Savings--The 1981 Economic Recovery Tax Act greatly expanded the potential of individual retirement accounts by making them available to workers already covered by a pension. Table III-12 presents the simulated IRA benefit recipiency rates and average annuities purchasable by the accumulations at retirement. The estimated recipiency rate for persons aged fifty-five to sixtyfour in 1979 is by far the lowest of the rates for the four cohorts. It should be kept in mind that by the end of 1982, the first year of expanded availability of IRAs, nearly one-third of that cohort will be age sixty-five and nearly 80 percent will be above age sixty. Many _For a discussion o[ these assumptions, see Svlvester J. Schieber, "Trends in Pension Coverage and Benefit Receipt," The Gercmtolo_ist,vol. 22, no. 6 (December 1982). _President's Commission on Pension Policy, Comin_ o/ A_e: Toward a National Retirement Income Policy Appendix (Washington, D.C., 1981),chapter- 36, p. 1541. "_Richard A. lppolito, "Public Policy Towards Private Pensions," presented at Western Economic Association Annual Meeiings, Los Angeles, Calit., July 19, 1982. 92 TABLE III-12 Age in 1979 and Estimated Percentages of Families to Receive IRA Benefits at Age 65, andAverage Family Benefits in 1982 Dollars, by Marital Status All Families Cohort Age in 1979 25-34 35-44 45-54 55-64 Married Couples Single Persons Percentage to Receive Benefit Average Amount of Benefit Percentage to Receive Benefit Average Amount of Benefit 62 62 55 24 $2,615 2,696 1,686 768 68 64 59 27 $2,960 2,939 1,863 851 52 59 48 19 policy simulation results. Source: EBR1 tabulations of PRISM current people in this will cohort have already retired Percentage Average to Receive Amount of Benefit Benefit under $ 1,939 2,291 ! ,344 585 the earlier lim- ited IRA availability. Nearly 70 percent of the regular wage and salary workers in this cohort prior to 1982 were automatically excluded from IRA participation. The estimated rate of receipt for people aged forty-five to fifty-four in 1979 is more than twice that for the oldest group, largely because of the extended exposure to the IRA tax deductions during the longer working life under the new policy. The trend continues, to some degree, with more than 60 percent of families in the group of people aged thirty-five to forty-four in 1979 estimated to receive IRA support when they reach age sixty-five. The growth in estimated average annual benefits among the oldest three cohorts is a direct result of the period of workers' careers under the IRA provisions in ERTA. The estimated recipiency rate for single persons in the youngest cohort is slightly lower than the rate of the preceding cohort for two reasons. The first is related to the size of the cohort and projected real wage growth. The macroeconomic-demographic model constrains the aggregate wage growth of this cohort below average wage growth of the total work force. The group of people twentv-five to thirtv-four years old in 1979 included most of the baby-boom generation. Because this particular cohort is so much larger than the preceding or succeeding cohorts, competition for jobs within this group will suppress the overall wage levels for these people throughout their careers. Since the IRA participation estimates are a function of wages, this phenomenon will dampen the IRA participation rates for the cohort. The second reason that the IRA recipiency rates do not grow is related to the projected continuing trend toward earlier 93 retirements. Earlier withdrawal from the work force reduces the period of exposure for picking up an IRA. The early retirement phenomenon also affects the estimated level of IRA benefits in two ways. First, a shorter period of earnings will mean fewer years of contributions to the IRA; fewer years of contributions mean smaller accumulations with which a retirement annuity can be purchased. Second, and more important, the IRA is converted to an annuity at the earliest year of eligibility after acceptance of pension or upon acceptance of Social Security. The annual annuity's value is adjusted on an actuarial basis, depending on the age at which it is accepted. Therefore, the earlier the retirement, the lower the annual benefit. Furthermore, the annuities are paid in level nominal dollars over the retiree's lifetime, while average benefits at age sixty-five are estimated in constant 1982 dollars. Therefore, the earlier the retirement, the more the benefit level is eroded by the assumed long-term 4 percent rate of inflation. There is little evidence yet available on which to base long-term IRA utilization rates. The assumptions used to simulate the benefits estimated here may be conservative. The newly eligible population in 1982 was assumed to open accounts in the first year at rates equal to those reported by the old eligibles during 1979 on a comparable age and family-income basis. The rationale for using the 1979 IRA participation among the newly eligible population was that these people were already participating in an employer pension program. Some analysts argue that, other things being equal, participation in a pension reduces the need for individual retirement savings; therefore, the newly eligibles will be less likely to establish IRAs than similar people were under the old provisions. There is another school of thought that argues that the expanded availability of IRAs will increase participation rates in all income and age classes. People who are participating in a pension have higher incomes, on average, than those not participating and thus are more likely to save. The Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 reduced the price of savings to pension participants by expanding IRA availability. Therefore, it is likely that increased savings will result. This conclusion is also based on the assumption that there will be a strong "information" effect on IRA participation rates. The broad expansion of IRA availability has raised the general level of knowledge that these vehicles exist, primarily through the increased marketing efforts of financial intermediaries. The prospect of long-term savings of $20 billion or more a year has led to a variety of investment opportunities for individual savers, and savings institutions are widely 94 advertising these opportunities. The competition for these savings is providing a broad level of understanding of the IRA option and encouraging many people to participate. A survey conducted for the Life Insurance Marketing and Research Association (LIMRA) in April 1982 found that 89 percent of eligible households knew of the change in IRA provisions in ERTA. This knowledge was found to be equally prevalent among all age groups except those under age twenty-five. Their survey results showed a strong correlation between age and family income and the intent to establish an IRA in 1982. II The results of the LIMRA survey suggest that IRA participation and contribution rates will be higher than the rates used in the base case simulations presented here. An alternative simulation was conducted to test the effect of these higher rates on the potential of IRAs to provide retirement income. That sensitivitv test provided significantly higher estimates of the number of people contributing to an IRA over their working careers. Among members of the oldest cohort in the simulation, 43 percent were estimated to receive an IRA annuity, in comparison with the base case simulation result of 24 percent. Because the alternative assumptions captured somewhat more low-income workers and because the pattern of contributions was more irregular, the average family IRA annuity at age sixtv-five was $535 under the modified assumptions, in comparison with $768 under the base simulation. For the youngest cohort, the base case simulation resulted in 62 percent of the families receiving an average IRA annuity of $2,615 in 1982 dollars, at age sixty-five. The alternative assumptions not only raised the proportion receiving an IRA to 93.5 percent, but also raised average annuities to $3,325. These results suggest that the somewhat higher participation rates that may result from expansion of the program could make this retirement savings program a particularly effective income supplement for the elderly in the future. Although the alternative assumptions result in much higher utilization rates and higher benefit levels over the long term, we decided to use the more conservative assumptions and results throughout the analysis of various policy scenarios. Relationship ofPensions and IRAs--When policymakers originally established the IRA program in 1974, one of their critical concerns was that some workers would never acquire a pension. For highly iiLife Insurance Marketing and Research Association, The Public's Response to IRA (Hartford, Conn.: LIMRA, 1982). 95 mobile workers and workers not covered by a pension plan for part or all of their careers, the IRA was to be a substitute vehicle through which these workers could make individual provisions for their retirement. With the passage of ERTA in 1981, the IRA program was expanded to complement pension participation. The extent to which pensions and IRAs overlap to provide retirement protection is important. Table III-13 shows the estimated percentage of families to receive benefits and average benefit levels when IRAs and pensions are considered together. The table shows that estimated receipt and average benefit levels are expected to rise consistently over the next four decades. By the time the people now aged twenty-five to thirtyfour retire 80 to 90 percent of them could be eligible for regular retirement benefits other than Social Security. The benefits provided by these programs are estimated to be comparable in size to the benefits provided by Social Security. How are these benefits to be distributed? The average level of benefits could be quite high but the distributions could be highly skewed. Table III-14 shows the estimated rates of receipt of IRA or pension benefits in comparison with the average salary for the highest five out of ten years prior to the reference person in the family turning age sixty-five. The estimated recipiency rates show significant increases at the intermediate income levels, especially among the two younger cohorts. The significant rates among the lowest income class across all four cohorts are the result of early retirements. People who retire in their mid-fifties--and early retirement is increasingly corn- TABLE III-13 Age in 1979 and Estimated Percentages of Families to Receive Benefits from IRAs and Pensions Combined at Age 65, and Average Benefit Levels in 1982 Dollars, by Marital Status All Families Cohort Age in 1979 Percentage to Receive Benefit 25-34 35-44 45-54 55-64 87 83 70 49 Source: Tabulation 96 Married Average Amount of Benefit Percentage to Receive Benefit $11,976 10,694 7,692 4,424 of PRISM current 91 86 75 56 policy Couples Single Average Amount of Benefit Percentage to Receive Benefit $14,220 12,078 8,878 4,847 simulation 82 79 61 38 results. Persons Average Amount of Benefit $8,185 8,393 5,393 3,501 TABLE III-14 Age in 1979 and Estimated Percentages of Families Receive an IRA or Pension Benefit, by "High-Five" Average Family Earnings in Ten Years Prior to Age to 65 Average Family Earnings During "High Five" Years Less than $10,000 $10,000-$19,999 $20,000-$29,999 $30,000-$39,999 $40,000 or more Percentage to Receive a Benefit by Cohort Age in 1979 25 to 34 35 to 44 45 to 54 55 to 64 72 83 89 86 94 68 74 81 87 94 46 67 72 73 92 29 41 50 59 68 Source: Tabulation of PRISM current policy simulation results. mon and projected to become more so--would have very low or zero average earnings over the period considered. Table III-15 compares estimated average Social Security benefits with pension and IRA benefits for the various age cohorts to the average earnings in their average "high-five" years. Social Security benefits are clearly larger than pension benefits for each of the lower income classes. The differences tend to decline and even reverse at the higher preretirement income levels. For most of the income classes, Social Security and pension benefits consistently rise with each successive cohort. For the income classes with average earnings at $15,000 and above, the growth in average pension benefits considerably outpaces Social Security. These results suggest that pensions and individual retirement provisions will play an increasingly important role in providing retirement income security to future generations of the elderly. Supplemental Security Income--The discussion in chapter II indicated that the number of persons qualifying for SSI after age sixtyfive has been declining since the program started in 1974. While the number of blind and disabled SSI recipients reaching age sixty-five largely offsets this decline in SSI statistics, there have been real declines in total elderly SSI recipients during the past couple of years. The likelihood of continued labor-force participation by women at current levels or higher and the prospects for future wage growth suggest that work-related retirement programs will diminish the rate of SSI recipiency in the future. 97 I_ "_ ..,, 98 o_I r_ r-,_ o0 tno-, "_ _n ,_ _- _ ¢_,)- _,=_. =°°o°o° The simulation of the SSI program suggests that the rates of receipt will decline over time. The average benefit rates are not estimated to rise significantly over time, which is not surprising. The program guarantees are now tied to the CPI and will stay constant in real dollars. A word of caution is in order in interpreting these results, however. The random process used to simulate these results will cause some variance from one simulation to the next. When dealing with high rates of recipiency for a program like Social Security, this random variance will be small in relative terms. When dealing with low recipiency estimates, as in the case of SSI, this random variance can be significant. A separate simulation with identical assumptions might estimate significantly higher recipiency rates than those for the younger two cohorts shown in table III-16. Projected Income Levels [or the Elderly--The previous section of this chapter provided estimates of recipiency and average income levels from various sources of retirement income. This section pulls these various income sources together to estimate combined income levels. It should be kept in mind that these estimates include only earnings, Social Security, pensions, IRAs, and SSI. Some people may have substantial property, asset, and in-kind income in addition to the sources considered here. Retirement Program Income Levels--Table III-17 shows the average family incomes provided by the selected sources considered here. The estimates are made during the year in the simulation in which the person being referred to turns sixty-five. The results show a consistent pattern of higher income levels for both married couples and single TABLE III-16 Age in 1979 and Estimated Percentages of Families to Receive SSI Benefits at Age 65 and Average Benefit Levels in 1982 Dollars, by Marital Status Cohort Age in 1979 All Families Percentage Average to Receive Amount of Benefit Benefit Married Couples Percentage Average to Receive Amount of Benefit Benefit 25-34 1.2 $5,527 35-44 1.0 2,552 45-54 3.9 2,959 55-64 5.9 3,237 Source: Tabulation of PRISM current Single Persons Percentage Average to Receive Amount of Benefit Benefit 1.3 $3,739 1.0 3,289 1.5 3,432 3.6 3,065 policy simulation results. 1.1 1.1 7.8 9.2 $3,133 1,564 2,817 3,337 99 TABLE III-17 Age in 1979 and Estimated Annual Family Income Levels from Selected Sources a in 1982 Dollars at Age 65, by Marital Status Age in 1979 All Families Married Couples 25-34 $26,802 $34,088 35-44 23,883 29,709 45-54 17,579 22,469 55-64 13,376 17,347 Source: Tabulation of PRISM current policy simulation results. _Estimates include earnings, Social Security, pensions, [RAs and SSI. Single Persons $ 15,697 i 4,921 9,846 7,127 persons. In the case oR single persons, the average income levels are estimated to more than double from the oldest to the youngest cohort. For married couples, average income levels are estimated to approximately double on this basis. Replacement of Earnings by Retirement Programs--The level of income is an important measure of standard of living for each of the cohorts over time. It does not provide a perspective on the relative standards of living that exist at various points in time, however. Workers aged twenty-five to thirty-four in 1979 should have much higher real earnings immediately prior to their retirement than people over age fifty-five. The relative effectiveness of the retirement system over time can be judged by its capacity to maintain preretirement standards of living. In order to estimate the capacity of pensions, IRAs, and Social Security to maintain living standards, a set of replacement rates were calculated. These calculations based the estimates on the average earnings for the highest five years out of the ten years prior to attaining age sixty-five. Retirement benefits were the aggregate of pension and IRA benefits estimated at age sixty-five plus the estimated Social Security entitlement prior to application of the earnings test. The replacement rates are based on income after taxes. Table III-18 shows the distribution of the estimated net replacement rates. The trend is clearly toward higher replacement rates for each successive cohort. Only 13 percent of families in the oldest cohort have replacement rates above 80 percent, while more than 46 percent of the youngest cohort have rates above this level. Although pensions and IRAs contribute to this significant growth, part of it is also attributable to the tax estimates on earnings and retirement income. The tax brackets were indexed on the basis of the assumed rate of 100 i TABLE III-18 Estimated Net Retirement Program Replacement Rates for Average High-Five Years of Family Earnings in the Ten Years Prior to Age 65 Replacement Less than 25% Rates 25-49% 50-59% 60-79% 80-99% More Than 100% 5.1 7.0 0.7 17.6 18.5 15.5 10.2 10.3 10.0 20.8 20.8 20.8 16.8 16.7 17.0 29.4 26.7 36.1 35 to 44 All Families Married Couples Single Persons 5.2 6.8 1.5 24.1 26.4 18.7 10.0 10.4 9.2 21.5 22.0 20.2 16.5 16.6 16.2 22.7 17.9 34.1 45 to 54 All Families Married Couples Single Persons 9.3 10.6 6.0 33.8 36.3 27.4 11.2 ! 1.1 I 1.5 19.6 19.2 20.6 12.4 12.7 11.7 13.7 10.0 22.8 55 to 64 All Families Married Couples Single Persons 21.0 21.8 18.8 40.8 38.5 47.2 11.6 1 ! .7 I 1.3 13.5 16.1 6.5 6.5 6.9 5.6 6.5 5.0 10.7 Cohort Age in 1979 25 to 34 All Families Married Couples Single Persons Source: Note: Tabulation of PRISM current policy simulation Includes pensions, IRAs, and Social Security. price increases. Because the assumed real wage wages growth results. are assumed to grow faster in the simulation gradually both marginal and average tax rates. Since Social Security are not taxable, they will replace an increasing proportion tax earnings over time. Table III-19 shows estimated median replacement rates earnings successive for each cohort, the earnings ment earnings absolute and of the cohorts for the "high-five" the median replacement rates categories. This suggests that retirees levels can expect to be considerably relative terms in the future. The complicated process by which these estimates give rise to a certain amount of skepticism. pensions will be more widely available in the not central to the results of these simulations. recipiency rates are not out of line with years. increase than prices, increases benefits of afterof family With each in each of at all preretirebetter off in both were made may The assumption that future is important but The estimated pension the estimates made by others 101 TABLE III-19 Estimated Re,_lacement,,Rates for Median Families for High-Five Years of Family the Ten Years Prior to Age 65, by Age Average Family Earnings During "High-Five" Years 55-64 (Percent) Earnings Earnings in 1979 CohortAge in 1979 45-54 35-44 (Percent) (Percent) of in 25-34 (Percent) Less than $5,000 100 + 100 + 100 + $5,000-$9,999 49 80 96 $10,000-$ ! 4,999 49 62 74 $15,000-$19,999 54 57 71 $20,000-$29,999 44 56 74 $30,000-$39,999 38 47 74 $40,000 or more 31 53 62 Source: Tabulation of PRISM current policy simulation rcsuhs. 100 + 99 78 76 82 81 67 using different methodologies or assumptions. The estimates of future IRA utilization are also important but appear reasonable within the limited information now available. The sheer magnitude of annual pension and IRA contributions has to lead to the intuitive conclusion that these programs are growing in importance. The simulation results presented here support this conclusion and vice versa. To ignore the conclusion that other programs than Social Security will play a significant role in providing retirement income security in the future will preclude certain policy options, narrow others, and possibly dictate yet other options that make little sense in a broader perspective. Implications of the The distribution Results and level of benefits estimated here would seem to indicate that there may be some flexibility for dealing with the long-term Social Security financing problems discussed in chapter IV. In the short term there is considerably less flexibility. An inescapable conclusion of the simulation results is that Social Security is the cornerstone of the retirement system in this country. If the long-term viability of Social Security cannot be assured, significant alternatives have to be devised, and it is unlikely that such alternatives can be developed and implemented in the near future. Therefore, it is imperative that the current system be made solvent in the short term and confidence restored, so that the system will be there for today's young workers when they retire. 102 IV. Social Security Problems Almost everyone today is aware Financing that the Social Security program is experiencing financing problems. There may be differences of opinion about the extent of the problems and about potential solutions, but there is undisputed Social Security Trustees way: agreement that problems exist. The Report summarizes the main problem 1982 this As in last year's trustees reports, the 1982 annual reports indicate severe financial problems for the Social Security program in both the short range and the long range. The short range financial status is significantly worse than estimated last year, because of continuing unfavorable economic conditions. The long range deficit for OASDI remains about the same as that projected last year. Under present law, which provides for temporary interfund borrowing, the Old Age and Survivors fund would not be able to pay benefits on time bv Julv 1983. Based on the intermediate II-A assumptions .... the long range average deficit for OASDI over the next 75 vears is estimated to be 0.82 percent of taxable payroll. Based on the II-B assumptions, which reflect somewhat lower economic growth than in II-A, the long range deficit remains the same as in last vear's report--l.82 percent of payroll. Even if the OASI, DI, and HI Trust they would fall short in 1984 under Measurement of Social Security's Funds were combined, the II-B assumptions? Financing Status It is common to see press accounts or other analyses that refer to trillions of dollars of unfunded Social Security liabilities. One measure of these unfunded liabilities is calculated on what actuaries call a "closed group" a specified date, basis. The closed no new workers group concept will contribute assumes that as of to or be covered ISummarv of the 1982 A_tnual Reports o]the Social Security Boards ofTrustees, Executive Summa_' (Washington, D.C.: Social Security Administration and Health Care Financing Administration, 1982), pp. i-iii. 103 under the existing system. For example, it is often assumed that workers under nineteen years of age on the date for which the estimate is made will no longer be covered under Social Security. This closedgroup estimate shows the extent to which the system is underfunded for persons now in the system. Robert liabilities Myers has calculated presented on this estimates of unfunded basis; table IV-I shows Social Security these estimates for the 1971-1981 period. The unfunded liabilities, presented table as the net deficit for the closed group, are calculated present value of future benefit payments (outgo) minus the value of future taxes and the trust fund balance. The annual figures indicate how much would have efits to the closed group under the law date. The changes in unfunded and flow of Social Securitv liabilities during TABLE in the as the present deficit been required to pay off benthat applied on the valuation over the the period. 1970s reflect the ebb The quadrupling of |V-I Actuarial Status of OASDI on "Closed Group" and "Open Group, Limited Period" Base, 1971-1980 Year a 1971 1972 _ 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 (pro-1977 1977 (post-1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 Sources: act) act) Valuation Interest Rate (Percent) Existing Trust Fund (Billions) 5.25 6.00 6.00 6.00 7.38 6.60 6.60 6.60 6.60 6.60 6.08 6.08 $41 44 44 46 48 46 40 40 35 33 32 27 Net Deficit b Closed Group (Billions) $ 433 1,865 2,118 2,460 2,710 4,148 5,362 3,456 3,971 4,225 5,601 5,858 Open Group (Billions) $ 8 - 140 176 1,312 2, l O0 4,177 4,787 786 929 847 1,464 1,555 Robert J. Myers, Social Security, 2nd ed. (Homcwood, I11.:Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1981) pp. 274, 303; and Office of the Actuary, Social Security Administration. _'Asol June 30 ['or 1971-1975, and September 30 lot 1976-1979. I'Exccss of' present value of future outgo over the sum of present value of luture taxes and existing trust fund. "Includes the effect of the 20 percent benetit increase enacted on July 1, 1972 (effective for September 1972). 104 the unfunded liabilities in 1972 reflects in part the effects of the 1972 amendments, including the 20 percent increase in benefits; but even more, that jump reflects a basic change in thc method of valuing future benefits using assumptions that wages and prices would grow in the future. Prior to 1972 the valuation procedures used static economic assumptions for these two crucial variables. The unfunded liabilities continued to rise between 1972 and 1975 because of a combination of benefit increases tions. The 1977 amendments and changes to the actuarial reduced the estimated Social assumpSecurity unfunded liability by more than one-third. Adverse economic conditions, resulting changes to valuation assumptions, and redefinition of the closed group to include persons over age fifteen combined to produce estimated Social Security unfunded liabilities of $5.6 trillion by the end of fiscal 1980. 2 The concept of unfunded liabilities on this closed-group basis in a pay-as-you-go program that is nearly universal is not particularly significant unless a policy decision is made to close the program out. If that were to be done, then those liabilities would have to be paid off to meet benefit payments as they came due for the closed group. A more realistic way to look at Social Security's financing--based on the assumptions that the program will continue to operate in the future and that new workers will continue to be covered--is to compare the value of projected future expenditures with projected tax revenues. The long-term unfunded liabilities, when calculated in this way, are estimated for a limited period by Social Security's actuaries. Table IV-I shows the Old-Age, Survivors and Disability Insurance estimates for the seventy-five-year valuation period in the "open group" column. The annual numbers show the extent to which future tax collections plus the trust balance fall short of future outgo on the date of the valuation, for the seventy-five-year projection period. At the beginning of the 1970s, the unfunded liabilities, on an opengroup basis, were negligible; they represented less than 1 percent of the present value of projected seventv-five-vear tax collections. The projected deficit started growing rapidly after 1973 and bv early 1977 represented a 70 percent shortfall in scheduled taxes over the valuation period. The 1977 Social Security amendments made significant adjustments to both the tax collection and benefit schedules and reduced the open-group net deficit by 84 percent, but the OASDI program was still underfunded by nearly 10 percent for the seventy-'Robert J. Myers, Social Security, 2nd ed. (Homewood, i11.:Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1981), discusses these changes at greater length on pp. 273-275. 105 five-year valuation period. Since 1977 the situation has deteriorated on the basis of the open-group net deficit projections. The net deficits on either the closed- or open-group basis become worse if the Hospital Insurance program is added to the picture. Although actuaries from the Health Care Financing Administration develop estimates for the seventy-five-year period, they publish only twenty-five-year projections. On the basis of the twenty-five-year projections, the HI program is running an open-group net deficit of about 70 percent of scheduled taxes. On the seventy-five-year projection, the HI deficit exceeds the projected OASDI deficits. The fact that there are unfunded future promises on a closed-group basis does not necessarily mean Social Security is inadequately financed. But the open-group projections do suggest that in the long term, the program is out of balance. These projections, however, aggregate the long-term characteristics of each or all of the programs into a single number that fails to capture the dynamics of the projections or the nature of the problem. An alternative concept for evaluating the financial soundness of the Social Security system was stated some years ago by George B. Buck, a Fellow in the Society of Actuaries, and founder of one of the largest actuarial consulting firms in this country. He described a properly financed system as: One which sets forth a plan of benefits and contributions to provide these benefits, so related that the amount of the present and contingent liabilities of the plan as actuarially computed as of any date will at least be balanced by the amount of the present and contingent assets of the plan computed as of the same date. 3 It is in this context that Social Security now faces "severe financial problems" in both the short and long terms. The short-term financing crisis and the potential long-term financing problem can be considered separately because the problems are different in the two time frames. The Short-Term Problem--Table IV-2 shows the actual and projected financial operations of the OASI trust fund for selected years. The table shows steadily increasing balances in the trust fund through 3GeorgeB. Buck, "Actuarial Soundness in Trusteed and Government Retirement Plans," in Proceedings of a Panel Meeting; "What is Actuarial Soundness in a Pension Plan?" sponsored jointly by the American Statistical Association, the American Economic Association, the American Association of University Teachers of Insurance, and the Industrial Relations Research Association, Chicago, Ill., December 29, 1952. 106 TABLE Operations Calendar Operations the Calendar Year 1940 1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 IV-2 of the OASI Trust Fund During Selected Years 1940-1981 and Estimated Future During Calendar Years 1982-1986 Under Intermediate Sets of Assumptions Income Total (Millions) $ 368 1,420 2,928 6,167 11,382 16,610 32,220 59,605 66,276 72,412 78,094 90,274 105,841 125,361 Disbursements Total (Millions) $ 62 304 1,022 5,079 11,198 17,501 29,848 60,395 67,876 75,309 83,064 93,133 107,678 126,695 _ Net Increase in Fund (Millions) $ - Fund at End of Period (Millions) 306 1,116 1,905 1,087 184 890 2,371 790 1,600 2,897 4,971 2,860 1,837 1,334 $ 2,031 7,121 13,721 21,663 20,324 18,235 32,454 36,987 35,388 32,491 27,520 24,660 22,824 21,490 Projectional: Alternative II-A: 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 $135,956 b 139,130 149,173 167,606 182,173 $141,770 155,637 169,272 182,573 196,104 $- Alternative II-B: 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 $137,083' 137,005 149,144 167,147 180,669 $141,771 156,392 173,183 191,059 208,524 $- 5,814 16,507 20,099 14,967 13,931 $ 15,676 831 -20,930 35,897 4,688 - 19,386 -24,039 -23,913 -27,855 $ 16,802 - 2,584 -26,623 -50,536 -78,391 1982 Anm_al OASD[ Trustees Report, p. 51. _Adjusted to include benefits for December 1981 that were paid on December 31, 1981, than on January 3, 1982, which was a Sunday. These benefits are included in 1982 figure so that amounts for 1981 and 1982 each reflect 12 months of benefit payments and are comparable to figures for their calendar years. _'Includes $7.036 billion assumed to be borrowed from the DI and HI trust funds under interfund borrowing provisions. _lncludes $11.060 billion assumed to be borrowed from the DI and HI trust funds under interfund borrowing provisions. 107 the 1950s. For a period during the 1960s, the fund's income was less than annual disbursements, but increases in the payroll tax and wage base arid generally good economic conditions resulted in trust fund growth of more than $14 billion between 1965 and 1970. In 1975 the trust fund balance began to decline and it has been declining steadily since then. Until recent years the fund balances were sufficiently large that a financing deficit in any one year was cause for adjustments, not for alarm. Even though the trust fund declined by nearlv $900 million in 1965, the balance at the end of the year still exceeded that year's total disbursements. The program's financing was adjusted during the 1960s, and at the end of 1970 the trust fund still exceeded the total disbursements for the year. The ability to make gradual adjustments today has been greatly reduced. Not only has the trust fund been declining but disbursements have been growing rapidly. For example, between 1965 and 1970, annual disbursements grew by $12.3 billion; in contrast, 1981 disbursements were $19.0 billion higher than those in 1980 and the trust fund balance was down to a two-month cushion. Under projections using the two intermediate sets of assumptions posited by the Social Security Board of Trustees (known as Alternatives II-A and II-B), the OASI trust fund will be totally depleted in 1983. The very earliest that Congress will seriously consider Social Security legislation is early 1983. Yet, it is widely agreed that under current law, the OASI fund will be unable to meet the July 1983 payment on schedule. Never before has the OASI program been pushed so close to the financial brink. The Disability Insurance program is somewhat more sound than its Old-Age and Survivors counterpart. Table IV-3 shows the actual and projected financial operations of the DI trust fund for selected years. Although the program has experienced periodic financing deficits, it has been regularly adjusted to keep it actuarially sound. Current Social Security legislation allows the OASI trust fund to borrow from the healthier DI fund through the end of 1982. In fact, the legislation allows OASI to borrow on the basis of projected operations for up to six months in the future, so although the borrowing window closes at the end of 1982, the trust fund transfers can get OASI through its first six months of operations in 1983. Even if the borrowing limit is extended, the OASI shortfall in 1984, under both sets of intermediate assumptions will exceed the projected DI trust fund balances. Assuming that the borrowing window is effectively closed, the DI program is projected to be financially solvent over the short term. 108 TABLE IV-3 Operations of the DI Trust Calendar Years 1960-1981 Operations During Calendar the Intermediate Sets Calendar Year 1960 1965 1970 1975 1976 1977 1978 ! 979 1980 1981 Income Total (Millions) Fund During Selected and Estimated Future Years 1982-1986 Under of Assumptions Disbursements Total (Millions) $ 1,063 1,247 4,774 8,035 8,757 9,570 13,810 15,590 13,871 17,078 $ Aher_lative II-A: 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 $17,020 _ 26,624 29,723 37,929 42,926 Alternative II-B: 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 $17,010 b 26,124 29,496 37,329 41,799 600 1,687 3,259 8,790 10,366 11,945 12,954 14,186 15,872 17,658 Net Increase in Fund (Millions) $ Fund at End of Period (Millions) 464 440 1,514 754 1,609 2,375 856 1,404 2,001 580 $2,289 1,606 5,614 7,354 5,745 3,370 4,226 5,630 3,629 3,049 $18,517 18,996 19,670 20,573 21,639 $ -1,497 7,627 10,053 17,356 21,287 $ 1,552 9,180 19,232 36,588 57,875 $18,508 19,073 20,099 21,459 22,864 $ $ 1,551 8,602 17,999 33,869 52,804 - - Projections: 1,498 7,051 9,397 15,870 18,935 1982 Ammal OASD1 Trustees Report, p. 54. $6.257 billion assumed to be loaned to the OASI trust fund under the inborrowing provisions. bExcludes $5.747 billion assumed to be loaned to the OASI trust fund under the inborrowing provisions. "Excludes third major trust fund in the Social Security family is the Hospital Insurance fund. The experience of the HI program has also more positive, to date, than has that of the OASI component. IV-4 shows the actual and projected operations of the health 109 program since its inception. Hospital Insurance trust three minor exceptions. sharply in the coming years costs. Until 1982 the annual income of fund regularly exceeded disbursements Disbursements are projected to increase because of persistent inflation in health TABLE IV-4 Operations of the Hospital Insurance Trust During Calendar Years, 1966-1984 Disbursement Total (Millions) Net Increase in Fund (Millions) Fund Calendar Year Income Total (Millions) Fund at End of Year (Millions) 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 ! 971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 $ 1,943 3,559 5,287 5,279 5,979 5,732 6,403 10,821 12,024 12,980 13,766 15,856 19,213 22,825 26,097 35,725 $ 999 3,430 4,277 4,857 5,281 5,900 6,503 7,289 9,372 11,581 13,679 16,019 18,178 21,073 25,577 30,726 $ 944 129 ! ,010 422 698 168 99 3,532 2,652 !,399 88 - 163 1,035 1,75 ! 52 i 4,999 Altenlative II-A: 1982 1983 1984 $38,139 _ 42,824 46,239 $35,670 41,055 46,608 $ 2,469 1,769 369 $21,217 22,986 22,617 Alternative II-B: 1982 1983 1984 $32,79T' 42,237 46, !45 $35,670 41,622 48,272 $ - 2,873 615 - 2,127 $15,875 16,490 14,363 $ 944 1,073 2,083 2,505 3,202 3,034 2,935 6,467 9,119 10,517 10,605 10,442 11,477 ! 3,228 13,749 18,748 Projections: 1982 HI Trustees Report, p. 29. income lot 1982 is reduced by the amounts assumed to be loaned on December by the HI trust fund under the interfund borrowing provisions. These amounts $779 million and $5.313 billion under alternatives II-A and I1-B, respectively. Current Social Security financing provisions also allow the OASI fund to borrow from the HI fund, but as with DI, these provisions expire at the end of 1982. According to the Social Security trustees, if the three funds were commingled beyond 1982, there would still be potential problems. If commingling were allowed, the combined program would barely be solvent through the 1980s under the Alternative [I-A assumptions; the demise would come in 1984 under the pessimistic assumptions used by the trustees. Actual economic experience can affect the short-term Social Security financing prospects. Table IV-5 provides the various economic assumptions used to generate the range of short-term financing estimates. The Trustees Report that was released April 1, 1982, reflects economic assumptions being used early in the year. Tracing the actual experience of the economy during 1982 can serve as an indicator of which set of projections may be more realistic. Measurement of that experience will not be available until sometime after the end of the year. Based on the level of economic activity early in 1982, the assumptions used in cost estimates in the Trustees Report can be assessed relative to later assumptions. The Reagan administration's mid-session review of the 1983 budget posited assumptions on the crucial economic variables that were much closer to the [[-B than the II-A scenario. Under these assumptions, the three trust funds combined would be insufficient to pay benefits on a timely basis through 1984. 4 Furthermore, the Congressional Budget Office has projected larger declines in real GNP and higher levels of unemployment than the administration's mid-session assumptions. 5 This all suggests that, at least t0r the short term, the more pessimistic midrange assumptions in the 1982 Trustees Report are the more realistic-and even they may prove to have been optimistic. The Long-Term Problem--The Social Security actuaries estimate the long-term cost of the programs as a percentage of total covered payroll. Comparison of the annual cost estimated in this fashion with the legislated tax rate indicates the adequacy of financing provisions for the system over the long term. Figure IV-I depicts the currently legislated OASDI tax rates in comparison to the long-term Social 4jeffrey L. Kunkel, "Estimated Operations o[ the OASI, DI, and H1 Trust Funds on the Basis of the 1982 Mid-Session Review Assumptions," Internal Memorandum, Office of the Actuary, Social Security Administration (August 5, 1982), p. 2. SCongressional Budget Office, The Economic and Budget Outlook: AH Update (Washington, D.C.: CBO, September 1982), p. 59. Ill TABLE IV-5 Economic Assumptions Used in the Projections for OASDI and HI in the 1982 Trustees Report Percentage Calendar Year OplimiMic 1982 1985 1995 2005 and Real GNIP_ of Average Annual Increase Over Previous Year Wages in Consumer Inpatient Covered PHce Hospital Employment Index Care Costs b Annual Unemployment Rate Assumptions: 8.2% 7.0 4.5 4.5 6.3% 4.2 2.0 2.0 16.5% 12.1 7.9 6.1 8.6% 5.8 4.0 4.0 Alternative II-A Assumptions:' 1982 0.3% 1985 4.8 1995 3.0 2005 and later 2.9 8.6% 7.4 5.0 5.0 6.8% 4.8 3.0 3.0 16.6% 13.1 9.1 8.4 8.9% 6.4 5.0 5.0 Alternative II-B Assumptio_ts: 1982 -0.8% 1985 3.0 1995 2.5 2005 and later 2.5 6.6% 6.9 5.5 5.5 6.9% 6.6 4.0 4.0 16.5% 13.7 10.0 9.3 9.1% 7.7 5.0 5.0 Pessimistic Assumplio_ts: 1982 - 1.5% 1985 3.8 1995 1.8 2005 and later 2.0 6.3% 9.2 6.2 6.0 7.2% 9.2 5.2 5.0 16.5% 18.3 13.3 11.4 9.3% 8.8 6.0 6.0 laler 1.1% 5.1 3.4 3.4 Source: 1982 OASDI Trustees Reports, Executive Summary, p. 22. _'Gross national product (the total output of goods and services) expressed in constant dollars. The percentage increase in real GNP is assumed to change after the year 2005. The values for the vear 2060 are 3.4, 2.5, 2.1, and 1.0 percent for the optimistic, Alternative [l-A, Alternative II-B, and pessimistic assumptions, respectively. Iqncludes hospital care costs for all patients, not just those covered under HI. Figures shown for "2005 and later" are tot 2005. _Alternative II-A uses the economic assumptions underlying the president's 1983 budget, adjusted to reflect the most recent data now available on wages and prices. Security cost projections under three alternative sets of assumptions. The combined employer-employee tax rate increases in steps from 10.8 percent of covered payroll in 1982 to 12.4 percent in 1990; the rate remains flat thereafter. The three cost projections are based on the Alternative II-A and II-B and the pessimistic assumptions presented in table IV-5. Cost lines below the tax line depict projected 112 FIGURE IV-I Legislated OASDI Payroll Tax Rate and Projected Rates Under Alternative Assumptions Cost Percent of Payroll 3O "_" 25 Legislated Tax Rate ...... II-A Assumptions ,,,,," -....... II-B Assumptions Pessimistic Assumptions s S J I 20 , I J .. •.,.."" js I I t I I j 15- eo eeeee°'e°°e°eee_°eeeeeeee° sj 6 • o• e" e• • 10" 1980 ee • • I 1990 ,e • 'leeee ! 2000 eoe °- oo I 2010 I 2020 I 2030 I 2040 I 2050 2060 Year Source: 1982 Ammal Report ol the Board olTrustees of the FederalOld-Ageand Survivors htsurattce and Disability Insurance Trust Fmtds (Washington, D.C,:Social Security Administration, 1982),pp. 67-68. surpluses for the program on a current-cost basis. Cost lines above the scheduled tax rate depict financing deficits. Under the II-A assumptions, the 1985 scheduled tax increase will move OASDI back into financing surpluses that will last until sometime between 2015 and 2020. Under the slightly more conservative II-B assumptions, the combined OASDI programs are projected to continue running deficits based on current law until the 1990 tax increase is implemented. Also under these latter assumptions, OASDI moves back into deficit financing between 2010 and 2015. Under the pessimistic assumptions, scheduled tax rates will not meet the OASDI costs at any time in the projection horizon. Over the next twenty-five years, the combined OASDI revenues are projected to exceed benefits by an average of 1.55 percent of covered 113 payroll under the II-A assumptions and by 0.64 percent under the IIB scenario. Under the pessimistic assumptions, revenues would fall short of meeting projected costs by an average of 0.62 percent of covered payroll. If recovery from the recession of 1982 is slow and drawn out throughout the 1980s, and if ultimate real wage growth falls somewhere between 1.0 and 1.5 percent per year, the actual experience of OASDI would be between the II-B and pessimistic scenarios. In that case, the first twenty-five year financing surplus would largely disappear. During the second twenty-five years of the projection period all three scenarios depicted in figure IV-! result in financing deficits substantially exceeding those now being experienced. Under both the II-A and II-B assumptions, the cost levels tend to stabilize around 2030. Under the pessimistic scenario, the situation continues to deteriorate over the whole seventy-five-year projection. Under all three scenarios, the short-term financing problem of OASDI discussed in the previous section of this chapter appears to be relatively minor compared with the long-term outlook. The picture is somewhat clouded by the financing prospects for the Hospital Insurance program. As indicated earlier the HI actuaries publish only twenty-five-year projections on the program. The rationale is that the health status of the population and the health care provisions change so significantly over time that estimates beyond this time frame are not meaningful. The HI cost projections for the 1982-2005 period based on the II-A and II-B assumptions are shown in table IV-6. While financing problems in OASDI can be separated into a current short-term problem and a long-term problem with a respite of fifteen to thirty years between, the HI financing problem bridges the gap. Under the II-A assumptions, the thirty-year OASDI financing surplus when combined with the HI deficit reduces the surplus years to less than fifteen. Under the II-B assumptions, the combined OASDHI programs will run a deficit in each of the next twenty-five years under current financing provisions. Under the pessimistic assumptions, the prospects become even more dismal. The consistent trend of increasing HI deficits added to projected OASDI deficits suggests that the second and third twenty-five-year periods would require payroll tax rates two to three times those now scheduled. Under a prolonged adverse economic scenario, the situation could be much worse. This prospect has led economists and Social Security analyst Michael Boskin to proclaim: "If we wait until the baby boom generation retires before we begin to deal with the 114 TABLE IV-6 Cost and Tax Rates of the Hospital Insurance Program, as a Percentage of Taxable Payroll Calendar Year Expenditures Under the Program a Trust Fond Total Cost Building and of the Maintenance b Program Tax Rate Scheduled in the Law c Difference Alter_zative II-A: 1982 2.60% _' 1983 2.68 1984 2.80 1985 2.94 1990 3.68 1995 4.59 2000 5.40 2005 6.18 0.09% 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.09 2.69% 2.77 2.89 3.03 3.77 4.68 5.49 6.27 2.60% 2.60 2.60 2.70 2.90 2.90 2.90 2.90 - 0.09% -0.17 - 0.29 - 0.33 - 0.87 - 1.78 - 2.59 - 3.37 Average d 4.40 0.09 4.49 2.86 - 1.63 2.98%" 2.75 2.90 3.06 3.93 5.00 6.01 7.03 0.10% 0. ! 0 0. I 0 0.10 0.10 0.10 0.10 0.10 3.08% 2.85 3.00 3.16 4.03 5.10 6. i 1 7.13 2.60% 2.60 2.60 2.70 2.90 2.90 2.90 2.90 - Alternative 1982 1983 1984 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 II-B: 0.48% 0.25 0.40 0.46 1.13 2.20 3.21 4.23 Average d 4.83 0.10 4.93 2.86 - 2.07 Source: 1982 HI Trustees Report, p. 37. Note: Taxable payroll is adjusted to take into account the lower contribution rates on self-employment income, on tips, and on multiple-employer "excess wages" as compared with the combined employer-employee rate. L'Cost attributable to insured beneficiaries only. Benefits and administrative costs for noninsured persons are financed through general revenue transfers and premium payments rather than through payroll taxes. hAllowances for maintaining the trust fund balance at the level of a half-year's outgo after accounting tor the offsening effect of interest earnings. • Rates tOr employees and employers combined. dAverage tot the twenty-five-year period 1982-2006. _'Takes into account amounts to be loaned to the Old-Age and Survivors Insurance trust fund under tile inter[und borrowing provisions. The loan is assumed not repaid under Alternative II-B; it is repaid in 1998 under Ahernative II-A. long-term and age deficit warfare in Social Security, we will see the greatest tax revolt in the history of the United States. ''6 This forecast OMichael Boskin, "Rebuilding Social Security," a Heritage Foundation nouncing a conference held on August 12, 1982 in Washington, D.C. brochure an- 115 is such a startling contrast to the outlook of ten to fifteen years ago that it is worth pausing to see how the situation and concerns have changed. Changing Perspectives In 1967 Paul A. Samuelson, wrote: later a Nobel laureate in economics, The beauty about social insurance is that . . . everyone who reaches retirement age is given benefit privileges that far exceed anything he has paid in. How is it possible? It stems from the fact that the national product is growing at compound interest and can be expected to do so for as far ahead as the eve can see. Always there are more youths than old folks in a growing population. More important, with real incomes growing at some 3 percent per year, the taxable base upon which benefits rest in any period are much greater than the taxes paid historically by the generation now retired. 7 Two of the crucial assumptions in Samuelson's assessment of Social Security were population growth and real income increases. After World War II there had been a substantial increase in fertility rates over the rates for the years prior to the war. In 1960, for example, the fertility rate was 3.61, meaning that for every 100 women who entered childbearing age and survived through their fertile period, 361 live births were expected. The fertility rates of the 1950s and 1960s offered the prospects of a continuously expanding work force paying Social Security taxes to support continuous growth in Social Security benefits. The 1960s were also a period of relative economic gains by workers. Between 1960 and 1964, wages grew at an annual rate of 2.1 percent faster than prices as measured by the consumer price index. Between 1965 and 1969, wages continued to grow 2 percent faster than consumer prices. This growth in the level of real wages increased the tax base providing added benefit support without raising the relative burden on workers over time. Increases in Benefits As Social Security entered 1971, payroll taxes were 5.2 percent for both employers and employees on the first $7,800 of covered earnings. 7paul A. Samuel,;on, p. 88. 116 "So_'ial Security," Neu.su,eek, vol. 69, no. 7 (February 12, 1967), Congress had just given beneficiaries a 15 percent benefit increase in 1970 and the prospects for the program looked good. On March 31, the 1971 Advisory Council on Social Security issued its report, stating: Adequate provision has been made in the law to meet all the costs of the cash benefits program both in the short run and over the long range future; the cash benefits program is actuariallv sound. Income to the supplementary medical insurance part of the Medicare program will be more than sufficient to meet the incurred benefit costs over the period, established bv the law, for which monthly premiums have been promulgated. However, unless income is increased, the hospital insurance trust fund will be exhausted in 1973._ The 1971 Advisory Council recommended that the supplementary medical insurance program should be financed bv a three-way even split instead of relying on beneficiary premiums and general revenues equally. 9 Employers and employees would each pay their shares through the payroll tax and the third portion would come from general revenues. There would no longer be a premium on beneficiaries under the proposal. The infusion of general revenues and increased payroll tax income would be combined with the HI portion of the payroll tax, and both HI and SMI benefits would be financed through a single Medicare trust fund. The council estimated that the payroll tax to finance the modified program would have to be increased from 0.60 percent to 1.30 percent of covered earnings for each employer and employee. The Medicare tax was projected to rise to 1.65 percent of covered payroll bv 1980 under the council's proposal, compared with the .80 percent under financing provisions then in effect. Congress has never implemented this recommendation of the 1971 Advisory Council, but it did implement several of the council's other recommendations that have significantly affected the program. SReport o[ the 1971 Adviso_ T Cotmcil o_t Social Security (Washington, D.C., 1971 ), p. 77. _Since 1973, beneficiaries and general revenue contributions have not shared the cost of SMI equally. During fiscal 1981, |or example, the general revenue transfers were about 2.6 times the participant premiums paid. This differential has occurred because even though medical cost inflation has exceeded general benefit increases, the elderlv's premium rate has not increased more rapidly than OASDI benefit rates. Moreover the premium rates for the disabled are the same as the rates [or the elderly in general, even though treatment |or disabled people costs more than treatment for the elderly on average. 117 Introducing Basic Changes Another recommendation of the 1971 Advisory Council was that the actuarial valuation procedure should be changed. Before 1972 the estimates of the long-range costs of the cash benefits program were based on the assumption that wages and prices would remain stable over the seventy-five-year valuation period. The council was convinced that increases in earnings over time would be greater than increases in benefit liability. The rationale was as follows: The increased income to the program that results from rising earnings is greater than the increased benefit because the contribution rate is a fiat percentage of all earnings up to the earnings base maximum, while benefits as a percentage of earnings decline as earnings rise, that is, the higher-paid worker gets a benefit that is a smaller percentage of his earnings than does the low-paid worker. I° On the basis of this assessment, the council was worried that every time wages rose, the program would end up with an actuarial surplus. The 1971 Advisory Council believed that Social Security cost estimates should reflect expected growth in earnings and benefits for future years. The council argued that future costs should be estimated on the basis of benefits provided by current law as kept up to date in current prices. In fact, the council also recommended that benefits should be automatically adjusted to keep up with price increases and that the contributions base should automatically grow with earnings. The council believed that using "dynamic assumptions" in the valuation procedure would provide a more realistic estimate of the program's long-term cost and strengthen the underlying fiscal discipline of the program, because improvements in benefit levels that would go beyond adjustment for prices would be reflected as higher costs to be borne by workers. One pleasant by-product of moving to the new valuation methodology was that the payroll tax burden was estimated to be lower for the next three or four decades than under the static valuation procedures. Table IV-7 shows the payroll tax schedule in effect in 1971 to finance Social Security benefits and the revised schedule recommended by the 1971 Advisory Council. On March 17, 1971, two weeks prior to issuance of the Advisory Council's Report, President Nixon signed Public Law 92-5, which I°Report 85. 118 o[ the 1971 Advisory Council on Social Security (Washington, D.C., 1971 ), p. TABLE IV-7 Payroll Tax Schedule for Employees and Employers in Effect in 1971 and Schedule Recommended by 1971 Advisory Council to Finance OASDI Benefits Tax Rate in Effect (Percent) Year 1972 1973 1974-1975 1976-1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982-1986 1987 2020 2021 2045 Source: Tax Rate Recommended by Council (Percent) 4.60 5.00 5.00 5.15 5.15 5.15 5.15 5.15 5.15 4.70 4.65 4.45 4.40 4.35 4.35 4.20 4.20 5.50 Report o]the 1971 Advisory ('o.ncil on ._qocialSecurity (Washington, p. 96. provided benefits a 10 percent across-the-board retroactive to January 1, 1971. D.C., 1971 ), increase in Social Security The tax base was raised from $7,800 to $9,000 for 1972. The tax rate [or the cash benefits programs was raised from 5.0 to 5.15 percent on workers and on their employers, to take effect in 1976 (see table IV-7). When the 92nd Congress convened in 1971, the first bill introduced in the House, H.R. 1, included significant Social Security legislation. The bill also included major welfare reform measures that had been passed by the House the previous year. On June 22, 1971, H.R. 1 was passed by the House and sent to the Senate. The Senate Finance Committee held hearings on the bill during July and August but did not consider the bill further until February 1972. In early 1972, concern over the slow progress of H.R. 1 and interest in providing a Social Security benefit increase before the elections in November led to separate consideration of Social Security legislation. In February 1972, Wilbur Mills, Chairman of the House Ways and Means Committee, introduced legislation calling for a 20 percent benefit increase and raising the taxable maximum income to $10,200 in 1972 and $12,000 in 1973. The tax rate schedule in the Mills hill was based on the 1971 Advisory Council's recommendations, and endorsed by the Social Security trustees and the Nixon administration. The Mills legislation also included provisions to adjust benefits automatically to corre119 spond to increases in the cost of living, starting in 1975. The House Ways and Means Committee report on the Mills bill specified a change in the actuarial method of Social Security cost valuation in accordance with the Advisory Council's recommendations. Toward the end of June 1972, when the Senate was considering extension of the public debt limit, Senator Frank Church introduced an amendment to the legislation under consideration that embraced most of the provisions of the Mills bill. The 20 percent benefit increase was to be effective in September 1972 instead of June, as under the House bill. Annual taxable maximum earnings were increased to $10,800 in 1973 and $12,000 in 1974. Beyond 1974 the maximum earnings level was to rise automatically with wages. Church's amendment also set a new tax rate schedule based on recommendations of the Advisory Council. This new tax rate schedule rcvised HI contl'ibution faced. rates to resolve the actuarial deficit that the program then The debt limit bill with the Social Security amendments was passed on June 30 and signed by the presidcnt on Julv 1, 1972, as Public Law 92-336. Members of Congress t0und themselves in a happy political situation for the middle of an election year. They had provided a 20 percent benefit increase that would show up in beneficiaries' mailboxes shortly be|0re an election; thcv could further assure beneficiaries that future benefits would not be eroded bv inflation. And as Robert M. Ball notes, "The financing recommendations of the Advisory Council made it possible to finance the existing Social Securitv benefits with lower contribution rates for the next 40 years than were then in the law. ''11 In the meantime, H.R. 1, including several provisions that would further modify Social Security, continued through the legislative process and became Public Law 92-603. It increased benefits tot widows and widowers; liberalized the earnings test and indexed it to wage growth for the future; changed the benefit computation procedure [or men (to match the provision lot women) to require three fewer computation years; established a special minimum benefit lot longcareer workers with low lifetime covered earnings; provided a delayed retirement incentive, raising benefits 1 percent for cach vear the worker did not claim benefits bctween the age of sixty-five and seventy-two; and extended Medicare to disabilitv-benefit recipients who had received cash benefits tot twentv-10ur consecutive months. IIRobert M. Ball, "Social History," ,_ocial Sectlritv 120 Security Amendments ot 1972: Summarv and Legislative Bulletin*, vol. 36, no. 3 (March 1973), p. 12. The bill that Congress passed in June 1972 reduced the payroll tax rate from the rates that had been provided for in the 1971 amendments. Table IV-8 shows the rates in effect prior to passage of Public Law 92-336. Yet, four months later this payroll tax reduction was completely reversed, and tax rates for all future years but three were raised over the rates that had prevailed in 1971. The cost estimates in Public Law 92-603 were based on the new dynamic cost-estimating procedure adopted earlier in the year. This quick turnaround on the payroll tax reduction was regarded as necessary to maintain the financial solvency of the program. Although this tax increase was not recognizable as such at the time, it was an ominous foreshadowing of subsequent events. The 1973 Trustees Report on the status of the OASDI trust funds was the first recognition of a financing problem. The end-of-year OASDI reserves wcrc projected to decline somewhat to 76 percent of expected annual outlays bv the end of 1977. The long-range projections showed an average deficit of 0.32 percent of taxable earnings over the seventy-five-year valuation period. In each of the subsequent four Trustees Reports, the Social Security financing situation was shown to deteriorate markedly, as table IV-9 shows. Bv 1975, it was clear that corrective action would be required to maintain the Social Security program. In the short-term, the OASDI trust funds were projected to decline to levels inadequate to meet TABLE IV-8 Payroll Finance Tax Schedule for Employees and Employers OASDHI Benefits Established by Legislation 1971 and in June and October 1972 1971 Amendments (Percent) Year 1973 1975 June 30, 1972 P.L. 92-336 (Percent) October 30, 1972 P.L. 92-603 (Percent) 5.65 5.50 5.85 1976-1977 5.85 5.50 5.85 1978-1979 1980 1981 - 1985 1986 1987- 1992 1993 2010 2011 and later 5.80 5.95 5.95 5.95 6.05 6.05 6.05 5.50 5.50 5.50 5.60 5.60 5.70 6.55 6.05 6.05 6.15 6.25 6.25 6.25 7.30 Source: Social Sect_ritvB,lletil, Ammal Statistical Sztpplemem, 1977 1979, to in p. 34. 121 TABLE IV-9 Projections of OASDI Reserve Financing in Successive Projected Start-of-Year Assets as a Percentage of Annual Expenditures 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 Year of Report 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 Sources: Ratios and Long-Term Trustees Reports 76 53 42 46 47 49 32 37 36 24 29 27 21 18 Long-Term Financing Deficit as a Percentage of Payroll 0.32 2.98 5.32 7.96 8.20 14 9 A_mual Reports o1 the Board o1 Trtlslees o1 the Federal Old-Age a_ld Snrvivors lnst_ra_we a_td Disabili O' lnsura_we Trust Ftmds, selected years. payment financing schedules. In the seventy-five-year long-term projection, deficil averaged more than 5 percent of payroll, and the the problem grew with each succeeding year. After the experience of the 1950s and 1960s, when growing benefits and sound financing had been assumed to continue torever, it was particularly difficult for policymakers Social Security in the 1970s system. Recognition of a Structural to understand or cope with a troubled Problem Social Security analyst David Koitz has pointed out that the initial warning in the 1973 Trustees Report of a long-term OASDI financing deficit was not the most significant aspect of the report. He finds it more instructive to look at the sensitivity of the long-term financing estimates to thc assumptions used in the valuation. For example, he notes that the trustees' "likely case" estimate, using 5 percent wage and 2.75 percent price growth assumptions, yielded a seventy-fiveyear cost of 11 percent of taxable payroll. Under 5 percent wage growth with 3.25 percent price increases, however, the projected cost of the system .jumped nearly 20 percent, to 13 percent of covered payroll. 12 The problem 1972 amendments formula called that Koitz described reflected a technical error in the relating to the method of computing benefits. The first for the computation of average monthlv wages 12David Koitz, "The Indexing of Social Security," in llzdexation o/Federal (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1981) p. 147. 122 Programs (AMW) based on the retiree's covered segmented, and different percentage earnings. factors This AMW were applied was then to each segment and summed to determine the primary insurance amount (PIA) payable to a worker at age sixtv-five. The 1974 Trustees Report showed that under certain economic assumptions, percentage formula for the products percent of Social Security would eventually replace an increasing of workers' final earnings. Table IV-10 shows how the June 1975, for example, calculated the PIA by summing of 129.48 percent of the first $110 of AMW plus 47.10 the next $290 and so forth. When the automatic benefit increase was provided to beneficiaries in 1976, the computation factors were also indexed. Table IV-10 also shows the effects of indexation on the benefit formula for 1976 and 1977. The problem into effect bv Lawrence with the modified the 1972 amendments H. Thompson of the benefit has Social computation been succinctly Security system stated put by Administration: The inflation adjustment mechanism causes replacement rates to rise whenever there are price increases; increases in wages cause replacement rates to fall whenever money wage levels rise. The net impact of the two, then, is to cause replacement rates either to rise or to fall depending on whether the price effect dominates the wage effect or vice versa. 13 TABLE Primary Insurance Amount Selected IV-10 Computation Years PIA Computation Average Monthly Earnings First $110 + next $290 + next $150 + next $100 + next $100 + next $250 + next $175 + next $100 + next $100 Source: Factors for Factor June 1975 (Percent) June 1976 (Percent) June 1977 (Percent) 129.48 47.10 44.01 51.73 28.77 23.98 21.60 0.00 0.00 137.77 50.10 46.82 55.05 30.61 25.51 22.98 21.29 0.00 145.90 53.06 49.58 58.30 32.42 27.02 24.34 22.54 21.18 Social Secziritv BMletm Ammal Statistical St_ppleme_it, 1977 1979, p. 18. 13Lawrence H. Thompson, "Toward the Rational Adjustment of Social Security Benefit Levels," PollO' A_za(vsis, vol. 3, no. 4 {Fall 1977), pp. 497-498. 123 Thompson Social based his assessment on a study that had been done by Security actuaries; the results of their analysis are reflected IV-I 1. The patterns of income replacement under the three assumptions led to quite different results. For example, sets B assume consistent price inflation of 3 percent per year. Set assumed 4 percent annual wage growth (i.e., 1 percent real growth), set B assumed 5 percent annual wage growth. This 1 percent differential in assumed wage growth, holding inflation constant, would resulted in strikingly different replacement rates over time. By turn of the century, the scenario characterized by assumption set would result in replacement rates ten percentage points higher than TABLE IV-II Replacement Rates for Successive Cohorts of Men Retiring at Age 65 after Having Always Earned the Median Taxable Wage in Employment Covered by Social Security Assumed Average Annual of Increase A B C wages prices 4 3 5 3 4 2 0.426 0.462 0.485 0.512 0.522 0.548 0.574 0.599 0.623 0.646 0.667 0.688 0.707 0.725 0.743 0.426 0.443 0.452 0.456 0.448 0.456 0.466 0.474 0.482 0.489 0.495 0.501 0.506 0.510 0.515 0.423 0.437 0.436 0.439 0.427 0.426 0.425 0.424 0.423 0.421 0.420 0.419 0.418 0.417 0.416 Replacement Rates: 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 Assumption Set Albert Rettig and Orlo R. Nichols, "Some Aspects of the Dynamic Projection of Benefits under the 1973 Social Security Amendments (P.L. 93-233)/' Actuarial Note no. 87 (Baltimore, Md.: Social Security Administration, 1974), table 5. the rates under assumption set B. (The only difference in the two sets of assumptions was the one-percentage-point differential in wage growth.) Different inflation assumptions, holding wages constant, also would result in wide variations in the replacement rate streams. In sets A and C, wages were assumed to grow at 4 percent per year. In set A, prices were assumed to grow at a rate of 3 percent per year, while in set C prices were assumed to grow at only 2 percent. The onepercentage-point greater growth in assumed prices in set A resulted in a replacement rate in 2045 for the projected average worker nearly 80 percent higher than the rate for set C. One particularly significant element of the table is the relative stability of the replacement rates under assumptions of 4 percent wage growth with 2 percent price growth. Myers's analysis leads to the conclusion that the 1972 benefit computation procedure would result in relatively stable Social Security replacement of final earnings if wages grew in a 1.9 to 1.0 ratio in relation to prices. If wages grew more rapidly than this relative to prices, however, the earnings replacement capacity would decline. If wages grew less rapidly than 1.9 times price increases, replacement rates would steadily increase. 14 In this regard it is interesting to compare the short-term expectations in 1972 with actual economic experience. The important variables to consider are prices, wages, and unemployment. The rate of price growth is important because after 1975, benefits were to increase automatically with the increase in the CPI. A two-step cash benefit increase of 11 percent during 1974, with 7 percent payable in March and the remainder in June, effectively moved the adjustment forward to account for price increases beyond 1972. The Effect o[ Short-Term Economics--The 1972 Trustees Report, under mid-range assumptions, assumed that prices would grow at a rate of 2.75 percent per year over the short term. Compounded over the five-year projection, the estimate was that prices would rise 14.5 percent through 1976, as table IV-12 shows. In fact, prices, as measured by the CPI, increased by 40.6 percent--nearly three times the expected growth. Since benefits were adjusted to reflect price increases, revenue demands on the OASDI program increased more rapidly than expected. On the revenue collection side, things did not work out as well as expected either. Actual unemployment exceeded the level expected _Myers, Social Security, p. 25. 125 TABLE IV-12 Comparison of Five-Year Economic Assumptions in the 1972 OASDI Trustees Report with Actual Experience 1972 Trustees Report 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 Total CPI Increase Assumeda Actual (Percent) (Percent) 2.75 3.3 2.75 6.2 2.75 11.0 2.75 9.1 2.75 5.8 14.53 40.6 Real Wage Increase Assumeda Actual (Percent) (Percent) 2.25 4.0 2.25 0.7 2.25 - 3.6 2.25 -2.5 2.25 2.5 11.77 1.0 Unemployment Rate Assumeda Actual (Percent) (Percent) 4.2 5.6 4.2 4.9 4.2 5.6 4.2 8.5 4.2 7.7 4.2 b 6.5 b Sources: Annual Reports o[ the Board of Trustees of tile OASDI Trust Funds, 1972; Economic Report of the President, 1982. _Mid-range assumptions. hEstimates fur five-year unemployment totals are five-year averages. in each of the five years in the short-term projections, so smaller segments of the work force were contributing taxes than had been expected. Moreover, wages had been projected to grow 2.25 percent faster than prices in each year in the forecast; real growth in wages is important because it expands the total base against which taxes are applied. During the 1972 to 1976 period, real wage growth was only about one-twelfth of the increase projected in 1972. The combined effects of higher than expected unemployment with disappointing wage growth meant that revenues were not keeping up with rapid benefit growth during this period. Putting the Social Security program on "automatic pilot" in 1972 had been endorsed as a conservative measure. The ad hoc benefit increases between 1969 and 1972 had far outpaced inflation, so policymakers thought that automatic indexation would limit benefit increases to the growth in prices in the future. The practical result of the 1972 amendments was to make benefit levels sensitive to economic conditions rather than responsive to explicit policy decisions by the Congress. The adverse economic conditions of the 1970s hit right when Social Security had become vulnerable to such circumstances. The Effect of Long-Term Demographics--Ahhough financial difficulties that Social Security faced stemmed from economic and technical problems, 126 the short-term in the early 1970s the growing proj- ected long-term increased OASDI incidence financing of disability deficit in the was earlv also 1970s the and result of an changes in birthrate assumptions. In the 1977 Trustees Report, the projected long-range DI costs as a percentage of taxable payroll were 1.8 times those projected in the 1973 report. The birthrate in the United States had declined steadilv for over a century prior to 1940. In 1840 there were approximately 52 live births for every 1,000 persons in the population. Bv 1940 this had dropped to 19.4 births per 1,000. I_ After 1940 the birthrate began to increase, with the most significant growth occurring after World War II. After 1957, however, declining birthrates again became the norm, as table IV-13 shows. The birthrate is particularly important to a national TABLE Birthrate, United IV-13 States, 1940-1979 Year Rate Per 1,000 Population Year Rate Per 1,000 Population 1940 194 t 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 19.4 20.3 22.2 22.7 21.2 20.4 24.1 26.6 24.9 24.5 24.1 24.9 25.1 25.0 25.3 25.0 25.2 25.3 24.5 24.0 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 23.7 23.3 22.4 21.7 21.0 19.4 18.4 17.8 17.5 17.8 18.4 17.2 15.6 14.9 14.9 14.8 14.8 15.4 15.3 15.9 Sources: U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics ofthe United States, Colonial Times to 1970 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975), p. 49; and U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract o[ the U_tited States, 1981, p. 60. _U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States (Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975), p. 49, Series B 5-10. D.C.: 127 pay-as-you-go retirement system because it determines the future level of workers who will be paying for the benefits going to future retirees. The birthrate is converted to a fertility rate for purposes of estimating the future costs of Social Security. (The fertility rate in a given year is the average number of live births that a woman would be expected to have in her lifetime, if at each year of her life she experienced the birthrates occurring that year for all women her age.) The measured fertility rates for years between 1966 and 1979 and those used in the average or intermediate valuations of Social Security done in those years are shown in table IV-14. The table shows a consistent pattern of assumed fertility rates above those actually experienced in the year in which the estimate is being made. The effects of varying the fertility rate on the long-term valuation of Social Security are shown in table IV-15. On the basis of these sensitivity estimates, it is clear that a significant portion of the actuarial deficit projected in 1974 was related to changes in the birthrate assumptions in the actuarial valuation of the program. Had the fertility assumptions used in the valuations been changed for years earlier, it is unlikely that Congress would have provided the 15, 10, and 20 percent benefit increases between 1970 and 1972. Certainly Congress would have been very unlikely to enact the benefit increase of 20 percent in 1972 if it had been generally understood that the benefit increase would put Social Security into a long-term financing deficit. Modification of the System By 1976 it was widely understood that the Social Security program would need modification to get through the next few years. By 1975 the forecasts of declining balances had become reality, as expenditures began to exceed income. It was clear to analysts that the initial benefit formula indexation had to be "decoupled" from the cost-ofliving adjustments (COLAs) being provided for postretirement benefits. The debate ultimately focused on two recommendations, both calling for a new method of determining initial benefit levels with continued CPI indexation of postretirement annuities. The first recommendation came from a panel of actuaries and economists in a report prepared for the Senate Finance Committee and the House Ways and Means Committee. This panel came to be known as the Hsiao panel after its chairman, William Hsiao, who is both an actuary and an economist. The panel recommended that initial ben128 TABLE Actual Sources: and Assumed IV-14 Total Fertility Years Rates for Selected Year Actual Rate Social Security Assumed Rate 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 2.72 2.56 2.46 2.46 2.48 2.28 2.02 1.90 1.86 1.80 1.77 1.83 1.80 1.86 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.1 2.1 1.9 2.1 2.1 2.1 U.S. Bureau of the Census, StatisticalAbstract o]the U_zitedStates, 1981 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1981), p. 58; Social Security Trustees Reports, selected years. efits for future retirees be based on their earnings indexed for historical growth in prices. The net effect of their proposal was that initial benefits would grow slowly over time in real terms but that wage replacement rates would decline gradually as real wages grew. Their financing recommendation called for a level tax rate of 10.3 percent on employers and employees combined for OASDI in 1980 and beyond. This rate was only slightly higher than provisions then in law for the period 1980 to 2010. Under the actuarial projections based on the intermediate assumptions in the 1976 Trustees Report, the average seventy-five-year cost of their proposal was 11 percent of covered payroll.16 The second proposal, developed by internal government staff and advocated by the 1975 Social Security Advisory Council, called for benefits to be based on earnings indexed for historical growth in average wages. The main intent of this proposal was that over time Social Security should replace the same proportion of preretirement I_William Hsiao et al., Report of tlle Consultant Panel on Social Security (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1976), pp. 3-6. 129 TABLE IV-15 Effects of Changing Fertility Assumptions from Alternative II-B of 1981 Trustees Report on OASDI Actuarial Balance, as a Percentage of Taxable Payroll for 2031-2055 Fertility Rate Assumption 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 2.7 2.8 2.9 3.0 3.1 3.2 Increase in Actuarial Balance II-B Assumptions 0.6 1.2 1.7 2.2 2.6 3.0 3.3 3.1 3.9 4.2 4.5 _ Source: Robert J. Myers, "Sensitivity Analysis of Assumptions in Alternatives I and II-B of 1981 Trustees Report," Memorandum no. 7 (Washington, D.C.: National Commission on Social Security Reform, March 15, 1982). _The actuarial deficit for the period is 4.4 percent of payroll under the II-B assumptions on the basis of currently legislated tax rates. earnings for each cohort of retirees. The Ford administration endorsed this proposal in 1976, but no legislative action was taken that year. The seventy-five-year cost of OASDI benefits under this proposal was estimated at 15 percent of covered payroll. The Hsiao panel argued against the wage indexation formula on the basis of its projected rising costs. Their estimates were that expenditures would be about 50 percent higher under the wage-indexed formula at the height of the baby-boom generation's retirement claims in 2030. They argued as follows: Perhaps the most important lesson learned from the financial difficulties now facing the OASDI program is that an element of flexibility must be built into its design. Abrupt changes in benefits and supporting taxes must be avoided. In our constantly changing society and economy, public interests can best be served by a system with built-in margins that will permit measured response to the needs of an uncertain future. 130 It has been pointed out that on reasonable economic and demographic assumptions the payroll tax rates needed to finance benefits payable in the first half of the next century will rise to more than double present rates. An issue that should not bc overlooked is what future tax rates \viii be needed to finance any proposal otfered as an improved benefit structure. The Panel believes that future generations of workers should not bc committed in advance to materialh rising lax rates. _7 The panel firmly should not decline recommended in real terms that Social Security benefit levels over time, but suggested that Con- gress should provide the marginal increments in benefits needed periodically on an ad hoc basis rather than by wage indexation. In addressing the Social Security financing problem in 1977, Congress opted for the wage-indexing formula on the benefit side and higher payroll taxes on the financing side. The 1977 amendments reduced the projected OASDI long-term actuarial deficit from 8.2 percent of payroll to 1.4 percent. Congress believed at the time that enactment of the 1977 amendments had assured financial solvency for the Social Security program, excluding Medicare, until at least 2020. Although the long-term problem loomed on the horizon, Congress believed that there was still time to deal with it. Continuing Problems It soon became apparent that the short-term benefits consistently ran ahead of the levels projected in 1977, and revenues ran behind. The problem stemmed from adverse economic conditions to which the program was still sensitive. According to the five-year projections in the 1977 Trustees Report, inflation was expected to decline, while prices were forecast to rise a total of 28.2 percent between 1977 and 1981. In fact, prices rose 60 percent, more than twice the forecasted amount, as table IV- 16 shows. Wages were expected to increase nearly 13 percent more than prices over the period, but in fact wage earners lost ground to price increases. Unemployment was expected to decline, while in fact it rose to about 50 percent above the projected level for 1981, and has continued to get worse during 1982. The full effects of the 1977 amendments have not vet been experienced. The transitional benefit provisions in these amendments left tTlbid., p. 2. 131 TABLE IV-16 A Comparison of Five-Year Economic Assumptions the 1977 OASDI Trustees Report with Actual Experience Year 1977 i 978 1979 1980 1981 Total CPI Increase Assumed a Actual (Percent) (Percent) Real Wage Increase Assumed a Actual b (Percent) (Percent) in Unemployment Rate Assumed _ Actual (Percent) (Percent) 6.0 5.4 4.3 4.7 4.1 6.5 7.7 11.3 13.5 10.4 2.4 2.7 2.5 2.4 2.3 1.5 0.6 - 2.6 4.9 - 1.5 7.1 6.3 5.7 5.2 5.0 7. I 6.1 5.8 7.1 7.6 28.2 60.0 12.9 - 6.9 5.9 _ 6.7 _ Sources: Assumptions trom 1977 Amtual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Sura,ivors Insurance and Disability Insurance Trust Funds (Washington, D.C.: Social Security Administration, 1977); actual experience lrom 1982 Economic Report of the President; real wage calculations by EBRI. "Mid-range assumptions. bEstimates from the 1982 Trustees Report tot all years. _Estimates for five-year unemployment totals are five-year averages. vestiges of the dual indexation problem started by the 1972 amendments in the program until 1982. Is Although the maximum taxable wage level was raised by the 1977 amendments, it reached the point of once again being adjusted by automatic growth only in 1982. The scheduled increases in payroll tax rates do not take full effect until 1990. The OASI trust fund balances are insufficient to guarantee meeting the benefit payment schedule in both the short and the long terms. Considering the failure of the 1977 amendments, the basic conclusion of the Hsiao panel that an element of flexibility should be built into the system has become particularly poignant. Still, the recommendations of the Hsiao panel would have left the OASI program in even worse financial straits than it is in today, since the panel's recommendations would have resulted in greater instability than has been experienced under the 1977 law. Because the OASI trust fund cial Security has been reduced The current tax schedule cannot has become practically depleted, Soto strictly pay-as-you-go financing. meet the benefit requirements in the laThe net eft;cot of the transitional provisions was relatively minor except t0r workers retiring at age sixty-two before 1979. Inflation was so high that most of those reaching age sixty-two alter 1978 used the AIME method tot the determination of their Social Security benefits. Beyond 1978, newly entitled disabilitv and survivor cases were covered by the modified formula. 132 1980s, so adjustments to the system have to be made. The basic policy question now is how to adjust Social Security to assure its continued viability, while continuing to provide economic security for the aged, the disabled, and survivors of deceased workers. The nature of the problem--stabilizing the system--and the means of addressing it are discussed in chapters V and VI. 133 V. The Mathematics of Social Security's Financing Problems and the Short-Term Policy Options Numerous proposals have been put forward to resolve curity's financial imbalance in the short and long terms: Social Se- • move forward the scheduled payroll tax increases now in law; • expand the income base subject to the payroll tax; • include in the tax base employee benefits not included in current wage payments; • finance part or all of Hospital Insurance from general revenue and allocate the HI portion of the payroll tax to the Old-Age and Survivors Insurance program; • finance part of the Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Disabilitv Insurance programs from general revenues on a continuing or a countercyclical basis; • reduce cost-of-living adjustments for a time; • change the COLA procedure; • tax Social Security benefits as regular income and earmark the revenues for OASDI financing; • reduce the projected growth in initial benefit entitlements; • eliminate or reduce benefits for certain categories of beneficiaries; • modify the benefit adjustments [or early and late retirees; • expand coverage; and • phase the program out altogether. Each of these proposals would have different implications in the short and long terms. The proposals also would have a range of distributional effects, because of their differential sharing of tax burdens and benefit modifications. Given the long history of attempting to balance the adequacy and equity goals in Social Security policy, these concepts will surely play a role in the selection of any particular option or set of options. Policymakers must seek to establish a workable solution, while restoring public confidence that there will be adequate levels of income security for both current and future retirees at a reasonable cost. Whereas the last chapter considered the magnitudes of' the short- and long-term Social Security problems and their discovery, this chapter explains the internal mechanics that account for the program's instability and for the projected financing shortfalls. The analysis flows from the "mathematics of Social Security," which is described in simple equations. These equations are then used to evaluate a range of short-term options that can help to 135 balance Social Security's financing in the near term. The equations also serve as the basis for a set of long-term modifications that are evaluated in the next two chapters. The Mathematics of Social Security Financing At present, Social Security is strictly a pay-as-you-go program which implies certain fundamental mathematical relationships in the financing of benefits to be paid in the near and distant future. It is useful to consider the mathematics because it identifies the general policy options for resolving the financing problems. It goes as follows: Total tax receipts = total benefits I Tax receipts = the payroll tax rate (t) times the number of workers (Nw) times average covered earnings (W) Total benefits = the number of beneficiaries (Nb) times the average benefit (B) This can be stated in standard mathematical form in the following way: (1)t. Nw.W - Nb.B. Congress can manipulate the variables in the financing equation in various ways. Congress can directly raise or lower the payroll tax rate and average benefit levels. To a lesser extent, Congress can alter the number of workers covered by the payroll tax and the average covered wage. If Congress were to expand coverage, the number of workers paying taxes would immediately increase and the number of beneficiaries and average benefit levels would ultimately be affected. By changing the eligibility requirements and retirement incentives, the benefit and beneficiary levels also can be manipulated. For example, if Congress were to encourage or mandate later retirement, the decline in beneficiaries might increase the number of covered workers. More covered workers and later retirement would help on both sides of the equation, raising taxes and reducing benefits. While the number of workers and wage level are subject to legislative manipulation, they are also sensitive to prevailing economic conditions and general benefit policies in the marketplace. In the context of resolving Social Security's financing imbalances, equation 1 has both short- and long-term implications. If it is assumed _Actually, the right side of this equation should include administrative expenses. These expenses are omitted here, however, because they account for less than 2 percent of total outlays and do not vary significantly over time. Hence including them would complicate the analysis without changing the basic results. 136 that Social Security will remain a pay-as-you-go program, it is possible to estimate the magnitude of adjustments required to balance the income and disbursement sides of the financing equation. Then we can assess various policy options that might actually balance the system financially. Short-Term Imbalances--The five-year short-term projected income for the Social Security cash benefits programs (i.e., OASDI) under the 1982 Trustees Report II-A assumptions is $930.6 billion. Under the II-B assumptions, it is projected at $926.7 billion. These income estimates do not include interest payments or expense (if the balance becomes negative) but do include reimbursements from the Treasury for special age seventy-two benefits and gratuitous military credits. Disbursements for the period 1982 to 1986 are projected to be $944.8 billion under the II-A assumptions and $972.9 billion under II-B assumptions. The disbursements include total OASDI benefit payments plus additional costs of administration, vocational rehabilitation, and transfers to the railroad retirement account. Under both assumption sets, projected payroll tax income accounts for 99 percent of total program revenues and benefit payments nearly 98 percent of total disbursements? On this basis, equation 1 captures about 98 to 99 percent of the total OASDI operations on a pay-as-you-go basis. Under the II-A assumptions, the projected rcvcnucs fall about $14.2 billion-1.5 percent short of meeting thc program cost over this five year period. Under the II-B assumptions the shortage is projected to be $46.2 billion--5.0 percent of projected revenues. On a comparable basis, the II-A OASI income is projected to be $778 billion for the 1982 to 1986 calendar years. Disbursements are projected to be $845 billion. Projected revenues other than interest income are projected to fall $67 billion short of disbursements over the five years. Under the II-B assumptions, the five-year income shortfall is projected to be $99 billion. 3 The OASI trust fund at the end of 1981 held $21.5 billion in assets and was insufficient to meet either shortfall. Just to maintain that trust fund and any interest it might accrue would require an increase of 12.9 percent in other income or a decrease of 11.4 percent in disbursements under the II-B assumptions. Of course, some combination of increased revenues or decreased benefits could accomplish the same result. Under the II-A assump21982 Anmml Report o/ Trustees of the Federal Disability htstlrance Trust Futtds (Washington, 1982), p. 56. 3Ibid., p. 51. Old-Age and Sura,ivors Insurance and D.C.: Social Security Administration, 137 tions, arios, the problem the situation is slightly less severe; under is significantly worse. the pessimistic scen- Long-Term Imbalances--The long-term cost and revenue estimates for Social Security are projected as a percentage of covered payroll. In terms of the mathematics of Social Security, this means that equation 1 is manipulated in the following way: (2) t = (Nb / Nw) • (B/W). Equation 2 shows that the tax rate required each year to finance the program on a current-cost basis equals the expected ratio of beneficiaries to workers times the ratio of average benefits to average covered wages. The Social Security actuaries refer to their projections of the right side of the equation as "cost rate" of the program. The "t" on the left side is the payroll tax rate. To the extent that the legislated tax rate and the projected cost rate do not balance, a financing surplus or deficit is projected for the program. The actuaries' long-term cost projections are made on the basis of a seventy-fiveyear period, as discussed in chapter IV. Table V-1 shows the average cost rates projected in the 1982 OASD[ Trustees Report over the next seventy-five years, along with the accrued and average surplus or deficit on the basis of currently legislated tax rates for the periods shown under the II-A, II-B, and pessimistic assumptions used in the valuation. Under both the II-A and II-B assumptions, the combined OASDI tax rates now in law are projected to be sufficient to meet the cost of Social Security cash benefits over the next twenty-five years. Under the pessimistic assumptions, OASDI never reaches adequate financing on a current-cost basis. Even under the II-B assumptions, the current short-term OASI deficits are sufficiently large that the twentyfive-year average stays negative, but there is a period between 1995 and 2010 when annual payroll tax collections are projected to exceed annual disbursements. Under all three sets of assumptions, the DI program is projected to have a surplus on a current-cost basis over the whole valuation period. The OASI trust fund would be depleted in 1984 under all three scenarios. The combined OASDI trust funds would be inadequate to meet the financing deficit in 1985. Based on the II-A assumptions, the OASI trust fund by itself would recover in 1995; under either of the other two scenarios, the OASI trust fund alone would never recover. The commingling of the OASI and DI trust funds would result 138 TABLE V-I Estimated Cost Rates and Tax Rates for OASDI Programs Combined and for DI and OASI Programs Separately for Alternative Periods (As percentages of taxable payroll) Average Cost Rate ILA II-B III Period Combined 1982-2006 2007-2031 2032-2056 OASDI Programs 10.46 11.37 13.15 14.08 15.65 16.81 1982-2056 Average Tax Rate Average II-A Surplus II-B or Deficit III 12.73 17.84 25.66 12.01 12.40 12.40 1.55 -0.75 -3.25 0.64 - 1.68 -4.41 - 0.72 5.44 13.26 -0.82 - 1.82 - 6.47 13.09 14.09 18.74 12.27 Alone 1. l6 1.57 1.54 1.23 1.65 1.61 1.36 2.00 2.07 2.07 2.20 2.20 0.92 0.63 0.66 0.85 0.55 0.59 0.72 0.20 0.13 1.42 1.50 1.81 2.16 0.73 0.66 0.35 OASI Program Alone 1982-2006 9.31 2007-2031 11.58 2032-2056 14.11 10.14 12.43 15.20 11.37 15.83 23.60 9.93 10.20 10.20 0.63 -1.38 -3.91 -0.21 2.23 -5.00 - 1.44 5.63 13.40 1982-2056 12.59 16.93 10.11 -1.55 2.48 - 6.82 DI Program 1982-2006 2007-2031 2032-2056 1982-2056 Source: 11.66 1982 Ammal Report o[ Trustees o[ the Federal Old-Age and Su_a'ivors htsura_we and Disability Insurance Trust Funds (Washington, D.C.: Social Security Administration, 1982), p. 70. in a two-year deficit under scenario. fund deficit under II-B, and a perpetual the II-A deficit assumptions, under the a nine-year Alternative III For the long term, then, policymakers must focus on resolving the OASI funding shortfalls. Under the 1982 Trustees Report II-A and IIB assumptions, OASI has a pay-as-you-go financing deficit every year in the valuation period beyond 2015. During the second twenty-five years in the cost projections shown in table V-l, the average shortfall ranges from 13.5 percent of projected revenues under II-A assumptions to 21.9 percent under the II-B assumptions, and 55.2 percent in the pessimistic scenarios. During the third twenty-five-year period, the revenue shortfall under the three sets of assumptions increases to 38.3, 49.0, and 13 [ .4 percent of revenues, respectively. The reason for this deteriorating situation is largely the result of changing demographics; it can bc attributed specifically to the proj139 ected increase in the number of beneficiaries dependency relative ratio. The dependency to covered workers--the ratio first is the factor on the right hand of equation 2 (i.e., Nb/Nw). Table V-2 presents three sets of dependency ratio projections. Both the OASI and OASDI dependency ratios remain relatively stable until the turn of the century. Around that time, however, they rise very rapidly because of projected rapid increases in the OASI recipiency rates as the baby-boom generation passes into retirement. Under the II-A and II-B assumptions, the dependency ratios stabilize again around 2030, when baby-boom generation retirements are expected to peak. Under the pessimistic assumptions, the ratios continue to rise because of the lower fertility rate assumptions in this scenario. Lower birthrates over the next three decades would lower the number of future replacement workers (i.e., taxpayers). The maximum effect would be seen during the last twenty-five years of the projection period. TABLE V-2 OASI and OASDI Beneficiaries Per 100 Workers Under 1972 Trustees Report II-A and II-B Assumptions Year 1982 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 Source: 140 II-A Assumptions OASI OASDI 27 27 27 28 28 28 30 34 38 42 45 46 45 45 45 45 45 31 30 30 31 31 32 34 38 43 47 49 50 50 49 50 50 50 II-B Assumptions OASI OASDI 27 27 28 28 28 28 30 34 39 43 46 46 46 46 46 46 46 31 30 31 31 32 33 35 39 43 48 50 50 50 50 50 51 50 III (Pessimistic) Assumptions OASI OASDI 27 27 29 29 30 31 34 40 46 53 58 62 64 67 70 73 74 31 31 32 33 34 36 39 45 52 58 64 67 70 73 76 78 80 1982 Amlual Report of Trustees o/ the Federal Old-Age and Sun,ivors htsura_we and Disability Insurance Trust Funds (Washington, D.C.: Social Security Administration, 1982), pp. 65-66. Not only will the beneficiary-to-worker ratio rise in the future, but the changing composition of the beneficiary population will exacerbate the long-term financing problem as well. This problem stems from the fact that different classes of beneficiaries do not all have the same claim on the system. Table V-3 shows the average OASI benefits paid to different classes of recipients over the years and compares them with retired workers' benefits. The table shows that for most categories of recipients, the relationship between benefits paid to persons other than workers and benefits paid workers has been relatively stable. For example, the average benefit paid to the spouse of a retired worker has ranged from a high of 53.8 percent of the average worker's benefit in 1950 to a low of 50.4 percent in 1980. There was only a 3.8 percentage-point swing in the ratio of spouse benefits to worker benefits over the thirty-year period. The real importance of the benefit comparisons becomes apparent when considering the projected changes in the relative sizes of the beneficiary categories. In 1980, for example, 63.1 percent of all OASI beneficiaries were retired workers. Under the 1982 Trustees Report II-B assumptions, retired workers are projected to increase to 72.6 percent of OASI beneficiaries by the year 2000, 82.6 percent by 2030, and 84.5 percent by 2060. The change in the composition of beneficiaries is important because retired workers receive higher benefits on average than other recipients. The potential size of the composition effect can be estimated by weighting the projected number of beneficiaries in each class by a "benefit equivalency" factor. The benefit equivalency factor converts each class of recipients into retired-worker equivalents on the basis of relative benefit levels. For examplc, in June 1980 there were 30.4 million OASI beneficiaries shown in the 1982 Trustees Report. 4 If the 1980 benefit equivalency factors in table V-3 are applied to all beneficiaries in each category, the 30.4 million beneficiaries are converted into 27.1 million retired-worker equivalents. Similar calculations can be performed on the projected beneficiary categories to show the composition effects that might be expected in the future. Table V-4 shows the results of applying the 1980 beneficiary-equivalence factors to the 1982 Trustees Report II-B projection of future recipiency levels. The table shows that the program is projected to grow somewhat more rapidly on a retired-worker-equivalent basis than the projected growth in beneficiaries alone would suggest. Thus, although changing demographics are largely responsible for proj4Ibid., p. 84 141 c._ _'_ ._ •- _ _"_ _ _ _ ._ _ _ _ _ _ _ _. ..- ___ _ _ _ __ _ _ __ __ ......... 142 _ ._ _ _ TABLE Number Equivalents V-4 of Beneficiaries and Retired-Worker and Percentage Growth Projected Over 1980 Levels for Selected Years Beneficiary Level Retired-Worker Equivalent Year Number (Thousands) Percentage Growth from 1980 Number (Thousands) Percentage Growth from 1980 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060 30,384 36,428 39,814 45,359 57,753 69,138 71,440 73,034 75,215 _ 19.9 31.0 49.3 90.1 127.5 135.1 140.4 147.5 27,148 33,351 36,744 42,216 54,272 65,279 67,993 69,562 7 1,730 _a_ 22.8 35.3 55.5 99.9 140.5 150.5 156.2 164.2 Source: Beneficiary levels based on actual level in 1980 and II-B projection presented in the 1982 Annual Report o[ Trustees o[ the Federal Old-Age and Survivors lnst_rance and Disability Insurance Trust Funds (Washington, D.C.: Social Security Administration, 1982), p. 84; the retired-worker equivalent levels were derived by applying the 1980 benefit equivalence factors from table V-3 to actual and projected beneficiaries bv class from the same projections as beneficiarv levels were taken. ;' 1980 is the base year for the remaining percentage calculations. ected increases in the future cost of Social Security, some socioeconomic factors also are causing costs to rise. The projected changing composition of the beneficiary population resulting from these factors would cause average benefits to rise in the future. The implications of these changes can be seen by further manipulation of equation 2 as follows: (3) W/B In equation to average parentheses the payroll cost basis. = (Nb/Ntt,)/t. 3, the term on the left side is the ratio of average wages benefits. On the right side of the equation, the ratio in is the dependency ratio discussed earlier, while "t" is tax rate required to finance the program on a currentBoth the dependency ratio and the cost rate are estimated by Social Security's actuaries; thus the implicit wage-to-benefit can be derived. Table V-5 shows the results of this derivation the 1982 Trustees Report ratio under II-B assumptions. 143 TABLE V-5 Projected OASI Dependency Ratios, Cost Rates, and Relationships Between Average Benefits to Average Wages for Selected Years Year Ratio of Beneficiaries to Workers Cost Rate Ratio of Average Wages to Benefits Ratio of Average Benefits to Wages 1982 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 0.2730 0.2685 0.2751 0.2790 0.2799 0.2842 0.3034 0.3400 0.3853 0.4297 0.4556 0.4632 0.4579 0.4552 0.4578 0.4599 0.4592 0. !042 0.1052 0.1054 0.1027 0.0975 0.0950 0.0994 0.1112 0.1272 0.1429 0.1523 0.1545 0.1520 0.1503 0.1509 0.1521 0.1522 2.62 2.55 2.61 2.72 2.87 2.99 3.05 3.06 3.03 3.01 2.99 3.00 3.01 3.03 3.03 3.02 3.02 0.382 0.392 0.383 0.368 0.348 0.344 0.328 0.327 0.330 0.333 0.334 0.332 0.332 0.330 0.330 0.331 0.331 Source: Ratios calculated by the author. The ratio of beneficiaries to workers was computed on the basis of II-B projections of OASI beneficiaries and covered workers; the cost rates were taken directly from 1982 Annual Report of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Disability Insurance Trust Funds (Washington, D.C.: Social Security Administration, 1982), pp. 64 and 66. In the assumed long-term cost projections to grow more rapidly than of the prices. OASI Under program, wages are the II-B projections, wages are ultimately assumed to grow 1.5 percent faster per year than prices. If initial benefits grow at the same rate as wages, and postretirement benefits grow at the slower rate of increasing prices, one might expect average benefit levels to decline relative to average wages over time. The changing composition of the beneficiary population to include a higher proportion of retired workers, however, will raise the level of average benefits. As a result, the ratio of average wages to benefits is projected the turn of the century. Then, to increase gradually until as the baby-boom generation to begin to retire under current eligibility criteria, using the II-B projections. If the projections made 144 shortly after is expected the ratio stabilizes on the basis of the 1982 Trustees Report II-A or if the pessimistic assumptions are used instead of the II-B assumptions the result is the same, only the ratios differ. In sum, then, under current law, the outgo of the OASI program is projected to exceed revenues by 9 to 13 percent on the basis of the short-term (five-year) projections. On the long-term (seventy-five-year) basis, projected benefits exceed revenues bv 15 percent under the I[A assumptions, by 25 percent under the II-B assumptions, and bv 68 percent under the pessimistic assumptions. Stabilizing the Financing of Social Security Just as the mathematics is useful in explaining Social Security financing problems, it is also useful in evaluating the policy options for resolving them. Before discussing specific options it is helpful to delineate some general policy considerations. Equation 2 was stated as follows: t = (Nb/Nw) • (B/W) where "t" is the payroll tax rate required to sustain the projected benefit levels, or what Social Security actuaries call the cost rate of the program. In the short term, the ratio of beneficiaries to workers is unstable because of variations in the economic cycle. During a recessionary period, the number of workers declines as unemployment rises, and the number of beneficiaries rises as people eligible for benefits who would have continued working are affected by unemployment. The opposite would be true during a recoverv. Furthermore, the ratio of average benefits to average wages can become unstable during periods in which either behaves erraticallv. Under assumptions that have been used in the Social Security valuations since 1972, the ratio of benefits to wages has been projected to decline gradually because of real wage growth. In fact, this ratio has not declined at the expected rate and has actuallv increased during several of the past ten years. If the ratio of benefits to wages is to be insulated against the kind of erratic economic behavior experienced in the past ten years, increases in benefits will have to be linked to an index of wages. This ratio could be held constant in the short term by using the average wage index as a basis for increasing postretirement benefits in increments. The ratio could be held constant when real wages are not 145 growing and decreased when they are by indexing benefits by the lower of wage or price growth. And the ratio could be forced to decrease in the short term, by indexing benefits by something less than wage growth (e.g., wage growth rate minus 15). In the last case, the ratio would not decline so rapidly during periods of rapid real wage growth as it would if benefits were indexed to prices. In the long term, the recomposition of the beneficary population would still stabilize the ratio of benefits to wages under the II-B assumptions. The ratio of beneficiaries to workers will never be absolutely stable in the short term. Assuming that the ratio of benefits to wages is stabilized, the only way the tax rate can be stable over economic cycles in the short term is for there to be resources other than the flow of payroll taxes available to meet Social Security benefit requirements. This means either that a trust fund has to be accumulated or that borrowing provisions from other revenue sources must be available. There have been several analyses of the size of trust fund reserves required to administer the Social Security benefit payment schedule. These analyses generally conclude that the trust fund balances at the peak of an economic cycle should be large enough to meet scheduled benefits through the trough of economic downswings. It is generally assumed that if economic conditions turn out worse than projected, Congress will have enough warning to make necessary adjustments to the programs. However, the time Congress needed to develop legislation to address the problem in 1977 and the time it is taking Congress to respond to the current financing problem suggest that some additional trust fund reserves might be required to provide more lead time for responding to financing problems when they arise. Even so, there is no guarantee that a larger trust fund balance would not also be depleted if Congress merely extends the amount of time it takes to react. An alternative source of Social Security revenues that has been recommended for economic downturns is countercyclical general revenue infusions, to offset lower payroll tax collections during periods of high unemployment. However, this proposal might exacerbate the normal growth in deficits that occurs during recessionary periods. Larger government deficits can lead to higher interest rates and retard recovery, thus prolonging adverse cyclical effects on Social Security financing. If neither a trust fund nor alternative revenues are provided to stabilize the program during unstable economic periods, then something else has to adjust. For example, consider the case of an economic 146 downturn with rising unemployment; during such a period the ratio of beneficiaries to workers (i.e., Nb/Nw) will rise. If there are no resources available other than payroll taxes (i.e., there is no trust fund) in the short term to meet benefit obligations and if the ratio of average benefits to average covered wages (i.e., B/W) is to remain constant, the tax rate has to increase as unemployment rises. If, however, the tax rate is to be held constant, as the ratio of beneficiaries to workers rises, it mav be necessary to hold benefit increases below levels that would otherwise be provided automatically. Neither raising taxes nor lowering benefits has been seriously proposed as the logical policy response to recessions. Nonetheless, short-term Social Security financing stability, based on the simple mathematics of the program, will require such measures if alternative provisions are not made. The long-term time frame provides a bit more flexibilitv but a problem of greater magnitude. The tax rate (i.e., "t") in equation 2 equals the ratio of beneficiaries to workers times the ratio of average benefits to average wages. Under current law the ratio of beneficiaries to workers is expected to rise markedly. The analysis in the prior section of this chapter has shown that the average ratio of benefits to wages is projected to stabilize. Both phenomena are expected to occur shortly after the turn of the centurv. Under the 1982 Trustees Report II-A assumptions, there is a projected OASI trust fund accumulation at the end of the 1980s and throughout the 1990s. This accumulation could help to buffer the effect of the babv-boom retirements for a while, but is not sufficient to fully absorb it over the long term. Under the II-B assumptions, the OASI trust fund is not projected to recover from its current shortterm deficiency. If part of the DI tax rate were reallocated, because that program apparently is slightly overfunded, the problem would be less severe but would not go away. The HI trust fund will itself be running substantial negative balances under current law long before the baby-boom generation reaches retirement age. The long-term financing options are bounded bv Social Security's mathematics. Tax rates can be raised but there is a serious question of how far. The ratios of beneficiaries to workers can be affected bv benefit eligibility criteria and work incentives, but the growing role of pensions and their own retirement incentives may significantly dampen the effects of modifications to Social Security. The wage base can be raised in several wavs and the overall benefit structure can be modified, but these actions mean either higher taxes or lower benefits for participants. Finally, alternative sources of revenue might be tound, but there are no "free" revenues to be had. 147 Each of the potential short- or long-term solutions to Social Security's financing problems is going to be somewhat controversial. The policy question is how to balance the equation in a reasonable fashion. General Policy Considerations--Historically, Social Security policy has attempted to balance the countervailing goals of adequacy and equity through its financing and benefit structure. Until recently this process has been relatively uncontroversial because virtually all beneficiaries have received, or could expect to receive, benefits that substantially exceed the value of their contributions. The days are quickly passing when all members of each retiring cohort of workers can expect to receive more than the value of their combined employeremployee payroll tax contributions. The future balance of adequacy and equity has to be considered in the framework of a broader set of priorities. Two additional and equally important policy goals for Social Security are solvency and public support. If these goals are not met, adequacy and equity considerations will become moot. The question of Social Security's solvency has gravely shaken the confidence of old and young alike. Many elderly beneficiaries fear their monthly benefits will be cut off, and many young workers do not believe the program will even exist when they reach retirement age. Without confidence that the program is solvent, continued support will wither. These intergenerational concerns about Social Security link the short- and long-term considerations. The policymakers seek solvency with total disregard for either adequacy or equity. There is public agreement, cutting across the entire political spectrum, that retirees must not be ravaged by program modifications. There is a general understanding, however, that many of today's retirees lead financially secure and comfortable lives. While it may not be as generally understood, it is a fact that current retirees receiving Social Security are getting benefits relative to their final earnings, even after adjusting for inflation, that are much higher than the benefits earlier cohorts of retirees received or those that workers who will retire in the future can expect. Figure V- 1 clearly shows of the benefit changes during the 1970s on average workers; were practically the same for low- and high-wage workers is not just beneficiaries who have retired since 1970 who the effects the effects as well. It have ben- efited, because the large increases for people already retired the 1970 to 1972 period raised their benefits comparably. 148 during FIGURE V-I Replacement of Preretirement Worker Retiring at Age 65, Earnings for Average by Year of Retirement Percent 6O 5O 40 30 I I I I t l i 1955 1960 1965 1970 Year 1975 1980 1985 1990 Source: Office of the Actuary, Social Security Administration. The linking of Social Security benefits to price increases in the 1970s insulated retired people from the major source of income erosion-the risk of inflation. This linkage occurred at a time when the shock of energy price increases had started to reverberate throughout the economy. Workers were not so insulated, and they have experienced real declines in earnings. The wringing out of inflation, furthermore, has not only reduced workers' wages in real terms; in many instances it has also taken their jobs. In addition, there is a growing concern that young workers who must support the program may not receive a fair return from Social Security when they retire. The analysis in chapter I showed that under currently legislated tax rates and benefit schedules, some workers in the future can expect to get back less from Social Security than the value of their employer-employee contributions. The perception that some workers may not get their "money's worth" out of Social Security has already led some critics to conclude that the program should be radically reconfigured or phased out. 149 Focusing just on rates of return to Social Security provides a relatively narrow perspective on retirement policy, but it is a perspective that has been encouraged by the development of Social Security policy which historically has often been made in a vacuum. The fact is that more than 90 percent of wage and salary workers with earnings above the maximum taxable earnings base are participating in an employer pension program. 5 Although some young workers may face low or negative returns on their Social Security contributions, these will tend to be earners in the upper-middle or high-wage brackets. Among such workers, pension coverage is most prevalent and the probability of receiving a pension is the highest. Such workers would also be likely to set up an IRA or to participate in a CODA during their working lives. Employer contributions to tax-qualified pension plans are not taxed until benefits are paid. Furthermore, the interest accruals on employer or employee contributions are not taxed as income until distribution, either. IRA and CODA accumulations and the interest accruing to such accounts are also taxed at distribution. In each case the tax code allows the distribution of benefits to be taken over a period of time or averaged over a number of years to minimize the amount of taxes paid on these retirement accumulations. In most instances, a person's income level after retirement will be lower than prior to retirement, so the marginal and average tax rates applied to retirement distributions are generally lower than they would have been if the income had been paid and taxed during the worker's career. This preferential tax treatment makes each of these vehicles more effective for middle- and upper-income workers than they would otherwise be. To focus only on low rates of return on Social Security for persons participating in other retirement programs ignores the added retirement benefits provided through other components of the federal tax system. Yet the continuing tax treatment of pensions is uncertain. In a recent book, Alicia Munnell, a Vice-President of the Boston Federal Reserve Bank, called for the taxation of pension accruals or complete elimination of tax concessions for employer retirement programs. 6 Merton Bernstein, a law professor at Washington University in St. Louis, Missouri, argued in 1980 that the tax concessions to pensions should be phased out and the added tax revenues be used "toward SSylvestcr J. Schieber and Patricia M. George, Retirement Income Opportunities in an Aging America: Coverage and Benefit Entitlement (Washington, D.C.: EBRI, 1981), p. 41. _'Alicia H. Munnell, The Economics ings Institution, 1982), p. 59. 150 o[ Private Pensions (Washington, D.C.: The Brook- meeting the needs of the Social Security system. ''7 Bernstein, now a consultant to the National Commission on Social Security Reform, has more recently written: "The voluntary nature of private plans and the quite unpredictable patterns of employment make the coverage and benefit results of private plans difficult to predict. ''8 Certainly the future of pensions cannot be precisely predicted, but neither can the future of Social Security, as it now exists. The pension coverage rates that prevail today and the maturing of plans discussed in chapter II suggest that the percentage of elderly people receiving pension benefits in the future will be significantly higher than now unless there is a radical change in tax policy. If the tax concessions to pensions were eliminated, the future prospects for supplemental retirement programs would be greatly diminished. Administrative costs and regulatory compliance requirements would cause manv employers to eliminate their plans. It would be cheaper for them to pay the benefits to workers in the form of direct salary. If such a policy were to be implemented, the Social Security money's worth issue would become far more credible and sharpen young workers' hostility toward the program. Meeting the combined Social Security goals of adequacy, equity, solvency, and support suggests a sharing of the adjustment burden. In seeking short-term solutions, policymakers should keep in mind the long-term implications and vice versa. Short-Term Policy Options If the OASI, DI, and HI trust funds were combined, there is a slim possibility that the combined payment schedule could be met until the OASI financing picture improves after 1990 but the HI picture gets much worse then. To do nothing in the hope that the program "might" survive the short-term problem would be a serious error. The erosion of confidence in Social Security since 1972 suggests there is a limit to what the public will take. The potentialpublic displeasure from a policy ofdoing nothing and being wrong is far greater than the hostility that wiU result as actual adjustments are made along with an assurance the problems are being solved. Taking action inadequate to solve the problems will also further erode confi'dence in the system. 7Merton C. Bernstein, "Social Security: America's Bcst Bet," prepared statement to the President's Commission on Pension Policy, March 13, 1980,p. 6. SMerton C. Bernstcin, "Problem Areas in Private Pensions and State and Local Government Pensions," General Memorandum, National Commission on Social Security Reform (May 4, 1982),p. 1. 151 In view of the fact that HI is on an inexorable path to its own financing crisis, the HI trust fund should not be used to meet shortterm OASI financing beyond the current borrowing period. The DI fund has only limited excess reserves, but these should not be reduced below a level to get it through a worst-case scenario. Solving the OAS1 problem by creating or exacerbating problems in the other two programs is not a solution. If these restrictions are accepted then it is fairly easy to define the policy options. At the beginning of this chapter the revenue and benefits sides of Social Security were defined mathematically. For the sake of describing policy options these will be considered separately. Equation 4 is derived from equation 1 with a significant modification and describes the revenue side (R) of Social Security as follows: (4) R = T + (t-NoW) Equation 4 differs from equation 1 by the addition of "T," which represents the potential infusion of general tax revenues. Action by Congress could affect each of the variables on the right side of the equation. The way in which each can be manipulated is discussed separately. General Revenue Financing--Congress could infuse general revenue into the OASI fund either directly or indirectly. It could do so directly by appropriating funds to Social Security or by allowing the trust fund to borrow from the general fund. In the latter case there would be a question of whether repayment would ever be made. Under the 1982 Trustees Report II-B assumptions, the OASI trust fund would remain in deficit beyond 1983 in all years projected under current law. Under the II-B scenario, the general revenue borrowing to get OASI through the short term would never be fully repaid. Alternatively, general revenues could be indirectly infused into the OASI trust fund by financing part or all of HI through the general fund and reallocating the released payroll tax revenues to OASI. The problem with infusing general revenues into Social Security at this time is that there are no surplus general revenues, only general deficits. On the basis of preliminary July 1982 economic assumptions the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) projects the total federal deficits to be between $160 and $180 billion in each of the next three fiscal years. 9 There have been several proposals submitted to Congress 9Alice M. Rivlin, prepared statement before the National Commission on Social Security Reform. August 20, 1982, p. 2. 152 to take Social Security out of the unified budget in order to remove the OASDHI financing debate from budgetary debate. Yet in a glaring contradiction, some advocates of removing Social Security from the unified budget also advocate general revenue infusions into the program. Such a combined policy would unquestionably put Social Security in the budget battle because any general revenue contributions to the trust funds would adversely affect the resulting budgetary balance whether they were paid out in OASDHI benefits or not. In short, the surest way to get Social Security in the budget battle is to provide general revenue financing. Raising Payroll Tax Rates--Under current taw the OASDHI payroll tax rate is scheduled to rise to 7.05 percent of taxable payroll on both employers and employees on January 1, 1985. The rate is to rise to 7.15 percent in 1986 and to 7.65 percent in 1990. If the 1985 and 1986 increases were moved forward to 1984, CBO projects additional trust fund revenues of $10.8 billion in 1984 and $6.2 billion in 1985; moving to the 7.65 percent rate in 1984 would generate increased revenues of $22.8 billion in 1984 and $23.3 billion in 1985) 0 Raising payroll taxes may be required as a partial solution to the short-term financing problem. This course almost certainly would be resisted by those political factions that have fought vigorously for tax reductions in recent years. Increasing the tax liabilities of both employers and their workers might be opposed bv a broad economic coalition as well. Expandi_g Coverage--Congress can increase the number of workers who are paying the payroll tax bv legislating coverage of workers now exempt from Social Securitv. There are now approximately 2.5 million federal civilian employees, 3 million state and local workers, and roughly 500,000 to 1 million employees of private, nonprofit organizations who are not covered by the program on the basis of their current employment. The potential revenues for the Social Security trust funds that would result from expanded coverage would be significant. Coverage of new federal civilian workers hired after January 1, 1983, would generate $9.6 billion in additional revenues during the first five vears. II Covering all federal workers more than ten vears t°Ibid., p. 15. ItSvlvester J. Schieber, "The Cost and Funding Implications of Modifying the Civil Service Retirement System" (Washington, D.C.: EBRI, 1982),p. 20. 153 from normal retirement on that date would result in additional OASDHI revenues exceeding $35 billion in the first five years. Coverage of all nonprofit employees on that date would result in added tax collections of more than $6 billion within five years. Coverage of new state and local employees hired after January 1, 1985 would add contributions of more than $13 billion before 1990.12 The argument has been put forward that mandatory universal coverage would be a further expansion of a program that is already beyond its limits. Actually, less than 20 percent of the approximately 6 million workers now in noncovered employment will never receive Social Security benefits; these workers constitute only 1 percent of the current work force. The other 80 percent will eventually take covered employment. Although universal coverage would significantly increase the base of covered earnings it would have little effect on the number of workers who become covered during their working careers. The issue of expanded coverage is more than a financing issue. It goes right to the heart of the equity of the Social Security program. The redistributive aspect of Social Security subsidizes people with periods of noncovered employment who ultimately receive OASDI benefits. During 1980 more than 80 percent of Civil Service Retirement annuitants over age sixty-five were also receiving OASDI benefits. The subsidies they receive because of the vagaries of Social Security were never meant to be perpetuated. The issues surrounding the coverage expansion debate are quite complex and are discussed in detail in chapter VII. Rede[i'ning Taxable Wages--There are two basic methods by which the payroll tax treatment of wages could be changed to raise additional revenues. One method would be to raise the taxable maximum earnings level, (1) by eliminating or raising the cap on both employers and workers, or (2) by making total employer payroll subject to the payroll tax. Some policy analysts prefer the latter form of this proposed method because, they argue, benefits would not have to be raised if the earnings base were not raised for workers. The second method of increasing the levels of wages subject to the payroll tax would be to subject nonwage benefits to the payroll tax in one of two ways. One way would be to count some or all of the nonwage components in employee benefits as wages for payroll tax 12Sylvester J. Schieber, "Universal Benefits and Costs" (Washington, 154 Social Security Coverage D.C.: EBRI, 1981), p. 20. and Alternatives: The purposes. Conceptually, there are overwhelming attribution problems if this were to be accomplished, but even if that objective were set aside such a policy would raise other issues as well. The two largest benefit components in the private sector are pensions and health benefits. In 1980, pension contributions and health benefits premiums probably cost employers in the neighborhood of $100 billion. If this amount could be attributed to individual workers, their taxable incomes would rise. This attribution would have no effect on the payroll tax liabilities of workers with incomes above the taxable maximum, but for lower- and middle-income workers, the attribution would mean added tax liabilities without any change in effect, this would amount to a tax increase for the least afford it. Such a redefinition of wages would erable opposition, especially in light of the fact employees do not even pay Social Security taxes laries. pretax income. In people who could meet with considthat many public on their basic sa- The second method proposed to capture nonwage benefits would be to index the payroll tax rate to account for growth in such benefits. Under this proposal, if nonwagc benefits grow as a percentage of total compensation paid to workers, the payroll tax rate would be automatically increased to keep total payroll tax collections a constant percentage of total compensation. Since different levels of benefits are provided to workers, the inequity of such a proposal should be easy to see. The most inequitable aspect of such a policy is that it would hit hardest the low-wage worker who often doesn't receive such benefits at all. Social Security Benefit specifies the expenditure can be stated as follows: Adjustments--The right side of equation position of the Social Security program. 1 It (5) E - Nb-B The expenditure level (E) can be controlled bv varying either the number of beneficiaries (Nb) or the average benefit levels (B). It is unlikely that anyone would seriously consider any policy option that would significantly affect the number of OASI beneficiaries in the short term. It is also unlikely that Congress would reduce monthly benefit levels to current recipients or significantly redefine benefit entitlements for persons who will retire in the near future. Indexing--Several short-term proposals to slow the projected growth in benefits would modify the benefit indexation procedures on either a one-time or short-period basis. Table V-6 shows CBO's estimated 155 TABLE Social V-6 Security Outlay Savings Under Cost-of-Living Adjustments by Fiscal Year Different Total 1983 (Billions) Eliminate 1983 COLA 1984 (Billions) 1985 (Billions) 1983-1985 (Billions) $2.2 $9.2 $9.5 $20.9 Delay COLAs from July to October 2.2 2.1 2.8 7.1 Cap COLAs at 4 percent 0.6 2.7 4.4 7.7 Set COLAs at growth in wages minus 1.5 percentage points _ 0.2 0.9 0.9 2.0 Source: Congressional Budget Office. _This option would result in small savings in outlays in the short term because of projected low productivity growth. Over the longer term, however, outlays could be either higher or lower than under current law, depending upon the relative behavior of wages and prices. savings under some of these options. Given the assumptions, the complete elimination of the 1983 COLA would be the most effective of the options considered in the table. Concerns about adequacy of benefits for people at the bottom of the income scale may dictate that at least some incremental benefits be provided. Given the high rates of return on contributions and high replacement of final earnings for current beneficiaries, a dollar cap on indexed benefits might allow full assurance of inflation protection for the more needy. At the same time it would provide limited savings by slowing the growth of higherlevel benefits. Taxing Benefi'ts--Another alternative would provide for the taxation of Social Security benefits as regular income. The increased general revenues would be earmarked to be paid back to the Social Security trust funds. There are several variants of this proposal. The most extreme would treat all Social Security cash benefits regular income. If both OASI and DI benefits were taxed and revenues earmarked, Social Security actuaries have estimated long-term additional revenues at "roughly" payroll. If only the OASI benefits were treated 156 1.4 percent as regular as the the of covered income, the additional trust fund revenue would be roughly 1.2 percent of payroll. 13 One argument against this approach is that employee payroll taxes are not themselves deductible for purposes of computing income taxes. The employer contribution is a business expense and is not taxed. Thus, although some of the contribution has not been taxed, treating all benefits as regular income would amount to double taxation of employee contributions. This criticism has led to consideration of a second variant that would treat only benefits in excess of employee contributions as regular income. This would bring the tax treatment of Social Securitv benefits in line with tax policy on other retirement programs. Employer pension benefits, for example, are taxed when benefits paid exceed employee contributions that were taxed in the vear that thev were earned. For most beneficiaries, the full benefit would be treated as regular income within two years after thev retire. A third variant would treat onlv 50 percent of cash benefits as regular income lot tax purposes. The argument for this approach is that the employee has already paid taxes on half the contributions that result in the benefit entitlement. This proposal would have little or no effect on those beneficiaries who rely solev on Social Securitv for their retirement income securitv. This option would generate additional long-term trust fund revenues of 0.5 percent of covered payroll if onlv OASI benefits were included and 0.6 percent if DI benefits were included as well. 14 If this proposal were implemented on Januarv 1, 1983, CBO estimates that added tax revenue would reach $4.5 billion in 1983, and $6.5 and $7.0 billion in the two succeeding years. 15 The taxation of Social Securitv benefits has met with considerable political opposition in the past and probably would be seriouslv contested if it were proposed for the future. Several considerations, however, mav make such a policy seem more reasonable. First, treating 50 percent of benefits as regular income would affect the level of benefits only for higher-level beneficiaries. For a single person over age sixty-five and thus receiving a double exemption, the tax would not affect anvone receiving a monthh' benefit below $716 if Social Security were their onlv source of income. For married couples in _3Steve Goss, "Rough, Preliminary Social Security' Monthly Benefii Transfer ot Additional Revenues Security" _41bid. Administration, October Estimates of Long-Range Cost Impact ot Subjecting Pavments to Federal Income Tax with Provision for to OASDI Trust Funds," O[t:icc o[ the Actuary, Social 26, 1982. t_Alice M. Rivlin, prepared statement bclorc curity RetotIn, August 20, 1982, p. 15. the National Commission on Social Se- 157 which both spouses were age sixty-five or over, this tax would not affect monthly benefits below $1,233 where Social Security was the sole source of income. Taxing Social Security benefits would also reduce the level of "tax expenditures" going to pension plans because it would raise the marginal tax rates on annuitants, especially those receiving particularly generous benefits. Furthermore, in the short term, treating half of Social Security benefits as regular income would be nearly as effective-raising $18 billion in the first three years--as completely eliminating the 1983 COLA, which would save an estimated $21 billion over the three-year period. Completely eliminating the COLA increment in 1983 would definitely raise official poverty rates among the elderly and would be widely opposed on those grounds. But taxing half of the Social Security benefits of the elderly would have virtually no effect on the elderly with lower to middle incomes. Selecting Short=Term Policies Tying the COLA increment to wages on some basis should be seriously considered because it would eliminate one major element of instability that now persists in the program. Although tying COLA to wages might slightly reduce the incremental benefits provided in the future, the effects of the linkage would be so diffuse as to be unnoticeable by the average beneficiary. If in fact we are now entering a period in which wage growth will exceed price increases by more than 1.5 percent, as some analysts suspect, this may be a most propitious time to accomplish such a policy change. If real wages grow more rapidly than expected moving to such a COLA procedure could actually increase benefits slightly in the near term. This would be a small price to pay to stabilize the program for the longer term. If Congress wishes to maintain Social Security on "automatic pilot," the indexation signal that it follows has to be steady. Even if the change to wage growth minus 1.5 points does reduce benefits slightly, the added peace of mind that current and prospective beneficaries would gain from the knowledge that the program is solvent would more than offset the pain of the reductions. Beyond this, if Congress decides to "share the pain" of balancing OASI financing in the short term, the burden will be more evenly distributed than will be the case if one particular group is singled out to bear the full burden. For example, table V-7 shows a set of five modifications that could be made that would move toward eliminating 158 the deficits the OASI trust fund is now incurring. Some mar- 159 ginal reallocation of the DI trust fund build up now projected would further help the OASI fund to accumulate a sufficient hedge against future unforeseen circumstances. There are other combinations of options that can be considered but exempting any one group from the burden of adjustment will increase the burden on other segments of society. It may seem unfair not to capture more of the required adjustment through even greater payroll tax increases. It should be kept in mind, however, that taxes already increase automatically as wages grow and the maximum taxable income rises. Furthermore, many of the current workers in the short term, will also feel the longterm program adjustments as well. Long-term policy alternatives must reconcile the possibility of significantly higher tax rates against the level and distribution of benefits in the future. The short-term solution may lead to significant trust fund accumulations toward the end of this decade and through the 1990s; those accumulations could cause broad fiscal problems and increased pressures tbr benefit expansions. The long-term perspective also has to take into account the continuing evaluation of the other retirement income security systems in this country. Because the long-term Social Security dilemma and the various distributional implications of specific proposals are so complex, chapter VI is devoted to the analysis of a range of options. 160 VI. Social Term Security Beyond the Short Chapter V suggests that in the long term, either revenues must rise or benefits be reduced if the Social Security mathematical equation is to be balanced. Some analysts argue that conditions may be much better after the turn of the century than current projections indicate and that it is premature to make adjustments to Social Security now in an attempt to balance the system in the future. Merton Bernstein, for example, argues that increased immigration, higher productivity, and the prospects of higher labor-force participation bv the clderlv may render the long-term problem moot. I Other analysts argue that we should attempt to balance the system now based on current projections, and let Congress reexpand the system later if conditions warrant. 2 One apparent problem with ignoring the long-term financing deficits in Social Security will be the difficulty of reestablishing the credibility of the program with today's young workers. The widespread fear that Social Security will not be there for them will persist unless something is done. Whether or not the traditional meaning of bankruptcy is appropriate when applied to Social Security, the term will be applied to the program if deficits are projected. From the original report of the Committee on Economic Security in 1935, through the first forty years of operation there were always adequate financing provisions in the Social Security program to meet the projected benefit schedules. To modify that funding policy now would represent a significant change in the tradition of the program. Social Security Benefits Under Current Law During the debate over the structure of Social Security in 1976 and 1977, there was widespread agreement that the automatic cost-Qfliving adjustment process established under the 1972 amendments had to be modified. Two major alternatives were put forward and seriously considered. The two differed chiefly in the treatment of covered earnings used to calculate retirees' initial benefits and in the automatic adjustment of the benefit formula. Since 1975, a multitude _Merton C. Bernstein, "Social Security: America's Best Bet," prepared statement to the President's Commission on Pension Policy, March 13, 1980. 2William Hsiao et al., Report oI the Consultant Panel on Social Security (Washington, D.C.: Congressional Research Service, 1976). 161 of proposals have been put forward to balance Social Security in the long term. Each of these has a set of implications for the structure of Social Security and its redistribution of income. If these implications are to be appreciated, the mechanics of the current system must be understood. Before 1979, when the transition to the formula established by the 1977 amendments began, benefits for most people were calculated on the basis of their average covered earnings since 1950. 3 The 1977 amendments significantly modified the benefit calculation procedures. Instead of using average monthly wages to calculate benefits, each worker's wages were to be adjusted--"indexed"--to account for the historical growth in average earnings levels. For the monthly benefit calculation, however, the modified system still relies on historical wages, which are indexed. These wages are technically referred to as average indexed monthlv earnings (AIME). In addition to modifying the treatment of earnings, the 1977 amendments also changed the benefit formula for deriving the primary insurance amount used to calculate actual benefit entitlements. 4 The benefit formula for deriving the PIA is itself indexed by average wage growth. The benefit formula has three replacement-rate thresholds and each threshold is indexed by wage increases. For people reaching age sixty-two in 1982, the PIA is 90 percent of the first $230 of their AIME, plus 32 percent of the next $1,158, and 15 percent of any remaining AIME above $1,388. The dollar factors, often referred to as the Social Security benefit formula "bend points," are indexed, but the percentage factors remain constant over time. The PIA is adjusted to account for age at retirement plus any dependent benefits in determining the monthly benefit amount. The actual benefit paid to the individual recipient and his or her dependents is complicated to derive, because it is subject to a great many variables, as the discussion in appendix B attests. Some analysts perceive the calculation procedure as a Rube Goldberg device greatly in need of simplification. Nonetheless, the calculation procedure does define a benefit structure now in operation, and it helps to define a set of proposals that various students of the system have 3people with a long history of low earnings have their benefits calculated under the "special minimum" method. In addition, a limited number of retirees' benefits are alternatively calculated under the "old start" method which accounted |or covered earnings prior to 1951,if it results in a higher benefit level. 4A detailed description of the benefit calculation procedure is included in appendix B. That discussion also describes the way in which earnings and the benefit formula bend points are indexed to account for annual wage growth. 162 made to balance its projected financing shortfalls. Some of these proposals antedate the 1977 amendments, while others have arisen during the recent deliberations of the National Commission on Social Security Reform. The Earlier Debate The major alternative to wage indexing of earnings and the formula bend points considered during the deliberations on the 1977 amendments was recommended bv the Hsiao panel in its 1976 report to the Senate Finance and House Ways and Means Committees. s The panel suggested that a worker's benefits should continue to be based on the average of that person's earnings history. They argued that historical wages should be adjusted to account for changes in the dollar's purchasing power between the year that wages were earned and the year of retirement. This "price indexing" of wages in combination with price indexation of the PIA formula bend points would protect initial benefit levels against the erosion of inflation and provide slight benefit increases with the growth in real wages. The Hsiao panel also proposed a safety-valve measure that would slow the growth in benefits if prices were to grow more rapidly than wages for a sustained period. If this were to occur, they proposed that the formula bend points and postretiremcnt benefits be indexed by the rate of growth of wages instead of the higher growth in prices. This measure--the lower of wage or price indexation--was to be invoked in instances when the ratio of wage growth to price growth declined in five consecutive years. 6 The debate over the wage-indexing procedures actually implemented bv the 1977 amendments versus the price-indexing recommendation bv the Hsiao panel centered on what each was expected to accomplish. The wage-indexing system sought to maintain Social Security's earnings replacement capacity over time. Because wages are expected to grow more rapidly than prices over time, maintaining replacement rates would mean higher real benefit levels for successive cohorts of retirees. Advocates of the price-indexing mechanism argued that Social Security should strive to grant "nearly equal purchasing power to comparable workers who retire at different times. ''7 _William Hsiao et al., Report D.C.: Congressional Research °Ibid., p. 6l. 7Ibid., p. 21. of the Ccmsulta_tt Service, 1976). Patzel o_ Social Security (Washington, 163 The policy question Congress faced in 1977 was whether to guarantee the purchasing power of initial Social Security benefits of future cohorts of retirees or to guarantee the replacement of preretirement earnings. Price indexing of wages and PIA formula bend points meant that the real level of benefits would be maintained for workers with the same real lifetime covered earnings. It also meant that Social Security would replace smaller percentages of the preretirement earnings for successive cohorts of retirees. The wage-indexing procedure actually implemented sought to guarantee replacement rates over time. Hence, as workers with equal real lifetime covered earnings reach retirement in successively later years, those retiring later will receive consistently higher real benefits than the workers who preceded them into retirement. This occurs because real average earnings for all workers are expected to grow over time. The Hsiao panel came down in favor of price indexing because it provided Congress with greater discretionary, power over the program. They argued: Congress would do best if it were to recognize that a fully automatic system is a less desirable goal than is a partly automatic system that embraces a limited objective and leaves to the future the key decision on how far beyond that limited objective the financial condition of the country and of the system itself will permit. An important implication is that this leaves Congress the flexibility to decide how the increase should be divided among different classes of beneficiaries, reflecting the social needs of the time. 8 This issue reappeared in the deliberations of the 1979 Social Security Advisory Council, two years after the passage of the 1977 amendments. The majority of the 1979 Advisory Council favored continued wage indexation, but five of thirteen members dissented on this recommendation. They proposed that starting in 1995, each successive cohort of retirees with the same real earnings history should receive the same real benefit. They argued that implementation of this proposal would leave to later Congresses the power: (1)to determine whether higher levels of real earnings warranted higher levels of real benefits; and (2) to impose the higher taxes needed to support them. Their proposal was based on two premises: Our first reason is based on our judgment that future Congresses will be better equipped than today's Congress to qbid., p. 22. 164 determine the appropriate level and composition of benefits for future generations. We fully anticipate that later Congresses would indeed elect to increase real benefits as real wage levels rise over time. We doubt, however, that thev would choose to do so in the precise wav implied bv the present method of automatic adjustment, nor that the average percentage increase would necessarily be the same as present law prescribes. Congress might elect to give more to certain groups of beneficiaries than to others, or to provide protection against new risks that now are uncovered, But precisely because we cannot now forecast what form those desirable adjustments might take, we feel that the commitment to large increases in benefits and taxes implied undcr current law will deprive subsequent Congresses, who will be better int0rmed about future needs and preferences of needed flexibility to tailor Social Security to the needs and tastes of the generations to come. Our second reason is that, as per capita income rises, the case tot increasing the amount of mandatory "saving" for retirement and disability through Social Security is far weaker than was the rationale for establishing a basic floor of retirement and disability protection at about the levels that exist today. 9 Opponents of the price indexing of wagcs argue that it puts in place an ever-decreasing rates if wages do grow more rapidly in the argue that future increase and that ards dexing of living and the benefit formula structure of replacement future than prices. They standards of living will be adjusted as real earnings Social Security should help to maintain those stand- for future cohorts of retirecs. Proponents of price in- respond: At levels of real income prevailing in the 1930s (or perhaps even in the 1950s), it can well be argued that it was appropriate, indeed, highly' desirable--perhaps even necessary for the preservation of our society--that government should, bv law, have guaranteed to the aged and disabled and their dependents replacement income sufficient to avoid severe hardship, and to have required workers (and their employers) to finance this system with a kind of "forced saving" through payroll tax contributions. But as real incomes continue to rise, it is not so easy to justify' the requirement that '_Henrx' J. Aaron, Gardner Ackley, Mar,,' C. Falvey, John W. Porter, and J. W. Van Gorkom, "Supplementacy Statement in the Future Course of the Replacement Rate," in Social Secllrit 3' Financing and BeHel}ts (Report of the 1979 Social Security Advisory Council, 1979), pp. 213 214. 165 workers and their employers "save" through payroll tax contributions to finance ever higher replacement incomes, far above those needed to avoid severe hardship. I° The implications of the different benefit determinations are significant in the context of the mathematics of Social Security discussed in chapter V and the long-term financing projections discussed in chapter IV. The second column in table VI-I shows currently legislated OASDI tax rates minus the projected cost rates in the 1982 Trustees Report based on their Alternative II-B assumptions lot various averaging periods. The OASDI program is projected to run a surplus of 0.64 percent of covered payroll for the first twenty-five years. For each of the subsequent twenty-five-year periods and the full seventy-five-year period, the current tax rate falls short of meeting the cost rate of the program. The third column in table VI-I shows the net savings of moving to price indexation of earnings and the benefit formula bend points starting in January 1985 under the II-B assumptions. In each of the two twenty-five-year periods t0r which there are financing deficits, and tot the full seventy-five-year projection period, the movement to price indexing of both earnings and formula bend points for benefit calculation would seem to more than balance the long run OASDI financing. Before we immediately proceed to that conclusion, however, a word of caution is in order. Under the II-B assumptions, real wage growth is assumed in every year beyond 1982. The ultimate rate of growth of real wages is assumed to be 1.5 percent (i.e., wages are assumed to grow faster than prices at a rate of 1.5 percent per year over the long term). If wages grow more slowly in real terms or if prices grow as fast or faster than wages for sustained periods, then moving to benefit determination on a price-indexing basis will save less than these projections estimate. The reason for the cost savings under these assumptions is that in the future, initial benefit entitlements will grow less rapidly than earnings. This would cause the ratio of average benefits to average earnings (B/W), discussed in chapter V, to decline over time. The rate of decline of B/W under II-B scenarios would more than offset the rate of increase of beneficiaries to workers (Nb/Nw) in the financing equation. As a result, the long-term projected cost rate would fall below legislated tax rates if price indexing of earnings and formula bend points were implemented and the II-B scenario were realized. TABLE VI-I OASDI Financing Surplus and Deficit Under II-B Assumptions and Net Savings as a Percentage of Payroll from Moving to Price Indexing of Earnings and Bend Points Surplus or ofDeficit Annual WageIndexed System Both Earnings and Bend Points Earnings Only Bend Points Only 25- Year Averages 1982 2006 2007-2031 2032 2056 .64 1.68 - 4.41 0.27 2.76 5.45 0.14 1.20 1.85 0.14 1.81 4.13 75- Yea r Average 1982-2056 - 1.82 2.83 1.06 2.03 Sources: Note: Price-Indexing 1982 OASDI Trustees Report, p. 64; and Office of the Actuary, Social Security Administration, September 2, 1982. The estimates are based on the 1982 Trustees Report Alternative II-B assumptions, modified to reflect the actual 1982 benefit increase of 7.4 percent. The linking to the consumer price index begins in all cases in 1983, first affecting benefits in 1985. Options for Modifying Social Security's Procedures The Option prospect of continually declining Benefit Calculation replacement rates and the magnitude of cost savings from price indexing both earnings and bend points has led to a set of hybrid price-indexing proposals and other possible formula modifications. These would provide some long-term savings, but less than those shown in table VI-1 for price indexing both earnings and formula bend points. The following paragraphs briefly describe the options for modifying the current procedures for calculating Social Security benefits. Index Earnings by Price Increases--One proposal would index torical earnings bv the price index but continue to index the points on the benefit formula bv the rate of increase in wages. indexing earnings would result in somewhat lower replacement final earnings than the current procedure of earnings indexing Under long-term assumptions of constant increases in prices and hisbend Price of does. wage 167 growth, both the current benefit calculation procedure and this option would result in stable replacement rates. The long term, however, is made up of a series of short-term periods. Over the years, the relative growth of wages and prices has varied considerably from year to year. These variations would result in different weighting patterns for historical annual earnings tot each worker when that person reaches age sixty-two. Thus, the change in the treatment of earnings would result in different distributions of AIMEs, and thus a different distribution of Social Security benefits, based on actual lifetime earnings patterns. The net savings from the option shown in table VI-I, if implemented in January 1985, is insufficient to reduce the projected cost rate in either the second or third twenty-five-year period to meet the projected shortfall in those periods. It also falls 0.76 percent of payroll short of meeting the seventy-five-year average cost rate projected under the II-B assumptions. This option would be sensitive to the correspondence with actual growth in wages and prices. If real wages grow more slowly than assumed over the long-term projection period, this option would result in smaller savings than projected. Index Formula Bend Points by Price Increases--Another variant of the Hsiao panel's recommendation would continue to index wages by the rate of average wage growth but index bend points in the benefit formula by price increases. The twenty-fiveand seventy-fiveyear projected savings under the II-B assumption set are also shown in table VI-1. The projected savings in the second twenty-five-year period exceed the projected shortfall under the II-B assumptions. In the third twenty-five-year period, the savings are within roughly 0.3 percent of payroll of meeting the projected cost. For the seventy-fiveyear projection period the savings would be sufficient, however, if the II-B scenario is realized. Of the three price-indexing options, this one would be most sensitive to the relative rates of price and wage increases. If wages rise more rapidly than 1.5 percent in excess of prices, the savings would exceed those projected. At the same time, this option would result in gradually declining replacement rates if the II-B scenario occurs. This decline of replacement rates would accelerate during periods in which wages grow more rapidly relative to prices than assumed. During a period of sustained price growth in excess of wage growth, however, replacement rates would rise at the worst possible time. As a result, average benefits would rise relative to average wages (i.e., increasing the B/W ratio discussed in chapter V). 168 Options fi)r Limiting Replacement-Rate Reductions--The concern over perpetually declining replacement rates and the prospect of introducing new volatility to the program have led to consideration of options that would limit the adjustments. These options would modify the rate of growth in the formula bend points for a limited period of time. Rapid Bend-Point Adfl_stment [or Limited Period--Koitz considered freezing the bend points until the long-term cost rate of the OASDI system fell to the level of the long-term tax rate contained in current legislation. Based on assumptions being used in the program's valuation in 1980, the Social Security actuaries estimated that the bendpoint freeze would have to last three years. If the freeze were to last three years, the actuaries also estimated that the ultimate replacement rates for the hypothetical average worker would decline from approximately 42 percent of final earnings to 39 percent. _] In May of 1981, the Reagan administration proposed reducing bendpoint indexing to a rate of 50 percent of wage growth for a six-year period, beginning in 1982 and running through 1987. While this proposed reduction to bend-point growth was only half the reduction considered by Koitz, applying it twice as long resulted in similar savings and replacement-rate reductions. Any adjustment of the Social Security benefit formula will affect several dimensions of the program. The relatively rapid adjustment of Social Security replacement rates downward would certainly raise serious equity questions, regardless of when it was done. These questions would be especially appropriate if people retiring in the immediate future incurred such replacement-rate reductions, because people retiring during the 1970s and early 1980s have already received much higher replacement of earnings than future retirees can now expect. A further argument is that people near retirement have defined expectations of Social Security. Being near the end of their careers, they cannot adjust sufficientlv to significant changes in their benefit entitlements and may end up with inadequate incomes throughout their retirement. Slow Bend-Point Growth Gradually on a Limited Basis--Both ade- quacy and equity considerations suggest that caution should prevail in implementing a long-term solution to the Social Security financing ItDavid Koitz, "The Indexing of Social Security" in lndexatio_zo[ Federal Programs (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1981),p. 190. 169 problem. Still, if the program is to get the level of public support it requires, people must perceive that the program will be solvent over the long term. To this end, Robert J. Myers has presented an option to the National Commission on Social Security Reform that would reduce replacement rates gradually over a number of years. 12 Under this option, the bend points in the PIA formula would be indexed at 75 percent of the rate of growth of wages for a limited number of years. Myers has described the effects of slowing bend-point growth in this fashion beginning in 1984 and continuing for either twelve or twenty years. The projected cost savings under the II-B scenarios are shown in table VI-2. Myers notes that the actual cost effects of this proposal will depend on future economic conditions. If real wages were to rise more rapidly than projected under the II-B assumptions, the actual cost reductions would exceed those estimated. At the same time, the level of preretirement earnings replaced by Social Security would decline more than expected. Myers suggests that this decline could be prevented by limiting the decline in the bend points, so they would not fall below 80 percent of the level they would have been if full indexing were continued. Once the 80 percent "trigger" point is reached subsequent bend-point adjustments would be at the full rate of wage growth.13 The implementation of such a procedure would gradually reduce the replacement of preretirement earnings. Limiting the decline as Myers suggests would stabilize replacement rates at a level that could be predetermined. For example, the "80 percent trigger point" that he discusses would reduce ultimate OASDI replacement rates by about 10 percent (Note: not ten percentage points). If the II-B scenario were to actually occur, this decline would be phased in over a sixteen-year period. This proposal has several characteristics that make it more appealing than some of the other long-term options discussed earlier. First, it limits the adjustment in benefits, which will make it much easier for workers and employers to design savings and pension programs to maintain living standards in retirement. Second, it does not depend on the economic scenarios being played out in accord with J2Robert J. Myers, "Possible Solutions to Long-Range Financing Problems of OASDI Program," Memorandum no. 24 (Washington, D.C.: National Commission on Social Security Reform, June 4, 1982), pp. 4-6. _3Robert J. Myers, "Cost Aspects of Indexing OASDI Benefit Formula by 75% of Wage Increases for a Limited Period," Memorandum no. 36 (Washington, D.C.: National Commission on Social Security Reform, July 2, 1982). 170 TABLE VI-2 OASDI Financing Surplus and Deficit Under II-B Assumptions and Net Savings as a Percentage of CoveredPayroll from Indexing PIA Formula Bend Points by 75 Percent of Wage Growth for Specified Periods Net Savings Surplus or Deficit of Current WageIndexed System Period of 75 Percent Bend-Point Indexation 1984-1995 1984-2003 25- Yea r A verab{es 1982-2006 2007 2031 2032-2056 0.64 - 1.68 - 4.41 0.26 1.09 1.36 0.29 1.60 2.10 75- Year Average 1982 2056 - 1.82 0.90 1.33 Sources: 1982 OASDI Trustees Report, p. 64; and Robert J. Myers, "Cost Aspects of Indexing OASDI Benefit FormuLa by 75% of Wage Increases for a Limited Period," Memorandum no. 36 (Washington, D.C: National Commission on Social Security Re|otto, July 2, 1982), p. 3. assumptions, have been which discussed. is a problem The rate in the price indexation options of wage growth will determine rapidly the trigger point is reached. Finally, even during tion to the lower replacement rates, each successive cohort should receive higher benefits in real-dollar terms. Options There for Changing is a valid Work concern and that Retirement any reductions that how the transiof retirees Patterns in Social Security benefits may increase the prevalence of elderly people who live out their retirement years with inadequate incomes. This concern has led to many proposals that seek to extend the period of work, thus increasing tax revenues while decreasing the period of benefit receipt and total lifetime benefits paid to the average retiree. It can be argued that these proposals already discussed. imply a benefit These proposals longer, yet provide benefits into the system for a shorter for extending expectancy with this the working suggest increased reduction similar in size to those seek to keep workers in their jobs comparable or equal to those number of years. Proponents lives potentially longevity of workers argue longer productive phenomenon, these that now built of options increases lives. In proponents in life keeping reason 171 that normal retirement ages should adjust to changing demographics. be adjusted or encouraged to Increase Normal Retirement Ages--In 1981 the National Commission on Social Security (not to be confused with the National Commission on Social Securitv Ret0rm) recommended that Social Security's normal retirement age be gradually increased by three years beginning around the turn of the centurv. The commission proposed raising retirement age by three months per year over a twelve-year period. Table VI-3 shows the exact phasing in of these increases, per their recommendations. There have been several variants of this basic proposal dating back to the 1975 Social Security Advisorv Council. The primary differences in the options that have been suggested relate to the time when the transition would start or the length of the transition period. Robert J. Myers has presented to the National Commission on Social Security Reform an option for automatically adjusting Social Security's retirement ages. This proposal calls for raising the normal retirement age in quarter-year increments to age sixty-six for persons who reach age sixty-two after 1994. Then, in 1995, the longevity improvements reflected in the U.S. Life Tables for 1989-1991 over the 1979-1981 tables would be taken into account for further adjusting the Social Securitv retirement age. The proposal would begin the adjustment seven years after the new longevity levels had been determined. If life expectancy were determined to have increased in 1995, the retirement age would increase in quarter-year increments starting in 2002 for people reaching age sixty-two. The adjustments would continue until life expectancy beyond the normal retirement age was only one-third the number of vears between age twenty and the normal retirement age. In 2005 and every subsequent ten years, the redetermination process would be repeated. Under the II-B demographic assumptions the normal retirement age would reach age sixty-seven in 2005, sixty-eight in 2009, sixty-nine in 2023, and seventy in 2052. As the retirement age rises, the number of years of earnings used to compute benefit entitlements would rise one year for each year's increase in the normal retirement age. j4 Change Actuarial Ad#4slmenl Faclors--A variant of raising ment ages would gradually increase the age at which a retiree retirewould 14RobertJ. Myers, "Cost Aspects of Increasing the Normal Retirement Age Under Social Security by an Aulomatic-Adjustment Method," Memorandum no. 29 (Washington, D.C.: National Commission on Social Securitv Reform, June 28, 1982). 172 TABLE National VI-3 Commission on Social Security Proposal Phasing in Later Retirement Ages Year Age for Full Benefits 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 201 I 2012 65 65 65 65 65-V4 65- % 65-V4 66 66-'/4 66-1/2 66-3/4 67 67-V4 67-1/2 67- V4 68 for Age for Reduced Benefits" 62 62-1/4 62-I/2 62-s/4 63 63-_/4 63-% 63-3/4 64 64-V4 64-1/2 64-s/4 65 65 65 65 Source: National Commission on Social Security, Final Report, Social Security in America's Furore (March 1981), p, 122. increase in the age at which reduced benefits are payable starts three years before increase in the age at which full benefits are payable. Thus, workers in a particular "birth cohort" (age group) who reach age sixty-three in 2001 and age sixtv-six in 2004, tor example, would be affected equally regardless of whether they chose to claim early retirement in 2001 at age sixty-three or full benefits in 2004 at age sixty-six. receive the full PIA. Under current law the PIA is payable to a single person at age sixty-five. The PIA is reduced by five-ninths of 1 percent each month prior to age sixty-five that benefits were accepted. monthly benefit for a person retiring at age sixty-two is only 80 percent of the PIA. Representative J. J. Pickle, Chairman of the House Ways and Means Social Security Subcommittee, has introduced legislation that would raise the age at which the full PIA is payable to sixty-eight. His legislation (H.R. 3207) would also change the reduction factor to oneof 1 percent for each month prior to normal retirement age that benefits were accepted. Although his bill would raise the normal retirement to age sixty-eight, it would leave the early retirement age sixty-two. His legislation specifies a transition mechanism that would require a double benefit calculation. It would calculate a ben173 efit under the current formula for persons retiring in 1990 and after. It would also calculate a benefit under a modified formula that provides the full PIA at age sixty-eight. The PIA for early retirees would be reduced one-half of 1 percent for each month prior to age sixtyeight that the person retired. This would provide 64 percent of the PIA at age sixty-two or a 6 percent reduction for each year of retirement prior to age sixty-eight. The transition from the first formula to the second would be gradual. Persons reaching age sixty-two in 1990 would receive 90 percent of the benefit from the current formula plus 10 percent from the modified formula. The 1991 cohort would receive 80 percent from the current formula and 20 percent from the modified formula. These shares would continue to adjust by 10 percent per year until the transition was complete in 1999, when only the modified formula would be used. Another method of accomplishing the same result would be to implement the new adjustment factors by one quarter per year. The advantage would be that a single benefit formula could be used, thus reducing the administrative complexity of transition. For example, the ultimate actuarial adjustment factors specified in this bill could be implemented over a twelve-year period, as table VI-4 shows. Under this transition mechanism, the normal retirement age would be increased by one quarter per year until it reached age sixty-eight. With each increment in the retirement age the actuarial adjustment factors would change. When the transition is completed, people retiring at age sixty-two would receive 64 percent of their PIAs instead of the 80 percent now provided by the system. One of the arguments in favor of this method of raising the Social Security normal retirement age is that it would continue to provide early retirement benefits at age sixty-two. Opponents of raising the early retirement age in lockstep with the normal retirement age argue that even with increases in the longevity in the future, the prevalence of ill health, disability, and indeterminate economic conditions will require income maintenance programs for some persons in their early sixties. Although people who argue this may not find the Pickle concept to be the optimal solution to Social Security's financing problem, they find it more palatable than other possible changes in the retirement age. If average wages grow at least 1.5 percent a year in real terms during the transition process shown in table VI-4, each successive cohort of retirees at age sixty-two should realize slight benefit growth in real terms. To the extent the added incentives for working longer 174 °_o_ _._! _ E _ _ _'= •=_ _ _ _o_o_o_o_o_o _+ _._ 175 are effective, average monthly benefits for new retirees tinue to rise during the transition period. should con- OASDI Savings with Later Retirement Ages--As with each of the other policy options discussed in this chapter, a primary consideration is the implication of changing policy for OASDI financing. Table VI-5 shows the projected savings from the three retirement age proposals just discussed under the II-B assumptions. None of the options by itself would completely eliminate the long-term financing deficit. According to the actuarial projections, the 1981 proposal by the National Commission to raise early and normal retirement ages by three years is the least effective of the options. The most effective is the automatic adjustment in retirement ages by increasing longevity because, according to the projections, it pushes the normal retirement ages somewhat higher than either of the other proposals. The Pickle bill and its gradual reduction of the actuarial adjustment factors would have about the same net financing effect as indexing the PIA formula bend points by 75 percent of wage growth for sixteen years discussed earlier. None of the retirement-age proposals considered here would match the 2.03 percent of payroll savings projected if PIA formula bend points were indexed by price growth in the future, assuming the II-B scenario is realized. If the only policy concern is to restore financial balance to Social Security then policymakers should simply pick the option that proTABLE VI-5 OASDI Financin_ Surplus and Deficit Under II-B Assumptions and Net Savings as a Percentage of Covered Payroll Following Raising of the Normal Retirement Age Surplus or Deficit of Current System (Percent) 25-Year Averages 1982-2006 Retirement National Commission (Percent) Age Proposal Automatic Adjustment (Percent) Pickle (Percent) 0.64 0.12 0.16 0.21 2007-2031 - 1.68 1.41 1.98 1.40 2032-2056 - 4.41 1.55 2.89 1.89 1.03 1.68 1.17 75- Year Average 1982-2056 Sources: 176 - ! .82 1982 OASD1 Trustees Administration. Report, p. 64; and Office of the Actuary, Social Security vides adequate savings to meet the projected deficit of the system. But, as the discussion thus far in this chapter has indicated, each of these proposals has different impacts across society. Although the goal of assuring Social Security's financial solvencv is paramount, attaining that goal must be accomplished with an eve toward the adequacy and equity aspects of the program. Distributional on Income Implications Levels of Benefit Formula Adjustments To evaluate the implications of various long-run Social Security policy options, the PRISM microsimulation model described in chapter IV was modified |or this pro.icct. The potential range and combination of options that could be simulated is almost infinite. Budget constraints, time limitations, and a limited number of options under serious consideration serve to define a handful of options that were analyzed. Specifically, five alternative modifications to the Social Security benefit determination process were considered: 1. Index uing wage 1985, earnings by the assumed rate of increase in prices while continto index the benefit formula bend points bv the assumed rate of growth. This modification was assumed to begin on January 1, and to continue indefiniteh'. 2. Index the PIA formula bend points bv the assumed ratc of growth in prices while continuing to index historical earnings by the assumed rate of growth in wages. This modification was assumed to begin on January 1, 1985, and to continue indefiniteh'. 3. Index the PIA formula bend points by 75 percent of the assumed rate of growth in wages while continuing to index historical earnings bv the full wage growth assumption. This modification was assumed to begin January I, 1984 and to continue tot sixteen vears. 4. Raise Social Security's early and normal retirement ages by one quarter per year until both Rave been raised by three vears. This was assumed to begin for the cohort of individuals reaching age sixty-two in 1998 and to continue t0r twelve cohorts. Under this proposal bv the National Commission on Social Security, the age for early retirement would reach sixtv-five in 2009 and the age tot normal retirement would reach sixtyeight in 2012. 5. Raise Social Securitv's normal retirement age one quarter per year starting in 1990, andmodifv the earh' retirement actuarial adjustment factors in accordance with the schedule shown in table VI-4. This implementation procedure, which captures the essence of the Pickle proposal, would provide approximately the same cost savings. It is simulated in this way because it simplifies the benefit calculation procedure during the transit ion. 177 Implications o[Modifying the Belle/i't Formula--Three of the simulated modifications maintained the current program's eligibility criteria but modified the benefit calcuRation procedure. As ah'cady noted, anv one of the three modifications could be expected to slow the growth of future initial benefit entitlements. This analysis was undertaken to assess the distribution of the various modifications on the level of Social Security benefits and the income of the elderly in the future. These simulations assumed that people would not change their behavior in response to reduced Social Security benefit levels; that is, the work, savings, and retirement behaviors simulated in the current policy scenario were assumed to persist under each of these alternatives. (It is clear that reduced benefit expectations from Social Security might encourage some people to work longer than they would have under current benefit promises, to save more for their own retirement, or even to find .jobs with better pension protections.) Nor did these simulations of alternative Social Security benefit calculation procedures assume that employers would modify their pension plans in response to reduced benefit levels, Some plans almost certainly will be modified through collective bargaining or in response to employers' desires to maintain target benefit levels. Assuming no behavioral response on the part of workers or employers seemed to provide a conservative perspective. It is unlikely that simply because Social Security benefits grow slightly more slowly that there would be massive changes in behavior that would reduce alternate retirement income resources. If anything, behavior should move in the other direction. Another reason for not assuming behavioral responses to these options was that this course was consistent with Social Security actuaries' assumptions for projecting the cost savings of these options. Finally, as the following analysis suggests, the decline in total income will be somewhat less, on average, than the magnitude of the Social Security reductions. Table VI-6 presents the simulated average family Social Security benefit levels at age sixty-five under four policy scenarios. This reference age of sixty-five is the same as that used in the current policy simulation results discussed in chapter III. In fact, the first column of average benefit levels in table VI-6 repeats the current policy benefit estimates presented in chapter III. The remaining benefit columns reflect the modified estimates based on the three modifications to the benefit calculation procedure. As expected, each of the modifications results in progressively larger benefit reductions for each successive cohort of retirees. The average benefit reductions do not vary greatly when those for married couples 178 _o_ - = __ _ __ 179 are compared with those tor single persons. The main differences can be seen in comparing reductions for cohorts. For the oldest cohort the reduction would be negligible, because most members of lhe oldest cohort would have retired before any of the options were implemented. The baseline age in the simulation was the age of the person in 1979. By 1984, the youngest reference person in the oldest cohort would already be age sixty. Each of the alternative policy options is applied to persons attaining age sixty-two in the first year the new policy is implemented. For the option that would index bend points by 75 percent of growth in wages, the first year of implementation would be 1984. For the other two options, the first year would be 1985. The two different dates were not picked to complicate the analysis but to correspond with the cost projections made by Social Security actuaries. Starting them one year apart has no significant effect in the long-term analysis. The initial benefit reductions are slightly more rapid under the limited wage indexation of the formula bend points than under the other two options, because of the assumed slow growth of real wages during the early years of the simulation. Under the II-B assumptions, wages are assumed to grow only 0.3 percent more than prices in 1985, gradually increasing to 1.5 percent in 1995. Since wages and prices are assumed to grow at roughly the same rate in the early years, little savings result from moving to the price index. Limiting the bendpoint growth to 75 percent of wages, however, virtually guarantees a slowdown in benefit growth, regardless of how wages or prices grow. This variation in the effects on early cohorts points to some of the caveats that policymakers will want to consider in comparing these options. The relationship between wages and prices will determine the effectiveness of either of the price-indexing options. If there is no real wage growth for a sustained period, these options will generate no savings at all. If the rate of price increase exceeds wage growth, the price-indexing bend-point option would increase the costs of the program. Alternatively, if real wages grow more rapidly than expected, limiting bend-point indexation to 75 percent of wages will garner much greater savings and benefit reductions than estimated. This suggests that the trigger mechanism discussed earlier should be given serious consideration. After the early years in the simulation, the situation changes. The limited wage indexing of bend points is applied only between 1984 and 1999. Thus, by the time the two youngest cohorts reach retirement age, the bend points will be growing again by the full rate of wage growth. The price-indexing options, on the other hand, would 180 have their greatest effects on the two younger cohorts. The price indexation of the bend points would have the greatest effect of any of the alternatives considered for the youngest cohort. Under the longterm II-B assumptions, price indexation of the bend points translates to a 70 to 75 percent wage indexation of the formula in perpetuity. Another facet of table VI-6 is important for considering Social Security modifications. The options for changing the benefit calculation procedure are often characterized as benefit reductions. That characterization is correct relative to current law, but the Social Security Act has been an extremely flexible piece of legislation over the years. To assume that the current law or one implemented in 1983 will remain unchanged beyond the turn of the century is not realistic. The simulation results presented in table VI-6 suggest that even if the rates of growth in benefits are slowed for some future period, average real benefits will continue to grow. The Response ofPensions and Other Resotzrces--The analysis in chapter III suggested that the rise in other income resources for the elderly would tend to reduce the share of total income provided by Social Security for future retirees. Table VI-7 shows the results of the pension/IRA benefit estimates under the current policy and under alternative benefit calculation options. The estimated average pension/ IRA benefits actually increase marginally under the options that would cause the largest Social Security benefit reductions. This pension response occurs because of automatically increased benefits from plans that are integrated with Social Security. Because of the prevalence of integrated plans, the pension benefit increases might be expected to be even larger than those projected, but they are restrained bv two factors. First, although the majority of private pension plans in this countrv are integrated with Social Security, the prevalence of integrated plans is highest among small employers; EBRI's analysis of the 1977 pension plan filings with the IRS in compliance with ERISA found that 92.6 percent of all plans had fewer than 100 participants. At the same time, at least 90 percent of all plan participants were in plans covering more than 100 members. The second factor is that many integrated plans, especially those of smaller employers, arc defined-contribution plans. The contribution rates to these plans will not be affected by any modifications to the Social Security benefit formula. Pensions will directly make up some of the difference in Social Security benefits. They will also help to minimize the relative impact 181 _ _ .E _.. E _." _ ._= 182 = -ooo _ooo _ooo dddd dddd dddd oooo oooo 2_2_ of Social Security modifications because they broaden the income base. Table VI-8 shows the simulated combincd average incomc lcvels at age sixty-five from earnings, savings, Social Security', pensions, IRAs, and SSI. The estimated income reductions resulting from various policy changes arc relatively smaller than the Social Security benefit reductions shown in tablc VI-6. The prospect of income reductions of only 3 to 4 percent for elderly people thirty to forty years hence suggests that none of these options has unduly damaging effects. Another wav to interpret table VI-8 is to say that instead of there being a doubling of average family income at age sixty-five between the oldest and youngest cohorts, the average income might go up only 1.9 times if the formula bend points are indexed at the rate of 75 percent of wages over the specified period. Distribzltional Considerations--Before making any decisions about changes to Social Security, policymakers must consider the distributional effects of ahernative policies. Each of the three benefit formula modifications considered here would tend to affect the distribution of benefits in roughly the same way. To simplify' the analysis of the distributional effects of modifying the benefit formula, the discussion that follows focuses only on the option that would index the formula bv 75 percent of wage growth for sixteen vears. Because total Social Security' benefit reductions would be greatest for the youngest cohort in the simulations, the discussion focuses on that group. Table VI-9 breaks down the Social Security benefit reductions based on average family earnings for the "high five" of the prior ten years bcfore agc sixty-five for this group. The largest Social Security benefit reductions occur in the low- and high-income ranges. At the lower end of the income spectrum, benefits are heavily influenced by the 90 percent factor in the PIA formula. Slowing the growth of the portion of AIME affected by the 90 percent factor would slow the growth of benefit levels fairiv directly. The second factor in the formula provides only 32 percent of AIME in monthly benefits at age sixty-five. For each dollar reduction in the AIME treated bv the 90 percent factor the PIA is reduced $0.58. At the top end, basicalh' the opposite occurs. Thc uppermost factor is 15 percent o[ AIME. Slowing down the bend-point growth will push an increasing portion of the high earner's AIME into the low-factor category. For each AIME dollar treated at the lower rate, the higher earner loses $0.17 in the PIA calculation relative to the middle factor. Since the bend point at which the upper factor changes is much larger than the Iowcr factor ($1,388 vs. $230 in 1982), slowing down 183 _ i _° om •184 _ _A._AA_: __ 185 the growth rate would retard the upper factor to a much greater extent. For example, if the 1983 bend points were determined on the basis of 10 percent wage growth, they would grow to $253 and $1,527. If they were augmented by only half the wage growth rate, they would grow to $242 and $1,506. In this example, the slower augmentation would retard the lower factor by only $11 but the upper one by $122. The middle-income worker would lose less than workers at either extreme because most of the AIME is subjected to the middle factor. In short, the low-income workers would lose a lot because the bottom factor is the basis for most of the benefit; the middle-income worker would lose a similar amount on the bottom factor, but the loss would average over a larger benefit from the middle factor; and the highincome worker would lose at both bend points in the formula. Pension benefits increase somewhat across the benefit spectrum, generally more toward the middle of the preretirement earnings distribution than toward either end. Because of the smaller income base at the bottom of the earnings distribution, the Social Security modifications can be expected to have a somewhat greater effect on levels of disposable income for the low-income retirees than on those for their higher-income counterparts. Implications of Taxing Benefits In the discussion of short-term policy options in chapter V, we pointed out that taxing half of Social Security benefits might be considered because this action would have distributional implications different from those associated with limiting postretirement COLA increases. The argument for the taxing option is that in any consideration of benefit reductions, policymakers should attempt to minimize the impact on the low-income elderly. Taxing only half of the benefits, it is argued, will hit only upper-income retirees drawing income from various sources. The Office of the Actuary in the Social Security Administration has developed a rough estimate that the revenues from the tax, if earmarked for the Social Security trust funds, would reduce the long-term deficit by about one-half of 1 percent of covered payroll. The long-term implications of such a policy in combination with one of the other benefit modifications were estimated through an additional simulation. Fifty percent of benefits are assumed to be subject to the federal income tax beyond January 1, 1984. This simulation included the modification to the benefit determination that would 186 index PIA formula bend points by 75 percent of wage growth for sixteen years. This combination of two policy changes simultaneously would have the smallest effect on workers in the cohort aged fifty-five to sixty-four in the simulation, and the greatest effect on workers in the cohort aged twenty-five to thirty-four. Table VI-10 shows the results of the simulation for these two cohorts. Income at age sixty-five is broken into income categories by $400 monthly or $4,800 annual increments. The table shows the simulated family income under the current policy sccnario and shows the incremental effect of implementing the bend-point modification by itself, and then adding the taxation of 50 percent of benefits on top of it. As expected, the income taxation of 50 percent of Social Security benefits has a larger effect on family income at the higher income levels than at the bottom of the distribution. For the older cohort in table VI-10, which is largely unaffected by the bend-point indexing modification, taxing 50 percent of benefits would maintain families with incomes below $400 per month. For families with incomes below $800 per month, the reduction is estimated to be 0.3 percent of their income under current policy. At the top end of the income spectrum the average reduction was estimated to be roughly 3 percent. The taxation of 50 percent of benefits dovetails with the reduced benefits resulting from the change in PIA calculation procedures. It tends to significantly reduce the regressive effects of changing the benefit formula on family income. Without the taxing option, people in the bottom income classes would have 6 to 7 percent lower family income than they would have under the current policy simulation. At the same time, people in the top income categories would experience reductions of only 3 to 4 percent. If half of Social Security benefits were taxed, the people at the bottom would not gain back any benefits, but those at the top would have familv income reduced by about 9 percent. Thus the combined modification would spread the adjustment more evenly. Implications of Raising the Retirement Age The last two modifications to Social Security that were simulated would gradually raise the normal retirement age. Thc first of these would begin raising the early retirement age bv one quarter per year starting in 1998 and would be completed in 2012 when the normal retirement age reached sixty-eight. The second would raise the normal retirement age by one quarter per year starting in 1990. Under this second option, the early retirement age would be maintained at 187 TABLE VI-10 Average Disposable Income at Age 65 in 1982 Dollars Under Current Policy and Alternate Formula and Taxing Provisions Indexing Bend Points by 75 Percent of Wage Growth Base Case Income Group By Age in 1979 Ages 25-34 Less than $4,800 $4,800-$9,599 $9,600-$14,399 $14,400-$19,199 $19,200-$23,999 $24,000-$35,999 $36,000 or more Ages 55-64 Less than $4,800 $4,800-$9,599 $9,600-$14,399 $14,400-$19,199 $19,200-$23,999 $24,000-$35,999 $36,000 or more Source: Tabulation Benefits Not Taxed Average Income Average Income $ 3,149 7,070 11,862 16,666 21,627 29,223 45,596 $ 2,936 6,632 11,036 15,691 20,501 28,056 44,401 Percentage of Base 2,940 2,938 7,040 7,037 11,864 11,834 16,446 16,443 21,310 21,305 27,539 27,533 46,830 46,828 of PRISM simulation results. Taxing 50 Percent of Benefits Average Income Percentage of Base 93.2 93.8 93.0 94.1 94.8 96.0 97.4 $ 2,929 6,581 10,767 15,086 19,542 26,519 41,693 93.0 93. I 90.8 90.5 90.4 90.7 91.4 99.9 100.0 99.7 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 2,938 7,022 11,679 16,206 20,886 26,865 45,470 99.9 99.7 98.4 98.5 98.0 97.6 97.1 sixty-two but the actuarial adjustment factors would be modified accordance with the schedule specified in table VI-4. These simulations assumed that there would bc a behavioral in re- sponse as a result of the increased Social Security normal retirement age. The probability of accepting Social Security benefits at each year of age above sixty-two was adjusted during the transition period. Thc probabilities, which were adjusted scparatcly for men and women, were modified to increase retirement ages in parallel with the retirement rates dcvclopcd by Social Security actuaries and used to estimate the cost effect of each of these options. Increasing the normal retirement age for Social Security is bound to increase the incidence of disability among older workers, and the disability probabilities in these simulations wcrc adjusted in accordance with probabilities developed by the Social Security actuaries as well. 188 Alternative probabilities of retirement and disability could have been specified. But to do so would suggest that the financing estimates developed in these options should be modified. The purpose of this exercise was not to question the actuaries' cost estimates, but to evaluate the distributional implications of various policy options under a stated set of assumptions. Raising both early and normal retirement ages and beginning the transition in 1998 as described earlier in table V1-3 would primarily affect the youngest two cohorts in the simu|ation analysis. A person forty-four years old in 1979 would be sixtv-three in 1998. The remainder of the cohort aged thirty-five to forty-four in 1979 would be subject to the transitional provisions in the proposal. The oldest persons in the youngest cohort would be sixty-four in 2009, the year that the age for early retirement under the proposal reaches age sixtyfive. The youngest cohort, therefore, would be subject to the later retirement years after the transition was complete. No behavioral response was assumed for either of the two oldest cohorts in the simulation because the people in these cohorts would not be affected by the policy modifications. There are several ways that the effects of this policy alternative could be considered. Table VI-11 shows the results of the simulation of the policy option for raising retirement ages for the youngest two cohorts of workers. The table presents the average income and percentage of people receiving income from the specified sources. The decline in average family Social Security benefit levels is the result of a combination of factors. Raising the retirement age in the specified fashion is bound to drive up the average age at retirement, and this happens in the simulation. As the retirement age is increased, the reference year for calculating the PIA is increased. Each time the reference vear is raised, the bend points in the PIA formula are raised bv the assumed rate of wage growth. As a result PIA levels tend to rise. The increases in the statutory retirement ages, however, were greater than the increases in the actual retirement ages that were simulated here, corresponding with the Social Security actuaries' assumptions regarding the potential response to this option. When actual retirement age increases more slowlv than the normal retirement age, the average actuarial reduction factors across a cohort will increase. The increase in the actuarial reduction factors reduces benefits, on average, by more than the indexing of bend points for later retirement increases than in the simulation. For the older cohort, average familv Social Securitv benefits at age sixty-eight decline 4.2 percent below the average in the current policy simulation. For the 189 TABLE VI- 11 Average Family Income from Specified Sources in 1982 Dollars at Age 68 Under Current Policy and Alternate Policy Raising Social Security's Retirement Ages by Three Years Average Income at Age 68 Increased Retirement- Age in 1979 Current Policy Case Percentage Average Receiving Amount Income Age Case Percentage Average Receiving Amount Income Percentage Change in Average Amount Ages 25-34 Social Security Earnings Pensions or IRA $10,542 20,975 l 1,766 96 26 88 $ 9,776 21,301 12,113 94 33 88 Total Family Income 26,042 NA 26,901 NA 3.3 8,719 16,584 9,979 95 28 82 8,355 17,132 9,960 96 29 82 -4.2 3.3 -0.2 Ages 35-44 Social Security Earnings Pensions or IRA Total Family Income Source: Tabulation 21,171 NA 21,180 of PRlSM simulation rcsuhs. -7.3 1.8 2.9 NA 0.0 younger cohort, the decline is 7.3 percent since this group feels the full effect of the implementation of the higher retirement age. There are offsetting effects in other income sources as earnings increase in two dimensions, recipicncy and average level. In the older cohort, recipiency increases only marginally at the reference vcar of age sixty-eight. In this simulation the average age at retirement for men is assumed to rise to 65.5 years at the end of the transition, which contrasts with an average retirement age of 63.2 years at the beginning of the simulation. The average retirement age of women was also assumed to rise in accordance with the assumptions developed by the Social Security actuaries. to increase during the transition, ance to defer retirement. Work Although earnings can be expected people may have a natural reluctand retirement decisions are almost certainly affected bv social as well as economic often work and socialize with others near their a friend, sibling, tance to dcl_'rred creases in Social 190 or neighbor retirement, Security's expectations. People own age. The fact that retired early may stimulate some especially during any transitional normal retirement age. resisin- The vations PRISM simulations and their effects did not attempt on the retirement to capture social motidecision. They merelv increased the probabilities of working longer on a gradual basis over a twelve-vear period. For the older cohort of workers shown in table VI-12, all but the very youngest workers would be facing normal retirement ages below sixty-eight even during the transition. While the actuarial increments for late retirement gradually increase with the retirement age, it is unlikely that labor-force participation rates for people over age sixty-eight would increase significantly during the transition period. At the completion might be expected. o[ the transition, Somewhat more TABLE Average Dollars Policy Family at Age Raising a pattern of later retirements early retirement would likely VI-12 Income from Specified 68 Under Current Policy Social Security's Normal Age by Three Years Sources in 1982 and Alternate Retirement Average Income at Age 68 Increased RetirementCurrent Policy Case Age Case Age in 1979 Ages 25-34 Social Security Earnings Pension or IRA Total Family Income Ages 35-44 Social Security Earnings Pension or IRA Total Famil Income Ages 45-54 Social Security Earnings Pension or IRA Total Famil' Income Source: Tabulations Average Amount Percentage Receiving Income Percentage Change in Average Amount 96 26 88 $ 8,565 21,013 I 1,794 95 30 88 - 18.8 0.5 0.2 26,042 NA 25,028 NA - 8,719 16,584 9,979 96 28 82 7,331 16,383 10,008 95 34 82 - 15.9 - 1.2 2.9 21,171 NA 20,763 NA - 1.9 7,268 14,938 6,252 93 31 72 7,061 13,795 6,373 94 34 72 - 2.8 7.7 1.9 NA - 0.7 Percentage Receiving Income $10,542 20,915 l 1,766 Average Amount 15,993 NA 15,878 of PRISM simulation results. 3.9 191 prevail than under current policy, but a segment of each cohort of workers would work until normal retirement age and beyond. This would not only raise the level of earnings among the elderly, but the extended work life would also increase pension and IRA accruals for elderly workers. The combined effects may well raise the level of total income available to many of the elderly, albeit from a somewhat differently weighted combination of sources. Raising Social Security's normal retirement age gradually while maintaining the current early retirement age would have an effect somewhat different from the effect of raising both in unison. First, even with greater actuarial reductions, the continued availability of retirement at age sixty-two would induce some early retirement. The incentives to work beyond the normal retirement age would be the same under the Pickle proposal as under the National Commission proposal. Because there would be some additional early retirement and no additional late retirement, the increase in average retirement age would be somewhat less under the Pickle proposal than under the other alternative for raising the retirement age discussed earlier. The proposal to raise both early and normal retirement ages increased the average retirement age between 2.0 and 2.3 years in the simulation. Still, raising normal retirement age and adjusting the early retirement actuarial factors back to age sixty-two were assumed to raise average retirement ages between 1.0 and 1.3 years. This would have distributional effects somewhat different from those of the former option for raising retirement ages. The transition to the Pickle proposal was assumed to begin in 1990 in the simulation and to affect persons age sixty-two that year. Anyone reaching age sixty-two in 1990 would have been fifty-one years old in 1979. Thus, this proposal would affect all but the oldest cohort considered in the simulation analysis. Table VI-12 shows the average family income from various sources derived from these simulation results. The results are somewhat startling. The Social Security benefit reductions for the youngest cohort, on an annual average basis, are two to three times those from the alternative simulation that considered raising both normal and early retirement ages. At first glance, the size of the Social Security benefit reductions would seem to imply greater reductions in average total family income than those shown in the table. The increased prevalence of earnings, however, causes the average total family income to fall significantly less than Social Security benefits. The changes in earnings among the three cohorts are interesting. For the oldest cohort, average earnings decline by 7.7 percent, but 3 192 percent more families are simulated as having earnings at the reference age. The reason that average earnings decline relates to the structure of the retirement decision inherent in the model. A person's retirement decision is affected not only bv Social Security eligibility but by pension eligibility as well. A person who is eligible for a pension, given current program characteristics, will be less sensitive to rising Social Security retirement ages than will a person who is not eligible for a pension. Furthermore, it is lower-wage workers who are less likely to be covered by a pension, in the labor market as we know it today and in the PRISM simulation. As the later retirement ages are phased in, it will be lower-wage workers who are more likely to extend their working careers, unless employers modify their pension plans in accordance with changes in Social Security retirement-age provisions. While it is impossible to estimate whether and how employers might react to higher Social Securitv retirement ages there is evidence to suggest that many employers would not change the retirement-age provisions in their pension plans at this time. _ A second interesting facet of the earnings data included in table VI-12 is that the increased prevalence of the receipt of earnings reaches its peak for the middle cohort in the three age groupings. The transition to this option would be completed about midwav through the cohort's attainment of age sixty-two. The increased prevalence of pension benefits and IRA annuities in the simulation significantly diminishes the effect of keeping lower-wage workers in the labor force. The further growth of IRA annuities and receipt of pension benefits in combination with the reassertion of the long-term trend toward earlier retirement in the simulation reduces the marginal growth in earnings for the youngest cohort in comparison with the middle group in the simulation. Average earnings actually increase slightly under the increased normal retirement age simulation. Assuming that increased earnings will make up for most of the declines in Social Security benefits, in the aggregate, ignores the distributional question that is central to the Social Security adequacy issue. In none of the three cohorts simulated does the prevalence of family earnings rise above 34 percent. Those families with the largest reductions in Social Security benefits under this policy option would be the least likelv to have significant earnings at normal retirement ages. _David Sheinerman, "Attitudes Towards Raising Social Security's Normal Retirement Age--A Survey of Connecticut General Pension Plan Clients," (Washington, D.C.: EBRI, 1982). 193 Although the average benefits are characterized as reductions relative to the current policy scenario, these benefits represent continuous growth in average benefits in real terms. Between the oldest and youngest cohort in table VI-12, the average simulated family benefits at age sixty-eight grew by 21 percent. In addition, this policy option would continue to allow people to retire at age sixty-two. Given the wide variations in workers' health characteristics and job opportunities as they reach their sixties, the value of this early retirement option may outweigh the benefit reductions. Comparing the Alternatives Any retirement age in a national program the magnitude of Social Security is somewhat arbitrary. The establishment of age sixty-five in 1935 as Social Security's retirement age was basically a normative decision. The same can be said about the other facets of the program as well, from the benefit structure to the financing provisions. The prospect facing Congress now is a new set of normative options, all of which somewhat change the course from the accumulation of past decisions. It is possible that if Congress were presented with a clean slate, it might design a program significantly different from the one now known as Social Security. But Congress does not have a clean slate; there is a defined structure with an inherent set of obligations. Congress faces the choice between making a set of incremental adjustments or more radically restructuring the existing system. In focusing on the incremental approach, this chapter has discussed a series of specific options. Thus far the discussion has centered on the effects of the option on benefits at various points in the simulated persons' lives. Another way to look at the effects of these various policy options is to compare the effects on lifetime benefits at some common age. PRISM adds an interesting dimension for comparing expected lifetime benefits under the various options because PRISM simulates a date of death for each sample person. In the PRISM project we compared the effects of all the options by calculating the present value of Social Security benefits, based on the simulated life beyond age sixty-two, under each of the options. We calculated the stream of annual benefits paid each year that a person lived beyond age sixty-two; this calculation included not only worker benefits but spouse and survivor benefits as well. Each benefit was attributed to the person to whom it would be paid; that is, a spouse benefit was attributed to the spouse, not to the primary beneficiary on whose benefit the spouse benefit was based. Annual ben194 efits were calculated in 1982 dollars and discounted bv a 2 percent real rate of return back to age sixty-two to give the value of lifetime benefits that would be paid to all persons who reached early retirement age under current policy for each of the policy options that was simulated. The value of benefits under each of the alternative policy options was then compared with the value under the current policy option, and the percentage change in benefits was calculated. Table VI-13 shows the results of these calculations for all individuals in the cohort of workers aged twenty-five to thirty-four in 1979. To limit the complexity of the analysis, only one cohort is shown. This cohort was chosen because these people would feel the maximum effect of each of the options simulated. From a lifetime-benefits perspective, the distributional effects of the various options are quite different. The bend-point options tend to cluster the benefit reductions, relative to current policy, below 15 percent. Under the price indexing of earnings options, benefit reductions for the majority would also be less than 15 percent. Under each of these options there is a clear modal group with narrowly distributed benefit reductions being spread across a wide range of the population. Under these options, almost everybody ends up in roughly the same boat, so to speak. The variations in the distributions that exist from the alternative formula adjustments stem from variations in work and earnings patterns in the simulations. Under the scenario for raising both the normal retirement and early retirement ages, about 34 percent of the people had benefit reductions of less than 5 percent. In fact some people with long lives beyond age sixty-eight, who worked to normal retirement age under both simulations, would receive higher lifetime benefits under the higherretirement-ages scenario. This occurs because their benefits would be calculated on the basis of a PIA formula whose bend points had been indexed three additional years. About 23 percent of the people at the upper end of the distribution would experience benefit reductions of 25 percent or more under this option, while 10 percent would lose benefits altogether. This wider distribution, compared with the distribution under the other options, stems from later retirement ages in combination with age at death. Even though average life expectancy increases over the simulation period, some people still die between the ages of sixty-two and sixty-five and sixty-five and sixtyeight. People who do not live to age sixty-five or who live only a few years into retirement would receive benefits for a shorter period under this option. Obviously, their benefits would be reduced significantly. t 195 196 The option that raises normal retirement age but maintains the current early retirement age would lead to somewhat larger benefit reductions on average than any of the other options. This occurs because people are expected to choose to retire at an age close to the retirement age under current policy, at the expense of larger actuarial reductions in their benefits. If older workers were to extend their careers in the future, however, this phenomenon might be less extensive than the simulation suggests. The size of the baby-boom cohort and the prospects of the mass exodus of these people from the work force might result in significant wage growth among the members of this cohort as they begin to retire. To some extent, this phenomenon is captured in the simulation, but possibly not sufficiently. If the wages of this cohort were to rise appreciably as the group approached retirement, the labor-force participation of the elderly could be expected to rise and the Social Security benefit reductions would be less pronounced than the simulation results shown in table VI- 13 suggest. The Social Securitv modifications discussed also will have somewhat different effects on men and women. These differences occur because of variations in male and female earnings patterns and life expectancy. Table VI-14 compares the results of the simulations for three of the options discussed on the basis of sex. The options that would modify the benefit formula would reduce lifetime benefits for men on average slightly more than for women. For example, the 75 percent wage-indexation option would reduce benefits for about 38 percent of the women by 10 percent or less. For another 60 percent of the women, the benefit reductions would range between 10 and 15 percent. In contrast, about 19 percent of men would experience benefit reductions of less than 10 percent, while about 81 percent would have reductions ranging between 10 and 15 percent. Raising both the early and normal retirement ages in Social Security would provide somewhat smaller changes in lifetime benefits for people who live well beyond retirement age, so women would benefit more than men. Under the option for-raising both retirement ages, the simulated lifetime benefits for 41 percent of the women were less than 5 percent below the current policy results, while only 26 percent of men had benefit reductions in this range. In contrast, about 37 percent of the men had cuts of 5 to 10 percent in lifetime benefits, while only 20 percent of women fell in this interval. Men were also slightly more likely than women to have cuts of 10 percent or more in lifetime benefits. 197 TABLE VI-14 Distribution of Relative Change in the Present Value of Lifetime Social Security Benefits for Men and Women at Age 62 Under Alternate Policy Scenarios Compared to Current Policy for Individuals Ages 25 to 34 in 1979 Relative Reduction in Lifetime Benefits Compared with Current Policy Less than 5 _ercent 5 to 9.99 _ercent 10 to 14.99 _ercent 15 to 19.99 _ercent 20 to 24.99 9ercent 25 to 99.99 _ercent 100 percent Total _ Policy Option Raising Normal Raising Early and Retirement Age and 75 Percent BendNormal Retirement Adjusting Actuarial Point Indexation Ages Factors Men Women Men Women Men Women (Percents of persons in each category) 0.9 3.3 26.1 41 .l 1.4 12.1 18.5 34.3 36.5 19.9 2.3 11.2 80.5 60.0 7.7 7.2 6.5 17.6 0.1 1.4 5.5 5.5 56.9 41.0 0.0 0.5 2.3 2.6 26.0 12.9 0.0 0.0 !00.0 0.6 0.0 100.1 11.4 10.3 99.8 14.0 9.6 99.9 5.0 1.8 99.9 3.8 1.3 99.9 Source: Tabulation of PRISM simulation results. _Totals may not add to exactly 100 percent because of rounding. The option that would raise normal retirement age to sixty-eight and adjust the actuarial factors back to sixty-two has a substantially greater effect on men than women. A larger portion of women than men would have benefit reductions of less than 15 percent, while a larger share of the men fall into the reduction categories 15 percent and above. Selecting Options No clear decision rule for rived from this analysis. The the various options showed each approach. Adjustments 198 selecting a particular option can be defirst part of the chapter that described the savings that can be garnered from can be made to each of the options to get more or less savings, but roughly gained by either reducing initial benefit ages. comparable savings can bc growth or raising retirement The latter part of the chapter that described the distributional effects of the options showed somewhat more pronounced differences in the options. Before Congress chooses one of these options, or a similar variant, it must ultimately decide how it wishes to distribute the benefit adjustments. Modifying the benefit formula will give a narrow range of benefit adjustments, but the adjustments will affect almost everyone. Modifying the retirement age, though, will give a much broader range of adjustments. If both normal and early retirement ages were raised, many future beneficiaries would be better off than they would bc under the formula modification options, while many others would be worse off. None of the options considered in the simulations would by itself resolve the long-term financial imbalance in the OASDI program, so other adjustments will also have to be considered. In the PRISM project, we simulated the implications of taxing 50 percent of Socia_ Security benefits in combination with 75 percent wage indexing of bend points. The results of that simulation, discussed earlier, suggest that this combination of policy change would not radically redistribute the income accruing to the elderlv in the future. In fact, it appears / that this course would come closer to maintaining the elderlv's income distribution than any single option considered bv itself. This ! combination of modifying the benefit formula and the tax treatment of Social Security benefits would probably still fall short of closing the long-term financing deficit, however. Raising the early and normal retirement ages in Social Security might seem particularly harsh because this action would completely eliminate benefits to some people who would, under current policy, receive benefits. The selection of any eligibility criterion for retirement age, however, has the effect of excluding some people from benefits. This is true of current policy, which does not provide retirement benefits prior to age sixty-two. The relevant question is whether raising Social Security retirement ages would exclude more people from benefits than current policy does. If retirement ages were increased, the Social Security Disability Insurance program would be called upon to a greater extent to deal with the greater prevalence of disability and health problems among older workers than is now the case. Considering the inherent response of the DI program to a policy of increased retirement ages, such a policy should not result 199 in greater benefit exclusions (because of death before entitlement) than have occurred over the life of the Social Security program. Certain combinations of benefit formula adjustments and changing retirement ages might be considered. But combining options just to get to financial balance could be devastating. A combination of benefit formula modifications with increasing retirement age would lead to greater benefit adjustment than any discussed here. Such a combination would accentuate the distribution of the adjustments as well. Rather than considering such combinations, Congress may wish to consider other alternatives that would help resolve the financing deficits in the long term. The next two chapters are devoted to a further discussion of such alternatives. 200 VII. Universal Coverage Social Security and the Alternatives* In the proccss of developing the 1977 Social Security amendments, the House Ways and Means Committee reported out a bill that would have mandated universal coverage. Had Social Security coverage been extended to all employment in the United States effective Januarv 1, 1978, the program would have no short-term financing problem today. In the long-term, the financing deficit would have been reduced bv 0.5 percent of payroll--slightly more than one-quarter of the financing deficit projected under the 1982 Trustees Report Alternative II-B assumptions. Coverage was not expanded by the 1977 amendments. In fact, since that time, a number of employers who had the option have withdrawn from the system. When the Social Securitv program was established in 1935, participation in it was compulsory for all private-sector workers in commerce and industrv who were not vet sixty-five years old. At that time, somewhat more than half of all U.S. workers were covered. Some categories of workers, such as federal civilian employees, were excluded because most of these people were protected under the Civil Service Retirement System (CSRS). State and local employees were excluded because it was believed that the Constitution might prevent their participation. Since 1935, both Social Security coverage and benefits have been greatly expanded. Today, more than 90 percent of the nation's workers have Social Security coverage. Of workers not now covered bv Social Security, 2.5 million are federal civilian employees, 3 million are state and local government employees, and 500,000 to 1,000,000 are employees of private, nonprofit organizations. Most of these employees participate in their employers' retirement, survivor, and disability insurance systems. Other persons without Social Security coverage include "quasi-workers," such as newspaper carriers and other casual laborers who do not earn enough in a year to meet the coverage criteria. Conscientious objectors, such as the Amish, are also not covered on the basis of self-employment. ":An earlier version of this chapter was presented at the American Enterprise Conference on Controlling Social Security Costs, June 26, 1981. lnstitute's 201 Problems with the Status Quo Although the Social Security program now covers almost all American workers, certain inequities and inadequacies result from the existing pattern of exemptions from the program. There are three major problems: (1) inadequate protection for persons not covered; (2) inequities inherent in exemption from participation in a mandatory redistributive program; and (3) subsidized benefits afforded partial participants in Social Security. Inadequate Protection [br Persons Not Covered--Most workers not covered by Social Security are covered by pension plans sponsored by their employers. Both Social Security and the typical pension plan require a period of employment under the system before the worker is eligible for insurance protection. As a result, workers who have noncovered jobs or who shift between covered and noncovered employment may experience periods without disability and survivor I coverage. Public pension plans usually require at least five years of service before the worker receives disability protection. Many employees in the initial five years of service are young people holding their first major jobs who have no other pension protection. Although disability is unlikely for most young workers, it does occur and the worker is often without insurance or assets. Workers who leave federal employment without CSRS annuity status, for example, are the least likely to have Social Security coverage and are the most likely to need it. Of workers who left federal employment between 1973 and 1977, an average of 39 percent of the men and 63 percent of the women were not insured against disability. Even the most vigorous opponents of mandatory Social Security coverage acknowledge that these insurance gaps warrant modifying the current system. Workers in employment not covered by Social Security also experience gaps in benefits. These gaps arise because many of the alternative pension systems do not provide disability and survivor benefits comparable to those provided by Social Security. A twentyone-year-old worker can acquire Social Security disability protection with credited earnings for six quarters of work in covered employment; in fact, these credits can be earned with as little as one month _The term "noncovered" used in this chapter refers to Social Security coverage. The overwhelming majority o[ "noncovered workers" in this context are actually covered by a pension other than Social Security. 2O2 of covered employment in two consecutive vears. To become insured under CSRS, the same person would have to work five vears for the federal government. Many noncovered state and local systems require even longer periods of coverage to qualify for disability benefits. 2 Furthermore, the benefits provided by these other pensions are often inferior, especially for young workers with families. The partial gaps in coverage extend bevond disability and survivor protection. A comparison of covered and noncovered state and local pension plans shows that the combined benefits (i.e., Social Security plus pension) of covered systems generally exceeded the benefits of noncovered systems by 20 to 60 percent in 1976. Given the fact that Social Security benefits are not currentlv taxable, the disparity between the annuities of covered and noncovered plans is even more marked. 3 In addition, dependent benefits are usually more generous under Social Security than they are under noncovered plans. Social Security provides better spouse, survivor, and disability benefits and medical protection than virtually any noncovered system. Social Security benefits are fully indexed to changes in the cost of living, whereas the benefits of most noncovered plans are not. These differences in coverage and benefit levels make all noncovered workers and their families more vulnerable than covered workers. Inequities Inherent in Exemption [rom Participation in a Mandatory Redistributive Program--Career noncovered workers are exempted from paying into an income-redistributive program that provides proportionately more generous benefits to low-wage than to high-wage workers. Part of the payroll tax contributions of high-wage covered workers is used to provide more generous benefits to retirees with low average lifetime earnings than they would otherwise receive if Social Security were not tilted to favor low-income workers. The highly paid noncovered worker does not share this burden. There is nothing inherently different in the employment of noncovered workers that differentiates their work from that of covered workers. There are accountants, lawyers, economists, actuaries, blue-collar workers, clerks, and secretaries in both the covered and the noncovered sectors. 2For example, the Louisiana State Public Employee Retirement Svstem requires five years of service for survivor protection and ten years for disability protection. 3Final report of the Universal Social Security Coverage Study Group, The Desirability and Feasibility o[ Social Security Coverage [br Employees of Federal, State and Local Government and Private, Nonproiit Organizations (Washington, D.C., 1980), p. 27, hereafter cited as Universal Coverage Study. 203 The only distinction is that some workers are employed by employers who do not participate in the system. It should be kept in mind, laowever, that some noncovered employees are low-paid workers who would actually benefit from expanded coverage. Women, for example, would benefit from wider Social Security coverage. Approximately 28 percent of women employed by the federal government in April 1978 had annual salaries below $10,000, whereas only 7 percent of the federally employed men did. Only 8 percent of the federally employed women had salaries above $20,000 in 1978, whereas 31 percent of the men did. Similarly, members of minority groups would benefit from the redistributive aspects of Social Security. Only 12.9 percent of the whites employed by the federal government had annual salaries below $10,000 in April 1978, but 19.4 percent of minority group employees did. In comparison, 11.6 percent of minority federal workers had salaries exceeding $20,000 per year, while 37.5 percent of white federal workers had such salaries in April 1978. 4 It is the redistributive aspect of Social Security to the third set of problems which many people the most important inequity resulting from the Social Security exemptions. that also gives rise believe constitutes current pattern of Benefits Af]orded Partial Participants in Social Security--Workers with periods of noncovered employment who qualify for Social Security benefits receive higher benefits in proportion to their contributions to Social Security than do workers with only covered employment. It is important to understand that although this difference is quantifiable, the issue is still highly emotional and controversial. Language must be selected carefully so that the issues are not obscured by rhetoric. 4This analysis is based on a six-year, 1 percent longitudinal sample of the |edera] government's Central Personnel Data File (CPDF). This file represents approximately 2.7 million [ederal workers in each vear and approximately 4.2 million workers for the total period. This sample excludes about 10 percent of federal employees covered under CSRS whose records are not maintained in the CPDF: legislative employees, employees of the District of Columbia, foreign nationals, agricultural extension employees, and several other relatively small groups of workers. In each year, roughly 10 percent of the workers in the sample were covered under Social Security through their federal employment. These workers were excluded from the analysis where appropriate. The CPDF data were linked with Social Security Administration records that provide detailed information on the extent of earnings of those workers who were covered by Social Security and a longitudinal record of their insurance status. These, in turn, were linked with the CSRS annuity file, which provided detailed retirement income data on federal workers who retired during the six-year period. 204 Frequently, people who have a favorable ratio of benefits to contributions from Social Security because of periods of noncovered employment are characterized as "double dippers." The attribution is misleading and brings a pejorative tone to the discussion. Both the description and the policy solutions that have been put forward to solve the "double dipper" problem reflect a lack of understanding of the problem or of potential effective solutions. "Double dipping" suggests receiving dual compensation or benefits based on one period of service. For people who work in noncovered employment, there is little double attribution of service both to a noncovered pension system and to Social Security. Dual beneficiary status occurs because recipients have complied with mandatory provisions under both covered and noncovered employment. While working in noncovered employment they contributed to their pension plan and became eligible for benefits. While working in covered employment they contributed to Social Security and met the eligibility requirements for a Social Security benefit as well. Many of those who receive preferential treatment from Social Security because of noncovered employment receive absolutely no retirement benefits from the noncovered employer's pension plan. 5 A more appropriate description widely used in the literature characterizes the relatively generous payments to people with periods of noncovered employment as "windfall benefits." The Universal Coverage Study characterized the windfalls as "unintended subsidies." The Fund to Assure Independent Retirement (FAIR), a coalition of federal unions that has amassed several million dollars to lobby against universal coverage, has taken the position that neither the windfall nor the unintended subsidy characterization is fair, as stated here: • FAIR finds it inconsistent who receive "windfall" • It is an discount • but not amusing that benefits are criticized, retired while public employees others are not. established [act that self-employed persons receive a 25 percent on the total contribution to the Social Security trust fund. When viewed against others who receive benefits from the fund, the self-employed clearly receive benefits in excess of the standard contribution rate. Yet nobody complains that they are ripping off the taxpayers. Similarly, individuals who use "non-earned" income, such as dividends on investments and capital gains from business transactions, [or part of their working lifetime do not pay a Social Security tax on such non- SThe term "noncovered employer" does not provide Social Security. throughout this discussion means the employer It does not mean that a pension is not provided. 205 earned income. falls" acquired No argument has been advanced to suggest in this manner should be eliminated. 6 that "wind- To place FAIR's position in perspective, it should be noted that Congress has explicitly decided to give preferential treatment to earnings of the self-employed and to unearned income. The equity of the special treatments of these kinds of income can be debated, but the intent of Congress cannot. The Social Security program is financed by a payroll tax on wage or salary income--not by a tax on capital. Congress has clearly legislated lower payroll tax rates from the selfemployed than for hired workers. Any subsidies that result from these policies are clearly the "intent" of Congress. At the same time, it should be noted that universal coverage has not been the intent of Congress thus far, either. The concern about unintended subsidies is substantiated, however, by the House of Representatives' Report on the Social Security Act Amendments of 1939: An average wage formula will also have the effect of raising the level of benefits payable in the early years of the system, but it will reduce future costs by eliminating unwarranted bonuses payable under the present formula to workers in insured employment only a few years. These bonuses result from the greater weight now given to the first $3,000 of accumulated wages. They are justified, if a total wage formula is used, in the case of older and low-paid workers who retire in the early years of the system and have not had time in which to build up substantial benefit rights. In the long run, however, such bonuses are unwise and endanger the solvency of the system by permitting disproportionately large benefits to workers who migrate between uninsured and insured employment and accumulate only small earnings in insured employment .7 Providing a Perspective on the Bonuses The Social Security bonuses to noncovered workers result from two factors: (1) the benefit formula provides a deliberate subsidy intended for workers with relatively low lifetime wages; and (2) the benefit calculation does not distinguish between truly low-wage earners and those whose average lifetime covered earnings are low because they work primarily in noncovered employment. The underlying premise 6"FAIR Facts No. 3," in Tlle National Rural Letter Carrier, vol. 79, no. 46 (December 31, 1980), pp. 863-864. 7House of Representatives, 76th Congress, First Session, Report no. 728, SocialSecurity Act Amendments o[ 1939 (June 2, 1939), p. 10. 206 in the unwarranted bonus concept is that Social Security should treat workers with comparable earnings patterns comparably. To demonstrate this premise, let us consider the beginning salary level and annual wage increases for each of the three hypothetical workers shown in table VII-I. The favorable benefit-contribution ratio that results from periods of noncovered employment is reflected in table VII-2. The table shows the value of employee taxes paid at retirement assuming 2 percent real interest on contributions, compounded annually. Each worker is assumed to work continuously between the age of twenty-two, attained in 1981, until the age of sixty-two, which occurs in 2021. The calculations assume that currently legislated payroll tax rates will apply, that there will be no inflation, and that average real wages will increase 1 percent per year. The value of expected total benefits at retirement age sixtv-two is 80 percent of the primary insurance amount based on current life expectancy tables (slightly more than eighteen years) discounted at a rate of 2 percent per year. Table VII-2 shows the effects of exempting periods of employment from Social Security coverage. Such exemptions result in far more rapid declines in contributions than in benefits. With only thirtv-five years of covered employment, the hypothetical workers pay only 86 to 90 percent of the full-career tax liability; vet they receive virtually full benefits. Thc workers with thirty vears of coverage make 72 to 78 percent of full-career contributions but receive 88 to 94 percent of a full benefit. For twenty years of coverage the workers make roughly half the whole-life contribution, but receive three-fourths of the full benefit. For ten vears of coverage, workcrs contribute about onefourth and receive about half of the full benefit. TABLE Wage Assumptions Worker Salary Level (Dollars) VII-I for Three l Hypothetical Worker Annual Increase (Percent) Salary Level (Dollars) 2 Workers Worker Annual Increase (Percent) 3 Salary Level (Dollars) Annual Increase (Percent) Year Age 1981 22 8,529 3 14,348 5 19,655 5 1990 31 11,129 1 22,258 1 30,491 3 2000 41 12,293 1 24,586 1 40,977 1 2010 51 13,579 1 27,159 1 45,264 1 2020 61 15,000 Source: Universal Coverage Study, Study Group, (Washington, 30,000 report of the Universal Social D.C., March 1980), p. 52. 50,000 Security Coverage 207 TABLE VII-2 Percentage of Total Employee Social Security Taxes Paid and Primary Benefits Accrued for Three Hypothetical Forty-Year Workers in Covered Employment, by Final Salary $15,000 Final Salary $30,000 $50,000 Taxes Benefits Taxes Benefits Taxes Benefits $53,391 $81,210 $104,668 $117,601 $150,191 $141,801 Value at retirement |0r f0rty-year coveredcareer Percentage Years o/Career Covered (35 years total) 6-40 years 88 1-5, 11 40 87 - 10, 16-40 86 - 15, 21-40 87 -20, 26 40 87 -25, 31-40 88 -30, 36 40 89 -35 89 Years o[ Career Covered (30 years total) 11-40 years 75 1-10, 21-40 73 i-20, 31-40 75 1-30 78 of Total Taxes Paid and Benefits Less than Forty Years Worked Accrued for 100 99 99 99 99 99 99 99 89 87 86 86 87 88 88 89 100 99 98 98 98 98 98 98 90 87 86 86 87 87 88 89 100 99 98 98 98 98 98 98 90 88 88 88 76 72 75 77 94 92 92 92 77 72 74 77 93 90 90 90 Years o[Career Covered (20 years total) 21 40 years 47 11-30 52 1-20 53 69 68 68 48 53 52 76 76 72 49 54 51 77 77 73 Years o] Career Covered (10 years total) 31-40 years 22 21-30 25 11-20 27 1-10 25 49 47 47 47 23 25 28 24 48 48 48 43 23 26 28 23 5I 51 43 43 Source: Note: 2O8 U_iversal Coverage Study, report ol the Universal Social Security Coverage Study Group, (Washington, D.C., March 1980), p. 36. All dollar amounts are in 1980 dollars. Although the effects of inl]ation have been eliminated, the computations assume I percent increases in productivity for each year between 1981 and 2020. The concern about this problem typically focuses only on persons who derive benefits from pension plans of noncovered employers at the same time that they receive Social Securitv benefits. Yet workers with verv short periods of exempted employment also receive preferential treatment from Social Security, whether or not they receive a pension from noncovered employment. During the development of the Universal Coverage Study, there was a considerable debate about the precise definition of the "unintended subsidies." The concept of windfalls for dual beneficiaries had been discussed and was generally accepted by serious students of Social Security. The concept of the "contribution gaps" for workers with short periods of noncovered service was developed and refined by the coverage studv staff and was accepted more slowly. One of the arguments against the idea of the contribution gaps was that it assumed that workers were somehow responsible for paying for their own benefits. The argument focused on the relation of benefits to contributions inherent in table VII-2. Table VII-2 is not based on the assumption, however, that there is necessarily any dollar equivalence between full lifetime contributions and an expected full retirement benefit for any particular worker. The underlying premise is simply that workers will contribute while employed and will benefit while retired. Workers who do not participate fully on the contribution side of the program should not expect to receive the full protection of the benefit side. Congress recognized this principle in 1939 when it cautioned against "unwarranted bonuses to workers who migrate between uninsured and insured employment. ''s Measuring the Cost to Social Security of the Bonuses The Universal Coverage Study also attempted to quantify the cost of the unwarranted bonuses from Social Security. Because of limitations in the available data, the subsidies to dual beneficiaries and to workers with short periods of noncovered service were estimated separately. The windfalls for dual beneficiaries were estimated as unwarranted bonuses paid. For workers with short periods of noncovered service, the windfalls were estimated as foregone contributions not reflected in proportionate benefit reductions under current policy. Estimates of windfalls for dual beneficiaries were based on the assumption that workers with periods of noncovered employment 81bid. 209 would not receive a higher replacement rate on their covered earnings than workers whose total earnings wcrc in covered employment. Calculating the "correct" replacement rate [br workers with noncovered employment required the derivation of phantom average indexed monthly earnings and primary insurance amounts; that is, total career earnings were treated as though they were covered. These phantom values were used to derive the intended or "correct" replacement rate, which was then multiplied by the AIME from covered employment to derive an intended or "correct" PIA. The adjusted PIA was then used to obtain the benefit that the annuitant was intended to receive under the Social Security program. The difference between this intended benefit and the benefit under the current law was the measure bonus. of the windfall used to derive an estimate of the aggregate As an illustration, consider three hypothetical workers shown in table VII-3 who retired in 1980 with identical wage streams and $12,000 in annual lifetime average indexed earnings. For worker A retiring at age sixty-five with a full career in covered employment, Social Security replaced 43.26 percent of the AIME. For workers B and C, the replacement rates under current law were 55 and 77 percent of AIME, respectively. The windfall calculation assumed that workers who had idcntical earnings histories should have the same replacement of AIME. The actual replacement rate for the fully covered worker was assumed to bc the target replacement rate for workers with noncovered earnings. Using that target replacement rate to calculate the benefits defines the "intended" benefit for workers with periods of noncovcred employment. An estimate of windfalls was derived from 1 percent of the annuitants who began receiving CSRS benefits between 1973 and 1978, had attained the age of sixty-two by April 1978, and were eligible to receive a Social Security benefit by that date. An average windfall was calculated that accounted for actuarial reductions based on age at receipt of Social Security. The calculation also accounted for a proportionate assignment of spouses and Medicare Part A benefits as windfalls. On the basis of average windfalls to this cohort of annuitants, extrapolations were made to the remaining CSRS annuitant population and noncovered state and local pension annuitants. The Social Security windfalls for dual beneficiaries were estimated to be $840 million in 1980. 9 9See the vation. 210 U_ziversal Coverage Stuclv, chapter 3, tot a detailed description of this deri- TABLE VII-3 Earnings Credits, Present Low Benefits, and Estimated Windfalls for Three Hypothetical Workers with Identical Wage Streams Earnings Credits Covered Not covered Total AIME Present PIA _ Worker A Worker B Worker C $12,000 $12,000 1,000 $ 6,000 6000 $12,000 500 $ 3,000 9_000 $12,000 250 $432.60 $272.60 $192.60 0 Law Replacement rate 43% Target Bene[its Replacement rate PIA 43% $432.60 55e/_ 43_ $216.30 77c_ 43cA $108.15 Windfall Be_te[its Actual PIA less target PIA 0 $ 56.30 $ 84.45 Source: Calculated bv author. "PIAs are computed using tile assumption that each benefit calculation procedure was fully e|'|;ective and using the 1980 benefit formula. Earnings credits "_veredivided bv 12 as if the', had been average indexed monthlycarnings. There are several reasons to believe that this is a conservative es- timate. First, only primary beneficiaries were considered, although survivor benefits would also include some windfall component. Second, windfalls were calculated at the point of entitlement, but were not indexed to account for cost-of-living incrcascs, which would apply" to the windlall portion of total benefits. Third, the calculation did not account for the fact that treatment of five years of noncovcred earnings reduces as "drop-out" contributions years in calculating relatively more than Social Security benefits it reduces benefits. Fi- nally, the dual beneficiary rates for state and local annuitants were considered to occur to the same extent as among CSRS annuitants, although the limited evidence available suggested that they may be more prevalent. This is especially' the case for teachers, whose summer vacations offer the opportunity t0r secondary' .jobs, and for police and fire fighters, for whom dual careers are the norm because of earh" retirement provisions. In future years, the total magnitude of the windfalls will be affected bv recent legislation that covers federal workers under Medicare, 211 beginning in 1983. In the immediate future, the effect will be to increase the windfalls, because even shorter-than-normal periods of coverage will provide Medicare eligibility. Although the regulations have not yet been released, early indications are that as little as one month's coverage will result in benefit entitlement. For a regular worker retiring in 1983 at age sixty-two, thirty-two quarters of coverage would be required. Federal workers eligible for retirement without the required quarters of coverage, it appears, will have to work only through January 1983 to become entitled at age sixty-five. In the long-term, the measure will reduce Medicare windfalls for federal annuitants, but it does not apply to other noncovered groups. Estimates of contribution gaps for workers with short periods of noncovered service who do not qualify for noncovered pensions were obtained by calculating the part of noncovered earnings that would have to be covered to establish parity between contributions and benefits under Social Security. For workers who spend fewer than five years in noncovered employment, virtually all earnings would have to be covered because of the "drop-out" years in the benefit calculation. If a worker spends fewer than five years in noncovered employment, there would be little effect on ultimate benefits, but lifetime contributions would be reduced by 10 percent or more. For workers with more than five years of noncovcred employment, only that portion of exempted earnings has to be counted that would insure parity between the portion of total lifetime payroll taxes contributed and the benefits received. The estimate of the contribution gaps for the federal work force was $576 million, or 1.1 percent of payroll covered by CSRS in 1980. This same payroll percentage was attributed to noncovered state and local salaries, raising the estimate another $500 million, for a total loss of $1.1 billion to Social Security in 1980. As the combined tax rates rise to 15.3 percent of payroll in 1990, this figure will climb to $1.4 billion in 1980 dollars. I° Estimates of total bonuses suggest that the combined windfalls to dual beneficiaries and contribution gaps for current workers will exceed $2 billion in 1982. These are costs incurred by Social Security and borne by the taxpayers who contribute to the program. Options There outlined _°lbid., 212 for Resolution of the Problems is a wide range of alternatives for resolving the problems above. Some analysts have argued that expanded coverage p. 44. should be encouraged by means of added incentives. Voluntary coverage of workers now exempted would be encouraged if Social Securitv revenues were raised whollv or in part through general revenues, a value-added tax, or a windfall profit tax on oil companies. Each of these options has been suggested as a potential source of Social Security funding. Because people in noncovered employment would share the burden of these taxes, the incentives for their voluntary participation would be increased. Although alternative sources of funding for Old-Age, Survivor, Disability, and Hospital Insurance have been suggested, they have been widely opposed to date. At the state and local levels, revenue-sharing funds could be made contingent on voluntary Social Security coverage. Because retirement systems are not always coterminous with units of government eligible to receive such funds, administering this incentive would be difficult. Anothcr approach would be to require that all employment subsidized by federal grants-in-aid be covered. The ultimate effects, howevcr, might be felt not bv state and local employees, but bv the people the grant programs are designed to assist. The problem of unintended benefits could be more directly eliminated bv revising the basic structure of the Social Security benefit formula. Because such changes could affect the benefits of almost all future recipients of Social Security, however, it is hard to justify them solely on the basis of reduction in windfall benefits. Given that such radical modifications would be like the tail wagging unlikely that the desire to reducc windfall benefits be sufficient justification for completely changing Social Security. the dog, it seems would, by itself, the structure of There are more limited options that deal directly with the Social Securitv benefits of persons now exempted from the program. These options leave other aspects of the program intact and modit\' only the relationship of Social Security to workers exempted under current law. This set of alternatives ranges from options to eliminate windfall benefits, to universal coverage. Although there arc several ways to address the problems that arise because coverage is not universal, the discussion here will focus on three sets of alternatives: (1) mandatory universal Social Security coverage: (2) modification of the benefit calculation to eliminate the unintended subsidies; and (3) proposals that would reduce Social Securitv benefits on the basis of the receipt ofa noncovered employer pension. 213 Universal Social Security Coverage--Universal coverage could theoretically be legislated and implemented for the remaining noncovered segments of the work force. Certain legal or constitutional questions would have to be resolved for state, local, and nonprofit groups. Legal opinion cuts both ways, and legislation mandating coverage would probably be tested in the Supreme Court if it encompassed these groups, i i If a decision were made to mandate coverage, certain decisions would have to be made to determine the specific groups of workers to be included. Coverage could be mandated for all workers as of a specific date, or coverage might affect only groups of workers. Workers already participating in a noncovered employer pension plan, for example, might continue to receive their coverage exemptions as long as they remained active participants in that plan. An intermediate set of options exists, of course, that could allow continued exemptions based on age or service, or a combination of both at the time coverage was mandated. An alternative would be to have continued exemptions based on the time until eligibility for retirement. Workers within ten years of normal retirement age, for example, might not have adequate working years left to earn a Social Security entitlement. The question of equity is the overriding issue that has given rise to consideration of mandating universal Social Securitv coverage. The financing implications of coverage were significant enough, however, that universal coverage was included in the House Wavs and Means Committee version of the 1977 Social Security Act amendments that was sent to the full House of Representatives, as discussed at the beginning of this chapter. The short-term effects would be more dramatic than the long-term implications. The short-term effects of expanded mandatory coverage relate almost entirely to the revenue side of the program. Bringing in cohorts of new workers would not generate new cohorts of retirees for several years. Bringing in cohorts of current noncovered workers who already have some years of coverage would increase benefits for workers retiring in the first few years after implementation but it would also reduce windfalls. For such workers who would otherwise receive a Social Security benefit, each additional year of coverage reduces the amount of the bonus. Table VII-4 shows estimates of the increased outlays that would result the Actuary of the Social from expanded coverage Security Administration that the Office of developed for the UniversalCoverageStudy includes a separate legal brief on the issues that would he raised by mandating coverage for I_ederalworkers, state and local governments, and nonprofit entities. liThe 214 ,e % Z_ _'_ _ _= - _ _._ _._ _ _.__ __ "_ "_,e_ _= "-o-_ '_ _ _ _ _ t_ oo _. "" 215 I U_liversal Coverage Study. The estimates were developed in 1979, and reflect assumptions being used at that time for Social Security cost projections. More current assumptions would change the precise estimate but not their order of magnitude. Most important, it is apparent that expanded coverage would result in less than $1 billion in increased benefits during the first lour years after implementation. Table VII-5 shows more recent estimates of the additional revenues that would flow into the trust funds if expanded coverage were mandated. Coverage of current workers would result in a massive infusion of new revenues, beginning in the first year of implementation and continuing on into the future. Coverage of new workers only would result in much slower growth in the level of new revenues in the short term. Implementation of mandatory coverage in 1984 for new entrants into currently noncovered jobs would result in new revenue of $700 million for Social Security in the first year and $21 billion during the first five years. In the context of the total Social Security budget, these numbers are not overwhelming, but they begin to add up quickly. As the late Senator Everett Dirksen used to say: "A billion here and a billion there and after a while you are talking about real money." More rapid implementation of coverage and inclusion of current workers could play a significant role in the resolution of the shortterm financing problems of Social Security. There is no practical reason, for example, why large portions of the current federal work force could not be covered as early as January 1, 1984. Virtually, all the workers who would be affected already have account numbers. Most already have a record of covered earnings under the Social Security program. Social Security could certainly post the additional earnings data without any modification of existing operations. The federal government could provide the needed information to Social Security without any major modifications of its own payroll systems. In fact, the needed inlormation is already being provided to Social Security but is not being posted. At the federal level, the only major practical roadblock to coverage is the redesign of the CSRS and other federal systems in coordination with Social Security coverage. The Universal Coverage Study includes a series of pension plan options coordinated with Social Security coverage that would maintain the average benefits of the current CSRS. Because of Social Security's redistributive aspect, these options would mean slightly higher benefits for lower-wage workers and slightly reduced benefits for higher-wage workers. 12Because cov12Universal 216 Coverage Study, chapter 5. _ _ _-_i _¢'_ _ - L_. _ _ _ _ -- -- ,_ _-_ _" _{_ P_ _ ................. 217 erage would mean warranted bonuses, benefits. the elimination of unintended subsidies or unthere would be some decline in total retirement At the state and local levels, the time required to implement mandatory coverage would be somewhat longer than at the federal level. A timetable would have to be developed for state and local jurisdictions to implement coverage and to modify existing plans. After enactment of federal legislation, the affected jurisdiction would need some time to consider and develop a plan for coordination with Social Security. The legislative bodies would need time to implement the new plan designs or to modify existing ones. These modifications would have to be implemented within each jurisdiction's budget cycle. Pension provisions that are contractual agreements would have to be modified. For nonprofit organizations, there are already legislative and fiduciary requirements that are applicable to pension plan design, although the extent to which the Employee Retirement Income Security Act and Internal Revenue Service regulations apply to this sector is not completely clear. Many of the employers that would be affected in this sector do not now provide any pension protection for their workers, so Social Security coverage would provide such protection for the first time. No problems would arise in designing coordinated pension systems where no systems exist to be coordinated. Because of differences in the implications of mandatory coverage, Congress might decide to mandate coverage only for federal workers or to mandate coverage for them before doing so for remaining noncovered workers. Congress also might choose to cover some existing federal employees while mandating coverage for new entrants only in other affected systems. The infusion of new revenues into Social Security would still be significant in the short term. Table VII-5 shows, for example, that mandatory coverage of all federal workers on January 1, 1984, would generate new OASDI tax revenues of more than $44 billion by 1988. Continuing the exemption for federal workers within ten years of retirement might reduce that amount by as much as 30 percent but would still generate more than $30 billion in the first five years of mandatory coverage. Coverage of state and local government and nonprofit new entrants in 1985 would add another $8 billion to $10 billion by 1988. Added Social Security benefits under such a scenario would be less than $1 billion between 1984 and 1988. At first glance, the long-term implications of mandatory coverage may appear less impressive than the short-term impact, but careful examination indicates otherwise. Table VII-6 shows the long-term 218 impact on the Social Security program of the two extreme mandatory coverage options. The table shows the amount by which payroll taxes resulting from mandatory coverage would exceed new benefits. The assumed implementation date is January 1, 1984. Coverage of current workers would have a significantly greater positive effect between now and the end of the century than would phasing in coverage for new-entrants only. After the turn of the century, the effect would shift and the new entrant option would provide a more advantageous balance. In both cases, however, the seventy-five-year average excess of taxes over expenditures is estimated to be 0.53 percent of total payroll for the OASDI program. The 0.53 percent may seem insignificant, but applied to taxable payroll in excess of $1 trillion in 1982, it would generate more than $5 billion in added revenues in excess of expenditures. Mandatory expansion of Social Security coverage would have a significant positive effect on the financing of the program. The shortterm versus long-term implications would depend on the inclusion of workers not currently covered. Although these results are impressive, it should be understood that any new revenues accruing to Social Security have to come from somewhere. Before considering the possible sources, we examine two alternatives to universal coverage. Modification o[ the Bene[i't Computation--Modifying the benefit computation lot workers with noncovered earnings could eliminate the unintended benefits now paid bv the Social Securitv program. Basically two options have received serious consideration--the "average-replacement-rate" formula, and the "proportional earnings" formula. The average-replacement-rate formula corresponds to the method for estimating windfalls for dual beneficiaries previously discussed. Under this modification, workers with noncovered employment would not receive a higher replacement rate on their covered earnings than workers whose total earnings were in covered employment. Calculating the benefit under this method would require the derivation of a phantom AIME and PIA. In this calculation, total career earnings would be tested as though thev were covered. These phantom values would be used to derive the intended or "correct" replacement rate, which would then be multiplied bv the actual AIME to derive the intended PIA. The PIA would be adjusted bv actuarial reductions to obtain the benefit that the annuitant was intended to receive under the Social Security program as designed. 219 TABLE VII-6 Estimated Amount by Which OASDI Taxes Exceed Expenditures, a as a Percentage of Total Taxable Payroll, after Extension of Coverage Effective on January 1, 1984, for Selected Calendar Years 1984-2060 Calendar Year 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 22O Employees Pre_nt and Futu_ (Percent) .88 .87 .87 .86 .85 .84 .83 .83 .81 .80 .79 .77 .76 .74 .73 .71 .69 .68 .67 .65 .64 .63 .62 .61 .61 .60 .56 .48 .40 .33 .29 .27 .26 .26 Affected Futu_ Hires (Percent) .04 .13 .19 .24 .27 .33 .39 .43 .48 .52 .55 .57 .59 .61 .62 .63 .65 .66 .67 .67 .68 .69 .69 .73 .79 .81 .78 .66 .53 .41 .34 .30 .27 .26 Calendar Year TABLE VII-6 (Continued) Employees Affected Present and Future Future Hires (Percent) (Percent) 25- Year A _,erages 1982-2006 2007-2031 2032-2056 .70 .58 .32 .45 .76 .38 75-Year Average 1982 2056 .53 .53 Source: Social Security Administration, Office of the Actuary. Note: The group affected includes federal civil servants and employees of state and local governments and nonprofit institutions. qncludes only OASDI portion ot the payroll tax. This proposal would reduce the windfalls provided bv Social Security to workers with periods of noncovered employment. Because it could not be implemented retrospectively, it would allow for a slow phase-in of the reductions in benefits from Social Security. It would partially meet the goals of expanded coverage and might actually serve to encourage coverage of all public and nonprofit workers not now covered. This option would not, however, completely eliminate all future windfall benefits for workers with only short periods of service in noncovered employment. For workers with less than five years of noncovered earnings, the proposal might provide virtually the same Social Security benefit as the current formula, but such workers would continue to be exempt from paying Social Security taxes on their noncovered earnings. This feature would continue the current pattern of high Social Security benefits in relation to contributions for workers with short periods of noncovered employment. The effect of this option on Social Security administrative procedures would be substantial. Information on noncovered wages is not recorded on any of the program record files maintained bv the Social Security Administration. Developing procedures to include, post, and verit_v this information would substantially add to current workloads. Such procedures would also complicate the benefit calculation process at the field level. The indexing computations would be required for each case in which noncovered earnings were included. This increase in processing would double the resources required for benefit calculations for the cases affected, and might also result in a larger number of manually handled cases. 221 The proportional earnings formula t3 is a modification of the average-replacement-rate formula that also attempts to eliminate the contribution gap resulting from short periods of noncovered employment. For workers with total work careers of thirty-five years or less after 1990, this alternative would result in the same benefit as the average replacement rate formula discussed above. For workers with more than thirty-five years of earnings, this option would result in a smaller Social Security benefit than the average replacement alternative. With a proportional earnings formula, a phantom PIA would be calculated on the basis of total earnings, consisting of all covered earnings plus all noncovered earnings up to the Social Security maximum for each year after the effective date. This phantom PIA would be reduced by multiplying it bv the ratio of total covered earnings to the sum of the total covered and noncovered earnings up to the Social Security maximum for each year. The product would be the actual PIA on which Social Security benefits would be based. The effect of this alternative would be to provide workers with noncovered earnings with the same ratio of expected Social Security benefits to covered indexed earnings that they would have received had their full career earnings streams been covered. Like the average-replacement-formula, this option would result in a slow phasing in of the reductions in Social Security benefits, because it could only be implemented on a prospective basis. This option would be more effective than the average-replacement-formula in eliminating the contribution gaps. It would reduce the benefits of a worker with fewer than five years of noncovered employment. There would be no effect on the benefits of workers with only covered employment, but the administration of the Social Security program would become considerably more complex. There have been no estimates of the effects of either of these modifications of the Social Security formula on system costs. If the estimates of the windfalls to dual beneficiaries are in the right order of magnitude, the average replacement formula should save the system at least 0.1 percent of payroll in the long term. Likewise, if the estimates of the total unintended benefits are close to being correct, the proportional earnings formula could save as much as 0.2 percent of payroll. If the estimates are as conservative as the previous section of the paper suggests, the proportional earnings formula might ul)3This is the proposal advocated Social Security, Social Security 191-192. 222 in the final report of the National in America's Future (Washington, Commission on D.C., 1981), pp. timatelv save as much as 0.3 percent of payroll. These would be longterm savings, though. The early-year savings would be minimal because Social Security cannot obtain noncovered earnings before 1978. Although Social Security now receives such data annually, noncovered earnings are not being posted to administrative records. More important, the contribution gaps are caused bv worker mobility, most of which occurs among young workers early in their careers. These proposals cannot capture the foregone contributions until retirement benefits commence, many years in the future. In contrast, mandatory coverage of new entrants only, would close most of the contribution gaps very quickly, because the majority of current workers who will leave noncovered employment without being entitled to a pension will do so in the next five years. O_setting the No_zcovered Pension Benefit--In May 1981, the Reagan administration's Social Security proposals aimed at reducing the unwarranted bonuses included a public pension offset. This strategy would involve determination of whether a person eligible for Social Security benefits is also eligible for a retirement benefit from noncovered employment. If so, the Social Security benefit would be reduced. During 1981, the Social Security benefit formula provided 90 percent replacement of the first $211 of the AIME, 32 percent of the next $1,063 of AIME and 15 percent of AIME in excess of $1,274. The administration's proposal called for reducing Social Security benefits for beneficiaries of these pensions bv providing only 32 percent of the first $211 of AIME subject to the benefit reduction not to exceed 50 percent of the pension amount. The difference between 90 and 32 percent replacement of $211 of AIME is $122.38 monthly. Under this proposal, the offset would be computed on the amount of the monthly pension at the time the worker becomes concurrently entitled to a Social Security benefit and a pension based on noncovered employment. If the pension benefit exceeded $245, the full offset would apply. If it were less, the offset would be half the monthly pension benefit. Dependents benefits, maximum family benefits, reductions due to age, and other calculations would be based on the new PIA after the reduction due to the offset. This recommendation has a precedent in that the Social Security benefit for a man receiving a benefit as a spouse is now reduced dollar for dollar if he is also receiving a public pension for noncovered employment. After December 1982, this provision will also apply to women. Unlike many of the windfall reduction proposals that call for direct modification of the Social Security benefit formula, pension offset 223 plans would not require a long phase-in period. Because the reductions could be implemented immediately, however, there could be larger benefit differences for persons becoming entitled at slightly different points in time, even though they had similar career and earnings patterns. A public pension offset could be viewed as introducing a means test into the determination of Social Security benefits. Persons with comparable covered earnings would receive different Social Security benefits according to the amount of their noncovered pension, and pension amounts paid by different public employment retirement systems on a given earnings history could vary significantly, depending on their benefit computation rules. A public pension offset would have no effect on the Social Security benefits of workers who do not become entitled to a noncovered pension. This feature would perpetuate the advantageous treatment of workers with short periods of noncovered employment who benefit from the contribution gap. This particular pension offset proposal would not address the windfall benefits of annuitants who receive small public pension amounts because of short periods of noncovered employment. Administratively, a public pension offset would be simpler than the average-replacement-rate or proportional earnings formula modifications. The biggest problem would be the verification of the pension amount by the noncovered employer. The IRS tax form W-2P contains the worker's Social Security number and the pension paid and is provided to the Social Security Administration. A system interface could be developed that would match W-2P reporting information with Social Security's master beneficiary record system to allow the computation of the appropriate offset. For this interface to work, IRS would have to require reporting of all public pension income on the W-2P form, which it does not now do, and would need to add some indication of whether the pension was based on earnings not covered by Social Security. The short-term effect on Social Security financing would be negligible because the proposal would affect only persons who retire after the implementation date. The Social Security Administration estimates the long-term effect on financing at 0.1 percent of payroll. The Effect Recipients of Eliminating the Unintended The options for reducing the unintended all have a positive effect on Social Security 224 Benefits on Social Security benefits financing. In the short- term, the pension offset and formula modifications would have little effect. The tull effect of the pension offset on specific individuals could be immediate, but it would be years before all existing dual beneficiaries would be replaced by retirees affected bv the proposal. Phasing in the formula modifications would occur even more slowly. Because historical data on noncovered earnings are not available, it would take years before specific individuals would feel the full effects of the proposals. This fact, in conjunction with the fact that the proposal would apply only to future retirees, suggests that the impact on shortterm financing issues would be insignificant. Coverage, of course, has the largest effect on the short-term financing situation. Coverage of currently exempted workers has the most significant and immediate effect. Even covering new entrants onlv is far more effective from a short-term Social Security financing perspective than the alternatives to expanded coverage. The major problem with the options that have been discussed thus far is that each has certain costs that someone must bear. Reducing the Social Security benefits to account for noncovered earnings or pension benefits would place the costs of windfall elimination directly on the worker alone. For persons receiving benefits from pensions resulting from noncovered employment, reductions in Social Security benefits would probably not result in offsetting increases in pension benefits. For persons withdrawing completely from such pension plans, these options would either reduce ultimate retirement income or have no effect on the unwarranted bonuses. Adjustments of Social Security benefit levels would not resolve the problems of gaps in insurance protection that now exist in systems that do not provide Social Security coverage. But, Social Securitv coverage would probably result in some redistribution of retirement benefits and might affect the magnitude and incidence of retirement costs. It is clear which persons will bear the burden of benefit reductions if windfalls are to be reduced or eliminated. The costs of expanded coverage warrant closer examination because, the issues varv with the groups of workers being considered. The Cost of Coverage for Federal Workers Advocates of mandatory Social Security coverage of federal workers often focus on the beneficial effects for Social Securitv. Critics of mandatory coverage, in contrast, argue that covering federal workers will raise the cost of federal civilian retirement programs and threaten the viability of their retirement trust funds. This section analyzes the 225 potential effect that Social Security coverage of federal workers would have on the cost of the federal Civil Service Retirement System and the federal budgetary effect of such a measure. In order for a discussion of this sort to be meaningful, it has to be concrete. This analysis focuses on an option--IV-A--discussed in a recent report issued by the Congressional Research Service. 14 Option IV-A was chosen because it closely parallels the plan included in legislation recently introduced by Senator Ted Stevens. The analysis assumes that all workers hired for federal civilian jobs after January l, 1983, would be covered by Social Security and by a defined-contribution plan that would be financed solely by employer contributions. This plan would provide contributions of 9 percent on the first $20,000 of salary and 16 percent above that. The $20,000 would be indexed by increases in the general wage schedule over time. In addition to the basic benefit, a supplemental thrift plan would also be available for workers covered under the new plan. This plan would allow the employee to contribute up to 6 percent of salary into the plan and would be fully matched by the employer. The Stevens bill would fully match employee contributions up to 3 percent of salary. This element of the Stevens bill would reduce the cost estimates presented. However, the Stevens bill would also provide contributions based on military service, raising costs compared with the option considered here. The option discussed here and the Stevens bill would also modify the federal employee sick leave and disability program to coordinate with Social Security. The cost of CSRS can be considered from different perspectives. One common way to estimate the cost of a retirement program is to use what actuaries call the "entry age normal cost method." This method estimates the percentage of a worker's salary that would have to be set aside each year to fully fund benefit entitlements by retirement. Aggregating the normal cost of all workers provides an estimate of the employer's total normal cost. As with most estimates, the normal cost estimate is sensitive to the assumptions on which it is based. Table VII-7 uses two different sets of economic assumptions to estimate the normal cost of the current CSRS program. The greatest variance in assumptions for the two estimates is in inflation, although the inflation/interest differential is most significant in explaining the variance in the normal cost estimates. The real interest rate, or return 14Congressional Research Service, Restructuring the Civil Sen,ice Retirement System: Analysis of Options to Control Costs and Mamtai_zRetirement hlcome Security (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1982). 226 TABLE VII-7 Effect of Economic Assumptions on Civil Service Retirement System Cost Estimates CSRS Board of Actuaries Social Security 1981, II-B Interest Rate (Percent) Wage Growth (Percent) Inflation Rate (Percent) Normal Cost (Percent) 6.0 5.5 5.0 36.46 6.1 5.5 4.0 31.23 Source: Congressional Research Service, Restructuring the Civil ServiceRetirement Svstern: Analysis o[ Options to Control Costs and Maintain Retirement Income Security (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1982), p. 50. on assets under the 1981 Trustees Report II-B assumptions, is twice that under the Board of Actuaries' assumptions. Higher interest rates raise investment income over time and increase the degree to which the trust fund supports benefits. Since employees covered by CSRS contribute 7 percent of salary to the retirement program, the cost of the program to the employer (i.e., the government) cost is 29.46 or 24.23 percent of payroll, depending on which set of assumptions is used. Since this discussion is focusing on Social Security coverage costs, the Social Security assumptions are used for the remainder of the discussion. The normal cost measure is a useful concept because it gives a good perspective on the generosity of the retirement program in comparison with pensions established by other employers. For example, in the private sector, employer normal costs for retirement programs generally run about 7 to 12 percent of payroll on top of Social Security. The normal cost is also useful because it is indicative of the portion of lifetime benefits paid to workers in the form of deferred retirement income. The projected employer cost of the defined contribution plan analyzed here is 14.50 percent of payroll. 15 By comparison, the projected employer cost of the Stevens proposal is 14.49 percent of payroll. Including the employer OASDHI contributions at the ultimate rate of 7.65 percent now legislated would raise total employer cost for the modified federal retirement program to 22.15 percent of payroll--substantially less than the cost of the current system. _Slbid.,p. 53. 227 An alternative way to evaluate the cost of CSRS is to look at the cost on a budget basis. This is useful because it reflects the relative cost of federal retirement for taxpayers and participants. Figure VIII pictorially represents the operation of the CSRS during fiscal 1980. The budget box represents the total federal budget components of the CSRS. It includes the off-budget Postal Service. The first inner box represents the unified budget. The arrows represent the budgetary flows relevant to CSRS. All transactions that cross the outermost box affect the total cost of CSRS. Transactions crossing the largest interior box affect the unified budget. FIGURE VII-I Flow of Funds Related to the Civil Service System, 1980 Employee Postal Contributions Retirement Contributions ($3.60 Billion) ($1.49 Billion) UNIFIED BUDGET \ GeneraI Revem_e._ Agency "_ CSRS F.nd CoMributions ($2.85 Billion) Direct Appropriations/ Transfers Interest ($11.23 Billion) on Investments ($4.9 Billion) Annuities, Refunds. ($14,78 Billion) Source: 228 Budget flows 1982, appendix taken from p.l-V118. Budget o[ the United States Government Expenses Fiscal Year The implication of this depiction is that most of the funding of CSRS is internal to the unified budget. Even the Postal Service contributions fall conceptually within the unified budget framework. If the United States Postal Service (USPS) increased its contributions, higher postage rates or general revenue support of that off-budget account could result. In either case the cost would be borne by the public. In terms of total federal outlays in 1980, benefits and refunds amounted to $14.78 billion while employee contributions were $3.60 billion. The 1980 USPS contribution was split between the normal 7 percent agency contribution ($775 million) and the obligations ($714 million) vis-a-vis unfunded liabilities. Since USPS is off budget, its contributions do affect the unified budget net costs of the program but not total outlays from the taxpayers' perspective. In short, the taxpayer cost of CSRS is equal to total benefits plus contribution refunds minus employee contributions. In 1980 this was $11.18 billion ($14.78 billion minus $3.60 billion). The example also raises another important point in regard to funding CSRS liabilities. Much concern has been voiced over the unfunded liabilities of CSRS. The total liabilities of the system exist because of the statutes that define the program. To the extent the system holds government securities as its funding instruments, it has a contractual promise from the government (IOUs) that certain resources will be available to meet benefit payments as required. The unfunded liabilities, in contrast, arc statutory promises that have arisen because benefits accrued under the law have not been matched by a comparable pool of assets (i.e., government IOUs). Converting statutory liabilities into contractual obligations would not affect benefit levels because they are separately defined by statute. The important point is that there be a funding mechanism available to meet these benefit obligations, as they come due. Even though the current system has sizable unfunded liabilities, the current funding method assures benefits for the foreseeable future. The budgetary process would allow more rapid funding of CSRS liabilities than now occurs without having an adverse effect on taxpayers. Although an added annual contribution, say $20 billion, would be an increase in general revenue expenditures, that contribution would be exactly offset by an increase in CSRS income. The U.S. government would increase its bond issues (i.e., the debt level) by $20 billion, but these would be offset by a $20 billion increase in CSRS funds. In the future, the interest on the additional debt would have to be paid to the trust fund, but current law requires interest 229 payment on the unfunded liabilities. There would be no practical impact on the taxpayers. This is not to suggest that CSRS should be funded instantaneously, or that the unfunded liability should be ignored. The presence of a fully funded system could well lead to pressure for benefit increases, which would, in turn, increase the taxpayers' cost. Yet the unfunded liability is a real cost that will eventually have to be covered. The important variable to consider is what it would cost to modify the current system. The foregoing discussion suggests that CSRS budgetary effects could be described by the following formula: (I) CSRS Budgetary Cost = benefits plus refunds minus employee contributions. Table VII-8 shows the long-term projected budgetary costs of the current CSRS if the program is not modified. 16 The budget is also affected by Social Security windfall benefits paid to persons covered by CSRS. The annual magnitude of these windfalls for federal workers and annuitants was estimated earlier in this chapter to have been roughly $1 billion in 1980. Because the current system gives rise to these Social Security windfalls, they should be considered as raising the cost of the current system. While the costs of these windfalls should be considered as part of the total, they are not included in the estimates of the current system's cost for comparisons with the modified system. They are not included because the Stevens bill does not provide for explicit windfall reductions. The Stevens bill would, however, gradually eliminate the windfall phenomenon for federal workers and result in real savings to taxpayers. The particular method for modifying the system analyzed by the Congressional Research Service and included in Senator Stevens's bill calls for Social Security coverage coordinated with a modified federal pension for new federal employees beginning in 1983. That means that the ongoing costs of the total system have to be estimated separately for the closed system that applies to old hires, and for the new system covering future employees. The budgetary costs of the separate systems can be aggregated to get the combined systems cost. The total budgetary impact of modifying CSRS would be different from the effect on the various accounts taken separately. Both CSRS I_See Sylvester J. Schieber, Sen, ice Retirement System of the derivation of these 230 The Cost and Funding Implications o['Modif_ving the Civil (Washington, D.C.: EBR1, 1982) for a complete discussion estimates. TABLE VII-8 Federal Agency and General Revenue Expenditure Projections for the Current Civil Service Retirement System and Modified System in Conjunction with Newly Hired Workers Under Social Security, Selected Years, 1983-2050 Current System (Billions) Modified System (Billions) $ 17.9 20.0 22.4 24.3 26.3 28.4 30.3 32.3 34.2 42.4 54.5 70.8 93.2 122.4 161.8 212.6 277.7 360.0 465.7 604.1 786.7 $ 17.7 19.2 22.2 24.1 26.1 28.1 30.1 31.7 33.7 41.7 54.7 68.1 86.1 102.9 130.8 167.3 211.8 273.6 360.3 499.2 683.6 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 Source: and Net Savings (Billions) $ 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.6 0.5 0.8 - 0.2 2.7 7.1 19.5 31.0 45.3 65.9 86.4 105.4 104.9 103.1 Svh'ester J. Schieber, "The Cost and Funding Implications of Modifying the Cixil Service Retirement System," (Washington, D.C.: EBRI, August 19, 1982), tables 2, 6, and 8. Social Security arc now within proposal analyzed here would costs for the various accounts (2) Closed CSRS (3) New CSRS (4) Social Costs Costs Security - the unified budget. Because the segregate the old and new systems, can be considered as follows: the benefits (old) plus refunds employee contributions. = benefits (new) plus refunds employee contribulions. Costs - benefits (SS) ittim_s contributions. mi_uLs minus employee 231 (5) Total Budget Cost - old CSRS cost plus new CSRS cost plus Social Security cost. _7 Equation (2) is essentially the same as equation (1) discussed earlier, which applies to the current system. The difference is that equation (2) applies only to those workers on the payroll or persons entitled to CSRS benefits (receiving or deferred) on the assumed date the modified system would be put into operation. Equation (1), in contrast, assumed that future new workers would continue to be covered under the current system. Equation (3) represents the budgetary cost of the new federal retirement program. Equation (4) shows the budgetary effects of Social Security coverage of new hires. The budgetary effect is different from the effect on the OASDHI accounts, in that the specific account would be credited for both employer and employee contributions. Since Social Security is in the unified budget, the employer contribution would show up as an expense in the agencies' budget and as equal trust fund income in the Social Security accounts. The two would cancel each other out. If Social Security is taken out of the unified budget it would change the analysis conceptually without affecting the practical result. For example, if Social Security were an off-budget account, the employer contribution would show up as a real budget expense. The contribution would show up as income to an off-budget account. The budgetary and off-budget accounts would both still be federal accounts, however. While taking Social Security off budget would change the bookkeeping, it would not change the overall fiscal position of the federal government if coverage were extended to federal workers. The total budgetary costs, modifying CSRS as considered here, can be calculated according to equation (5) and compared with the cost of the current system derived on the basis of equation (1). Table VII8 shows the projected budgetary cost of the current system and the proposed modified system and the net differences. Based on the projections, moving to the modified system on January 1, 1983, would reduce the budgetary costs of federal retirement by $1 billion over the first five years. While the cost savings during the early years would be moderate in relative terms, the actual numbers that would show up in the unified budget might be affected by moving accounts in or out of the budget. This would not affect taxpayer costs for federal retirement, however. 17SeeSylvester J. Schieber. Tile Cost and Fmldml¢ Implication,s olModil),i_l_ the Civil Sera,iceRetirement System (Washington, D.C.:EBRI, 1982)10r the detailed proiections of the component eiements of each o1 these equations. 232 The Stevens legislation would cover newly hired workers mandatorily and offer incentives for current workers to move to the new system. The savings from modifying CSRS in accordance with this proposal would grow significantly after the turn of the century as the federal work force becomes predominantly covered bv the new system. Ultimately, the savings would grow to nearly one-quarter of the current system's cost if it were to be perpetuated. The net savings estimates of moving to the modified system do not include any savings that could be realized if a Social Security windfall reduction provision for old hires were implemented. For example, Congressman J. J. Pickle, Chairman of the Social Security Subcommittee of the House Ways and Means Committee, has suggested legislation that would reduce future windfalls for persons not covered by Social Security for some portion of their career. His proposal would reduce the benefit derived under the current formula to that percentage of total lifetime earnings in covered employment. If such a proposal were implemented in 1983, the total savings would be small. However, if one assumed that windfalls were reduced at a rate of 2 percent per year, additional savings could be as much as $100 million by the mid 1980s and rise to more than $1 billion by the turn of the century. The Social Security actuaries have estimated similar savings. They estimated the Pickle proposal would save $100 million in both 1985 and 1986, and average 0.05 percent of total Social Security covered payroll over the next seventy-five years. The net cost increase in the proposed system around the turn of the century, shown in table VII-8, is the result of modification to vesting provisions under the new plan. By that time, significant numbers of terminating workers will be rolling their vested benefits into alternative retirement vehicles as they leave federal service. If the proposed modification of the new system were made in conjunction with a windfall reduction proposal, the cost savings that would result from modifications to the CSRS would be significantly greater than those shown in table VII-8. In sum, modifying the CSRS along the lines of the option analyzed here, or the Stevens proposal, would result in significant budgetary savings over both the short and long term. Coverage of new hires under Social Security would maintain the level of employee contributions for retirement purposes. In a budgetary sense then, any proposal coupled with Social Security coverage that just maintains or does not increase total federal retirement benefits cannot cost the taxpayers more than the current system. 233 The Stevens bill includes a "grandfathering" provision which seeks to maintain the "implied contract" between the employer and current employees. This provision would continue to cover all current workers under the current CSRS unless they voluntarily joined the new system. The Supreme Court has held that the current system is not a legal obligation but a gratuity. Congress has repeatedly modified the system over the years. The question that Congress will have to face in the future is whether the "implied contract" with its own workers who are only twenty, thirty, or even forty years of age is not subject to change during a period when the "implied Social Security contract" is being changed for the general populace. The CSRS could be closed for substantial numbers of current federal workers. Their earnings replacement accruals to date could be frozen and applied against their final average salaries when they are eligible to retire. Their future accruals would accumulate under the new plan, thus making the transition to the modified system far more gradual than under the Stevens proposal. Although the federal retirement program would still be comparatively generous, the costs of federal pensions would not rise as a result of Social Security coverage unless retirement benefits rose. The elimination of the unintended benefits now provided by Social Security would provide a net savings to the taxpayers who support the federal retirement programs. Analysis by the actuary of the Office of Personnel Management, provided to the Universal Coverage Study group, indicated that existing CSRS financing measures would keep the federal retirement program solvent through a transition to Social Security coverage. Solvency could be achieved if coverage were extended either to current workers or only new hires for any of the coordination models they considered. The Stevens proposal has explicit transition provisions to do so. The Cost The state of Coverage for State and local situation and Local is different Workers from the federal case in several respects. To identify the implications of mandatory coverage, the Universal Coverage Study group commissioned an actuarial analysis of several state and local plans. A constant-benefit concept was posited at this level as a reasonable constraint in designing modified pension plans in coordination with Social Security coverage. The concept was that initial benefits at retirement provided by the current system should be matched by the modified system. There was a major problem in putting this concept into operation, because the state and 234 local plans do not index benefits at levels near recent increases in the consumer price index, as Social Security and CSRS do. The typical state or local plan provides a capped cost-of-living adjustment of as much as 3 percent per year, and more generous plans provide 5 percent increases if the CPI exceeds that level. When the Universal Coverage Study group specified the dimensions for their constant-benefit plans, they stipulated that the modified plans coordinated with Social Security should provide benefits equal to the current plan in the first years of retirement for the average retiree. Because Social Security would provide a more fully indexed benefit than the portion of the pension benefit that it was replacing, the coordinated retirement program would significantly increase lifetime benefits if this approach were used in actual plan design. This effect can be seen in table VII-9, which shows the present values of benefits at retirement for a typical worker under a set of existing plans. The table also shows the value of benefits for a set of coordinated plans using the first-year constant-benefit design concept. In both cases the value of benefits are shown under two inflation assumptions. Employee turnover rates are also important in determining the potential effects of Social Security coverage on pension costs for systems that are not covered. One high-turnover plan discussed in the Universal Coverage Study, for example, had a normal cost of 10.9 percent of payroll. If turnover, except for death, disability, and retirement, were eliminated from this plan, the normal cost would be 18.8 percent of payroll. In contrast, a plan with very low turnover had a normal cost of 19.1 percent of payroll, which rose to only 21.1 under the assumption that all employees stayed to draw a benefit. The system's costs, in short, are reduced as a result of turnover. Social Security tax payments, of course, are not refundable. Part of the savings that noncovered systems now experience as a result of turnover would be eliminated if coverage were mandated. The Universal Coverage Study estimated that this added cost would range from 0.3 percent of payroll for low-turnover plans to 3.9 percent of payroll for high-turnover plans. _ The Universal Coverage Study also found that some noncovered public systems pay the Part A Medicare premiums for their annuitants who have not acquired Medicare coverage on the basis of covered I_Universal Coverage Study, pp. 210-211. This is the reason are withdrawing from Social Security and substituting ported to be as generous but at a much lower cost. that some retirement employers programs today pur- 235 mmbm_b__m U _ N = 236 _ s E --__ __.- _---__ _ _ _._ , m_ 237 employment. Their evidence showed, however, that most noncovered state and local employees do become eligible for Medicare, although they contribute nothing to the program from their noncovered earnings. For this reason, coverage would add more than 1 percent to the payroll costs of many of the affected employers, who would get negligible increments in benefits in return. Iv Social Security coverage would also result in higher survivor benefits than those provided by many noncovered state and local systems. Surviving spouse's benefits after retirement are often available if the annuitant takes a reduced annuity with the survivor option, but many systems simply refund the employee's contribution to the heirs of any worker who dies before retirement. 2° Each of these considerations suggests that mandatory Social Security coverage for noncovered state and local governments would raise retirement program costs. The Universal Coverage Study group undertook two independent efforts to estimate the costs of coverage for noncovered plans. The first was a study conducted by the Actuarial Education and Research Fund (AERF), which had actuaries for twentyfive noncovered employer plans estimate the costs of coverage. The second was conducted through an interagency study sponsored by the Department of Housing and Urban Development, which had provided a grant to the Urban Institute to analyze several facets of public pension policy. The Urban Institute contracted with Howard Winklevoss and Associates of Philadelphia for an analysis of the implications of coverage for twenty-one large noncovered state and local pension plans. Both studies showed that the total pension costs of noncovered systems would increase significantly if Social Security coverage were extended to these systems. 21 The AERF estimates for large plans suggested greater increases than the Winklevoss estimates. The reason is that the latter study designed coordinated plan benefits that would replicate first-year retirement benefits for an average retiree. The AERF study, in contrast, attempted to replicate first-year benefits for the modal group of annuitants. The result was that benefits were being matched for workers with salaries significantly above mean or median levels. 22 In both cases, the matching of first-year benefits would lead to significantly higher lifetime benefits under a coordiIgUniversalCoverageStudy, p. 21 I. 2°UniversalCoveragestudy, p. 188. 2_The summary results of the AERF analysis are shown in table VII-lO; summary estimates from the Winklevoss analysis are in table VII-11. 22UniversalCoverageStudy, p. 214. 238 nated system benefits. because of the greater indexation of Social Security The Universal Coverage Study concluded that the net effect of coverage on combined employee-employer pension costs under the constant-benefit formulas would range from 5 to 10 percent of payroll. The summary results of these cost estimates are shown in tables VII10 and VII-1 i. It is hard to project how these cost increases might be shared on a nominal basis. Employee contributions are more common to public defined-benefit pension plans than to their private-sector counterparts. Among public plans that already have Social Security coverage, the norm for employee contributions is 4 percent of salary to the pension in addition to the employee share of the Social Security payroll tax) 3 A fundamental question pertinent to this issue is whether state and local jurisdictions would modify their plans in response to Social Security coverage in the way hypothesized in the report. The answer is that they probably would not. They might attempt to "grandfather" current workers who were affected bv a coverage measure, but it is highly unlikely that pension plans would be redesigned to provide more generous retirement benefits for workers who have not vet been hired. If anything, recent modifications to public pension plans have aimed at reducing benefits. Specific recent cases where such redesigns have taken place include the Indianapolis, New York City, San Francisco, and Maryland State retirement systems. In three of the four cases, the plans allowed current workers to opt into the new, less generous plan by providing financial incentives. Maryland, for example, changed from a contributory to a noncontributory (but less expensive) plan. To encourage workers to transfer credits from the old plan to the new, rebates of employee contributions under the old plan plus interest were offered in exchange for new service credits. The transition issue might also cause particular problems for some state and local systems. The budgetary issues discussed for a coverage transition for federal workers also apply to state and local systems. At the federal level, however, pension financing occurs at the same level of government as Social Security financing. If benefits were the same after coverage as before, there would be no budgetary effect. At the state and local levels, the pension benefit stream would not be immediately reduced because of mandated coverage. The affected jurisdiction would have to continue meeting pension payments while simultaneously forfeiting revenue from employee contributions, in 23Ibid.. p. XV. 239 TABLE VII-10 Normal Cost of Current Plan Compared with Normal Cost of Constant Benefit Step-Rate Plus Social Security Payroll Taxes Current Plan (Percent) Plan a Large Plans (1,000 or more Constant Benefit Plan (Percent) Combined Benefit Plan Plus 15.3 Combined Social Security Payroll Taxes (Percent) members) H 1- t 11.89 (1) 5.21 (2) 20.51 H2 H3 H4 H5 H6 14.83 16.81 16.27 12.72 18.92 8.95 8.84 5.84 6.61 9.26 24.25 24.04 b 21.14 10.95 h 24.56 7.82 14.39 15.68 5.34 6.75 7.93 20.64 20.95 b 23.23 12.98 11.08 6.06 10.19 10.86 9.80 10.11 18.60 28.28 26.38 21.36 25.49 23.52 b 25.00 t' 25.41 33.90 19.20 34.50 11.04 8.10 17.33 8.89 23.78 25.24 26.34 23.40 32.63 24.19 39.08 40.54 18.59 33.89 - p,f g,t,p,f g g t LI - g L3 - g L6 - g Medium-Size M1 - p M2 - g,p,f M3 - p,f M4 - p M5 - g,p,f M6 - g,p,f M7 - f M8 - f Plans ( 100-999 members) 20.91 19.87 12.11 19.15 19.68 19.73 16.09 30.06 M9 - p,f Small Sl S2 $5 $6 T! T3 - Plans (Less than p p,f p p p f T4 - p,f Source: 23.13 100 members) 17.87 13.66 22.72 17.51 31.58 38.50 23.90 Universal Coverage Study, report of the Universal Social Security Coverage Study Group (Washington, D.C., March 1980), table 6-23, p. 194. _'ln this coding, f = Fire Fighter plans, g = general public employee plan, p = police plan, and t - teacher plan. _'Combincd Social Securitv taxes arc somewhat below 15.30 percent of salaries above the wage base. 240 TABLE VII-I 1 Normal Cost Versus Constant-Benefit Plan Plus Social Security Taxes for Selected Employee Retirement Systems as a Percentage of Payroll Current Present Plan's Normal Cost (Percent) Assumptions a Constant-Benefit Plan's Normal Cost Plus Social Security Taxes (Percent) Employees' Plan No. 80 120 140 260 620 675 685 735 830 980 995 17.1 12.4 10.9 12.0 13.5 13.6 12.2 15.3 10.5 12.2 17.5 23.6 20.5 20.0 19.6 23.9 20.1 19.5 22.5 15.6 20.4 22.1 Fighters' Plan No. 560 600 760 975 990 17.8 16.2 31.2 18.1 33.8 26.7 27.8 33.7 29.0 43.3 16.3 9.9 15.0 9.1 15.5 21.6 25.0 18.1 24.5 17.5 24.0 24.2 400 440 490 500 510 970 Coverage Study, report of the Universal Social Security Coverage (Washington, D.C., March 1980), table 6-26, p. 197. taxes include 15.30 percent combined employer and employee Estimates reflect plan actuarial assumptions. Plans shown arc Social Security. Income Security Act forty-year amortization of untunded liaboth cases. 241 many cases, and meeting employer payroll tax liabilities. Where the old system is fully funded, this problem may not be serious because (1)current benefits would be paid out of the pension fund and (2) contributions to the pension fund could be reduced because liabilities would accrue less rapidly under a plan modified in coordination with Social Security coverage. Where the plan is financed on a pay-as-you-go basis, the implications would he substantial. The jurisdiction would have to finance current benefits from its current budget while also paying any payroll tax liabilities that would result from coverage. From a strictly fiscal perspective, a set of financial incentives could be devised to encourage state and local jurisdictions to cover current workers. If newly covered state and local jurisdictions were mandated to cover current workers, for example, it would be possible to give the employer a break on the payroll tax for some period to help meet the transition costs to coverage. Table VII-12 shows the effects of covering all state and local workers beginning in 1985 if the full payroll tax is collected. The table also shows the effect if newly covered employers were given a five-year holiday from paying their share of the payroll tax. It is clear from the table that it would be to Social Security's advantage to cover current state and local workers, while giving the newly covered employers a temporary financial break on the payroll tax to help meet the costs of transition from noncoverage to coverage. In fact, it would be possible to go even further and, starting in 1990, phase in the employer portion of the payroll tax. The employer could be required, for example, to pay 1 percent of payroll in 1990, 2 percent in 1991, and so forth until the full payroll tax burden was met. Such financial incentives would result in greater added revenues for Social Security in the short term than the revenues that would result from covering new employees only. Such a plan would also make the prospects of coverage more palatable for the affected jurisdictions. The major potential problem with this approach is that jurisdictions that were already covered might complain that they were not offered similar incentives. However, considering the relatively low levels of the payroll tax that prevailed when most of these plans entered the Social Security system it might be argued that earlier entrants had received a comparable advantage. The new costs associated with mandatory coverage would not be distributed uniformly. Those states with substantial numbers of noncovered workers in the public sector would bear more new costs than states in which many localities or state agencies already participate 242 TABLE VII-12 Effects of Expanded Coverage for State and Local Workers on Social Security Revenues for 1985 and 1990 Under II-B Assumptions, 1985-1990 Year 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 Sources: Benefit Increases (Millions) Full Contribution Net Revenue Collection Gain (Millions) (Millions) $ 0 $ 7,500 40 8,1 O0 1O0 8,800 200 9,500 300 10,200 500 11,800 Benefit increase estimated derived trom table VII-5. Employee Contribution Only Net Revenue Collection Gain (Millions) (Millions) $ 7,500 $ 3,750 $ 3,750 8,060 4,050 4,010 8,700 4,400 4,300 9,300 4,750 4,550 9,900 5,1 O0 4,800 11,300 5,900 5,400 bv the author from table VII-4. Collections were in Social Security. Specifically, Colorado, Louisiana, Massachusetts, Nevada, and Ohio would experience the largest increases in total pension costs. In addition, California, Maine, Missouri, Illinois, and Texas have substantial numbers of public cmployees who would be affected. Sevcral noncovered local .jurisdictions within states that are largely covered also would have higher costs if coverage were expanded. Total pension costs in the affected jurisdiction, however, would generally not be higher than in localities alreadv covered by Social Security. Mandatory Organizations Social Security Coverage of Nonprofit The issues for employers of nonprofit organizations are less clearly defined than for public-sector workers. Mandatory coverage would improve the retirement income protection of most noncovered workers. Because much employment in this sector is sporadic, however, and because much nonprofit activity occurs without any contact with government, it would be hard to enforce mandatory coverage for all nonprofit enterprises. For employers who do not have any retirement plan, Social Security coverage would increase the cost of doing business. For employers who do have plans, the issues are similar to those discussed tor state and local employers. 243 Other Issues Coverage Associated with Mandatory Social Security The Fund to Assure Independent Retirement makes several in opposition to universal Social Security coverage: points FAIR research indicates that in the end, merger would cost the taxpayers more, not less. Today's contributor becomes tomorrow's liability to Social Security. And if government were to provide supplementary retirement, as is the case with "company" plans, taxpayers would have to absorb the cost of the additional plan. Public employees who are exempted from Social Securitv coverage actually pay more taxes than persons with corresponding incomes who are covered by Social Security. While working, both are taxed on their income, including the dollars paid either to Social Security or their retirement plan. But after retirement, ex-public employees from every level of government continue to pay taxes-- to evem, level o/ government--on their annuities. Social Security benefits are tax-free. The independent actuarial firm of Edward H. Friend and Company, engaged by FAIR, has determined that retired public workers pay approximately ten percent of their annuities in Federal income taxes. Taking Federal income retirees alone, this means that on the basis of disbursements in 1979, Federal retirees paid an estimated $1.26 billion in Federal income taxes. 24 This statement must be analyzed carefully since opponents of universal Social Security coverage widely subscribe to the underlying premises. The first misconception is that noncovered pension systems would be "merged" with Social Security. No one has ever talked about merging systems. There would be no expropriation of existing funds. The pension systems that would be affected would continue to be totally independent of Social Security. At least 70 percent of state and local workers are already covered by Social Security, and the overwhelming majority are covered by a pension plan in addition to Social Security. In 1979, 68.5 percent of nonagricultural privatesector workers between the ages of twenty-five and sixty-four who were working at least half-time and had been in their jobs for a year 24"FAIR Facts No. 1," in Tke National 5, 1980), p. 820. 244 R.ral Letter Carrier, vol. 79, no. 43 (November or more were working for an employer who provided a pension in addition to Social Security. 25 In no instance have any of these plans been merged with Social Security. The second point, that there are differences in tax treatment of Social Security and pension income, is partly correct. Public-pension annuitants under age sixty-five are eligible for the retirement income credit; after age sixty-five thev are eligible for the credit for the elderly. The credit is basically 15 percent of the first $2,500 of pension income for eligible individuals and 15 percent of $3,750 for married couples filing a joint return. These amounts are reduced bv nontaxable pensions received, monthly payments from matured U.S. government life insurance endowments, and Railroad Retirement and Social Securitv benefits. For people under age sixty-two, there is a further reduction for annual earnings over $900. Betwcen ages sixtytwo, and seventy-two, exempted income is reduced by 50 percent of annual earnings bctween $1,200 and $1,700 and all earnings above $1,700. After age seventy-two, there is no earnings test. The estimate of 10 percent federal tax liability on CSRS annuities is probably high. Thc Universal Coverage Study group was provided a 1 percent sample of primary CSRS annuitants in mid-1979. To estimate 1980 federal income tax liability on CSRS benefits roughly, the 1979 benefit levels were adjusted for COLA increases through the end of 1980. Each individual was treated as filing a single return. The standard deduction was taken in each instance, with a double exemption provided to annuitants over age sixty-five. No credits or other deductions were considered. No provision was made for the two years of tax-free annuities the typical beneficiary receives until benefits exceed the employee's contribution. On this basis, both the median and the average federal income tax rates for 1980 were estimated to bc almost exactly 10 percent. The sample did not include any survivors, who receive onlv 55 percent of the primary annuitant benefit, although survivors made up 26 percent of the total annuitants during 1979. Including them would have rcduced both the median and the mcan tax rates. Had spouses of primary annuitants been considered in calculating exemptions, the average tax rates would havc been reduced further. Finally, the consideration of available credits and potential deductions above the standard deductions would have resulted in further reduced estimates of federal tax liabilities on CSRS annuities. 2SSvlvester J. Schieber and Patricia M. George, Retirement Income Aging America: Coverage and Benefit Entitlement (Washington, chapter 2. Opporttmities D.C.: EBRI, in at_ 1981), 245 Even if the 10 percent average tax rate is considered correct, the implications of Social Security coverage are negligible for some time. If one assumes that workers within ten years of normal retirement would receive a continued exemption from Social Security coverage, there would be little effect on CSRS benefits for at least ten years. Then the CSRS benefit reductions would be gradually phased in. The presumption in the benefit designs developed by the Universal Coverage Study group was that any current workers affected would receive benefits based on a combined formula: periods of service under the current formula would be treated under the current formula and prospective service, if coverage were extended, would be treated under the new system. The same transition could be implemented if the CSRS was modified along the lines proposed by Senator Stevens. This would result in a gradual reduction in CSRS benefits as Social Security benefits increased with the length of covered service. Even after the full maturation of a coordinated system, there would be substantial benefits paid by the CSR system that would still be subject to federal taxes. The tax code is continuously changed for a wide variety of reasons. It is hard to believe that a potential loss of $1 billion dollars in annual federal tax revenues ten to twenty years from now is crucial to this issue. The last point in the FAIR position just cited implies that taxpayers would have new liabilities if the federal retirement plan were coordinated with Social Security coverage. The fact is that taxpayers now absorb the liability of most of the federal retirement system. The current system costs federal workers 7 percent of their salary, and the taxpayers 30 percent of the federal payroll. The unintended benefits paid by Social Security cost an additional 2 percent of federal payroll, which is absorbed by the full-career participants in Social Security. A coordinated system will cost the taxpayers more only if employees' contributions to the combined system were less than their current contribution or if benefits were raised. It has been argued that coverage should not be mandated at the state and local levels because such a mandate would be a further infringement of the federal government on the rights of other governmental bodies. The prospect of government infringement is certainly a serious issue, but so is the issue of equity for taxpayers and workers. In the case of mandatory Social Security coverage, these issues are at odds with each other, and each should be weighed carefully. State and local retirement costs may increase if Social Security coverage is mandated. Such an increase is serious at a time when the public wants to reduce the costs of government. The Social Security 246 "bonuses" "hidden" now provided to workers in these systems, however, are costs of government that would become visible to the tax- payers in the .jurisdictions affected by coverage legislation. The cost of increases in Social Security coverage would generally' be the result of increases in protection provided to public workers. The increases in protection would be largely directed toward individuals who now receive inadequate protection from their retirement plans. Expanded coverage would eliminate the windfall problem and thus result in a considerable reduction of Social Securitv costs. The worker equity issues may be best considered within the context of a current move in the federal government to determine benefit comparability using the framework of total compensation. Within this framework roughly 25 percent of workers' compensation would be attributed to the accrual of pension rights. This amount may be equitable for individuals who will ultimately receive a pension, but it is hardly fair for the 25 percent of current federal workers who will not. They face the prospect of being victimized in three ways: (1) they receive no pension protection for their service (86 percent have more than five years of covered service and are theoretically vested under the plan but will not receive any benefit from it; 62 percent have more than ten years of service under CSRS and would be vested under a private retirement plan); (2) during their period of federal employment, they would have their disposable wages reduced for benefits they will not receive; (3) thev do not have the portability protection provided by Social Security to more than 90 percent of the work force and may ultimately receive reduced retirement benefits because of substantial periods of noncovered service. The argument has been put forward that mandatory universal coverage would be a further expansion of a program that is already beyond its limits. This argument needs clarification. The 25 percent of federal workers who terminate their employment without entitlement to a pension presumably take jobs covered bv Social Security. The Universal Coverage Study cited evidence suggesting that as many as 70 percent of federal annuitants will receive Social Security benefits. 26Because of the prevalence of policemen, firefighters, and teachers at the state and local levels, the rates of Social Security entitlement may be higher among other annuitants on noncovered employer pensions. As noted in chapter V, less than 20 percent of the approximately' 6 million workers now in noncovered employment will not receive Social Security benefits; these workers constitute only 1 percent of e_'U_tiversal Coverage Sttu(v, p. 41. 247 the current work torce. Although universal coverage would significantly increase the base of covered earnings, it would have little effect on the number of workers who become covered during their working caFeeFs. One other argument against expanding coverage is that most noncovered workers today are already protected by a pension plan and they do not "need" the protections provided by Social Security. Laying aside the portability and vesting issues already discussed, it might be recalled this rationale did not hold forth for private sector workers in 1935. As was discussed in chapter I, the Clark amendment to the original 1935 Social Security Act, which would have exempted private-sector workers covered by an employer pension, was among the most debated issues of the original legislation. Neither private-sector employers with a pension nor their employees were exempted from Social Security participation in 1935 and they have never received such exemptions since. 248 VIII. Other Policy Considerations Throughout the discussion thus far, a series of issues related to the central Social Security policy debate have been treated tangentially. Some of these issues have been discussed for years, while others have entered the debate more recently. This chapter addresses five of these issues. The first section discusses the facets of the Social Security program that determine the distribution of benefits to dependents and survivors. The concern in this area relates primarily to the equity of Social Security's treatment of women. The second section deals with the earnings test that reduces or eliminates the Social Security benefits for people who continue to work and earn substantial income beyond the normal retirement age. The third section focuses on the prospect of significant OASDI trust fund accumulations during the 1990s, which would complicate the resolution of both the short- and long-term financing problems. It is premature to be overly concerned about this potential problem in light of the significant future financing deficits in the Hospital Insurance program, but the HI program is being scrutinized bv the current Social Security Advisory Council, which will make policy recommendations during 1983. Assuming that the HI problems are resolved, the potential OASDI trust fund accumulations under certain policy options would be significant and difficult to manage. A method of handling these potential trust funds, should they arise, is outlined. The fourth section considers the prospects of using general revenues to finance Social Security in the future. At the outset, Franklin D. Roosevelt was strongly committed to financing Social Security through a payroll tax system. Over the years, Congress has remained equally committed. Yet, some analysts and policymakers advocate general revenue infusions as the best wav to deal with Social Security's financing shortfalls in both the short and long terms. The final section evaluates a set of recommendations that would modify Social Security more fundamentally than any of the propositions considered throughout the other parts of this book. These proposals would change aggregate benefit accumulations, the method of financing them, and the ultimate benefit distributions. Horizontal and Vertical Equity in Social Security As was noted in the discussion of the evolution and its financing and benefit structure in chapter of Social Security I, the original 1eg249 islation included a benefit structure that provided relatively higher benefits to low-wage workers than to people with higher levels of earnings. The program was originally configured as a redistributive retirement annuity program. The 1939 amendments changed the fundamental characteristics of the program by providing survivor and dependent benefits. The architects of Social Security over the years have sought to balance the adequacy and equity goals of the program. The adequacy goal is fulfilled through the program's redistributive aspect. It is accomplished practically by the PIA formula, which provides relatively lower benefits at progressively higher levels of lifetime earnings. For two persons with the same characteristics in every regard but lifetime earnings, the equity goal is fulfilled through the PIA formula which provides higher absolute benefits to the retiree with higher earnings who paid higher taxes. The equity goal, however, was compounded--some critics say confounded--by the 1939 amendment's introduction of dependent benefits. Two sets of equity criteria must be considered: "vertical" and "horizontal" ones. For the program to be vertically equitable, they argue, a worker who contributed more to the program through the payroll tax should be paid a higher benefit than one who pays less. For the program to be horizontally equitable, equal contributions should result in equal benefits. The introduction of dependent and survivor benefits, in combination with the diversity of individual lifestyles and working patterns, has meant these two goals are not simultaneously attainable. This situation has given rise to a series of what are characterized as "women's issues" or "family issues." In fact, Social Security treats female workers exactly the same as male workers. Some would point out that it treats women better, because it does not actuarially reduce their benefits to account for their longer life expectancy. The changing role of women in society, however, has raised public "consciousness" on women's equity issues. In 1940, when Social Security started paying benefits, about one of four women over age fifteen was in the labor force. By 1980, more than half of all women of working age and two-thirds of those between the ages of twenty and forty-five were in the labor force. The equity conflict in Social Security arises because supplemental benefits are paid to dependents of "entitled" or regular beneficiaries. In the case of spouse benefits, they are payable to both men and women but in most cases it is a woman who is eligible to receive them. This is the case because among most married couples, it is the 250 husband who has the higher lifetime earnings of the two and the wife who is more likely to have had significant periods out of the labor force. A woman is eligible for 50 percent of her husband's basic Social Security benefit when she reaches age sixty-five. She can take that benefit as early as age sixty-two if her husband is receiving benefits. If she takes the benefit prior to age sixty-five, it is reduced on the basis of the actuarial tactors used to determine monthlv benefit levels. A widow is eligible to receive her husband's full benefit at age sixtyfive, but can take an actuariallv reduced benefit as early as age sixty. A widow can actually receive the husband's benefit at much earlier ages if she is caring for the deceased's children under eighteen years of age. Any woman who was married to a man for at least ten years is eligible for benefits based on her late husband's entire work career. A woman who is in the labor force and is entitled to Social Security on the basis of her own contributions does not receive the full amount of the spouse's benefits. The benefits are basically determined in the following wav: first, her own entitlement is determined on the basis of her earnings and age at retirement; second, her benefit as the spouse of an entitled beneficiary is determined and if that amount is higher than her own entitlement, she is paid the additional amount. In a practical sense, she gets the higher of the two benefits, although in Social Security's bookkeeping she gets her own entitlement plus the residual amount that is a spouse benefit. Under this system, vertical equity and horizontal equity are both maintained for any two families with exactlv the same characteristics and lifetime earnings patterns. When family characteristics or earnings patterns vary, the equity criteria break down. Specifically, they break down between single and married individuals, between singleearner and two-earner couples, and for divorcees. The single-married inequities arise on the basis of both survivor and dependent benefits. Two workers, one single and one married, with exactly the same earnings make the same contribution to Social Security but receive different protections. The single person who dies prior to retirement receives no benefit from Social Security (other than insurance protection against disability while he or she was alive). When a single person dies after retirement, all Social Security benefits related to that person end with his or her death. But when a married person dies prior to retirement, Social Security benefits may be paid both to a spouse and to children. When a married man dies after retirement, a widow's benefit may be paid. 251 One possible solution to this inequity in benefits available for single and married people is to increase the tax rate on married people or on people with potentially eligible children. In the case of children, however, it can be argued that the benefits are merely an investment in a future generation of taxpayers. Although workers with children do place Social Security at additional risk, these workers are also helping to preserve the future of the program by providing the replacement generation of workers. The same cannot be said for the single worker who has no children. In the case of a surviving elderly spouse, the issues are somewhat different. Here the equity problems relate to benefits provided people on the basis of labor-force participation. Consider, for example, three households, each with a total average indexed earnings of $1,000 in 1982. Assume that one consists of a single person, never married, who is sixty-two in early 1982; the second consists of a couple both reaching age sixty-two in 1982, one of whom never participated in the labor force; and a third consists of a two-earner couple, both partners of which had equal earnings throughout their lives and where both also reached age sixty-two in 1982. Further, assume each of the three "economic units" had equal earnings in each year since they reached age twenty-one. Table VIII-I shows Social Security benefits for the three households. In all these cases, the total earnings and payroll taxes in each family can be assumed to be equal; yet each family has a different level of benefits. The difference between the single person's benefit and the twoearner couple's arises because of the intended redistribution in the program. Both wage-earning partners in the couple received lower earnings throughout their careers than the single person, so each receive relatively higher but absolutely lower benefits. The principle of vertical equity is maintained, while the horizontal is not. Given the adequacy goal of the program, horizontal equity cannot be achieved across single versus married households with the same lifetime earnings. It is presumed that Congress has knowingly made this decision and may or may not reevaluate it on economic, social, and political grounds in the future. A failure of the equity conditions that has led to somewhat more criticism of the program is the higher benefit paid to the one-earner couple than to the two-earner couple. The two-earner couple in table VIII-1 consisting of husband and wife, both of whom had participated in the labor force throughout their lives and had paid taxes comparable to those paid by the single earner, receive less than the oneearner couple. Both the vertical and horizontal equity criteria are 252 TABLE Monthly Individuals Social Security Benefits for Specified and Couples Retiring at Age 62 in Early 1982 Individual's Benefit Widow's Benefit $1,000 $362.70 - $1,000 $362.70 157.40 _' $520.10 $374.00 b $234.70 234.70 _ $469.40 $234.70 b AIME Single Person One-Earner Couple Worker Homemaker Total Two-Earner Husband Wife Total VIII-I $1,000 Couple $ 500 500 $1,000 Source: Calculated by the author'. _'Assumes husband is alive at age sixty-two. bAssumes husband dies at age sixty-two. met if only the worker benefits are considered. If familv benefits are considered, both fail. Furthermore, in the case of survivor benefits, the spouse who did not participate in the labor force fares better than the one who did. In the example shown in table VIII-l, the death of the husband in the one-earner couple will leave the widow with a benefit that is roughly $140 per month higher than the benefit for the two-earner couple in similar circumstances. During the 1930s and 1940s, when fewer women participated in the labor force, this problem was less noticeable than todav when the majority do. There is a broad perception that women who stay in the labor force do not get their money's worth out of the program. The question that is not always addressed is, relative to what? The fact is that because of women's longer life expectancy at retirement, female wage earners actually get a better return from the program than male wage earners. It is only relative to non-wage-earning spouses that wage-earning women are disadvantaged. The primary concern about divorce is the ten-year marriage requirement. The woman married only nine years and eleven months is not eligible for spouse or survivor benefits, while an additional month of marriage would warrant such benefits. The marriage requirement was reduced from twenty years to ten in 1978. 253 The proposals that would resolve these equity problems cut in two directions. One set of proposals would "level up" the benefits of twoearner couples. To accomplish this, benefits could be paid to all couples as if only one partner in the couple had participated in the labor force. Alternatively, retired workers could be guaranteed some portion of the spouse's benefit. Another set of proposals would raise worker benefits relative to spouse benefits. Each of these proposals has certain merits, but in the context of Social Security financing deficits they hardly seem appropriate. Solving one problem by exacerbating another would lend little credibility to the solution. Another set of proposals would "level down" the benefits paid to one-earner couples. This could be accomplished by decreasing or even eliminating the spouse benefit for retired workers. Another approach would be to pay all spouse beneficiaries a flat benefit. The approach that has probably received the most serious consideration would "share" (i.e., divide equally) a couple's earnings or average their AIME. This would place the one-earner couple in the same position as the two-earner couple. A more restricted version of this option would call for earnings sharing only in the case of divorce. The earnings sharing on an annual basis or on the basis of AIME averaging would equalize the benefits of married couples regardless of their one- or two-earner status. Annual earnings sharing could also resolve the problem relating to benefits for divorcees, which may be more of a conceptual than a practical problem at present. The major limitation of either of these approaches is that participation in Social Security is not universal. If one spouse works in noncovered employment while the other works in covered, earnings sharing would result in further distortion of equity problems that already persist. The problem would be further exacerbated in cases of divorce. As a practical matter, only 8.2 percent of all benefits paid to retired workers and their dependents in 1970 were spouse benefitsJ Given the much greater participation of women in the labor force today than in the past, this problem may be even less prevalent in the future. The survivor issue is somewhat more important because two-thirds of all survivor benefits go to elderly survivors. The AIME averaging or earnings sharing option would reduce the benefit tot a spouse who did not participate in the labor force in table VIII-I to the benefit of the wage-earning spouse. Alternatively, the wage-earning spouse's benefits could be raised to the higher" level if the widow or widower _Social Security Bulleti_t istration, 1981, p. 108. 254 A_mual Statistical Suppleme_zl, 1980, Social Security Admin- could inheril the spouse's earnings history. Either option would be complicated and certain distortions would result because coverage is not universal. A simpler procedure for reducing the benefit for a spouse who had not participated in the labor force would be to provide that person a lower portion of the spouse's benefit. For raising the benefits [or survivors who are themselves entitled, it would be simpler to provide a fiat benefit or to develop a partial offset procedure rather than the full offset that now applies. There are practical problems with resoh, ing this issue in the short term. Reducing benefits of workers close to retirement can cause undue hardship. Raising benefits in the current environment max: be unpalatable. Resolving the problem, however, would reduce the criticism of the program. The Earnings Test Ever since the Social Security program began, the old-age benefits have been characterized as retirement benefits. To assure that benefits go to retirees, the program includes an earnings test for retirement. The earnings test reduces Social Security benefits by one dollar for every two dollars of earnings over an exempt amount. In 1982, the exempt amount is $4,400 tot persons under age sixty-five, and $6,000 for persons aged sixty-five to seventy-one. All earnings arc exempt above age seventy-two in 1982. Beginning in 1983, all earnings will be exempt tot workers over age seventy. The exempt earnings amounts are indexed by the growth in average wages. Advocates of the earnings test argue that Social Security is insurance against the loss of earnings because of old age. Critics of the earnings test argue that it should be eliminated on several grounds. First, they argue that the insurance principle is not appropriate tot old-age benefits because many people retire voluntarily. In this context, Social Security is not "insuring" against a circumstance beyond the beneficiaries' control, but against one these people bring on thcmselves. Critics argue further that it is hard to rationalize paying benefits to people who have voluntarily renounced their wages when people who continue to work lose benefits. It is also argued that there is no rational basis for trcating a worker at age sixty-fivc, the Social Securitv normal retirement age, any differently from the way someone age seventy-two is treated. Furthermore, there is widespread agreement that the earnings test is a disincentive to work beyond normal retirement age. Six of the thirteen members of 255 the 1979 Social Security of the population, such Advisory Council argued that with disincentives should be minimized. the aging 2 From a slightly different perspective, some people are concerned with the equity of treating earned and unearned income differently under what is perceived as a means test. In the 1979 Report of the Social Security Advisory Council, four members argued: There is also the perceived injustice in permitting full benefits to be received regardless of the amount of unearned income (dividends, interest, etc.) and reducing benefits when earned income is involved. The answer usually given to a complaint on this point is that the benefits are received as a matter of right and to reduce them because of unearned income would be equivalent to use of a means test. But the present rule seems to apply a means test based on earned income. If there is any difference in these two approaches, it is too subtle to be understood by the vast majority of workers covered by Social Security) One of the more serious problems with eliminating the earnings test for beneficiaries beyond age sixty-five is that it would raise Social Security costs. The program actuaries project that eliminating the earnings that would increase the seventy-five-year average cost by 0.14 percent of payroll. Until there is some agreement on other program modifications, raising the cost of the system would be perceived as irresponsible. If Congress were basis, as discussed earnings Trust test Fund might to consider in chapters make such taxing Social Security benefits V and VI, however, elimination a policy more on some of the palatable. Accumulations The prospects for trust fund accumulations are on any actual modifications to the Social Security end of a decade of relatively constant deterioration totally dependent program. At the in Social Secu- rity's financial status, potential trust fund accumulations may be perceived as either a pipe dream or a return to the blissful opportunities of the early 1970s. Recent experience, however, has shown 2Gardner Ackley et al., "Supplementary Statement on Liberalizing the Earnings Test," Social Security Financing and Benelits (Washington, D.C.: Report of the 1979 Advisory Council), p. 231. 3Grace Davis, Mary Falvey, John Porter, and J. W. Van Gorkum, "Supplementary Statement on the Need to Phase Out the Earnings Test," Social Security Financing and Benefits (Washington, D.C.: Report of the 1979 Advisory Council), p. 230. 256 that taking advantage of blissful opportunities in the short term can exact a substantial price in the longer term. The problem, whether it is merely perceived at this time or becomes real in the future, is the projected accumulation of OASDI trust funds around the turn of the century under various policy scenarios. For example, in 1980 there was some discussion of freezing the PIA formula bend points for three years starting in 1981. The Social Security actuaries projected that such a policy would reduce the long-term financing deficit by 1.1 percent of payroll or by about 88 percent under the intermediate assumptions used in the 1980 valuation. Under these projections, freezing bend points for three years was projected to result in OASDI trust funds that would be about three times the annual OASDI benefit payments bv the year 2000 and 5.3 times annual benefit payments by 2015. 4 There are precedents for trust fund ratios like these, but they predate the maturing of the program. A better perspective on such accumulations can be gained by comparing them with current benefit levels. Under the 1982 Trustees Report II-B assumptions, the 1982 OASDI disbursements are estimated to be $160.3 billion (see chapter IV). In the context of current benefit levels, a trust fund ratio of 3.0 translates into a trust fund of $481 billion. A ratio of 5.3 would equal $850 billion. Although trust funds of these magnitudes mav hardly seem a problem, there are several issues to consider. The Social Security trust funds are held in the form of federal securities; they are part of the federal government's formal debt, which is now about $1.1 trillion. Assuming that the government's formal debt does not grow anv more rapidly than annual OASDI disbursements, the OASDI trust funds would buy up a large shave of the federal debt now held by the general public. However, the government would be running substantial surpluses. If historical experience is any guide, it is unlikely that the federal government would run such surpluses for any sustained length of time. A combination of fiscal, economic, and political factors would undoubtedly dictate against doing this. There are several things that might be done instead of buying up the existing debt stock. The trust funds could be issued new debt and the revenues would be used to finance other activities of the federal government. Under this scenario, the federal budget could be balanced by offsetting increased payroll tax collections by reductions in the income tax. As the baby-boom generation reaches retirement age 4U .S. Senate Government Committee on Finance, Social Security Financing Printing Office, 1980), pp. 53 and 55. (Washington, D.C.: U.S. 257 and places claims on the svstem in excess of payroll tax collections, the opposite phenomenon w,ould occur. The securities held by the trust funds would be liquidated to pay benefits. The liquidation of these securities would be financed either by increasing general taxes to reduce the federal debt, or if the budget is running an overall deficit, by borrowing in the general credit markets to refinance the trust fund holdings. Alternatively, the program's expenditures and revenues could be more closely balanced over time to keep the system operating on a current-cost basis. For example, as the trust funds start to grow, benefits could be raised. The problem with this approach is that raising one generation's level of benefits leads to expectations of increased benefits bv subsequent generations. In this case, these increased expectations would mature with the baby-boom generation's retirement. The credibility of the program would be strained as longterm projected costs rise ta,r above current projections. Similarly, the system could be kept on a current-cost basis by reducing payroll taxes as the trust funds accumulate beyond some required reserve ratio for administering the program. Robert Myers has presented a proposal t0r automatically adjusting the OASDI tax rates to correspond with changing cost rates. For purposes of describing the option, he assumes that a trust fund ratio of 50 to 55 percent of prior-year benefits should be maintained, although he notes that a higher or lower ratio could be maintained. At the end of each fiscal year, the size ot the OASDI trust funds as of September 30 would be compared with disbursements for the year. If the fund ratio equaled or exceeded 60 percent of the year's disbursements, the combined employer-employee tax rate would be reduced 0.4 percent lot the next calendar vear. If the actual dollars in the trust funds declined from one year to the next, however, the tax rate would not be reduced, even if the trust fund ratio exceeded 60 percent. If the ratio fell below 55 percent, the tax rate would be raised 0.4 percent. If the trust fund ratio fell between 55.0 and 59.9 percent, the tax rate would be mainrained, s Myers has estimated the payroll tax variations that would result if this proposal were implemented in 1991. He assumed that the shortterm solution got the OASDI program through 1990 with approximately a zero trust fund balance, and he assumed that no modifiSRobert J. Myers, "How Operate," Memorandum Security Reform, June 258 a Proposal tor Automatic Changes in OASDI Tax Rates Would no. 23 (Washington, D.C.: National Commission on Social 4, 1982), p. 2. cations to the current benefits were implemented. He used the 1982 II-B assumptions in estimating the payroll tax variations. Under this scenario, the currently legislated combined OASDI tax rate of 12.4 percent would be stable between 1991 and 1998. After 1998 it would begin to decline, reaching 10.4 percent in 2003 and stabilizing for five vears. In 2008 and beyond, the tax rate would rise automatically and steadily, with one three-vear exception, reaching 17.6 percent in 2029. Beyond 2030, the rate would vary between 15.6 and 17.6 percent. 6 The portion of the population reaching age twenty-one and embarking on a career in 2008 or after will not be born until 1987 or after. Under this proposal, in a little over twenty years, the payroll tax rate could rise nearly 42 percent without Congress having taken a single vote. Bv 2029 half the work force would have been born after the passage of the legislation that raised their OASDI payroll tax rates more than 40 percent above the rate now in current law for 1990, and 63 percent above the 1982 rate. If conditions turned out less favorable than those assumed, the increases would be still higher. There is some skepticism about the potential buildup of the OASDI trust funds. The projected Medicare shortfalls are so large that some analysts believe that anv OASDI savings resulting from alternative policies will be more than used up bv HI financing. It may be premature, theretore, to design and implement provisions that would mean higher retirement benefits or lower payroll taxes during the 1990s. A newly appointed Social Security Advisory Council is only now beginning to grapple with Medicare problems. Until their deliberations and proposals and the resulting congressional actions are clear, the OASDI trust fund accumulation problem will be more perceptual than real. To the extent that excessive trust funds do accumulate, policymakers should consider making them an effective tool for use in resolving the long-term financing situation. Given the current structure of financing Social Security, it scents highly, unlikely that there will ever be the capability' of prefunding anv significant portion of the program's liabilities. Given the nature of trust fund holdings and broader fiscal policy, thc historical arguments against prcfunding probably' will prevail in the future. The discussion of funding, which actually dates back to the early days of the program, was described in chapter I. In the past, this debate has hinged on three basic concerns: (1) large trust funds would result in politically motivated benefit increases; (2)the central government could not manage a trust fund of the size involved; and (3) the gov"Ibid. 259 ernment would act as a severe fiscal drag on the overall economy during the period of fund accumulation. Any proposal to prefund Social Security obligations has to address these concerns. One aspect of previous funding discussions was the presumption that the funds would have to be accumulated and managed centrally. Some of the historical concerns regarding prefunding might be overcome by prefunding on an individual rather than an aggregate basis. For example, a trigger mechanism such as the one developed by Myers for adjusting the OASDI tax rate could be adapted to trigger payroll tax rebates rather than tax rate reductions. The rebates could be restricted to investment in approved vehicles similar to individual retirement accounts that could be converted into an annuity upon attaining Social Security eligibility status. If the redistributive aspect of the program was to be maintained, the credits could be weighted towards lower-income workers or based on annual hours of covered employment rather than wages. If it is politically more expedient to expose the retirement portfolios of higherincome workers to market risk, the rebates could be based on annual contributions. At retirement, the annuities could be offset against the computed Social Security entitlement. A major advantage of these special individual retirement security (SIRS) accounts would be that they could be used to smooth the tax rate over time. The problems of large centrally managed trust funds would not arise because the rebates would be held in individual accounts. Institutional investors could be encouraged to offer pooled investment vehicles, so that small investors could take advantage of the efficiencies and opportunities open to the wealthy. Rather than being a fiscal drag on the economy, such a program would provide a direct stream of investment dollars to the capital market. Furthermore, on the benefit side, SIRS would provide a direct claim on the capital base of the economy, a claim Social Security does not enjoy as it is now financed. One concern that would almost certainly be raised about such a program would be the responsiveness of SIRS annuities to inflation. The program could be structured to provide graded annuities as well as, or instead of, flat annuities. Further inflation protection, comparable to that provided by Social Security, could be underwritten by the federal government. Such protection would not be free, but would be much cheaper than underwriting the full cost of the SIRS annuities and inflation protection on a current-cost basis. This option would not replace Social Security or any of its basic characteristics, but would be a way of accumulating the surplus pay260 roll taxes [hal will be paid as the baby-boom generation matures through the work force. It would help to capture those taxes in a way that they could be used to provide the baby-boom cohort with retirement benefits. The current-cost structure appears to have a limited capacity to accomplish these goals. Before a program like SIRS could be implemented, it would require more detailed development than provided here. Such a program would not take effect, however, until adequate trust funds had developed in the OASDI program to assume Social Security's continued smooth operation, so there would be ample time to develop program details. There are, of course, other alternatives. General Revenue In the course Financing of the deliberations of the National Commission on Social Security Reform, the discussion has repeatedly focused on the relationship of projected Social Security benefit levels relative to the Gross National Product (GNP). The point is that future Social Securitv costs as a percentage of GNP will be much more stable than the costs as a percentage of covered payroll. Table VIII-2 shows averaging-period cost projections on these two bases. Under the II-B assumptions, the OASDI benefits are estimated to be about 5.16 percent of GNP during 1982. This rate is projected to decline steadily until after the turn of the century. The rate will begin to rise again as the baby-boom generation reaches retirement age during the second twenty-five-year averaging period shown in table TABLE VIII-2 Estimated Costs of OASDI System as a Percentage of Covered Payroll and as a Percentage of GNP Under 1982 Trustees Report II-B Assumptions Period Payroll Cost Rate (Percent) GN/PCost Rate (Percent) 25- Yea r Averages 1982-2006 2007-2031 2032 2056 11.37 14.08 16.81 4.75 5.30 5.78 75- Yea r Average 1982-2056 14.09 5.28 Source: 1982 Social Security Trustees Report, pp. 68-69. 261 VIII-2. The rate is projected to peak in 2030 at 6.10 percent of GNP, less than one percentage point more than in 1982. To put it somewhat differently, if the 1982 OASDI cost rate (11.78 percent) as a percentage of pay is compared with the II-B-projected cost rate (16.83 percent) for 2030, the cost of OASDI will be 42.9 percent higher in 2030 than in 1982. At the same time, OASDI benefits as a percentage of GNP are projected to be only 18.2 percent higher in 2030 (6.10 percent) than in 1982 (5.16 percent). The seventy-fiveyear average cost of OASDI as a percentage of payroll is 19.6 percent higher than the 1982 cost under the II-B assumptions. As a percentage of GNP, the long-range cost is only 2.3 percent greater than the 1982 level under the same assumptions. There is a large discrepancy between the additional share of payroll that would be necessary to finance Social Security benefits in the future versus the total share of GNP that would be required. As a result some analysts argue that the revenue sources used to finance benefits should be expanded beyond the current payroll tax. There has always been some strong opposition to general revenue financing of the program, however. As noted in chapter I, President Franklin D. Roosevelt supported financing through the payroll tax because it would be less subject to political manipulation than one financed bv other means. Over the years, the issue of general revenue financing has been raised on several occasions. In the initial conception of the program by the Committee on Economic Security, Social Security would have been partially financed through the general tax system. The logic was that as Social Security expanded, the role of old-age assistance would diminish and the "freed revenues" could be diverted to the old-age retirement program. President Roosevelt opposed this logic during the development of the Social Security Act in 1935. In 1944, however, the Social Security Act was amended to authorize appropriations to the OASDI trust fund any "additional amounts" required to finance benefits. The 1950 amendments increased the wage base, scheduled a series of tax rate increases, and eliminated the 1944 provision authorizing general appropriations from the Treasury to the trust fund. Congress has continued to favor a self-supporting system ever since. For many years, organized labor supported payroll tax financing of Social Security. According to Martha Derthick, labor's commitment was more strategic than philosophical, however. She quotes Nelson Cruikshank, who was Director of the Social Security Department of the American Federation of Labor-Congress of Industrial Organizations (AFL-CIO) for several years, as saying that labor accepted 262 the 1950 payroll tax provisions "as a practical move to get the benefits we wanted. ''7 In 1969 the AFL-CIO recommended adoption of a threetier financing scheme: one-third from general revenues and the remainder from the equally shared payroll tax on employers and workers. The Carter administration proposed countercyclical general revenue financing in 1977; general revenues were to be infused into the trust funds when unemployment reached 6 percent. This infusion would make up for revenue losses that occur when workers lose their jobs and reduce the aggregate wage base during adverse economic periods. Congress rejected the Carter proposal and instead raised the taxable wage base and scheduled a series of tax increases. Most opposition to general revenue financing is based on two premises. The first premise is that opening the financing to general revenues will result in increased pressure to expand benefits. The payroll tax, it is argued, acts as a political governor on the program, especially now that the program is mature. Anv benefit increases that are provided now must be met with corresponding tax increases. The theorv holds that this mechanism constrains political largesse that might otherwise prevail. The second premise is that there are no general revenues with which to finance the program. The United States government has a long history of federal deficits. Table VIII-3 shows the federal budgetary flows between 1940 and 1981. In each of the five-year periods between 1940 and 1979, the general fund was in deficit; there were only six years between 1940 and 1981 inclusive that the general fund ran a surplus. If trust fund receipts and outlays are included as part of the total federal budget there have been only eight years with a surplus. Given this fairly consistent fiscal record, opponents of general revenue financing argue that it would simply mean higher or alternative taxes or even larger deficits in the future. A more recent concern is the magnitude of expected federal budget deficits in the near future. The Congressional Budget Office has recently projected deficits, including off-budget accounts, of approximately $170 billion for each of the fiscal years 1983 to 1985. Considering only the unified budget, the projected deficits range between $150 and $160 billion in each of the three fiscal years. The CBO has also estimated that when the accounting is completed, the 1982 total fed- 7Martha Derthick, Policymaking Institution, 1979), p. 250. [or Social Security (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings 263 264 eral deficit will be $130 billion. 8 The escalating budget deficits, at levels significantly above historical levels, are cause for concern across the political spectrum. Establishing even greater claims on the general revenue funds at this time is inappropriate. Reorienting the Social Security Program As the debate about the Social Security financing problems has widened, some proposals have been made to modifv the structure of Social Security radically or to phase out the program altogether. Some of these proposals include detailed action plans, while others give only broad outlines. It would be easy to ignore or dismiss these proposals out of hand, but the authors, bv virtue of their backgrounds and current positions, appear to be serious-minded people whose ideas should be carefully examined. Three of these options will be briefly discussed here. The Family Plan--Peter Ferrara, currently a senior staff member at the White House Office of Policy Development, has developed a proposal that would gradually reform Social Security by creating a new system in its place. 9 He recommends a preliminary set of reforms that would include indexing the entire system bv the lower of wages or prices. Then he suggests gradually raising the normal retirement age for old-age benefits from sixty-five to sixty-eight. He also proposes to eliminate the progressivity of the benefit formula and to provide benefits in strict proportion to lifetime contributions through the payroll tax. The welfare elements of the current system would be met through the SSI program. Spouse and dependent benefits would be eliminated. Survivor benefits would depend on contributions rather than number of beneficiaries. The monthly benefit maximum and earnings test would be eliminated. Ferrara suggests that although these preliminary reforms "would not reduce benefits or expenditures in general, they would aid the proposed basic reform bv making it easier to compare Social Security with private alternatives. ''l° He goes on to note that the basic reform is not dependent on the preliminary modifications. *Congressional Budget Office, The Economic a_zd Budget Outlook: A_t Update (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, September 1982), p. 36. 9Peter J. Ferrara, Social SecuriO' Re[orm, the Family Plan (Washington, D.C.: The Heritage Foundation, 1982). Although Ferrara is a member of the Reagan administration, his proposal should not be construed as an administration recommendation. l°Ibid., p. 51. 265 The Family Plan would be phased in in three steps. Beginning on January 1, 1986, a worker could defer up to 20 percent of his or her OASDI contribution to an IRA and have the employer defer a comparable amount. The IRA provisions now in law would he modified so participants could use part of their IRA money to buy term life insurance. Ultimate OASI benefits would be reduced in relation to the portion of taxes deferred into the IRA. The government would continue to meet the Social Security obligations through infusions of general revenues. Ferrara suggests that the infusion of new investment capital would result in higher tax collections, because the return on capital is "partially taxed through the corporate income tax. The increased wages and new employment resulting from this investment would result in increases in both general revenue and payroll tax revenues .... Eventually, these two factors would entirely eliminate the net general revenue subsidy needed to pay Social Security benefits."ll The proportion of the OASDHI tax deferrable to IRAs would increase to 40 percent on January 1, 1996, and to 66 percent on January 1,2004. The remaining 34 percent would go to finance the Disability Insurance and Hospital Insurance programs. At this point, the employees who directed their employers to contribute 60 percent of the payroll tax to the IRA and who deferred 40 percent on their own could then use the remainder of the additional 26 percent however they chose. "This would be justified on the grounds that, since the benefits payable through the private alternative system would be so much higher than those through Social Security... individuals would not be required to save so much. ''12 On January 1, 2020, the DI share of payroll taxes would be deferrable. On January 1, 2014, the HI portion of the tax could be contributed to the IRA. Finally on January 1, 2016, a modification on the corporate tax would be implemented that would exempt corporate profits from taxes in proportion to the share of their stocks held by IRAs. The same basic rule would also apply to noncorporate businesses. Purchases of life, disability, and old-age insurance would be made tax exempt. Employee contributions to the IRAs would be tax deductible, but employer contributions would be treated as regular income. In accordance with the current tax treatment of Social Security benefits, IIIbid., pp. 52-53. 121bid., p. 53. 266 IRA distributions would not be taxable. The svslcm would require savings tor retirement and insurance purposes. Fcrrara estimates that "the new system would require total savings lot these contingencies equal to 87 percent of what individuals would be required to pay in total Social Security taxcs. ''13 This estimate is based on lhc assumption that "the real, full, before-tax rate of relurn on capital investment estimated by economists at 12 percent or more would prcvail. ''H Fcrrara's proposed modifications would definitely change the distribution of retirement benefits. Withdrawing the weighted benefits providcd by Social Security and substituting SSI instead would save money in cithcr the short or long term only if the withdrawn benefits were not replaced or if participation rates were much lower in SSI than in Social Security J0r the low-income elderly. It is unlikely that lowcr-incomc workcn's will evcr bccome sufficicntiv savvy in thc ways of the financial markets to realize rates of return on their IRAs that exceed inflation by 12 percent. More reasonablc rates of return would be in the range of 1 to 3 percent above the inflation rate, and there max' bc sustained pcriods when returns fall short of the inflation rate for many investors. As Michael Boskin, professor of economics at Stanford University and himself a critic of Social Security', recently stated: "Some, such as Fcrrara, assumed that the returns to the economy from the extra investment generated by private capital formation would be so lm'gc as basically to self-finance in a costlcss manner this change. I bclieve such estimates are well out of the reasonable range based on our historical experience and economic reasoning. ''1_ Perso,al Sec,rilv Acco,,Is--Prolessors Michael Boskin of Stanford University, Laurcnce Kotlikoff of Yale, and John Shoven of Stanford havc recommended a fundamental rcstrucluring of Social Security coupled with development of a program of personal security accounts (PSAs). They accept the view that there should be a Social Security svstem of some kind that requires people to help provide for themselves in view of the uncmtaintics of life. t_ Kotlikoff has spelled out a set of propositions as the foundation of PSAs. First, contributions representing t0rced savings should be treated on an individual account basis higher earnings would requirc higher contributions and entitle the earner to a larger benefit. Second, larger qbid., p. Lqbid., p. t_Michael National p. 8. '"Ibid., p. 62. 57. J. Boskin, "Ahcvnativc Commission on Social Social Sccuvitx Rct0vm Proposals," presented to the Security Rclorm, Washington, D.C., August 20, 1982, 4. 267 benefits, financed through larger contributions, should be available to married persons with spouses who do not participate in the labor torce. Third, workers at risk for survivor benefits should be required to pay lot such insurance protection. Fourth, rather than capping family or child survivor benefits, the plan proposes that added taxes should be levied on people at risk, to pay ['or benefits. Fifth, benefits should be paid in old age regardless of work status, t7 This proposal is based on the premise that people should get benefits only if they pay for them, and pay for them only if thcv receive them. Kotlikoff argues that the modified program should continue to be redistributivc, providing higher benefits relative to contributions for lower-wage workers. In addition to purchasing retirement benefits, the contributions would be used to purchase life, disability, and health insurance from the Social Security Administration. The program would fully cover individuals under age thirty-five, and provide transitional coverage for additional workers under age fifty-five. The PSA program aims to improve the horizontal equity in Social Security by setting the single person's earnings base at 70 percent of the combined-earnings base for married couples. The proposal calls for complete contributions sharing tot" married couples. Spouse survivor benefits would not be payable until agc sixty-two. Workers under age fifty-five would be given initial benefit credits equal to combined employer-employee taxes paid in their behalf accumulated at a 2 percent real interest rate. Additional credits would be given on the basis of "unaccrued bcncfits"--bcnefits promised under the current system that exceed the value of benefits purchasable on the basis of contributions. The additional credits would be scaled progressively, bv age, for workers aged thirty-six to fiftv-five. The PSA system would gradually accumulate a three-year cash reserve balance through manipulation of thc rate of return paid to individuals' PSA balances. By using low rates of return, the system could reduce benefit payments, thus maintaining any desired relationship between annual benefits and contributions. There are two fundamental differences between the current structure of Social Security and the modified PSA program. First, the current Social Security program is a defined-benefit program, whereas the PSA program would be a defined-contribution type. The authors of the proposed PSA program suggest that low-wage earners could accumulate weighted credits relative to high-wage workers under _7Laurence J. Kotlikoff, "Reforming Social Security lot the Young: A Framework Consensus," AEI Conference on Controlling the Cost of Social Security. June 25 1981, pp. 10-11. 268 lot 26, their program. That is, in order to balance grams, the low-wage earner would receive the financing a contribution of the procredit of more than one dollar for each dollar of taxes paid on the basis of their earnings, while high-wage workers would receive credits of less than one dollar on the basis of their taxes. Alternatively, the credit subsidies for low-wage workers could be financed through general revenues. In theory, at least, the credit accumulation could be structured to give roughly comparable primary benefit distributions to the benefits that result from the current system. If that is the desired goal, it is not clear that changing from a defined-benefit to definedcontribution program nets much in the sense of socio-political or economic goals. If there is really a compelling need for workers to know the value of their credit accumulations annually, it would be simpler to accomplish this with a defined-contribution plan. It is unlikely, however, that the average forty- or fifty-year old worker L could translate the account balance into its expected annuity value at retirement. In view of the fact that the PSA program would still be unfunded, the annual PSA wealth statements might even discourage alternative savings if stated weahh under the modified system were to exceed perceived wealth under the current one. The second fundamental change inherent in the PSA proposal relates to modified contribution rates for survivor and dependent benefits. For convenience, let us discuss benefits for children and spouses separately. The authors of the PSA proposal argue that a worker with children places the Social Security system at greater risk than a worker who does not have children. Focusing on the pay-as-you-go nature of Social Security as an intergenerational transfer program, however, yields a different perspective. It is the worker with children who provides replacement workers to pay benefits to future retirees. In fact, the declining birthrates of recent vears are responsible for much of the projected long-term Social Security financing problem. If we assume an interest in perpetuation of the program on some basis, it can be argued that people who do not have children place the system at considerablv more risk than those who do. Surviving parents with children now make up about 1.6 percent of all OASDI beneficiaries. According to the 1982 Trustees Report II-B projections, this figure will decline to 1.1 percent bv the vear 2000 and 0.6 percent in 2030. I_ If these benefits are a problem, they are a small one and they are one of diminishing magnitude. I_The 1982 Annual Report o[the Board o1 Trustees Insurance and Disability Insurance Trust Funds Administration, 1982), p. 84. ol the Federal (Washington, Old-Age and &m,ivors D.C.: Social Security 269 The inequities in cntitlcmcnts for spouses and widows/widowers that the PSA advocates are concerned about are somewhat more prevalent and possibly more troubling. Although Congress in the past has treated homemakers who have never participated in the labor torce in one way, equity' considerations may dictate alternative policies in the future. It is not clear, however, that the PSA approach is the best way to make the system more cquitable. The Freedom Pla_z--A. Haeworth Robcrtson, a tormer chief actuary of the Social Security Administration, has proposed a basic modification of the existing system that he labels the Freedom Plan. This proposal is based on the premise that some form of national social insurance is required but that it is not necessary to define the system for today's youth on the basis of a structure established nearly fifty years ago. Hc points out that in mid-1981,65 perccnt of the total U.S. population under age sixty-five was less than thirty-five years of age. _ The Freedom Plan would take effect on July 4, 1984, by Robertson's design, although other implementation dates could be selected. The population would be bifurcated on the implementation date; people over age forty-five would continue to be covered under the current system, while people under this age would be covered under the new system. The Freedom Plan would include three elements: ( 1) a demogrant-Senior Citizen Benefit--payable to all citizens upon attaining age seventy; (2)a governmental investment vehicle, "Freedom Bonds," for voluntary retirement savings; and (3) a cost-of-living supplement for private pensions. The "Senior Citizen Benefit" would be payable to all citizens meeting specified residency requirements when they became seventy years old. There would be no earnings test or means test of any kind. The eligibility age is set at seventy on the basis that life expectancy at that age, when the system started providing benefits, would exceed life expectancy at age sixty-five in 1935, when the Social Security program began. The monthly benefit would be set at about $250 in 1980 dollars, which compares with an average benefit for retired workers at that time of $295.51 in 1980. 2° For approximately onethird of retired workers in 1980, the program would have meant a benefit increase. Two-thirds would have received lower benefits, but in many instances the decrease would have been more than offset by P_A.Haeworth Robertson, Tile Comi_l_Revoluti_mi_lS_cial Security (McLean, Va.: The Security Press, 1981),p. 297. -'_lbid., p. 311. 27O an increase in the spouse benefit for married couples. 2' The benefit increases under the program would go primarily to persons with low lifetime earnings. The "Senior Citizen Benefit" would be indexed for increases in average wages, the demogrant program would be financed through the general tax system, and the payroll tax would be eliminated for its participants. The financing provisions would make the program as redistributive as the progressive income tax. The benefits themselves would not be subject to the income tax. Disability benefits would be provided to persons permanently totally disabled. There would be recency of work and residency to qualify, and beneficiaries rehabilitation and retraining and tests would have to agree to participate in a program. The monthly benefit would be the same as the "Senior Citizen Benefit" and would be similarly indexed. The disability benefits would be financed and subject to the same taxing provisions as benefits provided to the elderly. The second element of the program, "Freedom Bonds," would be available to any persons between the ages of forty-five and seventy participating in the Freedom Plan. Any person could purchase bonds up to l0 percent of prior-year earnings or l0 percent of average earnings, whichever is greater. The value of the bonds would be indexed each year for inflation and provide no additional return above inflation. Since the bonds would be purchased with taxable income they would not be subjected to any income taxes when redeemed. The bonds would be redeemable by the purchaser after age sixty or at the onset of disability, or payable to the purchaser's estate at death. "The purpose of the bonds is to offer a safe and inflation-proof vehicle to accumulate a reasonable supplemental retirement income during the latter half of one's working life. ''22 The third tier of the Freedom Plan would provide cost-of-livingadjustment supplements to pension plans. This provision would theoretically extend to IRA accumulations as well as to formal pensions meeting the standards set by the Internal Revenue Service. Monthly pension benefits would be covered for all benefits payable beyonct age seventy. These supplemental benefits would apply to both public and private plans and would be financed through general revenues as well. The Medicare and Supplementary Medical Insurance programs would be continued in basically their current form with the eligibility 21Ibid., 22Ibid., p. 312. p. 318. 271 age moved to seventy. Persons eligible for disability benefits would be covered by the HI and SMI programs as well, after a twelve-month waiting period. Benefits would be financed through general revenues and the payroll tax would be eliminated. During the transition to the new program, those persons who continued to be covered by Social Security would still be subject to the payroll tax. Since the revenues from the diminished tax base would not meet the residual obligations of the OASDHI program, these obligations would bc met through revenues from the general fund. In this way, the tax burden for paying off the current program's liabilities would be redistributed toward higher-income persons. In the short term, there would be limited savings under the Freedom Plan. The cost of the basic demogrant, HI, and SMI programs would range between 25 and 30 percent below that of the current OASDHI by the time the baby-boom generation retirement levels had peaked, according to Robertson's actuarial calculations. 23 If the Freedom Plan were implemented as proposed, federal debt servicing costs might actually fall. Although the proposal calls for inflation protection on the bonds, it does not provide a real return. It is unlikely that the federal government could find such favorable credit conditions elsewhere in the financial markets over a sustained period. The indexation of pension benefits would be an entirely new benefit, not provided by any facet of the current social insurance system. It would raise the cost, but the amount of the increase would depend on economic conditions. Estimates have not been developed on these potential extra costs. The Freedom Plan is fundamentally a "double-decker" type of retirement program. The bottom deck would be provided entirely through the federal government and would grow with wages over time. The top deck would be the responsibility of the individual, but the contents of that deck would be considerably enhanced and facilitated by the government. Although a double-decker system of this sort may be perceived as something radically new or different, it is not. As Ahmeyer notes, during 1940 the Social Security Board and President Roosevelt "were giving serious consideration to recommending a 'double decker' system providing a noncontributory, uniform, universal old-age pension, plus a contributory variable pension. ''24 The structural difference between the Freedom Plan and that plan deZ_Ibid., p. 333. 24Arthur J. Altmeyer, The Formative Yearsof Social Security (Madison: The University of Wisconsin Press, 1968),p. 259. 272 veloped in the 1940s is that bccn fcderallv administered. the second deck of the latter would have If Congress should decide early in 1983 to move post haste on the short-term financing but defer the long-term issues for further consideration, a double-decker system of some sort mav be a more feasible option than other major modifications. Should a program such as the Freedom Plan be considered, certain modifications mav be warranted. At least three are apparent from an equity perspective. First, if the government is going to provide some type of retirement bonds as a hedge against inflation, there should be some provision for real returns, at least when real returns are provided elsewhere in the market. Otherwise, a policy may develop, either explicit or implicit, that would seek to minimize federal debt costs at the expense of individual retirement savings. The payout of the real returns could be treated as regular income; tax provisions could assure that no undue advantage was accorded these vehicles. In addition, it would be desirable to allow investors to move their resources into other sectors of the financial market if they expect better returns elsewhere. Second, bifurcating the work force on an age- and date-specific basis would cause a considerable notch variation in the retirement provisions accorded to individuals who were nearlv the same age. It would be more reasonable to allow initial beneficiaries of the new program to become eligible to retire at roughly the same age as the last cohorts retiring under the program being phased out. This could be accomplished bv phasing in higher retirement ages for the younger cohorts of the old program or lower retirement ages for the older cohorts under the younger program. Third, providing unlimited COLA increases for pension beneficiaries might encourage further expansion of pension coverage and enhancement of benefit levels, but the distribution of benefits might be somewhat uneven across the income spectrum. Providing full indexation of these benefits at public expense might distort other broad political or fiscal goals. As a result, limited COLA provisions might be more rational. The senior citizen benefit program proposed bv Robertson would be somewhat cheaper than thc current OASDHI program. The savings derive primarily Dora raising the retirement age. Although the new program would ahcv thc basic distribution of benefits, it does not appear to bc significantly less generous, in the aggregate, than OASDHI with comparable normal retirement age provisions. Further analysis of the distributional implications of this proposal is warranted before such a change can bc seriously considered or implemented. 273 IX. The Future of Social Security Discussion in the previous chapters has focused on Social Security policy issues from a number of perspectives. The analysis in many instances was extremely detailed, in some, perhaps, it was gruesome. Anyone who has read this far may be disappointed that a well-defined list of "optimal" solutions has not yet been detailed for solving the "Social Security financing dilemma." The difficulty in doing that is that solutions have to evolve in the political arena. This discourse has been designed to describe the background and nature of Social Security; to define the position of the program in the broader retirement system that is evolving; to explain the nature of the program's financing problem; to present the main potential solutions; and to analyze their implications. Based on a substantial amount of work reported on here, however, we can offer certain observations. Recently it has become almost impossible to get through a single day without being exposed to a newspaper or magazine article or a television or radio news program addressing the Social Security concerns of this society. Regardless of the correctness or appropriateness of the content, these analyses are a fact of life. The stories tell of worried old people who fear the monthly green Social Security checks will not continue to arrive on time. They tell of workers who are convinced the Social Security program will not be there when they retire. They tell of widespread fear, resentment, and consternation among the American people that should be resolved. Redefining the Goals Social Security was established in an era of economic uncertainty, and the program had a fairly specific set of goals. It sought to provide a basic floor of income protection for elderly workers at retirement. It sought to provide proportionately higher benefits to low-wage workers than their high-wage counterparts. At the same time it established a link between preretirement earnings and postretirement benefits. It provided a financing mechanism tied to wages, partly as a practical matter but also on political grounds. President Roosevelt believed that payroll tax financing would give people the impression they were paying for their benefits, and he proved to be correct. He also believed that "earned" benefits would be less subject to political manipulation than benefits financed through some alternative mechanism. 275 In some ways Social Security can be characterized as a conservative response to growing demand for government protection of its citizenry, especially in old age. The Townsend movement during the 1930s was proposing a monthly benefit of $200 per month for everyone age sixty or over who was not working. Monthly benefits of this size in the mid- 1930s would be comparable to paying people over age sixty today between $1,400 and $1,500 per month. The Townsend movement was a major concern of President Roosevelt according to Ahmeyer and Witte, two central participants in the development of the Social Security program. The Social Security program that was designed by the Committee on Economic Security and modified and implemented by Congress was much smaller than the leading alternative of the time. Even taking into account the additional benefit categories that have been added to Social Security and all the historical growth in benefit levels, Social Security is still a smaller program than the Townsend plan. If everyone over age sixty in the United States today were provided a monthly benefit of $1,400, the cost of the program in 1982 would be at least $600 billion. The Social Security Act has been changed many times as the program has grown to be the single largest central governmental activity outside the realm of national defense. At the same time, the social, demographic, and economic characteristics been changing. This dynamic adjustment current state of affairs. of the U.S. society have process has led us to the Generally, public policy development is an incremental process. Revolutions or "big-bang" phenomena do not regularly occur in stable societies. People have an inherent resistance to radical change in major institutions because of the disruption and destabilization such change brings to their lives. Over the years the Social Security Act has been incrementally adjusted; coverage was gradually extended, benefits were added, the formula was modified, and tax rates and the wage base were adjusted accordingly. As the Congress convenes in 1983, it must readdress the fundamental issues relating to Social Security. Before dealing with the funding problem at hand, Congress might well stand back and reconsider several aspects of public retirement and economic policy in general. When the Social Security Act was passed in 1935, the basic socioeconomic unit in society was the "nuclear" family. The nuclear family then was typically a husband who worked, a wife who was a homemaker, and several children. The nuclear family had evolved from the "extended" family in which the grandparents often lived with, 276 or wcre supporled bv their own children. It was, to some extent, the decline of the extended family that gave rise to the development of Social Securitv. Older parents were no longer living in their adult children's homes, yet they still needed support. Since 1935, the nuclear family itself has changed, both in composition and behavior. The prevalence of single-parent households and two-earner couples has radically changed the population landscape. Whether the prevalence of working women has led to lower birthrates or vice versa is immaterial; what is important is that the majority of women are now earning their own Social Securitv entitlements and that there will be fewer workers in the future than there would have been if historical birthrates had prevailed. Both phenomena have implications for retirement policy development. In the case of couples, Congress should consider whether the concept of husband-earner with a wife-homemaker is still the appropriate premise for the program. It should consider the horizontal equity issues that arise between single-earner couples and two-earner couples (discussed in chapter VIII). Because of the lower birthrates that have prevailed in recent years, Congress also must set a modified course tot the twenty-first centurv. It should consider the implications and desirability of the alternative options for raising revenues or reducing costs. These considerations should be conducted in a broader context of general socioeconomic goals, of which Social Securitv financing is only one part. When the Social Security Act was passed in 1935, few workers were participating in a pension program. There were no tax incentives to encourage people to save for their own retirement income security. Prior to the Great Depression, there were no bank or savings and loan insurance programs to protect against the failure of financial institutions. Today the situation of workers is radically different. Social Security is by far the largest element of the elderly's retirement resources in 1982, but its relative position is changing and will be less significant in the future. This different economic environment has implications for the development of retirement policy in general and for Social Security policy in particular. During its early years, the Social Security program was largely "managed" by the Congress. This does not mean that Congress kept the earnings records or sent out the checks. The term refers to periodic congressional review of the benefit structure and levels and funding adjustments. After providing large benefit increases in the late 1960s and early 1970s, however, Congress significantly altered its role. Congress sought to move the program to an automatic adjustment process 277 so that benefit levels would be maintained in real terms over time, but would be less subject to political manipulation. The problems that arose from that adjustment have been detailed earlier, especially in chapters IV and V. Even after the adjustments in the indexing provisions made by the 1977 amendments problems have persisted. During the deliberations of the National Commission on Social Security Reform the potential of further indexing opportunities have been explored. Implementation of provisions for further indexing would move Social Security even closer to automatic self-adjustment. The members of the Commission have considered a variety of options that would: (1) index the normal retirement age to account for increased longevity; (2) index the payroll tax rate to maintain fund balances; and (3) index the payroll tax to offset increases in nonwage benefit costs not subject to the payroll tax. About the only thing not considered was indexing the birthrate. The policy issues that must be considered, however, relate to whether the Congress wishes to retake greater control of this program or cast it further into the mode of automatic adjustment. Evaluating Specific Options A wide range of options for addressing these issues has been presented and discussed in chapters V through VIII. Various considerations are important in determining which options deserve congressional review. Certain options seem to be outside the realm of reason; for example, eliminating any form of social insurance is in this category. Moving the social insurance system from an entirely public system to a more evenly divided public-private system might deserve consideration. Such a change should not be done in an impetuous short-term fashion that would drastically alter the expectations of workers near retirement or reduce benefits for those already retired. Nor should it be based on assumptions of unreasonable rates of return in private investment markets or wildly optimistic assumptions about future increases in productivity. The discussion of Social Security's financing situation in chapter IV indicates that in the short term there is not much room or time to maneuver. The OASI trust fund must borrow from the HI and DI trust funds in November 1982; it can borrow enough through the end of December 1982 to meet benefit schedules beyond July 1983. Even if interfund borrowing authority is extended, the three trust funds would probably be depleted sometime in 1984, and certainly during 1985. These projections are not meant to frighten anybody; they are 278 projections made by the Social Security actuaries and they indicate a situation worthy of concern, not panic. The important point to understand is that the short-term problem is surmountable. The discussion in chapter V describes Social Security's financing mathematics. Over short-run cycles, Social Security is susceptible to two problems: (1)under current benefit indexation procedures and in certain economic conditions, the ratio of average benefits to average wages is unstable; (2) the ratio of the number of beneficiaries to the number of workers varies directlv with unemployment. The product of these two ratios defines the tax rate required to finance Social Security. With no significant trust fund balance, Social Security has been buffeted by unemployment that has been higher than expected and by faster growth in average benefits than in average wages in recent years. As a result, the legislated tax rates have been insufficient to meet the benefit obligations. A degree of stabilitv can be established bv adjusting the benefit indexation provisions so that benefits do not grow more rapidly than wages in the future. Because the ratio of beneficiaries to workers will never be completely stable, trust fund balances somewhat larger than those maintained in the early stages of the early 1980s should be maintained in thc future. Chapter V discusses several options for meeting the short-term financing imbalance. In resolving the problems associated with Social Security, Congress must pursue four basic policy goals. Two of these, adequacy and equity, have been traditional concerns of policymakers. The other two goals for Social Security policy are solvencv and support. In the past, these latter goals have been met without much concern; solvency and support just happened. With the maturing of the program and the blossoming of tax rates and solvency problems, these goals will require much greater attention in future policy deliberations. The combination of the four goals--adequacy, equity, solvency, and support suggests that the burden of adjusting Social Security should be widely shared by American societv. The more widely the burden can be distributed, the smaller will be the burden on any one segment of society. In the long term, the financing problems also appear to be surmountable. The policy options are somewhat more varied than in the short term, however. They aim basically at adjusting the level and distribution of benefits to be provided by Social Security in the future. Some of the commonly discussed options would not have any effect on benefits for ten to twenty years; others would begin to adjust benefits almost immediately but accomplish the adjustment over a 279 long, gradual transition period. The options break down into two categories. One set of proposals would raise Social Security's normal retirement age. Such a policy might also raise early retirement ages but it would not necessarily have to do so. A second set of proposals would adjust the benefit formula over a number of years in a method different from the method now used. Raising retirement ages or slowing the growth of future benefit entitlements are both widely characterized as benefit reductions. For example, growth in the amounts that worker when determine the an option PIA formula arc applied that person basic Social evaluated in chapter VI would slow the bend points. These bend points are dollar against the average lifetime earnings of a reaches retirement age; the bend points Securitv benefit entitlement for an indi- vidual. These bend points are increased each year by the growth in average wages. If they were indexed at 75 percent of wage growth for sixteen years instead of full wage growth, under assumptions used by Social Security's actuaries, the new beneficiaries' average benefits relative to current law would be reduced by an average of roughly 10 to 11 percent bv the end of the transition period. Because expected wage growth would still increase the bend points under this approach, average new benefits would still have greater purchasing power for persons who retired at the end of the transition than current benefits have. The simulation results in chapter III estimated that average tamily Social Security benefits at age sixty-five ['or individual persons aged twenty-five to thirty-four in 1979 would be about 70 percent higher than benefits at age sixty-five for persons aged fifty-five to sixty-four in 1979 under current policy. Benefits relative to current policy would be about 11 percent lower if the 75 percent bend point indexation were implemented, but they would still be about 50 percent higher than benefits for the older cohort under current policy. To characterize such benefit modifications as a benefit reduction is to assume that the current policy benefits are already in the bank. It is no more realistic to assume that we can precisely define the retirement benefits [or workers thirty years old today than to assume that we can tell these people what a new automobile will cost at their retirement age. If a benefit structure is in place that assures them a benefit, one that grows in real terms over time as wages grow, then this assurance will provide a foundation on which other elements of the retirement system can be based. Raising the retirement age has also been considered as a way to adjust Social Security benefits in order to help balance the projected 280 long-term funding equation. This approach is also frequently characterized as a benefit reduction. The simulation results in chapter VI, indeed, show such reductions relative to current policy. The benefit reductions, in aggregate, from raising retirement ages may be roughly compared to those accomplished bv slowing initial benefit growth, however. An important distinction between the two approaches to reducing Social Security costs is the difference in their distributional effects. Raising the Social Security retirement ages, both earlv and normal, would completely eliminate payments to some people who would receive them under current policy. This phenomenon occurs because Social Security benefits are not paid to the deceased and there is no rebate of contributions on which benefits are not paid. Raising Social Security's retirement age will exclude some persons from receiving benefits who would receive them under current policy because they will die prior to reaching the higher age. Others will receive benefits for a shorter period because they will die soon after retirement and their period of receipt will be shortened. Finally, others will retire earlier, relative to Social Security's normal retirement age and receive a benefit that is actuariallv reduced to a greater extent than under current policy. Increasing life expectancy, which is accentuating Social Securitv's financing problems, cannot be ignored, however. People today are living longer, on average, beyond age sixty-five than thev did ten or twenty years ago or in 1935, when Social Security's normal retirement age was established. Increases in life expectancy are expected to continue for the foreseeable future. In the abstract this increase in life expectancy would lead directly to the conclusion that people should be able to work longer, but the increased incidence of disability and health problems among older workers, in combination with the benefit exclusions that result from early death complicates this conclusion. Nonetheless, .just as outcomes from modification in benefit formuias can be compared with the current levels of benefits, the same analvtical criteria can be applied to options for raising retirement age. The concerns over exclusion of some potential beneficiaries under higher retirement ages is equally appropriate for the current eligibility criteria. The worker who dies today at age sixty gets no benefits from Social Security. He or she mav indirectlv receive such benefits through the spouse and survivor provisions, but those provisions would continue to apply even if retirement ages were raised. The death exclusion alreadv exists for people who do not meet the eligibility criteria or accept benefits. The question is, what arc the 281 relative rates of exclusions that result because a particular retirement age is applicable? If retirement age remains constant while life expectancy rises, then the exclusion affects diminishing shares of each successive cohort of workers. If retirement age rises gradually as life expectancy rises then the death exclusionary effect could be held roughly constant over time. Although disability and health problems would increase as retirement ages are raised the Social Security Disability Insurance program should ameliorate part of that problem. If the response is insufficient then additional provisions might be required that would reduce the savings from raising retirement ages. Regardless of Social Security's retirement age policy the prevailing decline in birthrates over the past twenty-five years may mean that the economy will require extended working lives. To some extent, the size of the baby-boom generation and the withdrawal of these people from the labor market at retirement will lead to somewhat higher wages. Those higher wages will affect the tradeoff between labor and leisure or work and retirement. If the financial incentives for working increase, they will naturally encourage older workers to stay in the job market longer. Massive retirements of the baby-boom generation, however, could still create labor shortages that would lead to a decline in gross production. If such declines in gross product occur, they would coincide with retirees demanding a larger share of a smaller total. Will this phenomenon occur? No one knows for sure. Might it occur? Yes. Raising additional revenues through the payroll tax or alternative sources would help resolve the projected problem. To raise reserves now to the extent required to balance the system over the long term would cause the trust fund accumulation problems discussed in the previous chapter. Unless provisions are made to handle those trust funds, raising taxes might create even more problems. To merely schedule future tax increases sufficient to meet the long-term problems would be to levy on today's children and those not yet born, a burden that current or prior generations have been unwilling to bear. Will future taxpayers be willing to accept that burden? Maybe they will; possibly they won't. There is the distinct possibility that the adjustment or alternative structure that comes out of this process will result in an overfinanced system in the future. If that is the case, policy corrections will be easy to achieve: either benefits can be raised, or taxes reduced. There is also the possibility that the adjustments will not be sufficient; the choice in this case will be much harder. 282 Congress could move toward a system that indexes retirement age, taxes, initial benefit entitlements, and postretirement benefits, but there are problems with this approach stemming from Social Security's role in the broader economic structure. If employer pensions do not move in lockstep with the automatic Social Security adjustments, perverse benefit distributions could result. Legislation could require employer programs to move in unison with Social Security, but employers are influenced by a wide range of physical, economic, and technological factors in determining their work force policies and pension programs. To entirely constrict the ability of employers to adjust their own pension programs to fit their particular circumstances could destroy some employers' economic viability. Furthermore, unt'oreseen periodic modifications to their other retirement programs to stay in step with an automatically adjusted Social Security program would complicate the establishment and funding of pensions. Finally, adverse economic circumstances or technological change could place older workers who lack alternate provisions in particularly precarious positions. Furthermore, there is some merit in requiring Congress to vote periodically on the relative burden of taxes and level of benefits. The process of indexing personal income tax rates through bracket creep has been one of the most heated political issues of recent years. The phenomenon in the case of bracket creep is somewhat more subtle than the explicit indexation of payroll taxes would be. The indexing of retirement ages may not be warmly received, either. Telling young workers that they will be required to work a couple more years than their parents is one thing, but making them watch their expected retirement age creep further and further up the age spectrum could be quite another. The analyses in chapters V through VIII describe a fairly wide range of options that the Congress could mix and match to restore financial soundness to Social Security. The analyses in chapters V and VI present some of the distributional questions to which Congress should be sensitive in adjusting the current system. It should be understood that random combinations of options mav result in less savings than the sum of the separate savings of each option. Similarly, certain combinations of options could have significantly greater impact on benefit levels and distributions than each option separately. For example, slowing the growth of initial benefits in combination with raising the retirement age would cause greater changes in benefit levels and distributions than either option taken separately. In some 283 instances, combinations of policy effects on the elderly of the future. Maintaining Incentives changes for Private could have devastating Programs The simulation analysis that has been discussed throughout this report has assumed that pension and individual retirement savings incentives will be maintained in the future. On this basis it was assumed that gradual growth and use of these alternate retirement vehicles would continue. These assumptions are central to the analysis of the effects of Social Security modifications on the total income security of the elderly. Some people advocate radically modil_ving the tax treatment of private retirement programs for purposes of general revenue enhancement or Social Security financing. Before policymakers seriously consider such proposals they should scrutinize the implications. If the retirement income provided bv vehicles other than Social Security is reduced for future retirees, the eflects of Social Security modifications will become much more pronounced. If private provisions were Completely eliminated, the demands on Social Security would increase significantly beyond those discussed in chapters IV and V. If private retirement programs were eliminated, or even diminished, pressure to expand Social Securitv in the long term would be increased. While the elimination or curtailment of private retirement programs may appear to be an attractive idea to some policy analysts, Social Security's current financing problems would be dwarted by the magnitude of the problems that course would entail. In 1980, Social Security actuaries analyzed the costs of a National Pension Plan that would maintain living standards during retirement. I First, they estimated the levels of income replacement required to meet their adequacy goals t0r benefits and then compared these levels of income replacement with the levels provided by Social Security. A pension plan was designed to provide benefits that corresponded with those requirements. The plan would provide benefits only after age sixty-five. The plan included provisions for earnings sharing and survivor benefits and other adjustments to coordinate Social Security with the overall income targets specified in the plan. JFor a complete duscription ol this plan and its costs see Dwight K. Bartlcn, Ill, "National Demographics and Private Pensions," Conterenc¢ of Actuaries in Public Practice, Cambridge, Mass., October 7 and 8, 1982. 284 The plan was assumed to cover all workers, including those now exempt from Social Security participation, and to take effect in Januarv 1982. The long-term cost projections of the current OASDI system based on the intermediate assumptions in the 1980 Trustees Report are shown in table IX-1. The table also shows the cost of the current svstem projected at that time assuming universal Social Security coverage. The universal coverage estimates are shown so the marginal cost of the National Pension Plan can be compared with the cost of the current system on the same employment base. Implementing a national pension plan that, in combination with Social Security, would meet the stated benefit goals and be funded bv payroll taxes on a pay-as-you-go basis would raise the seventyfive year average cost of the federal retirement program by 63 percent. TABLE Projected with IX-I Expenditures of OASDI Under 1980 Policy, Universal Coverage and with Hypothetical National Pension Plan Estimated Expenditures Taxable as a Percentage Payroll of Current System Current System with Universal Coverage Hypothetical National Pension Plan 1980-2004 2005-2029 10.66 13.57 9.09 11.86 12.50 20.28 2030 16.98 15.18 26.01 13.74 12.05 19.59 25- Yea r Averages 2054 75- Yea r Average 1980-2054 Sources: Note: 1980 Social Security Trustees Annual Report, p. 75; and Dwight K. Bartlett, ill, "National Demographic and Private Pensions," Conference of Actuaries in Public Practice, Cambridge, Mass., October 7 and 8, 1982, p. 10. These projections arc based on the intermediate (Alternative II) set of assumptions appearing in the 1980 OASDI Trustees Report. Total taxable payroll is adiusted to take into account the lower tax rates on self-employment income and on tips as computed to the employer rates, and is also adiusted to take into account the elimination of the wage base. The Universal Coverage OASDI system is an extension of the present OASDI svstern to cover the earnings of federal, state and local government employees, and employees of nonprofit organizations, beginning January 1, 1982. The Hypothetical National Pension Plan is an extension of the Universal Coverage OASDI system to provide supplementary' old-age and disability pension benefits to those newly entitled persons after January 1, 1982. 285 It would raise these costs by 71 percent during each of the last two twenty-five-year periods in the projection period. The payroll tax now legislated beyond 1990 would meet only about half the projected cost of the system beyond the turn of the century. Furthermore, moving away from the current combination of Social Security and private provisions may be compared to "eating the seed corn" in more than one way. Private pension assets at the end of 1981, estimated from Federal Reserve data, amounted to $520 billion. State and local pension assets added another $222 billion. The combined assets in these pension plans amounted to 12.3 percent of all outstanding credit extended to the U.S. credit markets. The figure, up from 3.0 percent in 1950, represents a thirty-year pattern of steady growth .2 Pension assets are among the most important sources of capital in this country today and their role is growing. The potential of IRAs as a source of long-term savings is only beginning to be realized. Both pensions and IRAs will contribute to capital growth in the future, which is particularly important during a period of reindustrialization in this country. Furthermore, these assets will provide the elderly with a retirement income claim on the capital base of the United States economy, which Social Security cannot provide under current financing arrangements. Given the uncertainties of the public's acceptance of higher taxes, that claim is worth preserving. Maintaining Flexibility This report has been filled with projections and estimates from many sources. The story that these numbers tell is that the future may not be as dismal as a narrow focus on Social Security's current financing projections would suggest. While it is impossible for anyone to predict the future with great accuracy, some trends can be observed and their outcomes predicted. For example, American society is aging, and it will continue to do so. In addition, pensions are growing in importance as a source of retirement income security, and they will continue to do so in a favorable policy environment. Although the aging of society is bound to put extra stress on Social Security, the growth of pensions can help to relieve some of that burden. These two countervailing trends suggest that Social Security can adjust in the future to meet the needs of society. The uncertainty in 2Sophie M. Korczyk, Retireme_tt Opportumties i_l an Agi_llg America: Eco_tomy (Washington, D.C.: EBRI, 1982), p. 46. 286 Pe_tsio_ts and the the extent of changes in the economy, productivity, birthrates, life expectancy and a host of other factors suggests adoption of a Social Security policy that allows some margin for error. This means that any policy changes made in the current environment should not promise more for the future than we are sure we can provide. One has to assume that future Congresses will be better equipped in ten or twenty years hence to assess appropriate benefit and taxing provisions in their respective times. Policvmakers then wilt be better able to judge the relative needs and capabilities of their society and economy than anyone in Congress can judge today. If we cannot trust the future political process in this society, we should be seeking not to insure ourselves against that process, but to change it fundamentally. 287 Appendix A Pension and Retirement Model Income Simulation This appendix dcscribes the Pension and Retiremcnt Income Simulation Model used to simulate the current U.S. retirement system in chapter Ill. The model is also used to simulate the alternative longterm Social Securitv policy options discussed in chapter VI. A brief description of each of the main components follows. A more detailed description of the model is available from the Employee Bcnefit Research Institute on request. The Input Database The database uscd at the beginning of the simulation, which was developed by ICF Incorporated, includes a combination of data gathered from four separate databases. Three of these were sets of interview data from the Census Bureau's Current Population Survey. The tourth consisted of administrative record data from the Social Security Administration. A schematic of the component elements in the combined data set is shown in figure A-1. Because of the sample design used for the CPS, which is a monthly survey, there is considerable overlap from month to month of the people who are interviewed. In March of each year, the Census Bureau includes an extensive supplement to the basic interview which ascertains detailed information on employment and earnings. The annual March interview gathers this information for more than 100,000 adults. The March 1978 CPS questionnaire responses were matched to Social Security administrative records bv Social Security numbers, name, and sex. Each vear half of the March sample overlaps the sample administered bv the CPS the following Mav. During May 1979, the CPS included a special supplement that ascertained pension coverage, participation, and vesting information for persons who had also been surveved in the March 1979 CPS. Slightly more than half the people interviewed in the March and May 1979 survevs had also been in the CPS sample in March 1978. In the end, then, there were about 28,000 persons for whom there were data in each of the four separate databases. The combined ployment-wage database includes pension information along with emrate, industry, size of firm, age, sex, hourly/salaried 289 290 status, years of service on current job, Social Security coverage, union status, marital status, and a host of other information for 1979. The database also includes employment, earnings and income data, by source, for the years 1977 and 1978. It includes Social Security quarters of coverage earned for the years 1937 to 1977 and annual taxable earnings for 1951 to 1977. This combined information is available on an individual and family basis; that is, when married couples are included, information is available for both spouses. The Work History Model In the first stage in the PRISM simulation process, the model takes the input database as its definition of the population in 1979. Then, by using a Monte Carlo simulation process (described below), the model estimates annual hours worked and earnings level as well as changes in family and health characteristics for each year until retirement. The model simulates a series of discrete events for each person for each year in the simulation. One of the events that is simulated is the life or death of a person that year; based on age and sex, the probability of a person's dying in any given year is known from Social Security data. For cxample, assume that thc probability of death for a fifty-three-year-old man is 1 percent; the Monte Carlo process simulates the experience of such a man on the basis of drawing a random number between zero and onc. If the random number actually drawn falls below 0.01, the person is trcated as if he had died. If the number drawn falls between 0.01 and 1.00, hc is treated as living through the year and becoming a year older. Since only 1 percent of the random number drawn will fall below 0.01 when many such numbers are being drawn, only 1 percent of the fifty-three-year-old simulation will die each year. men in the The work history model estimates the occurrence of eight separate events for each person each year until the person dies or reaches age seventy: (l)whether the person dies, becomes disabled, or recovers from a disability; (2)whcther the person marries, gets divorced, or remarries; (3) whether a woman gives birth to a child; (4) whether the person decides to accept a pension or Social Securitv benefit; (5) whethcr thc person works, and if so, the number of hours of work; (6) whether the person changes jobs; (7) if the person changes jobs or enters the work force, the industry of employment; and (8) the wage rate for the person. 291 The simulation of each of these events is accomplished abilities estimated from recent Census Bureau, Bureau using probof Labor Sta- tistics, and Social Security Administration data. A general schematic of the model is shown in figure A-2. The information generated by the work history simulation contains sufficient information about marital status, labor-force participation, and retirement program coverage to estimate both Social Security and pension benefits for each person. Each worker's pension coverage status in the first year is determined directly from the input database. Coverage of workers changing jobs or entering the work force is estimated as a function of the person's industry of employment, hours worked, age, and indexed wage rate. This relationship is based on coverage rates reported for job changers and labor-force entrants in the May 1979 CPS. Over time, pension coverage is provided to some workers who do not change jobs and who were not previously covered. This, in essence, provides for pension plan growth with the passage of time. For workers covered by multiemployer plans who change jobs but remain in the same industry, there is no change in plan coverage. A pension plan sponsor selected from a representative sample of more than 300 employer retirement plan sponsors is randomly assigned to each covered worker. This representative database is stratified bv industry, including federal, state, and local employers; size of firm; and muhiemployer and single-employer plan sponsors. The database includes plan provision data for both the primary and supplemental defined-benefit and defined-contribution plans offered by public- and private-sector sponsors. The database includes all relevant plan provisions for participation, vesting, hours crediting, retirement, death, disability, joint and survivor benefits, and Social Security integration. Within an industry, in a firm of a given size in the multi- or single-employer category, the probability of being assigned to a given plan sponsor is proportional to the number of persons actually covered by that plan sponsor. The model assigns a specific plan or set of plans to each person for each period of covered employment. The assignment is random from a group of plans matched to the worker on the basis of industry, size of firm and employment characteristics of the worker. The Retirement Benefit Model Retirement benefits are estimated for individuals using the simulated work histories and their record of participation in retirement 292 FIGURE A-2 PRISM Work History PENSION AND SOCIAL Simulation SECURITY Model DATABASE RECORDS -- Social Security data and assumptions 1. DEATH AND DISABILITY Using National Center for Health Social Security data 2. MARITAL STATUS TRANSITION -- By age, education, From longitudinal 3. CHILD BEARING [ Statistics hours worked, number analvsis of CPS data I (NCHS) and of children 1 -- ACCEPTANCE From longitudinalOF analysis of CPS data 4. RETIREMENT BENEFITS [ 1 -- By age, sex, marital status, education From longitudinal of CPS data 5. HOURS WORKED analysis ANNUALLY 6. JOB CHANGE -- Bv age, hours worked, years of service From longitudinal analysis of CPS data 7. INDUSTRY --- OF EMPLOYMENT Fox" job changers, From longitudinal -From longitudinal 8. WAGE RATES labor force entrants analvsis of CPS data analysis ot CPS data I I I-[ REPEAT PROCESS FOR EACH SIMULATION Source: ICF Incorporated project staff. YEAR ] 293 programs. The first step in the benefit simulation model is the calculation of Social Security benefits based on the wage history. The primary insurance amount is determined on the basis of covered earnings used to derive the average indexed monthly earnings as defined in current law. The benefit formula and taxable wage base were assumed to adjust in accordance with the assumed rate of wage growth assumed in current law. The Social Security benefit level is calculated on the basis of the PIA and age at retirement. Benefits are also calculated for survivors of persons who died during the simulation. To calculate the pension benefit, the model first considers each worker's history of covered employment. The model determines benefit eligibility on the basis of annual hours worked, tenure of employment in the covered job, creditable service, and vesting standards in the plan. If a person is vested, the model uses the benefit formula in the plan to determine benefits based on creditable service. If the plan is integrated with Social Security, the model adjusts the benefit according to the plan formula. If there is a supplemental plan, the model also calculates benefits in accordance with the participation requirements and benefit or contribution standards in the plan. To determine total pension benefits, the model undertakes this process for each plan in which the worker vests. In addition to Social Security and employer pension entitlements, the model estimates the level of benefits, in the form of annuity, purchasable through IRA accumulations. IRA accumulations are estimated on the basis of the earnings history and family characteristics generated by the work history model. The probability of a worker's adopting an IRA in any given year of the work career is based on the worker's age and family earnings levels. These probabilities were derived from Internal Revenue Service data on IRA utilization and the May 1979 CPS, which included questions on IRA usage. After an IRA is established, using the Monte Carlo technique, the model calculates annual contributions as a function of family earnings. After estimating benefits from Social Security, employer-sponsored plans, and IRAs, the model accumulates total retirement benefits for each person in the simulation. These benefits can be accumulated either in the form of an annuity or a lump-sum value, although in this project the model converts all employer-sponsored plan benefits to life annuities. As a result, it is possible to examine the impact of changes in the accumulation of retirement wealth and in the payment of these benefits during retirement. 294 Once employment-related retirement benefits are estimated, the model simulates benefits from the Supplemental Security Income program in three steps. The first step determines an individual's or married couple's SSI eligibility status; once eligibility has been determined, the model calculates the benefit amount. Because about 25 percent of all SSI benefit amounts are provided through state supplementation, the model accounts for increased benefits in the major states providing such benefits. The state of residence for this purpose is assumed to be the state in which the individual resided during 1979. Finally, based on estimated participation rates in the program, the model simulates participation or nonparticipation in the program for individuals. Figure A-3 displays the general structure of PRISM's benefit simulation component. 295 FIGURE A-3 PRISM Retirement Benefit Simulation Model ! WORK HISTORIES FROM PRISM WORK HISTORY MODEL 1 I | 1. SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFIT ESTIMATION -- Simulated work history data for 1979 to retirement -- Actual data on Social Security coverage and taxable earnings prior to 1979 2. EMPLOYER -- Earnings Model -- Actual RETIREMENT and hours worked benefit provisions 1 PLAN BENEFIT simulated of plans ESTIMATION in the Work History. to which assigned 1 3. IRA ADOPTION ---- DETERMINATION Probability of adoption of IRA Estimated annual contribution Annual income from IRA when retired 4. SSI INCOME --- Earnings and retirement income Eligibility and benefit provisions simulated by model of program 1 BENEFITS ACCUMULATED Source: ICFIncorporated project staff. 296 FROM ALL SOURCES ] Appendix B Calculating Social Security Benefits 1977 Social Security Formula This appendix presents the basic steps required Security benefits under the formula established ments to the Social Security Act. Wage Under the to determine Social bv the 1977 amend- Indexing The first step in calculating a Social Securitv benefit under the formula established bv the 1977 amendments is to calculate the AIME. The AIME is based on actual covered earnings in each year multiplied by a wage index. A worker's actual covered earnings on his or her Social Security account are indexed up through the second year prior to the worker's reaching age sixty-two. People reaching age sixty-two in 1981, {'or example, had their wages indexed through 1979. Any earnings they receive beyond 1979 are treated at their actual face or nominal value. The index used to adjust wage histories is based on historical average wages. The averages for the period 1951 to 1977 represent the average wage level in covered employment. Beyond 1977, the average wage is based on growth in total wages in both covered and noncovered employment. The average wage series for computing the indexing factors used by the Social Security Administration are shown in the second column of table B-1. The annual indexes are derived bv dividing average wages in the second year prior to attaining age sixty-two by the average wage in each prior year. For example, the earnings for a worker who turned sixty-two in 1979 are indexed through 1977 when the average wages were $9,779. The index to be applied against 1976 earnings is derived by dividing the average wage in 1979 ($9,779) bv the average wage in 1976 ($9,226). The quotient equals 1.060 and is shown in the fourth column of table B-I for 1976. Each annual indexing factor for t979 is derived on the basis of 1977 average earnings in this fashion. For people reaching age sixtv-two in 1980, the basic year is 1978, when average wages were $10,556. The 1980 index is derived by the same procedure as the 1979 index, but the higher basis raises the index for each vear prior to 1978. The indexes increase each year at the same rate as average wages grew in the basis year. 297 TABLE B-1 Indexing Average Wage Series, Annual Maximum Taxable Earnings. and Wage Indexes Used in Calculating Social Security AIME, 1979-1982 Year 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 Source: 298 Average Annual Wage Se_es $ 2,799 2,973 3,139 3,156 3,301 3,532 3,642 3,674 3,856 4,007 4,087 4,291 4,397 4,567 4,659 4,938 5,213 5,572 5,894 6,186 6,497 7,134 7,580 8,031 8,631 9,226 9,779 10,556 11,479 12,513 NA NA Annual Maximum Taxable Earnings 1979 $ 3,600 3,600 3,600 3,600 4,200 4,200 4,200 4,200 4,800 4,800 4,800 4,800 4,800 4,800 4,800 6,600 6,600 7,800 7,800 7,800 7,800 9,000 10,800 13,200 14,100 15,300 16,500 17,700 22,900 25,900 29,700 32,400 3.494 3.289 3.115 3.099 2.962 2.769 2.685 2.662 2.536 2.441 2.393 2.279 2.224 2.137 2.099 .980 .876 .755 .659 .581 .505 .371 .290 .218 .133 .060 .000 .000 NA NA NA NA Social Security Administration. Annual Wage Indexes 1980 1981 1982 3.771 3.550 3.362 3.345 3.197 2.988 2.899 2.873 2.738 2.634 2.383 2.460 2.401 2.306 2.266 2.137 2.025 1.894 1.791 1.706 1.625 1.480 1.393 1.314 1.223 1.144 1.079 1.000 1.000 NA NA NA 4.101 3.861 3.657 3.638 3.477 3.250 3.152 3.125 2.977 2.865 2.809 2.675 2.611 2.508 2.464 2.375 2.202 2.060 1.948 1.856 1.767 1.609 1.514 i.429 1.330 1.244 1.174 1.087 1.000 1.000 NA NA 4.470 4.209 3.986 3.965 3.790 3.542 3.436 3.406 3.245 3.123 3.062 2.916 2.846 2.736 2.686 2.534 2.400 2.246 2.123 2.023 .926 .754 .651 .558 .450 .356 .279 .185 .000 1.000 1.000 NA Calculating the AIME The number of years considered in the calculation of AIME varies for different persons. The proper number of years is determined by the year in which the person reaches age sixty-two. For people who were at least twenty-one years old in 1950, the number is equal to the number of years between 1950 and the year the person reaches age sixty-two, dies, or is disabled. Thus, for a person who reaches age sixty-two in 1982, the number of years considered in calculating the benefit is the number of years between, but not including, 1950, and 1982, which is thirty-one years. For people reaching age twenty-one after 1950 the number of years elapsing between the year the person reached that age and the year they reach age sixty-two, die, or are disabled is used in the calculation. This means a maximum of forty years will be considered when the process matures. Once the number of years to be considered has been determined, a number of years can be discarded for purposes of these calculations. For retirement and survivor benefits, five years are dropped. For disability cases under age twenty-seven, no years are dropped. For disabled people between the ages of twenty-seven and thirty-one, one year is dropped. The number of dropout years increases in one-year increments for each additional five years of age at disability. Thus it reaches the five-year maximum for persons disabled at age fortyseven or later.J The actual number of years used to compute the AIME is the number of years considered, less the dropped years. The computation takes the highest years of indexed earnings beginning in 1951 and ending with the year before actual entitlement. This can include years before age twenty-one and after age sixty-two. If the earnings in the year of entitlement would raise the AIME, these earnings can be substituted later. Similarly, if a person returns to work after retirement, the AIME can be recomputed if it would be higher following the second retirement. For people reaching age sixtv-two in 1982 the number of AIME computation years is twenty-six (31 minus 5). This number will increase by one year each year until 1991, when the maximum of thirtyfive computation years will be reached. For the sixtv-two-vear-olds _Additional dropout years are provided to certain persons if they were living with a child under three years of age in years they had no earnings. If child-care vears are considered, no more than three vears of combined child care and regular years can be dropped. 299 retiring in 1982, the AIME equals the sum of the highest twenty-six years of indexed earnings divided by 312 (26 years times 12 months). The AIME is used to determine the basic Social Security entitlement. Calculating the PIA The primary insurance amount, which is the benefit payable to a person who retires at age sixty-five and receives no dependent's benefits, is calculated by a formula specified in the 1977 amendments. In the original formula for persons reaching age sixty-two in 1979, the PIA was equal to: 90 percent of the first $180 of AIME plus 32 percent of the next $905 of AIME plus 15 percent of AIME over $1,0852 These AIME dollar amounts multiplied by the various percentage factors are often referred to as the bend points in the formula; they accomplish the income redistribution from high-to low-wage workers. To see how this distribution occurs, consider three persons with AIMEs of $500, $1,000, and $2,000 using the formula above. Table B2 shows the results. The calculated PIA increases as the AIME increases, but the ratio of the PIA to the AIME declines as the AIME rises. Since the PIA determines the benefit amount, Social Security TABLE PIAs and Replacement Using 1979 of AIME in Selected Benefit Formula Case l AIME PIA Formula Case 2 Cases Case 3 $500.00 $1,000.00 $2,000.00 162.00 102.40 0.00 $264.40 .53 162.00 262.40 0.00 $ 424.40 .42 162.00 289.60 137.25 $ 588.85 .29 Application .90 of first $180 + .32 of next $905 + .1S of AIME over $1,085 Total PIA PIA/AIME Source: B-2 Calculated bv the author. 2There was a transitional guarantee in the 1977 amendments tor persons reaching age sixty-two between 1979 and 1982. This basically Iroze the old tormula and provided that retirement bcncl'its would be tile higher o1' benefits calculated on PIAs determined under the transitional or new formula. 300 will replace a larger share of preretirement earnings for lower-wage workers than for higher-wage workers, if other things are held constant. The bend points in the tormula established bv the 1977 amendments are themselves indexed bv the rate of wage growth. The bend points in the 1979 formula were indexed by the growth in average wages between 1977 and 1978 to derive the bend points for the 1980 formula. The growth resulting from this benefit formula indexation is reflected in table B-3. The net effect of this growth is that initial benefits grow at the same rate as wages grow over time. Both the annual wage indexes and benefit formulas are linked to workers attaining age sixty-two in the applicable year. The PIA for people who continue to work beyond age sixty-two and retire later, say, at age sixty-five, is determined under the formula for the cohort to which these people belong. But their initial PIA is then augmented to account for any general benefit increases that they would have received had they retired at age sixty-two. Thus until age sixty-two, the PIA grows as wages grow; beyond that age it grows in relation to prices. Calculating Benefits People who retire at age sixtv-five and disabled people reccive the PIA as their basic bcncfits. The benefits for people who retire before age sixty-five are reduced five-ninths of 1 percent for each month short of age sixtv-five that they draw benefits. This reduction is equivalent to a 6.67 percent reduction for each year prior to age sixty-five and to a 20 percent reduction of benefits taken at age sixty-two. For people reaching age sixty-five after 1981, the PIA is increased 3 percent for each vcar benefits arc not taken between the ages of sixtyfive and seventy-two. TABLE B-3 Social Formula Security Benefit Formula Selected Years Replacement Rates 1979 .90of first .32 of next $ .15 of AIME in excess of Source: Social Security 180 905 1,085 Bend 1980 $ 194 977 1,171 Points 1981 $ 211 1,063 1,274 for 1982 $ 230 1,158 1,388 Administration. 301 Benefits for dependents are also calculated from the worker's PIA, subject to a family maximum. A spouse of a retired or disabled beneficiary receives 50 percent if the spouse benefit is taken at age sixtyfive. If taken earlier, the benefit is actuarially reduced at the rate of twenty-five-thirty-sixths (i.e., 25/36) of 1 percent per month. Each child under age eighteen receives 50 percent of the PIA until the family maximum is reached. In the case of survivor benefits, the spouse taking care of children under age sixteen and the children below age eighteen are eligible to receive 75 percent of the PIA, up to the family maximum. The maximum family benefit (MFB) for disability cases is the lower of 150 percent of the PIA or 85 percent of the AIME, so long as it is not less than the PIA. For retirement and survivor cases, the MFB is calculated in a fashion similar to the PIA itself. The year in which a worker reaches age sixty-two or dies determines the MFB formula for the family. The formula is indexed by wage increases in the same way as the PIA formula. The bend points and annual amounts to which they apply are shown in table B-4. TABLE B-4 Maximum Formula Rates 1.50 of 2.72 of 1.34 of 1.75 of Source: 302 Family Benefit Bend Years Points for Selected 1979 1980 1981 1982 first $230 next 102 next 101 PIA in excess of 433 Social Security Administration. $248 110 109 467 $270 120 118 508 $294 131 129 554 I DRI Publi ati0n Economic Survival in Retirement: $10.00 ([SBN 0-86643-027-X) Which Pension Is for You?, 1982, America in Transition: Implications for Employee Benefits, 1982, $10.00 (ISBN 0-86643-026-1) Retirement Income Opportunities in an Aging America Volume/--Coverage and Benefit Entitlement, 198 l, $10.00 (ISBN 086643-013-X) Volume//--Income Levcls and Adequacy, 1982, $10.00 (ISBN 0-86643014-8) Volume lll--Pensions and the Economy, 1982, $10.00 (ISBN 0-86643-015-6) Retirement Income and the Economy: Policy Directions for the 80s, 1981, $10.00-paperback (ISBN 0-86643-023-7) $18.00-hardbound (ISBN 086643-025-3) Retirement Income and the Economy: Increasing Income for the Aged, 198 I, $10.00 (ISBN 0-86643-024-5) A Bibliography of Research: Retirement Income & Capital Accumulation Programs, 1981, $25.00 (ISBN 0-86643-022-9) A Bibliography of Research: Health Care Programs, 1981, $25.00 (ISBN 086643-021-0) A Review of Research Volume/--Demographics & Inflation: Cause for Concern Over Retirement Income Policy, 1980, $7,00 (ISBN 0-86643-003-2) Volume//--Retirement Income Systems: Coverage & Characteristics, 1980, $12.00 (ISBN 0-86643-004-0) Volume lll--Providing Retirement Income Security: Social & Economic Considerations, 1980, $7.00 (ISBN 0-86643-005-9) Retirement Income Programs: Directions for Future Research, 1980, $5.00 (ISBN 0-86643-006-7) Retirement Income Policy: Considerations for Effective Decision Making, 1980, $5.00 (ISBN 0-86643-007-5) Modeling Analysis for Retirement Income Policy: Background & Overview, 1980, $10.00 (ISBN 0-86643-008-3) Should Pension Assets Be Managed for Social/Political Purposes?, 1980, $10.00 (ISBN 0-86643-001-6) Arranging the Pieces: The Retirement Income Puzzle, 1980, $10.00 (ISBN 0-86643-009-1 ) The Application of Modeling Techniques to Retirement Income Policy Issues, 1980, $10.00 (ISBN 0-86643-010-5) Pension Plan Termination Insurance: Does the Foreign Experience Have Relevance for the United States?, 1979, $10.00 (ISBN 0-86643-000-8) At their November 1!, !982 meeting, the National Commission on Soda! Security Reform agreed that the Sociai Security cash benefits programs have serious financing problems. The Commission determined that they should seek between $150 and SZ00 bison in Social Security revenue and benefit modifications for the period from 1983 through 1989. For the longterm, seventy-five-year period, the Commission agreed to seek adh.tstrnents equal to !.82 percent of projected covered eamin_. Potential pro_am adjustments that would produce the _ancJrv 8 necessary to meet both short-term and long-term goals have different implications for various groups and members of society. This report provides the details for an evaluation of the status of the United States ret_ernent income security system in general, and the Soc.ia/Security system in particular. The analysis particularly acldresses the scope and mathematics of the financin 8 imbalances of Social Security, several options for baiancing the system in both the short and long terms, and implications of various options for the income security of the elderly. The analy-Msgoes beyond Social Security alone, however, because other elements of the retirement income security system mod_ffy the implications of'various policy adjustments in the Social Security program. The story that the numbers throughout this book tel1 is that the future may not be so dismal as a narrow focus on Social Security's current fi_'tancing projections would suggest_ While no one can predict the future with great accuracy, some trends can be obsena_ and their outcomes predicted. The various trends analyzed throughout this book suggest that Social Security can adjust in the future to meet the needs of society. 19ZO N Street, NW/Suite 5Z0/Washington, DC 20036 ISBN 0-80643-O_-8 Price$15.00 i I