Bus Concession Contracts— Lessons from Bogota`s Transmilenio
Transcription
Bus Concession Contracts— Lessons from Bogota`s Transmilenio
Bus Concession Contracts— Lessons from Bogota’s Transmilenio & the Integrated Public Transit System (SITP) Camila Rodríguez Hernández World Bank, Transport & ICT Global Practice Agenda Basics of Tariff Policy & Lessons Learnt Contract Incentive Schemes in Bogota’s Transmilenio and SITP (citywide reform) Conclusions 2 Bogotá: Targeted Corridor—Transmilenio (2000) 3 Bogotá: Citywide Transformation—SITP (2012) 4 Photo Credit: EMBARQ 2010 Tariff Policy— Competitive Bidding to Identify Cost Recovery • “Cost Recovery” Principle Formula… Trunk Feeder Fare Collection Trust Agent BRT Agency • Where, each of these elements (except the public sector administrator costs) are bid out separately: Trunk & Feeder Fare Collection Trust Agent Local BRT Agency • Provides public transit services • Competitive bidding process for trunk and feeder services. • Automatic fare collection, centralized fleet control/programming • Competitive bidding process. • Manages system’s resources and pays different agents • Receives a percentage over total tariff (fare) sales • System planning and control • Fixed payment Tariff Policy— Technical Tariff & User Tariff “Indicative” Technical Tariff Fare Collection 6-13% Agency 4-11% Trust Agent <0.5% Trunk & Feeder 70-90% • From “Cost Recovery” Principle, a notional Technical Tariff is calculated to estimate the required average revenue per ticket sold that is needed to guarantee remuneration of all of the system’s service providers • User Tariff set close to Technical Tariff and determined by decree (Mayor of Bogotá). Tariff Policy— Lessons Learnt Composition of the Technical Tariff – Selected Colombian Cities Bogotá Bus Operators (1) Barranquilla Bucaramanga Cali Pereira 87.96% 68.6% 67.6% 68.0% 87.2% Fare Collection 8% 6.0% 13.5% 13.0% 9.1% BRT Agency 4% 7.0% 6.85% 7.0% 3.5% Bus Scrapping (2) -- 9.4% -- 3.0% -- Infrastructure -- 9.0% 11.75% 3.0% -- 0.04% N/A 0.03% N/A 0.2% Transport Authority -- -- 0.27% -- -- Contingency Fund -- -- -- 6.0% -- 100% 100.0% 100.0% 100% 100.0% Trust Agent Total (3) • Notion of ‘technical tariff’ as an important information to set user tariff • Ridership estimates are a key critical input in determining initial technical tariff • Bidding process that guarantees efficiency in costs, depends on the competitiveness of the bidding process • Tariff “scope creep”: more and more cost elements not directly related to operations have been loaded on the tariffs Source: World Bank (2014) Tariff Policy—Peak/Off Peak Pricing Ridership in Transmilenio before (May) and after (September) the Differential Pricing Scheme • • • Transmilenio implemented a differential tariff policy to deal with a crush level peak-load problem. But relatively inelastic demand brought in very small changes in either peaking patterns or total ridership. Due to contract design (payment scheme tied to IPK), the differential tariff has not generated further cost savings or operational efficiencies in Transmilenio (which could be transferred to end-users) Source: World Bank Study Tariff Policy— Bogota Targeted Subsidies for the Poor • Feb 2014 roll-out. Important step towards targeted subsidies instead of general sociodemographic subsidies (students, elderly, disabled, etc.) • Population registered in the National Poverty Targeting System (called SISBEN) with a score <40 points are eligible to receive a public transit subsidy equal to a 40% discounted fare capped at 21 trips per month. • To obtain the card, beneficiaries can register online or visit a city service center. Once their ID is validated against the SISBEN database, the beneficiary receives the smartcard in person at a city center in about three business days. 9 Source: Webpage explaining the transit subsidy for SISBEN 1 and 2 beneficiaries. http://www.sitp.gov.co/publicaciones/beneficios_de_transporte_para_personas_sisbenizadas_pub Length of Contract— Lessons Learnt Selected Bus Concession Contract Length Contract Bogota SITP Bogota Transmilenio (Phase1 & 2) Santiago (Trunk Operators) Cost/Km 24 10 (+additional 3) USD2,85/km USD 3,42/km 12 USD 2,5/km Santiago (Feeder) 5 -- London 8 -- Source: World Bank SITP Study (2013) • Key driver in determining length of contract, is the time it will take the operator to recoup investment (i.e. fleet) • Critical contract feature that determines the public sector’s ability to adjust, and move towards truly ‘competitive bidding’ process Payment Mechanism— Transmilenio Trunk Operator CTi Kmi Inputs included Cost/Km factor: • Fuel • Tires • Lubricants • Maintenance • Labor • Fixed Costs (Fleet, RoI) • Trunk operators paid on a Cost/Km logged basis (gross cost contract); cost factor covers both variable & fixed costs. • Caveat--For every km logged, trunk operator gets paid cost/km in full, irrespective of the fact that fixed costs may have been covered before termination of concession contract (i.e. higher fleet utilization rate). Payment Scheme— Demand Risk in Transmilenio Available Remuneration to Trunk Operators (Disp)/Total Trunk Cost (CT) vs. IPK • Initial TM contracts introduced demand risk in two ways: Trunk operators get paid “last” Inverse relationship between passenger per km index (IPK) and Technical Tariff: TT 1/ IPK • Note: Available Remuneration (Disp)= Revenue distributed to Trunk Operators once all other system agents are paid (Feeder, Fare Collection, Trust Agent, BRT Agency) • Source: World Bank Study Calculations (2013), based on Vasquez (2012). CTi Kmi C A Pas A CR PV PV (1 %F %G) However, contract terms set a floor (4.75) and a ceiling (currently 5.08). for IPK. If IPK is bellow floor, trunk operator assumes demand risk. If IPK is above ceiling, trunk operator captures increased demand windfalls. New contracts (F3) take out this clause, and introduce payment scheme based on Kms logged and fleet in operation. Payment Scheme— Bogota’s SITP(citywide reform) • Payment to TRUNK Operators… RT f (Q)Tronccal TMVT NoVehT / 4.3 OEKmTronc TKMT CFR KMStronc • Where: TMVT NoVehT OEKmTronc TKMT CFR KMStronc •Payment per vehicle in operation; represents ~ 30% total remuneration •Payment per km logged; represents ~ 70% total remuneration New trunk operator contracts include payment scheme on the basis of number of fleet in operation and cost/kms logged, and eliminates the IPK factor, largely to address the aforementioned challenges. Payment Scheme— Bogota’s SITP(citywide reform) • Payment to ZONAL Operators… f (Q) Zonal CVehi ,k Vehi ,k CKmi ,k Kmi ,k CPaxi Paxi k • Where: CVeh i ,k Vehi ,k •Payment per vehicle in operation; represents ~ 22% total remuneration CKm i ,k Kmi ,k •Payment per km logged; represents ~ 56% total remuneration CPaxi Paxi •Payment per passenger transported; represents ~ 22% total remuneration Initially TranSantiago’s operators received a remuneration per passenger carried (demand risk) that represented approx. 20% of total remuneration (similar to Bogota’s SITP); however, this had to increase up to 70% to actually align incentives and cater to demand. Penalty & Reward System— Bogota’s SITP(citywide reform) • Payment to Zonal Operators… f (Q) Zonal CVehi ,k Vehi ,k CKmi ,k Kmi ,k CPaxi Paxi k In the SITP, fines & penalties are largely determined by this factor: f Q Max(0.40 IR 0.60 IP ,0.97) • Since the revenue loss for the operator is negligible (at max 3%), the operator may be better off reducing operating costs by lowering service (regularity and punctuality), since their income is largely unaffected. • On the other hand, a penalty system that is too stringent (such as contract termination) is rarely a credible and enforceable threat for the operator The incentive structure should include credible, enforceable, and significant penalties and rewards that align desired service standards to operator’s performance. Conclusions • In terms of tariff policies, the experience in Colombia suggests that tariffs set at ” cost recovery” should be stripped down to the operating essentials, so as not to have the users pay for societal benefits. Furthermore, it becomes increasingly important, particularly after the initial stages of the reform, that each element or service competent included in the tariff is openly tendered to ensure efficiency. • As there are steep learning curves in the initial years of the reforms, it becomes critical that contractual terms are not unreasonably long, so that subsequent phases can incorporate the lessons learnt and are truly opened up to competition. • In terms of incentive structures in bus concession contracts, the experience has noted that different reforms calls for different demand risk uptake from operators, and different payment & reward mechanisms. 16