Criterion Vol 4 No 4.indd
Transcription
Criterion Vol 4 No 4.indd
Publisher S. Iftikhar Murshed Director Finance Ismet Murshed Editor-in-Chief S. Mushfiq Murshed Business Development Manager S. Rashed Manzur Executive Advisers S. Mashkoor Murshed Riaz Khokhar Aziz Ahmad Khan Faizullah Khilji Dr. Tariq Hassan Cover Design by Fariha Rashed Printers Lawyersown Press 28, Alfalah Askaria Plaza, Committee Chowk, Rawalpindi. Editors Talat Farooq (Executive) Iffat Rashed Contact Editor The Criterion House 16, Street 15, F-6/3, Islamabad Tel: +92-51-2822659 Fax: +92-51-2822689 www.criterionpk.com ‘Criterion’ is a quarterly magazine which aims at producing well researched articles for a discerning readership. The editorial board is neutral in its stance. The opinions expressed are those of the writers. Contributions are edited for reasons of style or clarity. Great care is taken that such editing does not affect the theme of the article or cramp its style. Quotations from the magazine can be made by any publisher as long as they are properly acknowledged. We would also appreciate if we are informed. Subscription: Pakistan Rs. 200 per Issue or Rs. 800 for Annual Subscription (Inclusive of Postage) Overseas US $ 20 per Issue or US $ 80 for Annual Subscription (Inclusive of Postage) Price: Rs 200 US $ 20 Winter Issue Spring Issue Summer Issue Autumn Issue Criterion July/September 2009 Volume 4, Number 3 Terrorism and the Blasphemy Laws of Pakistan Editorial 3 Notes on the Financial Crisis, Global Faizullah Khilji Imbalances, Recovery and the East Asian Response: What We Know and What We Do Not Know 8 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 Internal Security Challenges for Pakistan A.G. Noorani 49 S. Iftikhar Murshed 86 Shahwar Junaid 133 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan Niloufer Siddiqui 149 Institutional Role Behind Civil-Military Equation Muhammad Ismail Khan 186 Essays A Strategy to Fight Militancy? Cyril Almeida 211 Between Dreams and Realities Iqbal Ahmad Khan 222 Cooperative Mechanism to Save Kashmir Environment and Water Wars The Price of ‘Sea Blindness’ Iftikhar Gilani 228 Muhammad Azam Khan 242 Editorial TERRORISM AND THE BLASPHEMY LAWS OF PAKISTAN “Oh Liberty, what crimes are committed under thy name,” exclaimed Madame Marie-Jeanne Roland as she mounted the platform to be guillotined during the Reign of Terror at the height of the French Revolution. More than two hundred years later, a similar reign of terror but this time in the name of religion was unleashed, particularly against the minorities of Pakistan, under the blasphemy laws introduced by General Zia-ul-Haq. In 1982 Section 295 B was added to the Penal Code prescribing life imprisonment for “defiling the Holy Qur’an” and in 1986 Section 295 C was incorporated mandating the death penalty for the “use of derogatory language in respect of the Holy Prophet.” Blasphemy laws have existed in the statute books of British India since 1860 and in 1927 Section 295 was included to deal with “deliberate and malicious acts intended to outrage religious feelings of any class by insulting its religion or religious belief.” Thus the law was nondiscriminatory and designed to protect equally all faiths. Furthermore, conviction depended exclusively on proof that the accused had deliberately injured or insulted another individual’s religious feelings. This was the law that prevailed in Pakistan during the first forty years of its existence and there was relative inter-faith harmony till the 1980s. Zia-ul-Haq’s blasphemy laws are vaguely formulated and cater only to the sensibilities of Muslims. Even worse, they have been arbitrarily enforced. After its meeting in Geneva from 26 August to 2 September 2009, the World Council of Churches issued a statement which noted that Editorial “on the testimony of a complainant, a person charged with blasphemy is immediately placed in detention. The penalty includes a mandatory death sentence for defaming the Prophet Mohammed and life sentence for desecrating the Holy Qur’an. Under the provisions of the present law, conviction is made possible without proof of deliberate attempt on the part of the accused. This is a violation of the fundamental rights guaranteed by the constitution of Pakistan.” Edmund Burke believed that bad laws are the worst form of tyranny and this has been vividly demonstrated by the blasphemy laws of Pakistan. Though 50 percent of the victims have been Muslims, it is the impoverished and under-privileged Christian minority, constituting a little more than 1 percent of the population, which has faced the brunt of the fanatical cleric-instigated violence. They have undergone imprisonment on frivolous unproven accusations, many have been killed and some even been burnt alive. Their homes have been razed to the ground, their places of worship destroyed, their sacred scriptures desecrated through an endless night of terror. So intense has this persecution been that in desperation the Reverend John Joseph, the first Roman Catholic bishop from the Punjab, shot himself to death in a Sahiwal court on 6 May 1998. A few years earlier he had kissed the feet of a murdered Christian during the latter’s funeral and swore that his would be the next death because of the blasphemy laws. Eleven years after Bishop John Joseph took his own life, a 22year-old Christian, Fanish (Robert) Masih, was imprisoned in Sialkot for allegedly desecrating the Holy Qur’an. He was kept in solitary confinement even though it had been established that the charges against him were fabricated. He hanged himself in his cell on 15 September 2009. Though innocent civilians have been ruthlessly killed in blasphemyrelated mob hysteria as in the Gojra outrage of 30 July 2009 and also in cold-blooded pre-meditated violence, the two suicides poignantly demonstrate the loss of all hope. In the first, a learned man of the frock, 4 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Editorial who had taught his flock that all life was sacred, ended his own in the hope that this supreme sacrifice would rekindle the conscience of those in power and spur them to rescind the infamous blasphemy laws. In the second, a terrorized poverty-stricken youth had convinced himself that he could not escape the gallows for a crime he had never committed. Justice cannot prevail if judges are intimidated and fear for their lives. In an editorial after Fanish Masih’s death, the Daily Times of Lahore recalled that a few months earlier hundreds of clerics wreaked havoc in a court after the judge had granted bail to a Christian couple who had been sent to prison for merely possessing a Qur’an. The accusation against them was that they had defiled the scripture because they were unclean as a community. Their plea that they had kept the holy book in their home out of respect for its teachings fell on deaf ears. They were subsequently charged with blasphemy but this did not deter the mob from ransacking the court. The few judges who dared to oppose the tidal-wave of fanaticism became its victims. On 19 October 1997, Justice Arif Iqbal Hussain Bhatti was gunned down in his office in Lahore because in 1995 he had acquitted two Christian brothers accused of defaming the Prophet. So intense and immediate was the clerical reaction to the ruling that the brothers had to be smuggled out of the country and sent to Germany. The police did nothing to protect Justice Bhatti though they were aware that he had been receiving threatening letters from extremists who were so convinced about the righteousness of their cause that they had no hesitation in disclosing their identities and contact particulars. In several instances the law enforcement authorities not only abetted but also participated in the violence which they regarded as retributive justice for insulting the Prophet or desecrating the Qur’an. In 1997 a frenzied mob of 20,000 which included 500 policemen went on the rampage in the Shantinagar-Tibbi Christian colony following reports about defiling the Qur’an. On 24 May 2004 a police constable bludgeoned Samuel Masih to death as the latter had been accused of spitting on a mosque wall. The CRITERION – October/December 2009 5 Editorial policeman had no qualms of conscience, no sense of guilt, no remorse. He said that as a Muslim it was his duty to kill Masih. This cannot be brushed aside as an aberration or as the outpourings of a demented, semiliterate mind because the contagion of religious extremism has spread to all levels of society. The constable was probably aware that barely four years earlier none other than a judge of the Lahore High Court, Justice Nazir Akhtar, had publicly declared that blasphemers should be killed on the spot. Since the introduction of the blasphemy laws in the 1980s, the senseless slaughter of ordinary citizens, vandalism, arson and the destruction of churches - all brewed from an alarmingly fascist religious narrative - keep recurring with startling frequency. The symbiotic relationship between religion-motivated extremist violence and terrorism is obvious. The 30 July 2009 carnage in Gojra was the work of the banned anti-Shiia terrorist outfit Sipah-e-Sahaba and with each such incident the authority of the state is being progressively subverted. The Federally Administered Tribal Areas (FATA) of Pakistan is no longer the exclusive breeding ground for terrorist outfits. Southern Punjab, the home of the Sipah-e-Sahaba and its offshoot the Lashkar-eJhangvi as well as other extremist groups notably the Jaish-e-Mohammad, shares that distinction with FATA. The seminaries in south Punjab, sponsored by these and other groups, churn out ideologically motivated diehards who have been responsible for sectarian killings, the slaughter of minorities and Muslims alike on concocted allegations of blasphemy as well as many of the most dramatic terrorist attacks in recent years. The Lashkar-e-Jhangvi has not only earned a fearsome reputation as Al Qaeda’s foot soldiers in Pakistan but is also acquiring a global jihadist agenda. The hackneyed refrain that Pakistan does not tire of reiterating ad nauseam in every international forum is that it condemns terrorism “in all its forms and manifestations.” However it has still not come to terms with the reality that violence against innocent civilians in the name of religion is one of these “forms” of terrorism which the government professes to staunchly oppose. Al Qaeda, the Taliban of FATA and 6 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Editorial the extremist groups of southern Punjab are mutually supportive and collectively constitute a triangle of terror that has been responsible for more than eight thousand deaths in the last one year. Indoctrinated youths from the madrassahs of the Punjab are trained to become suicide bombers in the tribal belt under the tutelage of Al Qaeda. The nexus between blasphemy-related violence and the recurring incidents of terrorism is obvious. The ideological motivation is a distorted interpretation of religion. So long as the blasphemy laws remain in the statute books, vigilante death squads and terrorist groups like the Sipahe-Sahaba will not be deterred from their criminal activities. It is a shame that successive governments after the death of Zia-ulHaq in 1988 have done nothing to repeal this law which is repugnant to Islam. The Qur’an does not prescribe punishment for blasphemy which, like apostasy, though a grievous sin will be punished only in the hereafter. The worldly punishments specified in the Holy Scripture are for crimes against society not for sins against God. The nineteenth century reformer Jamal ad-Din Afghani observed, “Every Muslim is sick, and the only remedy is the Qur’an.” Till the true teachings of the Qur’an are clearly understood, obscurantist clerics will continue to preach hatred and violence in the name of religion. There can scarcely be a greater blasphemy. CRITERION – October/December 2009 7 NOTES ON THE FINANCIAL CRISIS, GLOBAL IMBALANCES, RECOVERY AND THE EAST ASIAN RESPONSE: WHAT WE KNOW AND WHAT WE DO NOT KNOW Faizullah Khilji1* Abstract. These notes are an attempt to lay out what we know and what we do not know about the financial crisis, global imbalances, the “recovery”, and how the East Asian response to the crisis is shaping up. We begin with a brief recapitulation of events, and then consider the mechanics of the crisis, and in that context, consider the concerns relating to global imbalances. A discussion of how this crisis might unwind follows. The present financial crisis occurred chiefly in the United States and the United Kingdom, New York and London, but soon enough the impact of these developments was being felt in other financial centres of the developed market economies. East Asia though faced the crisis from a different perspective and with somewhat different concerns: chiefly as an exporter to the developed market economies where demand was slowing down on account of the crisis, and as a major investor in dollar and dollar denominated securities. We briefly consider the East Asian response. In particular we consider the proposition that there may be informal arrangements being improvised by the East Asians to solve issues in real time. * Faizullah Khilji is a former Chairman of the Tariff Commission of Pakistan. Email fkhilji@ gmail.com Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... The man walking slowly by my side is haunted by something more than the uninterrupted revolution; by a gigantic conception of which neither of us has spoken …Three hundred years of European energy are now on the wane; the Chinese era is dawning… Behind our entire conversation the hope of a twilight world stood watch. Andre Malraux, 19672 Introduction “How could this happen?” begins the recent Bank of International Settlements (BIS) annual report,3 which seems to date the onset of the crisis from August 2007 when, in its words, the interbank market was “disrupted”, i.e., the beginning of the credit crunch.4 The BIS though is not alone in expressing a loss of understanding. The Queen of England, a well informed person briefed weekly by the British Prime Minister and with enviable access to other equally well informed persons including heads of state, asked of a London School of Economics professor of management “If these things were so large, how come everyone missed them?”5 And Professor Garicano of LSE too was in good company in his inability to offer a satisfactory explanation to his monarch about the limitations of economists: Alan Greenspan had earlier expressed his inability to comprehend both the nature of financial engineering as well as to regulate the markets because the two phenomena surpassed his understanding.6 Indeed that venerable spokesman for the “financial times” that we reportedly live in, did tell us that “unfettered finance” was “fast reshaping the global economy”. But our concerns were allayed because it had “proved possible to tame domestic finance in the US”; the “emerging economies” though, lacking in the sophistication found in US financial system, needed to “manage their involvement with the global financial system cautiously”; that is where there was something to really worry about, and naturally so!7 These notes are an attempt to lay out what we know and what we do not know about the financial crisis, global imbalances, the “recovery”, and, finally, how the East Asian response is shaping up. We begin with a brief recapitulation of the widely known chronology of events, and then consider the mechanics of the crisis, and in that context, the CRITERION – October/December 2009 9 Faizullah Khilji issue of global imbalances, which of course has further ramifications. A discussion of what lies ahead for the world economy, and how this crisis might unwind follows. It is an important aspect of the present financial crisis that it occurred chiefly in the United States and the United Kingdom, New York and London. Soon enough though the impact of developments in New York and London was being felt in other financial centres of the developed market economies. East Asia though faced the crisis from a different perspective, the perspective of a region which had methodically prepared itself to cope with any repeat of the Asian crisis of 1998. And East Asia faced the new crisis also with somewhat different concerns: chiefly as an exporter to the developed market economies where demand was slowing down on account of the crisis, and as a major investor in dollar and dollar denominated securities; a currency which surely looked like losing some of its sheen, if not some of its credibility. We briefly consider the emerging East Asian response. In particular we consider the proposition that the institutions of international economic relations may have lagged in their ability to cope with developments, and that there may be informal arrangements being improvised by the East Asians to solve real issues in real time. Chronology of events8 It was in the summer of 2007 that sustained reporting on what was then seen as the emerging “sub-prime” problem began to appear in the press. Interest rates had risen and defaults were expected on some home loans as a result. On the face of it this did not seem to be an alarming development to a lay observer as some loans do go bad whenever interest rates rise, and also because not much change was evident in the behaviour of the banks to suggest any impending crisis. The term “sub-prime” was not until then understood sufficiently well outside the banking community: the term “sub-prime”, it turned out, broadly means a loan made without much scrutiny because serious scrutiny would not justify lending. Thus the gravity of the situation did not quite filter through to the public for some time, even though some of the news reports did mention that the mortgage defaults were sending ripples through the financial system. 10 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... Public policy in the United States had contributed to the growth in housing ownership. House ownership was seen as helpful in enlarging the “Republican tent”, i.e., vote bank, and it also reportedly furthered the business interests of major donors to the Republican party.9 The first unmistakable signs of a definite turn in the public confidence and that we might be living through extraordinary times came in September 2007 with queues forming outside Northern Rock, a United Kingdom home loan mortgage institution turned bank. It had been well over a hundred years since something like this had been seen in Britain.10 For the British, this was a live example of the oft mentioned but never seen (by any living soul) textbook case of a run on the bank. By Autumn of 2007, a deepening of the crisis was quite visible with Fed sharply reducing interest rates as bank after bank in the United States announced losses, and attributed these to “sub-prime” loans gone bad. By January 2008 the stock market movements reflected the depth of the crisis: the NYSE dutifully crashed. Later that year in March, Bear Stearns, one of the institutions that defined success on Wall St, imploded like those old buildings that look so formidable and then suddenly disappear in a puff of dust.11 In July 2008 Fed and Treasury, in a move that could only be anathema to the very spirit of the United States, nationalised the two well known home loan institutions, i.e., Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac; the word nationalisation was never mentioned, and, indeed, there was, some felt, a sense of pathos and sad irony on seeing the Treasury Secretary, Hank Paulson, make the announcements: this ex head of Goldman Sachs - for Wall St provides both the market makers and the regulators to regulate the market makers, hence setting up a situation where it is both judge and jury in its own cases – saying that the Treasury would backstop the two institutions then on the brink of bankruptcy.12 By the summer of 2008 the credit crunch was a full one year old as far as newspaper reporting went, but a belief also began to shape up that the measures taken by the central banks and the governments had largely contained the crisis. There was nothing in living memory to suggest that this was only a pit stop for what Alan Greenspan was to subsequently refer to as the financial tsunami. CRITERION – October/December 2009 11 Faizullah Khilji It was against this backdrop in September 2008 that the Fed and the Treasury decided to selectively apply their belief in the rationality and efficiency of market outcomes: it was judged best in the public interest not to bail out Lehman Brothers, a pillar of Wall St but also a noted rival of Goldman Sachs. Lehman Brothers duly collapsed forthwith, (as indeed would have any other bank in the United States that fateful day if the government had publicly withheld support), and with this collapse public confidence in the financial system went in to a free fall.13 The public obviously did not share the authorities’ faith that the markets were working for the best. For the public, collapse of Lehman Brothers was tantamount to Wall St, the very citadel of capitalism, coming apart. The crisis had turned into a global meltdown, nothing less. With the total collapse of public confidence in the financial system staring in the face, Treasury and Fed worked non-stop to launch bail out plans. But the Congress approved the bailouts only rather reluctantly, (for many in Congress too have great faith in the “magic of the market” whilst others in Congress saw these plans as handouts of “taxpayers money” to bankers), and only after President George W Bush talked at them with his usual rough-hewn man-of-authority turn of phrase: “this sucker could go down”!14 A stock market crash, greater in relative intensity than 1929, followed. The autumn and winter of 2008 witnessed the design and implementation of rescue and stimulus plans. Bank after bank was being rescued through an infusion of equity capital as well as through extension of loans at near zero rates, debt service burdens were being reduced through lowering of interest rates, and the economy was being boosted directly through policies that increased public expenditure. By December 2008 US interest rates had fallen to between zero and 0.5 percent. Interest rates in the UK were approaching zero by March 2009. Nonetheless, as 2009 unfolded, the public saw unemployment and bankruptcies going up. The mechanics of the crisis The alleged causes of this financial crisis were diverse. Press reports initially referred to greed and dishonesty as causes, perhaps because 12 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... these two “capabilities” are easily understood by the average reporter as well as the general public; but both these factors are also an intrinsic part of the human condition, and that is why we have regulators and watchdogs. Another alleged cause was inadequate regulation,15 and that goes to the heart of the philosophy that guides present day economic policy in market economies. Some argued that the problem had its source in ”global imbalances”. And others attributed the difficulties to “complexity” of financial engineering, and markets, use of mathematics “too difficult to understand”, etc. No one though attributed the crisis to the incompetence of the bankers, or accused them of getting involved in matters way beyond their competence. The story properly begins with the concepts and principles that guided the market makers and players as well as the regulators. The underlying economic concepts The conceptual framework under which the finance sector operates goes by the rubric of “efficient market hypothesis”, EMH for short. The essence of EMH is captured in the definition attributed by the Economist to Eugene Fama, of the University of Chicago, “that the price of a financial asset reflects all available information that is relevant to its value”.16 The far reaching implications of EMH are that markets would always price financial assets correctly. If the price of a share seemed low, investors (well-informed by definition) would buy it forthwith to their profit. If it looked too high, they could sell it and again end up making money. It also followed that bubbles could not form, as these would be immediately perceived by investors who would profitably prick them. Trying to beat the market was therefore futile, and, importantly, regulation was by and large superfluous.17 As the EMH did not admit of bubbles building up, it is not much help in explaining or understanding the crisis, and in an EMH world any crisis therefore must logically be on account of interference in the markets by the authorities. This sounds (and is) too simplistic, reflecting only an insistence on viewing developments through the prism of EMH; but a more plausible, albeit “non-standard”, explanation owed chiefly to Hyman Minsky goes something like the following.18 CRITERION – October/December 2009 13 Faizullah Khilji The post 9/11 part of Alan Greenspan’s stewardship at the Fed was a time when the economy was in a situation of low interest rates and experiencing good returns on equity. Banks were awash with funds.19 It follows that firms and individuals with relatively higher proportion of debt were earning relatively higher returns because of low interest rates. The advantage of contracting increasing amounts of debt to enhance the return on equity was evident. “Financial engineering” by devising instruments such as the CDOs and CDSs gave a boost to the process: CDOs by further lowering the perception of risk, and the CDSs by enabling an increase in leverage and hence increasing the funds available for investment in housing and elsewhere.20 It is worth digressing briefly to see as to how CDOs and CDSs worked to reduce, or spread, or transfer the risk element underlying a loan. The CDO instrument, a collaterised debt obligation, bundled together different loans into one package (which could be sold in parts or as a whole). By bundling together loans that were in principle uncorrelated, the risk of any one default was reduced as it was spread over the larger bundle of loans, and as all loans (being uncorrelated) were most unlikely to default at the same time. Once this logic was accepted, it was a small step to use the CDO “technology” to rationalise extending credit to persons with a poor or no credit history, i.e., the “sub-prime” loan. The other instrument was the CDS, the credit default swap. This CDS made it possible for the bank to transfer the risk attaching to a loan or other asset either by paying someone to carry the risk, or by insuring against the risk of default, whilst retaining the loan as well as its income stream. The implication was that if the risk attaching to default was transferred, then the capital that the regulator required of the bank to keep as a reserve against the loan had been freed and could be “re-used” for advancing more loans. In the event the regulators found the proposition in keeping with “markets know best” concept, and hence acceptable. And those among the regulators who did not quite see it like this were shown the door.21 The result was two-fold. Firstly, insurers such as the AIG insured the risk of default and thus took on huge risks even though this particular insurer had no previous experience of such business! Just the lure of profit was enough: the premiums were 14 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... trivial but the immensity of the volume of business raked in a large income. And insurers did not face the capital reserve requirements that were reining in the banks. Secondly, as a bank transferred the risk but retained the loan, the loans made by a bank kept growing as a factor of that bank’s capital and leverage shot up. At the time the crisis became evident, these leverage ratios for the main investment banks had reached levels associated with hedge funds!22 The lowered perception of risk encouraged optimism about returns on proposed projects, and this caused the value of assets to increase.23 The bubble It is important to remember that one of the defining characteristics of the market economy in the present context is the relentless pursuit of profits.24 In the circumstances therefore it is clearly advantageous to contract higher debt at the prevailing low rate of interest so as to increase the returns.25 Firms and individuals were therefore motivated to undertake riskier projects and ventures, and to contract more debt to enable them to do so. The decline in risk aversion set of an increase in the volume of investments being undertaken. As investment volume increased, there was a consequent increase in asset prices. Rising asset prices raised the prospect of capital gain, encouraged yet more investment, and speculative behaviour gained strength. Finance was increasingly sought from the banks to fund investments and asset purchases. The banks were very willingly forthcoming with loans as they shared the general optimism of the borrowers regarding rising asset values and potential capital gains. All these forces worked themselves out to increase home loans in the US economy, and indeed elsewhere too. The housing industry experienced a boom of such extraordinary dimensions that houses were being built even though demographic and other data showed that there would be no demand as far as one could see for these units for habitation purposes.26 This is also the euphoric moment in Minsky’s formulation. Lenders as well as borrowers feel that the future is assured. In the build up to the CRITERION – October/December 2009 15 Faizullah Khilji present crisis the regulator too felt that the future was assured and the economy and its financial sector had shifted to a new trajectory, where risk had been correctly priced so that the system worked safely.27 In this situation, which is characterized by rising asset prices and high investor excitement, a particularly risky type of investor appears. This investor trades on a market where asset prices are rising sharply, and in the process incurs substantial debt, in the widely shared expectation that expected capital appreciation on the assets far exceeds the servicing costs of the debt, even though these costs are well in excess of the net cash inflows of the business. The first round consequences of this act include pushing up asset prices to yet higher levels, pushing up the demand for credit yet another notch, and consequently maintaining the upward momentum in the rate of interest, and thus increasing the fragility of the system to any reversal in the growth of asset values. This configuration of events is referred to as a Ponzi scheme, and the investor is referred to as Ponzi financier, in deference to one of the better known practitioners of this particular art form.28 Liquidity though tightens as the indebtedness of the economy, and its debt / equity ratios (i.e., leverage) increase. As growth in credit accelerates, ceteris paribus, the ratio of interest payments to profits also rises. Highly liquid but relatively low yield financial instruments such as bonds fall in price; in response, the purveyors of these instruments raise interest rates to help them compete better for investor funds. Thus the interest rates in the market rise, without any intervention on the part of the authorities. With increasing leverage and interest rates also moving upwards, a situation of tight liquidity develops and the vulnerability of the business and the economy to any further upward shifts in credit, leverage or the rate of interest increases dramatically. But the increase in borrowing to invest in assets continues even at higher interest rates, as long as the expected returns from investment significantly exceed the cost of such borrowing. With time this dynamics of high interest rates combined with high 16 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... leverage begins to tell. The upward drive of credit and asset prices falters, and these stumbles render sound business speculative,29 speculative business begins to resemble a Ponzi scheme, and the Ponzi financier needs to sell assets immediately to cover the current debt service, as perhaps do others. The asset sales prick the asset price bubble and the prices of assets come under pressure to move down. With a downward move in asset prices, investors other than the Ponzi financier also wish to sell. If an investor is levered up, even modest market movements can force a sale in a hurry to stop losses becoming catastrophic. The Ponzi financiers find themselves with assets that can only be sold at a loss, and levels of debt that simply cannot be serviced. Banks find that customers cannot pay back the loans, and this prospect of losses causes the banks to further jack up the interest rates. Credit becomes dearer, liquidity in the system tightens, and this squeeze, combined with the continuing need for funds, further intensifies the need to offload assets, specially the illiquid ones. The asset market is flooded with sellers. A state of panic exists. The boom is fast turning into a slump. The credit crunch The credit crunch in the present crisis was characterized first and foremost by the extreme reluctance of the banks to lend to each other, and even overnight loans disappeared. This reluctance was arguably owed to the likelihood that the banks simply did not trust each other’s valuation of assets as the crisis unfolded.30 They did not trust one another’s valuations because the assets in question were the CDOs and products derived from the CDOs. The credibility of these assets, (which caught the label toxic), suffered on two counts. Firstly, these assets were derived from “sub-prime” mortgages in whole or part, and in the light of day “sub-prime” loans were finally recognised for what they always were: loans advanced to a punter (often with no income or assets or a job) gambling on a continuing increase in the price of the house (the underlying collateral). And, secondly, CDOs were bought and sold by banks, not individuals. CRITERION – October/December 2009 17 Faizullah Khilji The prices at which these transactions occurred were kept private, known only to the transacting parties. The assets were never publicly traded and their prices were not a public fact.31 It was therefore impossible to judge whether the CDO transactions met some market criteria. Frequently, the extent of SPV or SIV operations was also not disclosed by the investing bank in its balance sheet.32 Hence, in a situation of a crisis when there was no evident demand for CDOs, one could not realistically attribute a market value to them. And if the assets of a bank were a mystery at best and worthless at the other extreme, how could one lend money to such an entity. Eventually, the fair value accounting or the mark to market condition, a requirement with the consequence that a bank acknowledge and therefore write off the implicit losses on the assets it owns, was relaxed.33 Even though the continued application of this rule would show the banks to be in a far worse situation than is now being reported, and the crisis to be far more grave, the dangers of this relaxation are only obvious and have been noted.34 The carry trade There was at least one other factor deepening the crisis as it unfolded. The ease of flow of capital and investments across national borders that characterises the world increases the scope and range of any developments in the markets, making them increasingly interlinked. Such free flow of capital combines with instantaneous flow of information, and enables the markets to respond to policy and other developments almost immediately, arbitraging in the process between the differences in applicable prices or regulations such as might obtain in different countries. An “investor” capable of profiting from these differences is always lurking on the scene. In this context, one set of developments (that are quite apart from the developments related to the asset bubble that originated with the United States non-banking financial sector, but have added to the gravity of what followed) is the “carry trade” issue. “Carry trade” involves borrowing in a low interest currency regime and investing in a high interest currency regime. In the present situation such traders were borrowing in Japanese yen to invest in New Zealand, Iceland and Hungary in particular. Investing borrowed money in a different currency 18 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... exposes the borrower-investor to foreign exchange risk, and the critical assumption is that any exchange rate variation would not wipe out the gains. The unexpected appreciation of the Japanese yen, chiefly reflecting a flight to safety once the crisis set in, turned the tables on this trade, and traders moved out of Hungary, Iceland and New Zealand currencies very very fast so as to meet their yen liabilities and hence limit their yen losses. Problems naturally ensued for Hungary, Iceland and New Zealand banking systems (and consequentially economies), as capital outflows accelerated. Even Iceland with its traditional remoteness from the news made the front page repeatedly at one point. Thus there were elements unrelated to the CDO and CDS developments, particularly on the foreign exchange markets, that furthered the sense of financial fragility and crisis, but these constituted only a sideshow in the larger scenario. Profits and bonuses The combination of high leverage with low interest rates and lowered perceptions of risk made possible the unusually high profits for the banks as well as others in the financial sector. Profits were booked even when the underlying assets could not be sold because there was no market for them. This was done through applying mathematical formulas.35 These formulas were fraught with unrealistic assumptions inherent to the EMH world. But high profits attract negative attention, and one approach adopted to lower the profile of these profits was to jack up costs. The easiest of the costs to jack up were the salaries and bonuses; the share of salaries and bonuses for the finance sector in the national economy has shot up over the years.36 The profits, as has been widely reported, reached new heights, and even after meeting these higher salary and bonus costs, the profits in the finance sector significantly increased their share in national income!37 Global imbalances Background “Global imbalances” is often mentioned as an answer to why the banks were flooded with funds. But the label global imbalances CRITERION – October/December 2009 19 Faizullah Khilji covers a range of narratives, old as well as new, and the issue of global imbalances may well be at the heart of the continuing problems with the international monetary system, including the financial crises that we see from time to time. The history here though is not the simple kind, i.e., the kind that repeats itself in varying forms, or even the kind where historians repeat each other. Indeed, part of the problem is that we do not have enough history; and, even where we have history, perhaps it has not been studied carefully enough. There are two basic issues, and these have been with us at least since the gold standard was abandoned. The first issue is that of the nature of a world currency. Ideally a world currency should be a super sovereign and stable unit, and not subject to vicissitudes of a national economy and its policies. A stable super sovereign unit imposes a certain monetary and fiscal discipline on national policies. The second issue is a consequential one. Some economies save relatively more than others whilst some other economies are not able or willing to save very much. Yet others are more inclined to spend against future income, i.e., dis-save for the present and perhaps also dis-save for the foreseeable time horizon. Given that the world economy is a closed system (i.e., expenditure by one country in excess of its income must be balanced by savings of another country), those who save lend to those who dissave on a world scale, and these balances are reflected in trade and capital flows. The existence of a super sovereign world currency would impose a certain discipline on these balances. In the absence of such a currency, the balances are held in dollars by default (and these balances are variously described as “global imbalances”, “savings glut”, and in an earlier era, the 1960s, as the “dollar glut”), and this aspect gives rise to all the concerns that relate to United States economic policy as well as behaviour. Even as the Bretton Woods system was being contemplated, the issue of policies that would impose adjustment on a country that was in external surplus for long periods was on the table along with proposals to counter such an eventuality (the scarce currency clause). The surplus country at the time was the United States, which also then accounted for half the world economy. The United States as the surplus country 20 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... was not willing to accept potential constraints on its monetary conduct, and the rest of the world had neither the will nor the authority to include such conditions in the IMF articles. Preparations for the Bretton Woods conference also included discussion on a super sovereign international currency unit defined in terms of a bundle of commodities, which could in principle be used for reserves as well as to settle international balances, i.e., the Bancor.38 But such a currency too would have constrained national policy, and was not in keeping with the spirit of the times, being inconvenient for the United States. What finally emerged from the Bretton Woods deliberations was the gold-dollar standard. Countries would peg their currencies to the dollar, and the dollar would have a stable value in relation to gold. With two-thirds of the world’s gold in the coffers of Fort Knox,39 the United States undertook to convert dollars held in official accounts into gold on demand. The dilemma in due course of time for countries holding dollars was that if a demand was indeed made for gold, and a sufficient supply of gold was not forthcoming from the United States, then the dollar might well be devalued against gold.40 But a demand for gold leading to a devaluation of the dollar would mean a loss in gold value of reserves held in dollars, and could thus be counterproductive. In any event “gentlemen” were clearly not expected to make such demands for converting their official dollars into gold.41 Alas, the concept of a gentleman made little sense in a republic founded on the creed: Liberté, Égalité, Fraternité. President Johnson’s preference for financing the Vietnam war through printing dollars rather than raising taxes or curtailing expenditure brought matters to a head with France.42 President Charles de Gaulle, advised by Jacques Rueff, saw the dollar-gold system as a sort of expropriation of his country’s business firms and as exposing him to the charge of financing the United States war in Vietnam, financing United States assistance to Chiang Kai-Shek, financing the ill fated US intervention in the Dominican Republic, etc.43 Thus there were picturesque moments in 1971 when a French battleship lifted anchor off New York with gold from Fort Knox in exchange for the paper dollars in its hold. The French demand to exchange what they saw as paper IOUs for gold had indeed been honoured by the United CRITERION – October/December 2009 21 Faizullah Khilji States.44 But in the wake of this battleship, the world witnessed a turning point in the international monetary system: President Nixon announced the de-linking of the dollar from its gold peg, the world went on to a new paper dollar international monetary regime, and the United States entered an era of continuing external deficits and mounting accumulation of dollars overseas. “Global imbalances” had arrived, but in a time when the United States Treasury Secretary John Connolly could still credibly say to the Europeans who were holding the dollars: the dollar is our currency but your problem.45 The situation now Today it is no longer just the Europeans who are holding the dollars. A number of countries have been following export-led growth policies. This is not a particularly novel development, and such policies are frequently attributed to successful East Asian economies, beginning with Japan, then Hong Kong, Korea, Singapore and Taiwan, and more recently to China among others. In addition, Germany too continues to be the major net exporter. As a result of such export orientation of the economies, receipts for exports well exceed payments for imports, leading to surplus in the balance of payments. Equally, exporters of natural resources, chiefly oil, also generate trade and balance of payments surpluses. These balance of payments surpluses, in turn, add to reserves, and a substantial build up of reserves thus comes about over a period of time.46 These piles of reserves do not yield any income unless invested. One relatively secure investment is the United States government debt, also referred to as United States Treasury Bonds. Purchase of these bonds raises the price of these bonds, and hence lowers the interest rate in the United States economy. These purchases of United States Treasury Bonds by the surplus economies thus inject additional liquidity into the United States economy. It is in this manner that the overseas trade and balance of payments surpluses facilitate credit in the United States, and as the influx of funds lowers the rate of interest, it is argued that credit at low rates of interest is facilitated. The argument though short circuits logic at this point and attributes the surfeit of lending by the bank to these deposits. It is a strange argument: just because money has been deposited in a bank, it is not reason enough for the banks to lend it 22 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... out to borrowers with no jobs, no incomes, and no assets! The bank is expected to hold the deposits in trust. Thus a good part of what the United States pays for its imports is voluntarily handed back to the United States as a loan at relatively low rates of interest, making it possible for the United States to acquire yet more goods and services with the same funds. One might surmise that the United States would not be unhappy with living beyond its means in this manner, and therefore has little reason to tinker around with an international monetary system that works so well to its advantage. Indeed, the fact that this phenomenon has endured for so long is some testimony to the likelihood that these arrangements must suit all involved politically, if not in terms of finance and economics. In his time Jacques Rueff had summed up the “system” and its advantages quite admirably in simple prose that is difficult to match in its brevity and effect.47 A positive adjustment out of this for the United States would be one of high and sustained growth that increasingly diminishes the debt and creates confidence in the economic performance of the United States. In such an eventuality, the dollar may quite naturally acquire even greater authority as a world currency. But if the United States were to continue on the present path, the question whether a country could go on borrowing year after year and pile up debt with no suggestion as to how these sums are to be eventually settled would be pursued with increasing vigour, and, also, as the share of the United States in the world economy shrinks, with increasing relevance. It is important to remember that this is no longer simply a matter of getting the arithmetic right. These imbalances represent deeply ingrained lifestyles. Forcing a change of lifestyle towards a lot more frugality has political consequences as well as implications for trade policy and openness. Given the size of the United States economy, its engagements with respect to a global socio-economic agenda as well as a global security agenda imply that the world would be greatly affected by any developments involving curtailment of expenditure in the United States. Indeed, the big question is whether the required discipline can be imposed; can it be done at all. Jacques Rueff’s answer was a definite no; not in a democracy.48 CRITERION – October/December 2009 23 Faizullah Khilji Nonetheless there is a view shared by informed and reputed academics in the United States that a change in the role of the dollar to a more modest stance is essentially an adjustment of asset portfolios in financial markets,49 and, indeed, if it were to decline as an international currency it may follow the path of sterling, and similarly settle down to a more affordable existence.50 This view increasingly looks simplistic and questionable. The “recovery” With economics in disrepute,51 more so the prevalent “efficient market hypothesis” version of economics, it would be a brave economist indeed who would try and predict what comes next for the world economy. What we do know is that the some major economies, particularly the United States and the United Kingdom, now face a gross mismatch between debts incurred to purchase assets, and the cash flows generated by these assets to service the debts. The business firms and the households therefore need to reduce their respective debt to bring it more nearly in line with their respective ability to meet interest payments. The debt, it would seem, may only be brought down through frugality and higher savings: a policy of inflation, an option for lowering the real debt burden, if pursued, may help reduce its real value only up to a point, before debasing the currency altogether and hence landing the economy in a different ballpark of problems. Any frugality by households also does not spell well for the business sector that produces goods and services, and hence for the economy and employment. In addition, banks would be cautious in lending until they have rebuilt their capital base, and this too would take time. This configuration appears to be the reality that may of necessity have to be faced; and efforts at changing sentiment by “talking up the economy” may not be sufficient to undo this reality, no matter how authoritative and credible the speakers. How long might such an adjustment of debt reduction take: the answer is that one does not really know any where near enough about the behaviour of economies through time to predict with confidence. Economic change does not occur in isolation, there are invariably political and social consequences. And when change involves a potentially 24 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... downward adjustment in an economy the size of United States, there are surely implications for the working of international economic relations as well. Comparison with Japan’s lost decade One previous situation of an economy finding its way out of a real estate bubble is that of Japan in the 1990s. Japan’s bursting of the real estate bubble and collapse of its property market was followed by long years of stagnation, commonly referred to as Japan’s “lost decade”; many years were taken up with “repairing the balance sheets”, i.e., deleveraging or reduction of debt. In this respect Paul Krugman has made a comparison of United States now with Japan then. Krugman’s comparison shows leveraging up to the bubble (the borrowing frenzy) in the case of the Japanese and American economies, and he also displays the trajectory of deleveraging, i.e., adjusting the level of debt, that followed in the Japanese case.52 The chart below illustrates. Source: Paul Krugman, The Return of Depression Economics Part 2: The eschatology of lost decades, Lionel Robbins Memorial Lecture, London School of Economics, June 9, 2009. CRITERION – October/December 2009 25 Faizullah Khilji In considering the comparison charted by Krugman, it needs to be borne in mind that the financial system that suffered the present crisis is arguably more complex than the Japanese one of the nineties, and the United States trajectory of leveraging up too is indeed some what different, showing a concave profile. The chart shows that the Japanese build up of leveraging was convex in shape, and the Japanese deleveraging process seems to have mirrored in time scale the pace of its leveraging process. It would not be wise to hazard a guess on how long United States might take to deleverage, American social and cultural practices differ appreciably from those of the Japanese, but the unspoken implication behind Krugman’s comparison is that the crisis will only be behind us once the deleveraging has taken place; the logic of this proposition is difficult to fault. Any comparison with Japan has at least one other important limitation though: the Yen was not the world’s currency; the dollar is! And this latter fact has deep implications for international economic relations. Comparison with the great depression Another historical situation with which the present crisis is frequently compared is that of the great depression, chiefly 1930s. Eichengreen and O’Rourke have made a comparison of the movement of a range of economic indicators in the present crisis with the great depression.53 The charts below show how industrial output and trade volume compare for the two periods, i.e., the great depression and now. Source: Barry Eichengreen and Kevin H O’Rourke, A tale of two depressions, June 4, 2009, at http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3241. Consider first the world industrial output. Thus far this indicator seems to be following the great depression trajectory rather faithfully, 26 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... as the chart shows. One important qualification to be considered is that industry accounted for a substantially larger share of the economy at the time of the great depression than it does today. Hence movements in an indicator on industrial output may have less relevance to the overall state of the current world economy, and this fact might arguably reduce the relevance of the indicator as a predictor of how long the crisis might last. Equally, the question may be asked as to why a services indicator might follow a different trajectory. There is no clear answer. Consider next the volume of world trade. As is clear from the chart, world trade volumes have plummeted much more sharply now than was the case at the corresponding stage in the great depression.54 This is an extremely disturbing development; one would expect a negative feedback loop from this fall in trade volumes to output of goods and services. It is worth recalling that in the 1930s, protectionism was on the rise and contributed to deepen and prolong the depression. Eichengreen and O’Rourke also review the policy response in the two situations, i.e., the present crisis and the great depression. Here the developments differ significantly between the two episodes as the charts below illustrate in respect of interest rates and fiscal deficits. World budget surpluses Source: Barry Eichengreen and Kevin H O’Rourke, A tale of two depressions, June 4, 2009, at http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3241. In the case of interest rates we find that the present crisis started at a much lower level of rates, and there has been a sharper reduction since CRITERION – October/December 2009 27 Faizullah Khilji then. With interest rates well below 1 per cent, there is little scope left for further easing now as there is not much further to go! Equally, the fiscal deficit has been building up much faster in the present case. The fiscal action too has been quicker and much larger. There is a sense of alarm arising from the sharp decline in trade volumes, as shown in the illustration above, and proposals have been made to relax some of the trading rules so as to facilitate trade flows as well as to use moral suasion to deter any overt or covert protectionist measures.55 Again one cannot be overly optimistic on this count; trade negotiations tend to be extremely contentious and drawn out even at the best of times, and actual developments are not encouraging. In course of the current crisis, the area of trade relations seems to have suffered policy neglect at best and stirrings of protectionist sentiments if not implementation of actual measures at the other end of the scale (support to auto and finance sectors undertaken recently in a number of economies may be recalled, as may the recent safeguard measures taken by the United States against the import of Chinese tyres). Trade environment could well suffer if the high levels of unemployment continue for some time. Given the nature of the processes leading up to the current crisis, the Eichengreen and O’Rourke graphical comparison with the great depression does not hold out much hope of an early sustained recovery either; the considerable macroeconomic easing notwithstanding. Looking at the underlying factors at work, it is not difficult to see why the trends may continue downwards for a while before reversing direction. We may recall that consumers are indeed saddled with debts and a good number are without jobs and incomes. Businesses too have accumulated debt and need to repay. Business may be reluctant to invest until the finances have been sorted out. To repeat, banks too need to rebuild the capital base, and are cautious in making new loans in an uncertain environment. Some other considerations in a recovery An important consideration, which may weigh increasingly with time, is the impact on any recovery of the present policies of monetary 28 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... expansion and fiscal stimulus in the drive to overcome the crisis. The major economies are awash with money as a result of monetary policies to combat the crisis, and sooner or later this will fuel demand but it would also likely engender inflation. The fiscal burdens, that are a consequence of stimulus packages and are also to be settled in the future, are unprecedented, and imply hefty taxation in the years to come. Hence there may be tight macroeconomic policies on the extended horizon.56 If the events take this likely turn towards strong contractionary policies to counter inflation and to achieve fiscal balance, there would be plenty of scope in the ensuing political milieu of hardship for developing a case for protectionism. And it may be difficult to counter this because an organised anti-protectionist lobby, quite unlike the finance sector,57 is simply non-existent outside the ranks of academics. Another aspect of the stimulus packages is whether the “green shoots” would remain green when the existing measures come to an end, or whether new stimulus packages would be necessary. There is no clarity on this point, and it would take considerable political courage to make an informed statement. It follows if an economy was not highly leveraged then it should not have suffered the financial crisis to the same extent that the United States and the United Kingdom did. This provides one important explanation why the financial sectors in the Asian economies have fared better thus far, and may be expected to survive the global downturn much better. But a slowdown in the United States impacts Asian economies through two obvious channels. Firstly, the slowdown in the United States, on account of the financial crisis, chokes demand for Asian exports, and thus far Asian exports, along with the rest of world’s exports, have indeed suffered (as noted above). These negative effects may be offset or at least minimized with some foresight, and one approach towards that objective could be for Asia to further increase intra-regional commerce as well as domestic demand. China’s reflationary package aims at the latter aspect, as do similar albeit more modest measures by other East Asian countries. The second channel through which the crisis affects Asia is investment by Asians of their savings in “toxic” assets in the US financial system.58 CRITERION – October/December 2009 29 Faizullah Khilji The East Asian response And it is indeed the East Asian59 context of international economic relations that offers a particularly interesting study. It is important for East Asia that output growth and employment in the region and its rapidly expanding intra-regional and international trade not be hostage to speculators or any lack of visible capability on the part of East Asia to respond to speculation as required. Views as well as institutional arrangements have been evolving for some time in East Asia on how best to cope with the instability arising from speculative capital flows, as well as with the quandary of global imbalances and consequent reliance on the dollar as a world currency. The East Asian riposte to the Asian crisis of 1998 With the benefit of hindsight, it would seem that the experience with the financial crisis of 1998 deeply influenced East Asian thinking on the existing international monetary arrangements, and added a sense of urgency to its concerns. The East Asians saw the crisis as an outcome of the failure of the international monetary system (centred on the IMF) to check investors and currency speculators profiteering at the expense of public welfare. By contrast, the IMF saw the Asian crisis as gross mismanagement on the part of Asian governments, and there were widespread references in the media to the event being an outcome of long standing policies of “crony capitalism”. In the event wrenching contractionary policies were applied, on the insistence of the IMF, as a condition of the latter’s support. Having developed some understanding through the disruptive experience over 1998-2000 of how the international monetary arrangements really worked out for those in trouble, the East Asian then seem to have proceeded in a quiet and determined manner to develop regional mechanisms (in addition to national measures) that would help defend their economies and societies from the impact of currency speculators, and also avoid what they perceived as unjustified public humiliation of the governments and peoples, and unnecessary disruption of their economies in the future. Two regional measures in particular need mentioning. The first of these developments was the Chiang Mai currency swap arrangements. These arrangements facilitate drawing upon another’s 30 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... foreign exchange resources in the event of a foreign exchange crisis, and were put in place in 2000; subsequently the size of the potential facility was expanded.60 The creation of these swap arrangements for a good part also expressed the view that the IMF could not be reliably counted upon to either correctly diagnose the problem or to provide really useful and timely relief. The Asian crisis had shown that damage would be done by the time IMF came around to help, and because the IMF might diagnose the developments differently (“crony capitalism” rather than speculation) such help would likely be accompanied with conditions that might worsen the prospects of output and income growth for some time, apart from imposing unnecessary humiliation on the nation. One important feature of these Chiang Mai arrangements was that agreement had been reached without any protracted negotiations, or without numerous well publicised ministerials, etc., as is generally the case. The second development of note was the build up of reserves by the East Asian economies, almost in concert; this arguably is again work to develop self-help capability, being the only kind of help one can count on, in case of a financial crisis. Thus, in the event of need, these economies would not go hat in hand to the IMF for assistance, and be obligated to follow policies, counterproductive in the East Asian reading, that are a condition of any IMF support. Wittingly or otherwise, in instituting these policies of regional currency swaps and large reserves, the East Asians have reduced much the applicability and relevance of the international monetary system centered on the IMF to East Asian economies! The East Asians have effectively put in place a substitute informal regional monetary system of their own for some limited purposes. This though was not the intent of the IMF efforts in 1998, and the IMF, it seems, had misjudged both the seriousness of the mood and the effectiveness of capabilities with regard to the East Asians. IMF thus overplayed its hand this one time too often, and now finds itself without its traditional role in East Asia! This view of developments is lent some credence by the discussion amongst East Asian central bankers.61 CRITERION – October/December 2009 31 Faizullah Khilji The East Asian response to the current crisis Thus with the deterrent of large reserves and the regional swap arrangements in place, the financial crisis of 2007-2009 passed Asia by,62 except for the worrying thought that their reserves were for a large part composed of dollar related securities, albeit chiefly government debt; and that it was the United States and hence the dollar that was in the eye of the storm. In this environment the East Asians voiced two related concerns, albeit in a moderate tone. The first concern was security and safety of dollar denominated assets.63 The second concern was the need for stable international monetary arrangements that would be independent of the vicissitudes of political and economic cycles such as may characterise any world currency that is primarily a national currency. Such an approach would also provide a neutral means to help equilibrate any global imbalances. In itself the issue was not a novel one, having been brought to prominence as noted earlier, by Robert Triffin in the 1960s. This issue resurfaced publicly in the East Asian context in 2009.64 A reflective piece by Zhou Xiaochuan appeared in China Daily.65 The argument was broadly as follows. The existing system of using the dollar, a national currency, presents problems; even though the “crisis may not necessarily be an intended result of the issuing authorities, it is an inevitable outcome of the institutional flaws” noted the article, and went on to make the point that, in any event the “acceptance of creditbased national currencies as major international reserve currencies, as is the case in the current system, is a rare special case in history”.66 The problem with the use of a national currency is the existence of the well known “Triffin Dilemma67, i.e., the issuing countries of reserve currencies cannot maintain the value of the reserve currencies while providing liquidity to the world”. Therefore the issuing country “may either fail to adequately meet the demand of a growing global economy for liquidity as ..(it tries).. to ease inflation pressures at home, or create excess liquidity in the global markets by overly stimulating domestic demand.” And the “frequency and increasing intensity of financial crises following the collapse of the Bretton Woods system suggests the costs of such a system to the world may have exceeded its benefits”. What was 32 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... being said was that in the East Asian perception it was the inadequacy of the existing international monetary arrangements centred on the dollar that were leading to creation of excess liquidity and hence contributing to the occurrence of financial crises; the excessive quantities of dollars in the world economy were causing problems. The Zhou Xiaochuan article pointed out that the need is for a “super-sovereign” international reserve currency that “not only eliminates the inherent risks of creditbased sovereign currency, but also makes it possible to manage global liquidity”. Such a reserve currency “managed by a global institution could be used to both create and control the global liquidity”. Arguably, a world monetary authority is being proposed, and this authority and the global currency it issues would naturally impose a discipline on national currencies. And when a country’s currency is no longer used as the yardstick for global trade and as the benchmark for other currencies, the exchange rate policy of the country would be far more effective in adjusting economic imbalances. This will “significantly reduce the risks of a future crisis and enhance crisis management capability.” The East Asians seemed to be recalling Rueff’s concerns as well as the Triffin plans of 1960s! The proposal by Zhou Xiaochuan goes on to advocate short run and long run measures to address the reserve currency question. “In the short run, the international community, particularly the IMF, should at least recognize and face up to the risks resulting from the existing system, conduct regular monitoring and assessment and issue timely early warnings.” In the present circumstances, one can surmise that in the article it is the United States economy that the IMF is being asked to monitor and issue early warnings about, and that the suggestion is that IMF should proceed to do so immediately.68 The proposal then says that “special consideration should be given to giving the SDR a greater role” and for this purpose SDR allocations be increased. And such measures could also “lay a foundation for increasing SDR allocation to gradually replace existing reserve currencies with the SDR”. In the long run, the proposal suggests, the best course would be to create an international reserve currency. The example of Keynes’s Bancor is recalled.69 The proposal recognizes that any scheme that aims CRITERION – October/December 2009 33 Faizullah Khilji to create “an international currency unit, based on the Keynes’s ideas, is a bold initiative that requires extraordinary political vision and courage”. Then there is the three-fold criteria to be met by any international reserve currency and this is laid out in the proposal: the international reserve currency should firstly be anchored to a stable benchmark and issued according to a clear set of rules in order to ensure orderly supply; second, its supply should be flexible enough to allow timely adjustment according to the changing demand; third, such adjustments should be disconnected from economic conditions and sovereign interests of any single country. There is also mention of using SDR in the long run, but one may infer that the character of the SDR would change significantly if it were to resemble Keynes’s Bancor, and meet the three-fold criteria. This aspect of matter is not spelt out in any detail in the proposal. Whether the East Asians were seeking support for a change in the existing international monetary arrangements, or just seriously airing an idea, this scheme for an international reserve currency has found some support outside Asia as well; in particular Brazil as well as Russia have responded positively.70 The United States response was initially to consider the proposal, but no sooner had Secretary Geithner uttered these words that the markets saw the dollar plummeting, and plummeting very, very fast. Within fifteen minutes of the announcement, no more, Geithner “corrected” the “misunderstanding” created by his remarks.71 Governor Bernanke followed up to further set the record straight, and then President Obama himself spoke to remove any remaining doubts about the dollar’s future. The Chinese officials too confirmed that the intent was not to undermine the dollar. And, finally, Richard Cooper, the Keynesian éminence grise of international monetary affairs, wrote up a brief to say that dollar would continue in its present role for years.72 Thus calm has returned for now. Aspects of this East Asian currency proposal have been explored by Fred Bergsten.73 Bergsten suggests the creation of an open-ended SDR-denominated fund at the IMF into which dollar balances could be exchanged for SDRs, instead of converting unwanted dollars through the market.74 There is also awareness now in the United States for “a large increase in China’s voting rights at the IMF, where Europe 34 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... is so heavily over-represented”, and the need “for China and the US to develop the informal ‘G2’ partnership… needed to provide global economic leadership”.75 Whilst American scholarship on China is no doubt first rate, and those at the Peterson Institute are behind none, yet the Bergsten proposal seems to interpret China as a different kind of United States, and, for this reason, seems to be off the mark. For the foreseeable future at least, the East Asians are seeking nothing more than measures to defend their economies from the uncertainties of the world economy; to this end they feel the discipline of an international currency should be created and applied. And they feel that they have the capability to live and work within the discipline of an international currency. The East Asians certainly do not appear to be seeking to run the world or pursue global agendas.76 Furthermore, the Bergsten idea of using SDRs and a SDR based fund fall short of the three-fold criteria specified in the East Asian proposal: the dollar/sterling combination on which the SDR is inter alia based does not perhaps amount to being “anchored to a stable benchmark”, and it also does not offer a unit that is “disconnected from economic conditions and sovereign interests of any single country”. Whilst the East Asian idea of an international currency germinates, at an immediate policy level three recent measures taken in East Asia seem to be aimed at reducing the recourse to dollar as an international currency. The first development is the East Asian effort to use currencies other than the dollar in international transactions. China, the largest trader in East Asia, is reportedly discussing a number of agreements to conduct bilateral trade in the currencies of the countries involved,77 and, once in place, such arrangements may help to insulate some of the trade flows from the effects of fluctuations in the value of the dollar. Secondly, China has also authorized some of its corporations to conduct their trade in Renminbi. The latter measure is said to aim at providing stability for local exporters buffeted by the dollar’s fluctuating value.78 CRITERION – October/December 2009 35 Faizullah Khilji It needs mentioning here that the significance of using a particular currency in actual trade has to be seen in context of China’s large external trade and the importance of China’s trade in the East Asia region. There are two aspects to this. First is the remarkable fact that even in the absence of formally binding agreements, the intraregional trade for the five economies of Northeast Asia (China, Japan, two Koreas, and Taiwan Province) now accounts for 52 percent of the total trade of these economies. This integration has been achieved in a natural fashion, without formal agreements a la the EU to force integration and harmonization. By comparison, the EU intra-trade is 60 percent of the total EU trade, and it took the EU countries protracted negotiations leading to formal agreements, besides a period of over fifty years, to get to this 60 per cent statistic. The intra-trade volume is both large and seems to be growing in an organic manner. Second, in this intraregional trade, China is a net importer from most of the trading partners in the East Asian region, and regional exports to China have expanded at record rates over the past 20 years. In this manner China’s situation with regard to bilateral trade balances in East Asia may be somewhat akin to that of Germany in EU. The third development, that may be read as lessening the importance of the dollar, is the use to which official reserves are being put. China appears to be articulating a position that has been fairly common historically, i.e., substituting real assets for financial assets through the export of capital as direct foreign investment. Premier Wen JiaBao is reported to have said recently that China should hasten the implementation of its ‘going out’ strategy and combine the utilisation of foreign exchange reserves with the ‘going out’ of its enterprises.79 ‘Going out’ refers to China’s direct foreign investment policy, and includes efforts of the larger state-owned industrial groups such as Petro China, Chinalco, and China Telecom. This policy appears to aim at “reserve diversification in a broader sense”.80 In this manner more of overseas long-term corporate real assets substitute for dollar foreign exchange reserves. To a considerably lesser extent India and other Asian surplus countries too seem to be pursuing similar policies. 36 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... It is a reasonable and prudent inference that the East Asians take this crisis at least as seriously as the Asian crisis of 1998, and wish to develop capacity to meet any recurrence of another event such as the 2007-2008 crisis. And given that the response in the case of the Asian crisis of 1998 was to solve the problem, there is every reason to believe that international reserve currency issue would be pursued further to some logical and practical conclusions. Given the determination and persistence, which have been evident characteristics of the East Asians thus far, some solution that meets the regional East Asian requirements would be found, even though it may be short of the Bancor concept and its usefulness may largely lie in East Asia.81 If the lesson that East Asia drew from the Asian crisis was to build up reserves and put in place currency swap arrangements, then the lesson it is drawing from the present crisis is to gradually lower its exposure in terms of the dollar.82 This may also be interpreted as a pragmatic and evolutionary approach to further lessening the region’s dependence on the international monetary system centred on the IMF. The fact that the Asian economies faced the present crisis fairly confidently may partly, if not wholly, be owed to the credibility that the reserves and swap arrangements offered. Taken together, the recent moves in East Asia, from which the United States as well as the EU appear to be absent, aim to reduce the role of traditional reserve currencies, for China as well as its trading partners, and lend something of a new significance to the Renminbi in the region. These arrangements also further reduce the potential need for recourse to the IMF and its facilities, should there be another crisis. Change is afoot, even though the shape of things to come is far from clear. References: 1 S M Naseem first raised the idea of writing on the theme of the financial crisis and reviewed draft versions, making pertinent comments on each occasion on how it might be improved. Apart from making relevant and useful suggestions to sharpen the text and improve the content, Wei Liang also very generously undertook the painstaking task of reviewing some of the citations. Stephen Browne, Khalil Hamdani, Gary Hufbauer, Nasir Khilji, Taimur Khilji, Changlin Ma, Hafiz Pasha, Eric Rahim and Yang Guotao, all provided helpful suggestions on the draft version. The author is deeply indebted to all of the above, but remains solely responsible for the opinions and views expressed. CRITERION – October/December 2009 37 Faizullah Khilji 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 38 Andre Malraux, account of a conversation with Mao Zedong in Beijing, in Antimemoires, Paris 1967, translated by Terence Kilmartin, (London, Hamish Hamilton, 1968), p. 395. Bank for International Settlements, 79th Annual Report, Basel 29 June 2009, p. 3. Bank for International Settlements, 79th Annual Report, Basel 29 June 2009, p. 15. And, Professor Garicano is reported to have replied that “at every stage, someone was relying on somebody else and everyone thought they were doing the right thing.” See Alan Beattie, Good question, Ma’am Financial Times, November 14 2008. Alan Greenspan writes “Markets have become too huge, complex, and fast moving to be subject to twentieth century regulation. No wonder this globalized financial behemoth stretches beyond the full comprehension of even the most sophisticated market participants…Only belatedly did I, and I suspect many of my colleagues, come to realize that the power to regulate administratively was fading…Since markets have become too complex for effective human intervention, the most promising anticrisis policies are those that maintain maximum market flexibility – freedom of action for key participants.” See Alan Greenspan, The age of turbulence (New York, Penguin, 2007), p. 489. Curiously, the belief about the incomprehensible complexity of the financial system is shared by others in authority, even though the social usefulness of such complexity is not subjected to any searching or critical examination. Thus we have the Bank for International Settlements annual report saying the following: “ The modern financial system is immensely complex – possibly too complex for any one person to really understand it. Interconnections create systemic risks that are extraordinarily difficult to figure out.” See Bank for International Settlements, 79th Annual Report, Basel 29 June 2009, p. 4. See Martin Wolf, Unfettered finance is fast reshaping the global economy, and Risks and rewards of today’s unshackled finance, Financial Times, June 18 and 27, 2007, respectively. Tables summarizing the chronology may be seen in Bank for International Settlements, 79th Annual Report, Basel 29 June 2009, and 78th Annual Report, Basel 30 June 2008, pages 15 and 18-19, and 95-96 respectively. Joe Becker, Sheryl Gay Stolberg and Stephen Labaton, The reckoning: White House philosophy stoked mortgage bonfire, The New York Times, December 20, 2008. This news report carries a telling photograph of President George W Bush looking pleased as he speaks with a banner behind him carrying the evocative text “A Home of Your Own”. Niall Ferguson notes that the last run on a bank in Britain was in 1866. See Niall Ferguson, The ascent of money, (New York, Penguin, 2008), p. 336. The building still stands in good shape. One wit on a television newscast saw it as “Chinese socialism with American characteristics”. The “permitted” collapse of Lehman Brothers presents something of a “mystery”. No other institution of this size was allowed to collapse, even though some of these institutions such as AIG may have been in even worse shape. One view is that Mr Fuld of Lehman Brothers “did not help matters by riling Hank Paulson, the former boss of Goldman Sachs turned treasury secretary, at a private dinner in early 2008” (see Lehman Brothers and the crisis: A year on, in The Economist, September 10, 2009). Another view, attributed to Kenneth Rogoff is that “the standard playbook is to let the fourth or fifth largest bank go under and you save everybody else”, without offering any credible reasoning for a such a “playbook” rule, or, indeed, why Lehman Brothers was chosen (see Economic focus: CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... What if??, in The Economist, September 10, 2009). 14 As cited in Andrew Gamble, The spectre at the feast, (Basingstoke, Palgrave, 2009), p. 33. 15 With the benefit of hindsight, regulation, or rather inappropriate regulation, did not work in public interest. Firstly, the Glass Steagall Act was repealed in 1999 to permit deposit-taking institutions to conduct investment business. This brought the banks in a big way into this - CDO package, slice and dice, CDS, spread the risk - business, without an appropriate regulating framework. Whilst this state of affairs is often referred to as “too complex”, etc., for the human mind, no credible reasoning is forthcoming as to why this complexity was permitted to build up by the regulator, or as to its social usefulness. Secondly, leverage built up very fast. One reason was that the regulator accepted the transfer of the risk that attaches to a loan (via CDS) and the consequent idea that such transfer meant that the bank could “re-use” the capital earlier tied up with the loan; the regulator also accepted that some of these activities (which, to remind, involved funds held in public trust by the banks) could be carried on outside the reporting framework, i.e., off balance sheet. This led directly to the high leverage ratios for the banks, and the missing piece here is the need for clarity on the prudent capital ratio for the bank and the need to bring “off balance sheet” activity on to the balance sheet. There is nothing here that can really be labeled as too difficult or complex to be understood. Thirdly, conflict of interest situations were “over-looked”: the remuneration of the mortgage broker who helped arrange the loan was directly dependent on the volume of lending furthered by that broker, and that a good quantum of loans was being made to persons without income or jobs or assets was glossed over (one cannot conceive of any “complex mathematics too difficult to understand” that would make such loans safe - in such cases at least it is more likely that the “complex mathematics too difficult to understand” may have only helped conceal the poor nature of lending); and, the credit rating agency was paid by the party whose risk was being assessed, hence raising an obvious conflict of interest. Fourth, there are factors that engender herd behaviour. The ratings industry is dominated by a couple of firms. Their assessments, i.e., ratings, are highly correlated, causing investors and speculators to act in unison, and thus generate a procyclical movement causing euphoria or pessimism as the case may be. Another aspect that creates herd movement is that the models used by different financial institutions to assess risks and to guide buy and sell decisions, tend to be homogeneous, giving broadly similar results. This is probably owed to the fact that modeling work is generally outsourced and there are only a few firms that provide this service: if a firm is modeling for half a dozen banks, the models it produces would likely give similar directional results in a given situation. This factor thus leads to a number of different institutions buying the same asset at a given time (and vice versa), quite unlike the concept of a market, which has optimists and pessimists in relation to any given situation. (See Zhou Xiaochuan, Changing procyclicality for financial and economic stability, People’s Bank of China website: http:// www.pbc.gov.cn/english/hanglingdaojianghua.) Fifth, and most importantly, the Fed believed that asset bubbles were not on its watch. The only development the Fed needed to monitor, as a part of its function, was the price level, more specifically the consumer price index. In the event, the Fed provided a big push to the whole process by following an easy monetary policy for extended periods, boosting the demand for financial and other assets in the process, and hence contributed CRITERION – October/December 2009 39 Faizullah Khilji to the bubble. 16 See Financial economics, Efficiency and beyond, in The Economist, July 16, 2009. Robert Lucas in a subsequent article in The Economist offered a more nuanced definition of EMH: “One thing we are not going to have, now or ever, is a set of models that forecasts sudden falls in the value of financial assets, like the declines that followed the failure of Lehman Brothers in September. This is nothing new. It has been known for more than 40 years and is one of the main implications of Eugene Fama’s “efficient-market hypothesis” (EMH), which states that the price of a financial asset reflects all relevant, generally available information. If an economist had a formula that could reliably forecast crises a week in advance, say, then that formula would become part of generally available information and prices would fall a week earlier. (The term “efficient” as used here means that individuals use information in their own private interest. It has nothing to do with socially desirable pricing; people often confuse the two.)” See Economic focus: In defence of economics, guest article by Robert E Lucas, in The Economist, August 6, 2009. 17 Alan Greenspan seems to have shared this conviction, as did Ben Bernanke. See Alan Greenspan, The age of turbulence, cited above, and Ben Bernanke, The great moderation, February 20, 2004, http://www.federalreserve.gov/BOARDDOCS/ SPEECHES/2004/20040220/default.html 18 With prescience, Minsky had noted his reservations about the applicability of EMH-like propositions of neoclassical economics in the following words: The major theorems of the neoclassical synthesis are that a system of decentralized markets, where units are motivated by self-interest, is capable of yielding a coherent result, and in some very special cases, the result can be characterized as efficient. These main conclusions are true, however, only if very strong assumptions are made. They have never been shown to hold for an economy with privately owned capital assets and complex, ever evolving financial institutions and practices. Indeed we live in an economy which is developing through time, whereas the basic theorems on which the conservative critique of intervention rests have been proven only for “models” which abstract from time. See Hyman P Minsky, Inflation, recession and economic policy, (Brighton, Wheatsheaf, 1982), p. xii. 19 This point is discussed at greater length later in the essay. 20 See discussion in Bank for International Settlements, 79th Annual Report, Basel 29 June 2009, as well in earlier issues of the annual report. 21 Alan Greenspan, as one important guardian of public interest, frequently affirmed that Wall St had mastered risk, in contradiction to the assessments by George Soros and Warren Buffett (two persons perhaps forced into thinking with greater clarity because their own funds were on the line). Greenspan’s views seem at best to be unfounded articles of faith combined with goodwill towards Wall St. “Not only have individual financial institutions become less vulnerable to shocks from underlying risk factors, but also the financial system as a whole has become more resilient”, said Greenspan in 2004, and his book “The age of turbulence” (cited earlier) is replete with expressions of similar sentiments. There were others among the regulators though who were more aware and alert and less caught up with the charms of Wall St bankers. One such reported case is of Brooksley E Born who was heading the Commodity Futures Trading Commission. She testified before Congress that unfettered, opaque trading in derivatives could “threaten our regulated markets or, indeed, our economy without any federal agency knowing about it”, and called for greater disclosure of trades in derivatives and reserves to cushion 40 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... 22 23 24 25 26 against losses. These views drew fierce opposition from Alan Greenspan, Robert Rubin (the then Treasury Secretary), and Larry Summers (then Deputy Treasury Secretary). Greenspan is reported to have told Born that she did not know what she was doing and would cause a financial crisis, Rubin saw the move as threatening to the markets, and Summers phoned her to chastise her. The two principals, Greenspan and Rubin, then called on Congress on June 5, 1998, to prevent Born from taking any further action. Congress obliged, and duly froze Born’s authority for six months, and, shortly thereafter, she departed from the Commission. Evidently, Ms Born was not among those who are born to be a Treasury Secretary or even a Treasury Secretary’s adviser. She did however get the JFK Profiles in Courage award in 2009. See Peter S Goodman, Taking a hard look at a Greenspan legacy, The New York Times, October 8, 2008. Also see http://www. jfklibrary.org/JFK+Library+and+Museum/News+and+Press/2009+Profile+in+Courage +Award+Recipients+Announced.html An extreme ratio of 134:1 was reported for Bank of America in a talk in London by Niall Ferguson on November 8 2008; the video link is: http://www.thersa.org/events/vision/ vision-videos/niall-ferguson. Also, Philip Augar gives the following data in this respect: Goldman Sachs 24:1, Morgan Stanley 25:1, Lehman Brothers 32:1, Bear Stearns 33:1. See Philip Augur, Chasing Alpha, (London, Bodley Head, 2009), p. 169. For a fully reasoned statement of how a financial crisis develops, see Hyman P Minsky, The financial-instability hypothesis: capitalist processes and the behavior of the economy, in Charles P Kindleberger and Jean-Pierre Laffargue, editors, Financial crises: Theory, history and policy, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1982, pp. 13-47. This volume puts together the proceedings of a conference. The three well known and distinguished discussants of Minsky’s paper at this conference rejected his hypothesis. The first, J S Fleming, stated that he was “rejecting claims implicit in Minsky’s exposition”. The second, Raymond W Goldsmith, did not believe that Minsky’s hypothesis “provides an explanation of the financial development of a modern economy”. The third, Jacques Melitz, said that some of Minsky’s arguments “evade me completely”, and then went on to express his disagreement with bits that did not evade him completely. Also see Hyman P Minsky, Inflation, recession and economic policy, Wheatsheaf, Brighton, 1982, and Stabilizing an unstable economy, McGraw Hill, New York, 2008. In relation to the current crisis, the bonuses of those who worked in the financial sector and the banking industry were tied to profits. There was a clear incentive to show as high a profit as possible and as soon as possible as this work force tends to be footloose. In some cases this quest for high and quick profits also led to playing with the accounting definitions and rules as well as taking on risks that ordinarily would not be seen as prudent. Giving the labyrinthine nature of the transactions, it is not uncommon for the higher management to be unaware of all the operations in the field. See discussion in Bank for International Settlements, 79th Annual Report, Basel 29 June 2009 For example, Robert Solow has written that “By 2005 the country had clearly built many more houses, maybe two or three million more, than it could afford to occupy and finance”, and that “this housing boom was enhanced by riskier and more opaque financial products that entangled a wider variety of highly leveraged financial institutions. The word “bubble” is often misused; but there was a housing bubble. Rising house prices induced many people to buy houses simply because they expected prices to rise; those purchases drove prices still higher, and confirmed the expectation. Prices rose because they had been rising.” See Robert M Solow, How to understand the disaster, New York CRITERION – October/December 2009 41 Faizullah Khilji Review of Books, May 14, 2009. 27 See Alan Greenspan, The age of turbulence, cited earlier, and Ben Bernanke, The great moderation, also cited earlier. 28 In the present crisis the Bernard Madoff case offers a good example of the Ponzi financier on a grand scale. See for example discussion in Diana B Henriques, Madoff is sentenced to 150 years for Ponzi scheme, New York Times, June 29, 2009. 29 This would be true of the major banks in the present episode. They had borrowed to the hilt. See leverage ratios cited in footnote 22 above. 30 See discussion in Bank for International Settlements, 79th Annual Report, Basel 29 June 2009 31 This point has been discussed in a number of articles. Jeff Madrick writing in the New York Review of Books says: “One problem was that the Fed did not have adequate information about these markets because derivatives were not traded openly and the latest CDOs, including mortgage-backed obligations, were mostly on the books of the shadow banking system. It was a serious lapse of judgment, not to mention responsibility, on the part of the Federal Reserve under Greenspan and the Securities and Exchange Commission under Christopher Cox to fail to seek more comprehensive information far earlier about the surge of lending.” See Jeff Madrick, How we were ruined and what we can do, New York Review of Books, February 12, 2009. A more detailed discussion of the relevance of public facts for functioning of financial markets may be seen in Donald MacKenzie, End-of-the-World Trade, London Review of Books, May 8, 2008. 32 SPV and SIV are widely used acronyms for Special Purpose Vehicle and Structured Investment Vehicle. These were names given to entities set up by the banks outside the ambit of their balance sheets to transform loans and other receivables into CDOs. The Bank for International Settlements notes as follows: “Beyond the problems with incentives and risk measurement was the fact that financial institutions found it relatively easy to move activities outside the regulatory perimeter. Inside the supervisors’ sphere of influence, banks are required to hold capital in order to engage in risky activities. While it may be hard to believe, the regulatory capital requirement did limit the build-up of leverage on bank balance sheets. However lower leverage meant lower profitability, so bank managers found ways to increase risk without increasing the capital they were required to hold. That is the story of the structured investment vehicle.” See Bank for International Settlements, 79th Annual Report, Basel 29 June 2009, p.10. 33 A striking perspective on the change of rule is offered by Benjamin M Friedman who notes that “the Financial Accounting Standards Board—the independent organization designated by the SEC to set accounting standards—acting at the strong urging of Congress, recently changed its rules to allow banks more latitude to claim that assets on their balance sheets are worth more than what anyone is willing to pay for them. (Next time you apply for a loan, try mentioning FAS 157-4 and telling your banker that you should be allowed to calculate your net worth with your house priced not at what comparable houses are selling for now but at what you paid for it and what you hope you’ll get for it if you hold on to it for some years. The banker will laugh, even while the bank applies just such standards to its own balance sheet.)” See Benjamin M Friedman, The failure of the economy & the economists, New York Review of Books, May 28, 2009. 34 See, Robert Kaplan, Robert Merton and Scott Richard, Disclose the fair value of complex securities, Financial Times August 17 2009 35 See discussion in Bank for International Settlements, 79th Annual Report, Basel 29 June 42 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... 2009, p. 8. 36 The finance industry’s share of US wages and salaries is reported to have increased from 3 percent in the early 1950s to 7 percent in the current decade. See Benjamin M Friedman, The failure of the economy & the economists, New York Review of Books, May 28, 2009. 37 Benjamin M Friedman reports that the “share of the ‘finance’ sector in total corporate profits rose from 10 percent on average from the 1950s through the 1980s, to 22 percent in the 1990s, and an astonishing 34 percent in the first half of this decade.” See Benjamin M Friedman, The failure of the economy & the economists, New York Review of Books, May 28, 2009. 38 J M Keynes, Proposals for a currency union, December 15, 1941, in John Maynard Keynes, The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, volume XXV, Activities 194044, Shaping the post-war world, The clearing union, (London, Macmillan, 1980), pp.6994. 39 Barry Eichengreen, Global imbalances and the lessons of Bretton Woods, (Cambridge, MIT Press, 2007), p. 15. 40 Those with large holdings of dollars today are said to experience a similar fear: any efforts to diversify out of dollars involves selling dollars and may cause a flight from the dollar with the consequent fall in the value of their dollar assets. 41 Robert Triffin wrote: “Our old friend, Sir Roy Harrod, was the first to characterize these moves, many years ago, as institutionalizing the inconvertibility of the reserve currencies through gentlemen’s agreements.” See Robert Triffin, The international monetary system, Yale University, Economic Growth Center, Center paper no 76, 1966, p. 4. 42 Robert Triffin, The paper exchange standard 1971-19??, in Paul A Volcker, et al, International monetary cooperation: Essays in honor of Henry C Wallich, Essays in international finance no 169, Princeton University, December 1987, p. 80. 43 See Robert Triffin, The international monetary system, Yale University, Economic Growth Center, Center paper no 76, 1966, p.6. 44 Following the French, the British, notwithstanding their gentlemanly characteristics, too sent out a battleship to obtain gold for dollars but Nixon’s announcement came through before the exchange could materialise. 45 Some see this statement of the problem as quite valid in our time. See William Buiter, Our currency and our problem, November 17, 2007 at http://blogs.ft.com/maverecon/2007/11/ our-currency-anhtml 46 Unlike the time when Connolly had firmly stated that the dollar was America’s currency but the rest of the world’s problem, the large dollar balances currently outside the United States are sometimes seen as conferring power on those who hold these balances. It is also recognised that the holders cannot exercise their power without inflicting damage to their own positions. In this context, Larry Summers introduced a new phrase and spoke of the “balance of financial terror” as between the United States and those who have the large dollar balances. See Lawrence H Summers, The US current account deficit and the global economy, Per Jacobsson lecture 2004, (Washington DC, Per Jacobsson Foundation, 2004). But concerns, which visualise East Asian governments as a kind of currency speculator, are, as anyone observing these matters would judge, far from the truth. Such scenarios are closer to plots of those odd Hollywood movies such as might centre on evil foreigners with bent minds who are keen on damaging good honest America. The inexplicable fact is that persons in authority sometimes do indulge in propagating a “Hollywood scenario” of the evil other. CRITERION – October/December 2009 43 Faizullah Khilji 47 “It is when a key currency has a deficit in its balance of payments – that is to say, the United States for example – it pays the creditor country dollars, which end up with its central bank. But the dollars are of no use in Bonn, or in Tokyo, or in Paris. The very same day they are re-lent to the New York money market, so that they may return to their place of origin. Thus the debtor country does not lose what the creditor country has gained. So the key-currency country never feels the effect of a deficit in its balance of payments. And the main consequence is that there is no reason whatever for the deficit to disappear, because it does not appear. “Let me be more positive: if I had an agreement with my tailor that whatever money I pay him he returns to me the very same day as a loan, I would have no objection at all to ordering more suits from him.” Jacques Rueff quoted in Fred Hirsh’s interview of Jacques Rueff in The Economist, February 13, 1965, cited in Filippo Cesarano, Monetary theory and Bretton Woods, The construction of an international monetary order, (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2006), pp. 191-192. The text of the whole interview, also issued as a Princeton essay in international finance (Jacques Rueff and Fred Hirsch, The Role and the Rule of Gold: An Argument, Essays in International Finance 47, Princeton University, International Finance Section 1965) may be seen at http://goldismoney.info/forums/showthread. php?t=7281 48 “And they (the United States) have had for five years an enormous deficit in their balance of payments. If they have not done by credit policy what the gold standard would have done by automatically restricting purchasing power, it is proof that it is not possible. And why is it not possible? I cannot imagine any parliamentary country with a democratic regime in which you could do such a difficult thing.” Jacques Rueff cited in Fred Hirsh’s interview of Jacques Rueff in The Economist, February 13, 1965. 49 Paul R Krugman, Currencies and crises, (Cambridge, MIT Press, 1992), pp. 179-183. 50 Barry Eichengreen, Global imbalances and the lessons of Bretton Woods, (Cambridge, MIT Press, 2007), pp. 123-148. 51 It is revealing that the discussion about the limited usefulness of the “efficient market hypothesis” has reached newspapers, and that most of this discussion reflects negatively on the economics that is taught and on the common sense of those who choose to believe in the doctrine. See for example discussion in the Financial Times http://blogs.ft.com/ economistsforum/ and the newspaper articles cited there. See also the extensive discussion in The Economist, July 16, 2009. 52 Also see Dick K Nanto, The global financial crisis: Lessons from the Japan’s lost decade of 1990s, CRS report for Congress, Washington DC, May 2009. 53 Barry Eichengreen and Kevin H O’Rourke, A tale of two depressions, June 4, 2009, at http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3241. 54 One point of note is that in the great depression trajectory, for both the world industrial output and trade volume indicators, shows momentary upward ticks in what was a essentially a downward movement. The question whether these upward ticks qualified as “green shoots” at the time does arise, and the answer we believe is that they did. 55 See for example discussion in Gary Hufbauer, Trade policy in a time of crisis: Suggestions for the developing countries, lecture at the Geneva Institute of Graduate Studies, Geneva, July 9, 2009, and Jeffrey J Schott, Trade and the global economic crisis: If it’s not part of the solution, it’s part of the problem, Remarks presented at the APEC symposium, “Addressing the economic crisis, preparing for recovery,” Singapore, July 17, 2009. 44 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... 56 Richard Koo has put forth an argument that in a recession, that is marked by excessive debt, private expenditure would not recover until the private debt comes down to more manageable levels. And, public expenditure, Koo argues, must therefore continue to substitute for any “shortfall” in private expenditure until the latter recovers. A policy based on these ideas would naturally imply fiscal deficits for some time to come. The obvious question then would be whether the economies suffering the downturn would have the fiscal space. See Richard C Koo, The holy grail of macroeconomics, Lessons from Japan’s great recession, (Singapore, Wiley, 2009), especially pp. 253-293. 57 To take some recent examples, Rubin and Paulson have worked in the major banks as well as the government. Tony Blair has been affiliated with one of the banks since the end of his tenure in the government. 58 Japan is reported to present a case where a large volume of savings had been invested in “toxic” CDOs and CDSs. See Anton Brender and Florence Pisani, La crise de la finance globalisee, Editions La Decouverte, Paris 2009 (translation by Francis Wells distributed as Anton Brender and Florence Pisani, Globalised finance and its collapse, Brussels, Dexia, 2009) 59 The term East Asia is used here in a broad sense to connote China, the Asean economies, Taiwan province, Hong Kong SAR, Japan and Republic of Korea. 60 As at the end of April 2009, these arrangements provided access to US $ 92 billion in total. See http://www.mof.go.jp/english/if/CMI_0904.pdf 61 At the 50th Anniversary ceremony of Bank Negara Malaysia, Kuala Lumpur, February 10, 2009, People’s Bank of China Governor Zhou Xiaochuan’s remarks included the following: We notice that the drastic increase of imbalance of savings and trade started after 1997. It is therefore worthwhile looking at the impact of the Asian financial crisis on the savings behavior of these countries. Asian countries were seriously shocked and alarmed by the Asian financial crisis. The attack of speculative capital led to plunging exchange rates and capital flight and nearly exhausted all foreign reserves, leaving a great sense of vigilance for East Asian countries in macroeconomic management. In the years that followed, countries in the region boosted exports, amassed trade surplus and accumulated large foreign reserves. It is fair to say that the high savings ratio and massive accumulation of foreign reserve in recent years in East Asian countries reflect the lessons learnt from, and the natural reaction to the Asian financial crisis. The large savings and foreign reserves of these countries are also the result of defensive reactions against predatory speculation. At the time, large capital inflows and the ensuing sudden stop and reversal as well as the rampant speculations of the hedge funds exacerbated the situation. People were shocked and frustrated by these speculative behaviors. At the onset of the crisis, Malaysia saw a weakening export, plummeting stock market and sharply depreciating currency. Despite criticism from some countries and international institutions, the Malaysian government imposed temporary capital restrictions and safeguarded currency stability. In Hong Kong SAR, which was also attacked by hedge funds, stock prices plunged, and its linked exchange rate regime was severely tested. The belief prevailed in the region that unregulated predatory speculation was an important factor behind the crisis, and it highlighted tremendous potential risks to the international financial system. It was hoped that the international community would bring it under necessary regulation. However, for some reason, the authorities of the countries CRITERION – October/December 2009 45 Faizullah Khilji 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 46 concerned were against regulating predatory speculative capital flows, and failed to see the need to adjust the regulatory frameworks. At the same time, international financial institutions failed to perform its regulatory responsibility over abnormal capital flows. East Asian countries are thus forced to amass foreign reserves to defend themselves. To some extent, the increase of savings ratio and current account surplus in East Asian countries are a result of the rescue plan of the international financial institutions. The rescue plan kept silent on international speculative capital flows, which otherwise should have been put under scrutiny. Instead, excessive and stringent conditionalities were imposed, demanding that the crisis countries adopt stringent fiscal and monetary policies, raise interest rates, cut fiscal deficits and increase foreign reserves. In the decade thereafter, East Asian countries have learnt the lessons, increased savings and foreign reserves and successfully enhanced their resilience to financial crisis. See People’s Bank of China website: http://www.pbc.gov.cn/english/hanglingdaojianghua/. The view is widely shared across East Asia; for example, Governor Dr Zeti Akhtar Aziz expressed broadly similar sentiments in his keynote address at the same ceremony. See the Bank Nagara Malaysia website: http://www.bnm.gov.my/index. php?ch=9&pg=15&ac=310 The concerns about exports and toxic assets have been discussed earlier. The financial sectors of the East Asian economies have not suffered and these economies seem to be maintaining growth. See David Pilling, Asia banks for a world turned upside down, Financial Times, September 16 2009, and Martin Wolf, Wheel of fortune turns as China outdoes west, Financial Times, September 13 2009. Premier Wen Jiabao is reported to have said: “We have lent a huge amount of money to the United States and of course we’re concerned about the security of our assets and, to be honest, I am a little bit worried, … That’s why … I would like to urge the US to keep its commitment and promise to ensure the safety of Chinese assets.” See Olivia Chung, Wen puts US honor on the debt line, March 14, 2009, Asia Times Online. Also see Michael Wines, China’s Leader Says He Is ‘Worried’ Over U.S. Treasuries, New York Times, March 14, 2009. Discussion of a reserve currency is an ongoing matter. This is the first time though that central bankers publicly discussed the matter since the 1970s. Zhou Xiaochuan, Reform the International Monetary System, China Daily, March 23, 2009. Also see: http://www.pbc.gov.cn/english/detail.asp?col=6500&id=182 The article by Zhou Xiaochuan brought to mind the more summary assessment by General Charles de Gaulle in his press conference of February 4, 1965. “We consider that international exchanges must be established, as was the case before the great worldwide disasters, on an unquestionable monetary basis which does not bear the mark of any individual country.” Robert Triffin wrote extensively on these issues, from 1950s to 1970s, and first formulated the specific issue, just as the Bretton Woods system was coming apart because of an excess of dollars. Triffin identified the problem for the US Congress in 1960 but it took another 10 years before the system came apart. There has been some development in context of monitoring economies by the IMF since Zhou Xiaochuan’s article appeared. At the recent G 20 meeting in Pittsburgh “The leaders pledged to rethink their economic policies in a coordinated effort to reduce the immense imbalances between export-dominated countries like China and Japan and debt-laden countries like the United States, which has long been the world’s most willing consumer. CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Financial Crisis, Global Imbalances... 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 “The United States will be expected to increase its savings rate, reduce its trade deficit and address its huge budget deficit. Countries like China, Japan and Germany will be expected to reduce their dependence on exports by promoting more consumer spending and investment at home. “The ideas are not new, and there is no enforcement mechanism to penalize countries if they stick to their old habits. But for the first time ever, each country agreed to submit its policies to a “peer review” from the other governments as well as to monitoring by the International Monetary Fund. “That in itself would be a big change, given how prickly national leaders have often been toward outside criticism of their policies.” See Edmund S Andrews, Group of 20 Agrees on Far-Reaching Economic Plan, New York Times, September 26, 2009 The Economist though noted that the “Developing countries are uneasy about formalising such a realignment. They are publicly supportive, but that may only be because they suspect it will be impossible to police.” See The G20 summit, Regaining their balance, Economist.com, September 26th 2009. Back in the 1940s, Keynes had already proposed the introduction of an international currency unit named “Bancor”, based on the value of 30 representative commodities. Unfortunately, the proposal was not accepted. The collapse of the Bretton Woods system, which was based on the White approach, indicates that the Keynesian approach may have been more farsighted. Andrei Denisov, Russia’s first deputy foreign minister, said: “This proposal is aimed at a practical realisation of the idea about a new global accounting unit or a new global currency. It is a question that should be discussed to create a consensus.” See Julia Kollewe, Global currency flies with push from Russia and slip from Geithner, the Guardian, March 26, 2009. See Anahad O’Connor, Geithner Affirms Dollar After Remarks Send It Tumbling, The New York Times, March 26, 2009 See Richard N Cooper, The future of the dollar, Peterson Institute Policy Brief, September 2009. C. Fred Bergsten, We Should Listen to Beijing’s Currency Idea, Financial Times, April 8, 2009. The SDR, as Bergsten notes, “is denominated in a basket of currencies – 44 per cent dollars, 34 per cent euro and 11 per cent each of yen and sterling”, and this would not appear to meet the criteria laid down in the Zhou Xiaochuan article (see discussion above). Bergsten also notes that this is “essentially the substitution account idea negotiated in the IMF in the late 1970s and for which detailed blueprints were developed. Similar anxieties about the dollar at that time prompted its sharpest plunge in the postwar period, intensifying the double-digit inflation and soaring interest rates that brought on the deepest US slowdown since the 1930s, until now”. See Fred Bergsten, We should listen to Beijing’s currency idea, Financial Times, April 8 2009 See Fred Bergsten, We should listen to Beijing’s currency idea, Financial Times, April 8 2009 As noted above ‘Wen told a press conference after the conclusion of a two-week meeting of the country’s legislators that he was “a little bit worried” about the safety of Chinese assets in the US, and called on the US “to maintain its good credit, to honor its promises and to guarantee the safety of China’s assets.”’ See Olivia Chung, Wen puts US honor on the debt line, March 14, 2009, Asia Times Online. CRITERION – October/December 2009 47 Faizullah Khilji 77 See Michael Hudson, Washington cannot call all the shots, Financial Times, June 14 2009 78 See Richard McGregor, China to allow Renminbi trade payments, Financial Times, July 2 2009. 79 See Jamil Anderlini, China to deploy foreign reserves, Financial Times, July 21 2009. Also see for a specific example, Justine Lau and Geoff Dyer, CNPC boosts war chest with $30bn loan, Financial Times, September 9, 2009 80 Remarks made by the Chief Economist, HSBC, cited in Jamil Anderlini, China to deploy foreign reserves, Financial Times, July 21 2009. 81 “China is a country with a record of continuous self-government going back 4,000 years, the only society that has achieved this. One must start with the assumption that they must have learnt something about the requirements for survival, and it is not always to be assumed that we know it better than they do. “It is imperative to realise that we cannot do in China in the 21st century what others thought to do in the 19th, prescribe their institutions for them and seek to organise Asia… …and though we need not agree with every action taken by Chinese leaders, we cannot simply set ourselves up as their critics.” Henry Kissinger cited in Stephen Graubard, Lunch with the FT: Henry Kissinger, Financial Times, May 23 2008. More recently, Kissinger wrote in context of China and the current crisis: “China has a major interest in a stable -- and preferably growing -- U.S. economy. But China also has a growing interest in reducing its dependence on American decisions. Since American inflation as well as deflation have become for China nightmares as grave as they are for America, the two countries face the imperative of coordinating their economic policies. As America’s largest creditor, China has a degree of economic leverage unprecedented in the U.S. experience. At the same time, the quest for widening the scope of independent decision exists in ambivalent combination on both sides. “A number of Chinese moves reflect this tendency. Chinese officials feel freer than they did previously to offer public and private advice to the United States. China has begun to trade with India, Russia and Brazil in their own currencies. The proposal of the governor of China’s central bank to gradually create an alternate reserve currency is another case in point. Many American economists make light of this idea. But it surfaces in so many forums, and China has such a consistent record of pursuing its projects with great patience, that it should be taken seriously. To avoid a gradual drift into adversarial policies, Chinese influence in global economic decision-making needs to be enhanced.” See Henry A Kissinger, Rebalancing relations with China, Washington Post, August 19, 2009. 82 See Peter Garnham, Beijing’s dollar trap, Financial Times, July 30, 2009. 48 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 THE SINO-PAK BOUNDARY AGREEMENT A. G. Noorani* Abstract The agreement of 1963 is, thus, based on a history that stretched to the 19th century. If India had consulted the records in the spirit as Pakistan did, an accord could have been reached in April 1960. For India, as it did for Pakistan in 1963, the McDonald’s Note of 14 March 1899 provides a key to the resolution of the India-China boundary dispute. Author. On 15 July 2009, India’s Minister of State for External Affairs, Preneet Kaur, made a statement in the Lok Sabha in reply to a question on the dimensions of India’s perceived loss of its territory. Both the question and the reply are repeated seasonally. She said India has been raising with China the issue of Pakistan’s illegal cession of part of the territory, under its occupation, in the erstwhile State of Jammu & Kashmir under the China-Pakistan Boundary Agreement of 2 March 1963. She replied: “The Government’s position is that this so-called ‘Boundary Agreement’ is illegal and invalid. This has been reiterated to the Chinese side in the on-going discussions on the boundary question.” Under “the so-called ‘Boundary Agreement’ of 1963, Pakistan illegally ceded 5,180 km. of Indian territory in Pakistan-occupied-Kashmir to China.” Pakistan, she added, was in “illegal and forcible occupation of approximately 78,000 square kms. of Indian territory in Jammu and Kashmir since 1948 while 38,000 square kms. were under the occupation of China.” * A.G. Noorani is an eminent Indian scholar and expert on constitutional issues. A.G. Noorani The Press Trust of India’s report, published in The Tribune of 16 July 2009, faithfully put the words boundary agreement within quotes. One is sick of the Indo-Pak lingo about “Pak-occupied Kashmir” for Azad Kashmir and “Indian-occupied Kashmir” for the rest. The BBC and better informed print media in the West prefer the more sensible word “administered” to describe each half of what is undoubtedly a disputed territory. But one cannot expect any better of either New Delhi or Islamabad in such matters. Fifteen years ago, on 10 August 1994, the Minister’s predecessor in office, R. L. Bhatia had used identical language. Pakistan had “illegally ceded approximately 5,120 sq. kms. of Indian territory” in Kashmir to China (The Hindu; 11 August, 1994, italics mine throughout). Cession is a legal concept with a precise connotation. One looks in vain for any mention of cession in that agreement. It defines, instead, a procedure for reconciling conflicting maps. It is, therefore, an agreement on a boundary settlement a distinction recognized by the Supreme Court of India in a case challenging the Award of the Arbitral Tribunal on the Rann of Kutch Dispute (Maganbhai J. Patel vs. Union of India (1969) 3 Supreme Court Reports, (1970) 3 Supreme Court Cases 400); AIR 1969 S.C. 783). The Court drew a clear distinction between cession of territory and the settlement of a boundary dispute. (H. M. Seervai; Constitutional Law of India; N. M. Tripathi, Bombay; 4th Edn; Vol. 1; p. 311). More recently, on 12 July 2001 the Minister for External Affairs, Jaswant Singh, alleged that “the Shaksgam Valley of the State of Jammu and Kashmir has been illegally and wrongly ceded by Pakistan” (Dawn; 13 July 2001). This statement was made on the eve of the Agra Summit. This narrows down the issue as to whether the Shaksgam Valley was indeed part of the State of J & K. on 15 August 1947. Involved in the controversy are two distinct issues. One concerns the law; namely, Pakistan’s legal capacity to conclude that agreement. The other concerns the history of the area. Was it comprised in the territory of undivided India of which the State was a part? If one were to go by the maps published in the West, one will find, for the most part, a legend indicating that the area was ceded to China. But almost every 50 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement scholar holds that, to the contrary, it was Pakistan which acquired 750 sq. miles of administered territory. This is an issue which the facts of history alone can resolve. The legal issue must not be evaded, however. On this the Indian stand is valid. Pakistan itself does not claim sovereignty over the area in question. The Preamble to the Agreement describes it as “the contiguous areas” – that is, contiguous to “China’s Sinkiang” – “the defence of which is under the actual control of Pakistan.” This is similar to the description and proportions in the Resolutions of the U.N. Commission for India and Pakistan of 13 August 1948 and 6 January 1949 which, both, India and Pakistan accepted. The Resolution of 13 August 1948 mentions in Part II A para 3 that the territory “evacuated by the Pakistani troops will be administered by the local authorities under the surveillance of the Commission.” They did not withdraw because the troops withdrawals schedule provided by India did not comprise “the bulk of its forces” as Para 1 of Part B required. However, the legal status of the two parts of the State is not identical. Josef Korbel, the UNCIP’s Chairman, assured Prime Minister Jawaharlal Nehru on 25 August 1948 that the Resolution will not be “interpreted or applied in practice, so as (a) To bring into question the sovereignty of the Jammu and Kashmir Government over the portion of their territory evacuated by Pakistan.” Korbel described the evacuated territories as those “which are at present under the effective control of the Pakistan High Command.” (UNCIP’s First Report S/1100, Para 79; The Kashmir Question edited by K. Sarwar Hasan with the cooperation of Zubeida Hasan; Pakistan Institute of International Affairs, Karachi; 1966; p. 186). The Plebiscite Resolution of 5 January 1949 (The UNCIP’S Second Report S/1196, para 51; Hasan; p. 212) provides that the Plebiscite Administrator “will be formally appointed to office by the Government of Jammu and Kashmir” (Para 3(a) ) and shall report the result of the plebiscite to, both, the UNCIP “and to the Government of Jammu and CRITERION – October/December 2009 51 A.G. Noorani Kashmir” (Para 9). Article 257 of the Constitution of Pakistan (1973) says: “When the people of the State of Jammu and Kashmir decide to accede to Pakistan, the relationship between Pakistan and that State shall be determined in accordance with the wishes of the people of that State.” Article 203 of the Constitution of 1955 was identically worded. This was not an assertion of sovereignty over that State, but its disavowal. This is Pakistan’s supreme law. Its terms cannot be overridden by an ordinary statute. On 24 August 1974, the Assembly of Azad Kashmir adopted the Azad Jammu and Kashmir Interim Constitution Act, 1974, with the concurrence of the Government of Pakistan. It establishes a Council presided over by the Prime Minister of Pakistan and comprising federal as well as Azad Kashmir’s ministers. In effect the Constitution rivets Azad Kashmir to Pakistan administratively. The issue of sovereignty remains. International law permits a State in de facto and effective possession of an area to conclude agreements of a limited local character to maintain peace and tranquility. It has, however, no right to conclude a definitive boundary treaty. The Sino-Pak agreement is a definitive agreement though it is termed “Provisional.” It provides for the appointment of a Boundary Commission, setting up of boundary pillars and drawing up of protocols; the characteristics of a definitive boundary agreement. Article 6 of the Agreement does not alter the fact for it forecloses any significant revision of its terms or the reopening of the accord: “The two parties have agreed that after the settlement of the Kashmir dispute between Pakistan and India, the sovereign authority concerned will reopen negotiations with the Government of the People’s Republic of China on the boundary, as described in Article Two of the present agreement, so as to sign a formal boundary treaty to replace the present agreement, provided that in the event of that sovereign authority being Pakistan, the provisions of the present agreement and of the aforesaid protocol shall be maintained in the formal boundary treaty to be signed between the People’s Republic of China and Pakistan” (For the text vide China, India, Pakistan, edited by K. Sarwar Hasan; Pakistan Institute of 52 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement International Affairs, Karachi, 1966; pp. 378-383). The Agreement thus envisages that, “sovereign authority” competent to sign a boundary agreement will emerge only after the settlement of the Kashmir dispute. But that authority, if it is India, can do no more than “reopen negotiations” with China “so as to sign a formal Boundary Treaty to replace the present Agreement.” This does not bar revision of its terms explicitly, but the hint of finality is clear. The Press Note issued by the Government of Pakistan on 22 February 1963 announcing Foreign Minister Zulfikar Ali Bhutto’s visit to Peking to conclude the agreement mentioned that “on attaining a common understanding of the boundary alignment, an agreement of a provisional nature will be signed” (ibid., p. 378). The Agreement is anything but “provisional” and was beyond the legal competence of the Government of Pakistan to conclude. Pakistan’s retort does not help it; namely, that nor had India any right to conclude such an agreement in respect of a disputed territory. The UNCIP’s Resolutions treat both parts of the State of J & K and both Governments differently. There is, however, something rather unreal and arid about this undoubted legality. In law the British Parliament could have replaced the Indian Independence Act, 1947, but it could not have regained its sovereignty over the subcontinent. The Privy Council considered precisely such a denouement in respect of the Dominions and gave a sensible answer; “The Imperial Parliament could as a matter of abstract law repeal or disregard the Statute (of Westminster). But that is theory and has no relation to realities” (British Coal Corporation & Ors. vs. The King (1935) Appeal Cases 500). Courts prefer to reckon with “realities” when the “abstract” law runs counter to them. India’s private offers of settlement of Kashmir on the basis of the status quo (1948 – 1955) were followed by Nehru’s offer at a public meeting in New Delhi on 13 April 1956, “I am willing to accept that the question of the part of Kashmir which is under you should be settled CRITERION – October/December 2009 53 A.G. Noorani by demarcating the border on the basis of the cease-fire line. We have no desire to take it by fighting.” The Simla Agreement of 2 July 1972 replaced the cease-fire line with the line of actual control. Indeed the Agreement itself was preceded by the Swaran Singh-Bhutto talks from 26 December 1962 onwards in which India reiterated its proposal offering some 3,000 square miles more in the bargain (Vide the writer’s article Bilateral Negotiations on Kashmir, Criterion, Vol. 1 Vol Oct-Dec. 2006, pp 26-52). The law, however relevant once, is relevant no longer, nearly half a century since the Agreement was signed and confronts us with the issue of its soundness. History alone can answer the question and it does so decisively. It all began when the British created the State of Jammu and Kashmir by the Treaty of Amritsar. In a Collection of Treaties, Engagements and Sanads relating to India and Neighbouring Countries compiled by C.U. Aitchison, Under-Secretary to the Government of India in the Foreign Department, Volume XI of the 1909 edition. He wrote: “The present State of Jammu and Kashmir was created by the British government when Gulab Singh was established as Maharaja under the Treaty of Amritsar.” The British first signed the Treaty of Lahore with the Lahore State on 9 March 1846 after the First Anglo-Sikh war, and acquired “in perpetual sovereignty” inter alia the province of Kashmir. This was in part-payment of the equivalent of “one crore of rupees” which the British demanded as “indemnification for the war expenses.” A week later, on 16 March 1846, the British ceded to Maharaja Gulab Singh the lands it had thus acquired – the territories of Jammu, Kashmir and Ladakh “for the sum of seventy-five lakhs of rupees.”He “acknowledged the supremacy of the British government.” Article 4 said: “The limits of the territories of Maharaja Gulab Singh shall not be at any time changed without concurrence of the British government.” There was reason for this. The Treaty of 16-17 September 1842, between Ladakh and Tibet, one of non-aggression rather than boundary treaty, marked the collapse 54 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement of Zorawar Singh’s ambitious Dogra venture with Tibet and an equally unsuccessful retaliation that brought the Tibetans to Leh. It is in three separate, but essentially identical, versions. One each between Tibet and Ladakh, and another between their principals: the Sikh Darbar and China. The Persian text in Tibet’s possessions reads: “We shall remain in possession of the limits of boundaries of Ladakh and the neighbours subordinate to it, in accordance with the old customs, and there shall be no transgression and no interference in the country beyond the oldestablished frontiers” (emphasis added, throughout). The Tibetan text in Kashmir’s possession was of the same tenor. On 17 October 1842, the Sikhs and the Chinese concluded a treaty which said (Article 1): “That the boundaries of Ladakh and Lhassa shall be constituted as formerly, the contracting parties engaging to confine themselves within their respective boundaries, the one to refrain from any act of aggression on the other” (An ‘Agreed’ Frontier: Ladakh and India’s Northernmost Borders 1846-1947) by Parashotam Mehra: Oxford University Press, 1991; pp. 167-170). The British did not want to be saddled with a war by Gulab Singh’s ambitions. They made earnest efforts to seek a boundary accord with China, five months after the Treaty of Amritsar; they failed. China was weak and suspicious. Two Boundary Commissions were set up. The first comprised R.A. Vans Agnew and Alexander Cunningham. Its task was to determine a boundary between British territory (the districts of Lahoul and Spiti in Himachal Pradesh) and Ladakh. The second, set up in 1847, comprising Cunningham, Henry Strachey and Dr. Thomas Thomson, was to define the boundary between Ladakh and Tibet on the east. The northern boundary divided Kashmir and East Turkestan (now Xinjiang). The first task was accomplished; not so, the second. However, Vans Agnew wrote a memorandum dated 13 May1847, defining a boundary which he thought was clear with the exception of its extremities. Aitchison wrote: “On the appointment of the second commission steps were taken to secure the cooperation of Chinese and Kashmir officials; but no Chinese delegate appeared and the demarcation had to be abandoned. The northern as well as the eastern boundary of the CRITERION – October/December 2009 55 A.G. Noorani Kashmir State is still undefined.” (Aitchison, Vol. 12, 1929; p. 5). Nothing happened thereafter to alter this position till India became independent on 15 August 1947. The Governor-General of India, Henry Hardinge’s letter to China and to the authorities in Tibet, dated 4 August 1846, sought their cooperation “to lay down the boundary” between the two countries. China did not respond. Surveys of the frontier regions proceeded apace. The first was by Henry Strachey of the 1847 Commission. W. H. Johnson of the Trignometrical Survey of India came next (1865), followed by G. W. Hayward (1868) and T.D. Forsyth (1874). A century later, India relied on Johnson’s map since its alignment for the Aksai Chin supported its claim. He was, however, censured by the British; resigned and was made Governor of Ladakh by the Maharaja who was pleased with the map. Col. Walker, Surveyor-General in 1867, ridiculed Johnson’s map as published. It differed from the original. Since official maps had to be printed the question continued to nag as to how the boundary in this sector was to be depicted. Nor could the boundary be left undefined. Russia had begun to expand in Asia. The British were anxious lest its influence reached India’s frontiers. They were careful to have the Wakhan corridor extended to touch China’s territory to avoid a gap there but were anxious also that no gap should exist between the frontiers of India and China in the no-man’s land that existed. China’s passivity did not inhibit cartographic exercises in Calcutta, Simla and London. The details are not relevant. Suffice it to say that two schools of thought emerged. One favoured the Mustagh – Karakoram range, the other the Kuen Lun range further to the north. A large majority favoured the former. The problem was complicated by the ambiguous status of Hunza (or Kanjut as it was also called) as a vassal of China, since at least 1847, if not earlier, and also of Kashmir. The Mir of Hunza concluded a treaty with Kashmir before his death in 1864. In 1891-92 British and Kashmiri forces occupied Hunza. Sir John Ardagh, Directory of Military Intelligence in the War Office in India and formerly Military Secretary to the Viceroy (188856 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement 1894) wrote a Memorandum on New Year’s Day 1897 which set the alarm bells ringing in Calcutta, then capital of the British Raj in India. It was on “The Northern Frontier of India from the Pamirs to Tibet” and it advocated the Kuen Lan line, for strategic reasons, not on the merits, as a desirable boundary (For the text vide Dorothy Woodman; Himalayan Frontiers; Barrie and Rockliff, 1969; pp. 360-363). It was “denounced” by one and all in Calcutta who studied it. The Viceroy Lord Elgin wrote to the Secretary of State for India Lord George F. Hamilton on 23 December 1897 setting out the objections (ibid. pp 364-365). Captain A. H. McMahon, then Political Agent in Gilgit, wrote an elaborate Report, dated 10 May 1898, on the claims of the Kanjut tribe (the people of Hunza) to territory beyond the Hindu Kush in the Tagdumbash Pamir and the Raskam valley. Chinese officials had begun to obstruct the cultivation of the Raskam valley by the Kanjutis. McMahon’s Report, running into 32 paras covering 11 closely printed pages, is a locus classicus on the Hunza boundary. “The first point to be noticed in the history of the Kanjut tribe is its dual vassalage to both China and Kashmir. Both states consider it to be their vassal state. China claims that Hunza has paid tribute to her since the time of the emperor Chien-lung (1736-1796), while the vassalage to Kashmir is first proved by a treaty made by Shah Ghazanfar, Raja of Hunza, at sometime prior to his death in 1864. In Central Asia it is not an uncommon thing for one state to pay tribute to two or more other States.” (Foreign Department Secret Frontier; July 1898, Proceedings 327 Nos. 306-47; National Archives of India, for the text, vide Mehra pp. 94-97). Vassalage to China survived British invasion in 1891. “The boundaries of Tagdumbash, Khunjerab and Raskam, as claimed by the Kanjuts, are the following: The northern watershed of the Tagdumbash Pamir from the Wakhirjrui pass through the Bayik peak to Ilijilga, about a mile above Dafdar, thence across the river to the Zankan nullah, thence through Mazar and over the range to Urok a point on the Yarkand river between Sibjaida and Itakturuk. Thence it runs along the northern CRITERION – October/December 2009 57 A.G. Noorani watershed of the Raskam valley to the junction of the Bazar Darya river and the Yarkand river. From thence southwards over the mountains to the Mustagh river leaving Aghil Dewan Aghil pass within Hunza limits. … On no less than three occasions the Mirs of Wakhan have asked the Mirs of Hunza to allow them to occupy Raskam, and were refused. … “Hunza claims, as stated above, the territory beyond the Hindu Kush. … China has definitely recognized their right to the portion of this tract, including the Taghdumbash Pamir, and the Khunjerab and Oprang Valleys, by acknowledging their right to revenue in those tracts. It matters little what reason or reasons they may assign for this admission – the fact remains, the Hunza rights are acknowledged and recognized with regard to the remaining portion of the above territory, i.e., Raskam, the Chinese have, while verbally denying that it belongs to Hunza, practically admitted their right to it by giving them permission to re-occupy it. The question now about to be settled is that of the terms on which are to occupy it. … “The necessity for contending for a sphere of influence, however limited in area, beyond the Hindu Kush and Mustagh ranges, will, perhaps, not be readily conceded ; but, however strong the arguments may appear at first sight for restricting ourselves to a definite frontier like the Hindu Kush and Mustagh ranges on strategic grounds, it would be wide, I venture to think, before irrevocably committing ourselves to such a frontier, to carefully consider the wisdom of gratuitously surrendering, in doing so, territory which belongs to the people on whom we will have to depend for active assistance in defending that frontier. … I earnestly trust that what I have written above will suffice to show how matters now stand. If our present position on this side of our so-called strategic frontier of the Hindu Kush and Mustagh ranges is to be maintained, it is absolutely necessary to take timely action regarding territory claimed by Hunza beyond those regions.” British concern on the Taghdumbash Pamir was confined to China’s possible cession of the tract to Russia. Raskam was a different preposition. Hunza needed its grazing pastures for its livestock to feed a growing population. 58 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement After prolonged deliberation Elgin sent a dispatch to Hamilton on 27 October 1898 defining the line to be offered to China. “The following is a description of this line: beginning at the north end at the peak Povalo Schveikovski, the line takes a south-easterly direction, crossing the Karachikar stream at Mintaka aghazi, thence proceeding in the same direction till it joins, at the Karachanai Pass, the crest of the main ridge of the Mustagh range which it then follows passing by the Kunjurab Pass and continuing southwards to the peak just north of the Shimshal Pass. At this point the boundary leaves the crest and follows a spur running east approximately parallel to the road from the Shimshal to the Hunza post at Darwaza. The line, turning south through the Darwaza post, crosses the road from the Shimshal Pass at that point and then ascends the nearest high spur and regains the main crests, which the boundary will again follow, passing the Mustagh, Gusherbrum, and the Saltoro Passes to the Karakoram. From the Karakoram Pass the crest of the range runs nearly east for about half a degree and then turn south to a little below the 35th parallel of North Latitude. Rounding then what in our maps is shown as the source of the Karakash, the line of hills to be followed runs north-east to a point – east of Kizil Jilga and from there, in a south-easterly direction follows the Lak Tsung Range until that meets the spur running south from the Kuen Lun Range which has hitherto been shown on our maps as the eastern boundary of Ladakh. This is a little east of 800 east Longitude. …” (Alastair Lamb; The Sino-Indian Border in Ladakh; Australian University Press; 1973; p. 45-46). The line included two tracts beyond the watershed. One was the western end of Taghdumbash, the other was a “small deviation from the main crest of the Mustagh near the Shimshal Pass to Darwaza. This is in accordance with actual possession.” A Kanjuti post at Darwaza existed as late as in 1899. On 14 March 1899 Britain’s Ambassador Sir Claude MacDonald gave a Note to China’s Foreign Office. It was the first time that India offered a precise boundary line to China as a basis for a settlement. It said “It is now proposed by the Indian Government that, for the sake of avoiding any dispute or uncertainty in the future, a clear understanding should be come to with the Chinese Government as to the frontier between CRITERION – October/December 2009 59 A.G. Noorani the two States. To obtain this clear understanding, it is necessary that China should relinquish her shadowy claim to suzerainty over the State of Kanjut. The India Government, on the other hand, will on behalf of Kanjut, relinquish her claims to most of the Taghdumbash and Raskam districts.” He defined the proposed boundary: “Commencing on the little Pamir from the Peak of which the Anglo-Russian Boundary Commission of 1895 ended their work, it runs south-east, crossing the Karachikar stream at Mintaka Aghazi; thence proceeding in the same direction it joins at the Karchenai Pass the crest of the main ridge of the Mustagh range. It follows this to the South, passing by the Kunjerab Pass, and continuing southwards to the peak just north of the Shimsahl Pass. At this point the boundary leaves the crest and follows a spur running east approximately parallel to the road from the Shimshal to the Hunza post at Darwaza. The line turning south through the Darwaza post crosses the road from the Shimshal Pass at that point, and then ascends the nearest high spur, and regains the main crests which the boundary will again follow, passing the Mustagh, Gusherbrun, and Saltoro Passes by the Karakoram. From the Karakoram Pass the crests of the range run east for about half a degree (1001i), and then turn south to a little below the thirty-fifth parallel of north latitude. Rounding then what in our maps is shown as the source of the Karakash, the line of hills to be followed runs north-east to a point east of Kizil Gilga, and from there in a southeasterly direction follows the Lak Tsung range until that meets the spur running south from the K’un-lun range, which has hitherto been shown or maps as the eastern boundary of Ladakh. This is a little east of 800 east longitude.” (ibid.; p. 49). Once again, as in 1846-47, China ignored the offer. In Calcutta the Note’s phrasing was criticized. Britain did not possess sovereignty over the Raskam lands which it could relinquish; only the grazing rights. Matters were brought to a head by a far-sighted Viceroy, Lord Curzon, in a despatch to the Secretary of State for India John Brodrick on 24 March 1904. Curzon reminded Brodrick that the 14 March 1899 Note on the boundary proposal had not been answered by China. He proposed “it would be well to sever the connection between Hunza and China 60 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement without further delay. We should hardly be likely to make anything out of the presence of a few Kanjuti cultivators along the Raskam Daria – even if we did succeed in reinstating them … “We accordingly recommend that a formal notification be made to China that since the Chinese Government have been unable to fulfill their promises to the Mir of Hunza, that State, under the advice of the British Government withdraws from all relations with China, and henceforth will own suzerainty to the Kashmir State and the British Government alone. As regards the boundary between Kashmir and the New Dominion, we strongly recommend that the Chinese Government should be informed that, as they have not shown any reasons for disagreeing with the proposals placed before them in Sir Claude MacDonald’s despatch of the 14th March, 1899, we shall henceforward assume Chinese concurrence and act accordingly.” (ibid.; p. 61). A despatch was prepared and sent by Curzon to Brodrick on 26 January 1905. It responded to his query on effective control of the lands by sending him the correspondence with the Resident in Kashmir. Control over the Taghdumbash was impossible. “The circumstances in regard to the tract about Darwaza are different. Though this lies beyond the watershed, and would probably be claimed by the Chinese, the Mir of Hunza has for many years past maintained there a regular post of four men without, as far as we are aware, any objection being raised by the Chinese. According to information now furnished by the Resident in Kashmir, the people of Shingshal depend for their grazing almost entirely on the valley between the Shingshal Pass and Darwaza. They are in the habit of going twenty miles beyond Darwaza for grazing, and there is a place about five miles beyond Darwaza from which they fetch salt. The inclusion of the Ghorzerab valley, which lies eight miles below the junction of the Shingshal stream with the Mustagh River, and four miles above the point where the Oprang joins the Mustagh, is a matter of considerable importance to the Shingshalis, who mainly depend on their flocks for their livelihood. The Mir of Hunza states that the grazing in the Ghorzerab has been enjoyed since time immemorial by the Shingshalis, and he doubts whether the Kirghiz or Sarikolis even know of the existence of the valley. We consider it very desirable to CRITERION – October/December 2009 61 A.G. Noorani retain this tract on the British side of the boundary line, and we trust that it will be possible to do so, when a settlement is come to with China.” Such an opportunity was not arise till 1963. Finally Curzon sent to Brodrick, on 10 August 1905, a map indicating both the 1899 and the 1905 lines and explained the difference between the two. “The proposals of 1899 contemplated that the line after leaving the crest of the Mustagh range in the vicinity of the Shingshal Pass, should run in an easterly direction, and then turn southwards so as just to include the part of Darwaza within the Hunza frontier. Thereafter it was to continue its southward trend until it regained the main crests. We now recommend that the boundary should run from the Khunjerab Pass south along the main watershed, as far as a point about six miles south-west of the Oprang Pass. At this point the line should leave the main watershed, run due east for about five miles, and then continue in a south-easterly direction until it strikes the Mustagh River at Kuramjilga. The Mustagh River would then form the boundary up to a point about four miles above the junction of the stream from the Shingshal Pass; from this point it would ascend the nearest high spur to the west and regain the main crest, which it would then follow on the lines indicated in Sir Claude Macdonald’s dispatch to the Tsungli Yamen of the 14th March 1899.” (ibid., p. 62). In 1907 when the question of which line to show on the map arose, the Secretary of State for India’s cable of 1 August 1907 to the Viceroy gave clear orders. The map “should indicate the frontier as following the line described in Notification of 1899 to China with addition of the deviation in neighbourhood of Shimshal which was proposed in your secret Despatch No. 153 of August 10th, 1905.” (Mehra; p. 130). Foreign Secretary Denys Bray’s letter of 7 September 1917 to J. E. Shuckburgh, Secretary Political Department, India Office discussed the boundary at length and constitutes an authoritative statement of perceptions of the border in 1917. “These limits however exist only on paper and have been indicated by us not as the result of any treaty or engagement with China nor as 62 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement finally and definitely marking the bounds of our sphere of influence, nor altogether as forming a scientific or strategic border, but partly because they follow a lofty and well-defined watershed and partly in order to assign some limit to China’s indefinite political relations in that neighbourhood. The Chinese Government were invited to accept the line in Sir Claude MacDonald’s dispatch dated the 14 March, 1899, but as nothing resulted, it was proposed in Lord Curzon’s dispatch, No. 70 (Secret-Frontier), dated the 24th March 1904, to inform the Chinese Government that we assumed their concurrence. His Majesty’s Government however demurred in their telegram dated the 10th August 1904. The line was slightly modified in Lord Curzon’s despatches Nos. 20 and 153 (Secret – Frontier), dated 26th January and 10th August 1905. … … We cannot therefore regard ourselves as absolutely bound by a border line which we have ourselves laid down without the concurrence of the other party concerned, which we have already more than once altered without reference to this other party, and the substantial pushing forward of which we have already advocated should a certain chain of circumstances render this desirable. “Hunza’s claims to Raskam by right of conquest were never questioned and were frequently recognized by China up to 1897, when, for political reasons, we advised Hunza to make terms with China for the occupancy of the tract. Since then the Chinese twice cancelled the agreements which gave these lands to Hunza under certain conditions (Lord Curzon’s dispatches Nos. 158 and 21 (Secret-Frontier dated the 17th August, 1899 and 8th February, 1900) and the Mir at the request of the Chinese withdrew from Raskam. The lands remained uncultivated till 1911, when some Kirghiz started cultivation – a step which the Mir regarded as a breach of faith on the part of China, there having been a tacit understanding that if the Karjutis were prevented from cultivating Raskam no one else would be allowed to cultivate there. With our approval the Mir resumed cultivation in 1914 and was advised to hold the lands unless forced by superior numbers to vacate (weekly letter No. 21-M, dated the 27th May 1915). The Chinese Government did not interfere and the Mir’s men have occupied Raskam and cultivated the CRITERION – October/December 2009 63 A.G. Noorani valley ever since. … The position then would appear to be that though the Chinese have deliberately cancelled the agreements which gave the land to Hunza conditionally, their responsible officials have on two occasions acquiesced in Hunza occupying the land unconditionally and that till China definitely asserts the Mir’s actual status with respect to Hunza there is justification for recognizing his de facto possession. “ (Mehra, PP. 225-227).” In 1936, on British advice, the Mir of Hunza stopped sending the annual tribute to China and abandoned his rights beyond the border in Raskam as well as the Taghdumbash Pamir. China retaliated by expelling the Kanjutis from the Shimshal Valley near Darwaza. In the controversy that ensued it was pointed out that the legendary Francis Young Husband’s book The Heart of A Continent published in 1896 supported Hunza’s case. At p. 259 he referred to “a Kanjuti outpost called Darwaza or ‘the gate.’” The Kanjutis continued to enjoy grazing rights across the Shimshal Pass. After independence the Government of India published two White Papers on Indian States in July 1948 and February 1950. Both showed the entire northern boundary from the India-China-Afghan trijunction, the subject of the Sino-Pakistan agreement to the India-China-Nepal trijunction as “undefined,” in contrast to a clear depiction of the McMahon Line in the east. This was the position when India and China signed the Panchsheel Agreement on Tibet on 29 April 1954. In June that year Zhou Enlai came to Delhi. Nehru paid a return visit to China in October. Between the two visits Nehru wrote a fateful document. He first wrote to the Secretary-General of the Ministry of External Affairs on 12 May 1954: “We should establish checkpoints at all disputed points wherever they might be, and our administration should be right up to these borders” (Selected works of Jawaharlal Nehru, Volume 25; page 470). The details of why, how and when the Sino-Indian boundary dispute arose need not detain us. We are concerned with its eruption in the open in 1959, its impact on relations between Pakistan and China, culminating 64 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement in 1963 in the boundary agreement. On 1 July Nehru wrote a 17-para Memorandum in which he gave a fatefully explicit directive. Paras 7 to 10 read thus: “7. All our old maps dealing with this frontier should be carefully examined and, where necessary, withdrawn. New maps should be printed showing our Northern and North Eastern frontier without any reference to any ‘line.’ These new maps should also not state there is any un-demarcated territory. … this frontier should be considered a firm and definite one which is not open to discussion with anybody. There may be very minor points of discussion. Even these should not be raised by us. It is necessary that the system of check-posts should be spread along this entire frontier. More especially, we should have check-posts in such places as might be considered disputed areas. ….” (SW JN. Vol. 26 p. 481). He shut the door to negotiations on the boundary – “not open to discussion with anybody.” India unilaterally revised its official map. The legend “boundary undefined” in the Western (Kashmir) and middle sectors (Uttar Pradesh) in the official maps of 1948 and 1950 were dropped in the new map of 1954. A firm clear line was shown, instead. Accordingly, when, in response to Nehru’s demarche on the maps on 14 December 1958, Zhou Enlai squarely raised the border issue on 23 January1959, Nehru’s letter of 22 March 1959 cited the Treaty of 1842 to assert that the boundary was a settled issue. Zhou’s letter of 23 January 1959 offered “to take a more or less realistic attitude towards the McMahon Line.” He offered an overall settlement and was concerned with the boundary “particularly its western section.” Fundamentally, Zhou said “All this shows that border disputes do exist between China and India.” Nehru’s reference to the Treaty of 1842 was historically incorrect. That was a treaty of non-aggression after a war; it did not define a boundary. If it had, the British would not have proposed negotiations in 1846-47, made the offer of 14 March 1899 and racked their brains on where the line should be drawn. Nehru’s reply of 22 March 1959 was sent, two months after Zhou’s letter of 23 CRITERION – October/December 2009 65 A.G. Noorani January 1959, evidently after full deliberation in which the Historical Division of the Ministry of External Affairs was also involved. Beneath the historical error lay his riposte to Zhou “there is no room for doubt about our frontiers as shown in the published maps.” This reply based on his decision in 1954, foreclosed compromise. (Notes, Memoranda and Letters exchanged and Agreements signed between the Government of India and China 1954-1959, White Paper I, Ministry of External Affairs Government of India; 1959; pp. 52-57 for both letters). Nehru’s initial demarche of 14 December 1958 centred on the McMahon Line in the eastern sector, which was drawn up in 1914. Zhou’s reply of 23 January 1959 raised the issue of the western sector in the Ladakh province of Jammu and Kashmir; precisely it was Aksai Chin. “The Sinkiang – Tibet highway built by our country in 1956 runs through that area.” (ibid. p. 53). Contrary to the stand he took in his letter of 22 March 1959, on as many as six occasions later in the year Jawaharlal Nehru admitted that Aksai China was very much a territory in dispute. 28 August 1959: “The Aksai Chin area, that is an area about parts of which, if I may say so, it is not quite clear what the position is.” 31 August 1959: “It is Indian territory and we claim it so because we think that the weight of evidence is in our favour, maps, etc., but the Chinese produce their own maps, equally old, which are in their favour.” 4 September 1959: “So far as the corner of the Aksai Chin area is concerned, that has been claimed by the Chinese as their territory and I believe in their maps too, not the new maps, but the old maps, that is shown as their territory. That is disputed and there are two viewpoints about that…” 4 September 1959: “The actual boundary of Ladakh with Tibet was not very carefully defined. It was defined to some extent by British officers who went there, but I rather doubt if they did any careful 66 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement survey.” 10 September 1959: “We have always looked upon the Ladakh area as a different area, if I may say so, some vaguer area so far as the frontier is concerned because the exact line of the frontier is not at all clear as in the case of the McMahon Line … Nothing can be a more amazing folly than for two great countries like India and China to go into a major conflict and war for the possession of a few mountain peaks, however beautiful the mountain peaks might be, or some area which is more or less uninhabited.” 12 September 1959: “This place Aksai China area is in our maps undoubtedly. But I distinguish it completely from other areas. It is a matter for argument as to what part of it belongs to us and what part of it belongs to somebody else. It is not at all a dead clear matter … I cannot go about doing these things in a manner which has been challenged not today but for a hundred years. It has been challenged to (sic) the ownership of this strip of territory. That particular area stands by itself. It has been in challenge all the time…. I cannot say what parts of it may not belong to us, and what parts may. The point is there has never been any delimitation there in that area and it has been a challenged area.” (Prime Minister on Sino-Indian Relations VOl. I, Part I, MEA; 1961; pp. 84, 99, 105, 119-120, 134-135, 148-149, respectively). When Zhou met Nehru in New Delhi in April 1960, he was prepared to yield on the McMahon Line if Nehru conceded the Aksai Chin. Nehru refused. Already by then China had recognized the Line, in so far as it extended to Burma in the boundary agreement with Burma on 25 January 1960. At the first meeting of the summit on 20 April, Zhou told Nehru: “The one common feature in the boundary between China and Burma and India is the presence of the McMahon Line. We stated that we do not recognize the McMahon Line but that we were willing to take a realistic view with Burma and India.” At the press conference in New Delhi on 25 April, Zhou defined CRITERION – October/December 2009 67 A.G. Noorani the boundary in the west as “the line which runs from the Karakoram Pass south eastward roughly along the watershed of the Karakoram Mountains to the Kongka Pass.” He also said: “China has no boundary dispute with Sikkim and Bhutan.” Zhou formulated these six points at the press conference: “(I) There exist disputes with regard to the boundary between the two sides. (II) There exists between the two countries a line of actual control up to which each side exercise administrative jurisdiction. (III) In determining the boundary between the two countries certain geographical principles such as watersheds, river valley and mountain passes, should be equally applicable to all sectors of the two sides. (IV) A settlement of the boundary question between the two countries should take into account the national feelings of the two peoples towards the Himalayas and the Karakoram Mountains. (V) Pending a settlement of the boundary question between the two countries through discussions, both sides should keep to the line of actual control and should not put forward territorial claims as preconditions, but individual adjustments may be made. (VI) In order to ensure tranquility on the border so as to facilitate the discussions, both sides should continue to refrain from patrolling along all sectors of the boundary.” These were, in fact, an elaboration of five points he had put forth to Nehru on 22 April in private after two days of sterile debate on the rights and the wrongs. The six points were in fact an elaboration of four because a crucial point was omitted. “(IV) Since we are going to have friendly negotiations, neither side should put forward claims to an area which is no longer under its administrative control. For example, we made no claim in the eastern sector to areas south of the McMahon Line, but India made such claims in the western sector. It is difficult to accept such claims and the best thing is that both sides do not make such territorial claims. Of course, there are individual places which need to be re-adjusted individually; but that is not a territorial claim.” He repeated them in crisp formulations in a meeting with Nehru the next day as forming “a common ground.” They were: “(i) our boundaries are not delimited and, therefore, there is a dispute about those; (ii) 68 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement however, this [sic. there?] is a line of actual control both in the eastern sector as well as the western sector and also in the middle sector; (iii) geographical features should be taken into account in settling the border. One of the principles would be watershed and there would be also other features, like valleys and mountain passes, etc. These principles should be applicable to all sectors, eastern, western and middle; (iv) each side should keep to this line and make no territorial claims. This does not discount individual adjustments along the border later; (v) national sentiments should be respected. For both countries a lot of sentiment is tied around the Himalayas and the Karakoram.” Nehru’s approach was radically different. “We should take each sector of the border and convince the other side of what it believes to be right” – an impossible exercise in international politics. It is unreal even in domestic politics. On the fourth point, renunciation of territorial claims by both, Nehru responded on 24 April: “Our accepting things as they are would mean that basically there is no dispute and the question ends there; that we are unable to do.” Nehru’s stand was unsupported by the facts of history; was politically unwise and diplomatically disastrous. Two Chinese pronouncements should have alerted India to the course events later took. One was a Statement by Ambassador Pan Tsu-li to the Foreign Secretary Subimal Dutt on 16 May 1959 couched in language so unusual, with proverbs and all, as to suggest Mao Tsetung’s draftsmanship: “We cannot have two centres of attention, nor can we take friend for foe … Friends! It seems to us that you too cannot have two fronts. Is it not so? If it is, here then lies the meeting part of our two sides.” He ended with his “best regards” to Nehru who replied in a manner appropriate to his Headmaster at Harrow. On 23 May, Dutt read out a statement, drafted by Nehru, upbraiding the Ambassador for breach of “diplomatic usage and the countries due to friendly countries.” He sharply attacked China (White Paper I; pp. 73-78 for both statements). The other pronouncement was direct. Zhou’s delineation of China’s boundary began from the Karakoram Pass eastwards. He pointedly CRITERION – October/December 2009 69 A.G. Noorani omitted the boundary to the west of the Pass. In 1960 Chinese officials refused to discuss this sector with their Indian counterparts at Peking on 27 June 1960. Chang Wen-Chin, Director First Asian Department in China’s Foreign Ministry interrupted, a junior colleague to make his stand clear; “It is necessary for both sides to adopt a matter of fact attitude and avoid serious political questions unrelated to our work.” (Parshotam Mehra; Negotiating With the Chinese 1846-1987; Reliance Publishing House, New Delhi, 1989; p. 222) A Sino-Pak settlement was very much on the cards. It was not China which pressed Pakistan for a settlement. On the contrary it dragged its feet. It obviously preferred to settle with India first. It was Pakistan who pressed for an accord, not to forge an alliance with China – and thus wreck its alliance with the United States – but to profit by India’s experience and secure peace and tranquility in the area. It had been disturbed by China’s patrols. On 23 October 1959, President Ayub Khan disclosed at a press conference that Pakistan’s Foreign Office had received a map showing certain areas of Pakistan as part of China. Pakistan would therefore, in due course, approach China “for a peaceful settlement of the border question by demarcating the northern frontiers.” (Dawn, 24 October 1959, Vide S.M. Burke; Pakistan’s Foreign Policy; Oxford University press, 1973; p. 290 and Altaf Gauhar; Ayub Khan, Sang-e-Meel Publications, Lahore; 1993; pp. 234-5). Ayub Khan’s memoirs record how and why he went about this task in some detail. In August and October 1959 there were armed clashes between the troops of India and China in Longju, in the east, and at the Kongka Pass in Ladakh, respectively. Ayub Khan was concerned at the risks of patrolling. “A similar situation could arise on our own undemarcated borders in the Sinkiang and Baltistan areas. We had been receiving reports from time to time that Chinese patrols were coming up to Shamshal. There had been no shooting incident, but the Chinese had driven away some cattle in certain areas. I thought it might be a 70 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement good idea to approach the Chinese and suggest to them that the border be demarcated. After all, neither side had anything to gain by leaving the border undefined. I inquired whether any attempt had been made in the past to demarcate this border and I was shown the relevant maps and papers. Some attempts had been made by the British. I asked our experts to mark what from our point of view constituted the actual line of control on the map, and this was done. We also found that we could legitimately claim control up to a point opposite the Shamshal Pass. The people of Shamshal village could, according to custom, take their cattle for grazing in a fertile valley on the other side of the Pass where the Chinese had established a couple of posts. They also used to get salt, a rare and valuable commodity, from the soil in that area. I mentioned this matter at a Cabinet meeting, but the feeling was that the Chinese were unlikely to respond to any suggestion for the demarcation of the border. I felt that there would be no harm in preparing a memorandum and getting in touch with the Chinese authorities. This happened towards the end of 1959. “There was no response from the Chinese government for a long time. …. On my return from the United States in December 1961, the Chinese Ambassador came to see me. He asked for our support for the proposition that the Chinese entry into the United Nations should be decided on the basis of a simple majority rather than a two-thirds majority. I asked him about our suggestion of demarcating the undefined border between China and Pakistan. He said that that was a very complicated matter. I told him that if border demarcation was a very complicated matter, China’s admission to the United Nations was even more complicated. I suggested to him that we should look at the two problems on merit regardless of whether they were simple or complicated. We should be prepared to do what was right and sensible. … “Our Foreign Minister, Mr. Manzur Qadir, later took up the matter with the Chinese Ambassador and asked him pointedly whether they were refusing to discuss the demarcation of the border because of the disputed nature of the Kashmir territory. The Foreign Minister got the impression that that was the real reason, and that China at that time did not want to get involved in another argument with India. We were CRITERION – October/December 2009 71 A.G. Noorani able to explain to the Chinese government that all we were asking for was the identification of the line between two stated points. The area to the north of the line would constitute Chinese territory; the status of the area to the south of the line did not have to be determined. China would be responsible for the defence of the area north of the line and the defence of the area south of the line would be Pakistan’s responsibility. Soon after this the Chinese told us that they were prepared to discuss the problem of demarcation of the border with us. The two sides nominated their teams of experts to examine the problem. … “Formal discussion with the Chinese started soon after. The Chinese were very difficult in the beginning, but once they realized that we were there not to outwit them but to seek an honourable solution their attitude changed. They produced a map on the basis of which they claimed certain areas on our side of the actual line of control, the valley of Khanjarab and some areas near K-2. Eventually they agreed to the actual line of control as shown on our map and it was adopted as the demarcation line with certain marginal adjustments. The watershed of the Indus Basin rivers was shown on our side and the watershed of the rivers of Yakang and certain adjoining areas on their side. There was some argument about K-2 and it was agreed that the line of control should be put right on top of K-2, thus letting the mountain peak belong to both sides as had been done for Mount Everest with Nepal. Once we had agreed on the demarcation line, aerial surveys were undertaken and the whole matter was settled amicably and without any difficulty. “We raised the question of the grazing ground which covered several hundred square miles on the other side of the Shamshal Pass. We proved to the Chinese representative that this area had been traditionally under the use of the people of Shamshal and that if they were denied access to the area it would cause them great hardship. The Chinese said they would check with the people of Sinkiang but agreed, in principle, that the matter be resolved on merit. They finally agreed to let us have the area.” (Friends not Masters; Oxford University Press; 1967; pp. 161164). Pakistan proposed border talks on 23 October 1959, Foreign Minister 72 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement Manzur Qadir announced on 15 January 1961 that China ”had agreed in principle to the demarcation of its border with Pakistan.” This was over a year after Pakistan had approached China for talks on the matter. It took another year and more for China to agree to conduct formal negotiations. On 28 March 1961 Pakistan sent a Note formally proposing talks. China replied only on 27 February 1962. An announcement was made by both sides on 3 May 1962 apparently as a result of Ayub Khan’s talk with China’s Ambassador in December 1961. The two sides affirmed that “the boundary between China’s Sinkiang and the contiguous areas, the defence of which is under the actual control of Pakistan, has never been formally delimited and demarcated in history. With a view to ensuring tranquility along the border and the growth of good-neighbourly relations between the two countries, they have agreed to conduct negotiations so as to attain an agreed understanding of the location and alignment of this boundary and to sign on this basis an agreement of a provisional nature.” Maps were exchanged in July 1962. Talks were started in Peking on 12 October 1962, “Upon reaching agreed views on the procedural matters concerning the talks, the representatives of the two parties exchanged plain topographical maps, which were checked technically by map experts of both parties and on which an agreed understanding was attained. Following that, the two parties exchanged maps depicting the boundary line and held formal meetings as well as friendly consultations in a spirit of equality, cooperation, mutual understanding and mutual agreement. And now an agreement in principle has been reached on the location and alignment of the boundary actually existing between the two countries.” (China, India, Pakistan; edited by K. Sarwar Haroon, Pakistan Institute of International Relations, Karachi; 1966; pp 366-367). The de facto boundary was legitimized but with significant changes. China treaded the path cautiously after its experience with India’s stand on boundary talks. It indicated on 27 February 1962 its readiness to conclude with the Government of Pakistan “an agreed comprehension of the location and alignment of this boundary so as to prevent the tranquility on the border from being adversely affected on account of misunderstanding.” The note made it clear that any agreement that CRITERION – October/December 2009 73 A.G. Noorani might be reached between China and Pakistan would be of a provisional nature on the location and alignment “actually existing between the two countries” pending the settlement of the Kashmir dispute. In his report to Ayub (24 October, 1962), the Pakistan Ambassador gave his evaluation of the position China was likely to adopt during the boundary talks. The Chinese, he indicated, would treat the traditional customary boundary as the de facto boundary line.” (Altaf Gauhar; pp. 236-238). A former Foreign Secretary of Pakistan, who had also served as Ambassador to China disclosed to this writer that China sought to know the basis on which Pakistan proposed to determine the boundary. Pakistan’s response clinched matters. The basis would be the facts of history and existing realities. If India had adopted such a stand the boundary dispute would have been settled in April 1960. It is hard to think of any other boundary dispute which is as easily susceptible to a fair compromise with each having its vital, non-negotiable interest securely under its own control – India has the McMahon Line and China the road through the Aksai Chin. Nehru’s reaction to these developments was inconsistent and shortsighted. He expected Pakistan to adopt India’s stand that the boundary was defined; ergo, no dispute existed. He came to Pakistan to sign the Indus Waters Treaty and had extended discussions with Ayub Khan at Murree on 21 September 1960 after their talks in Karachi. Ayub Khan records: “He asked me whether we had approached the Chinese to demarcate the border and I informed him of the position. He wanted me to show him the map on which we were basing our claim and wanted to know exactly the area to which our claim extended. I told him quite frankly that we had no intention of claiming any area which we did not honestly believe to be covered by the actual line of control as determined by our experts. We might ask for certain areas beyond the line of control to provide facilities for the local population. 74 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement “Mr. Nehru asked me to let him have a copy of the map and I agreed to this in principle. As soon as he went back to India, he started criticizing us for having approached the Chinese to demarcate the border. He mentioned the map I had shown him and said that we did not even know where the border was and that we were acting in a childish manner” (Ayub Khan; p. 163). Nehru’s version corroborates this, though not quite the language Nehru was said to have used. Shortly after his return to Delhi, Nehru said at his press conference on 18 January 1961 “The fact of the matter is, so far as I know, Pakistan does not know very much about that border to which you refer. It is a remote border for them on the west of the Karakoram and their knowledge of that is extremely limited.” He said also, “In our opinion, we have nothing to negotiate, our minds are quite clear.” (PMSIR; Vol. II, Press Conferences; pp. 100-101). In a speech in the Rajya Sabha on 3 May 1962, Nehru elaborated on the theme “In Murree and Pindi I thought that I might discuss this Chinese question with President Ayub Khan and let him know – I did not want to discuss so much on our border – what the position was on that part of the Kashmir border on which they were at the present moment; having occupied a part of Kashmir, they have to face the Chinese. So I told them of our maps, I showed them our confidential maps as to where we thought the Chinese were and where we were, and asked them what the position of the Chinese was on their side of the border. “Well, I did not get much help from them because I found they knew less than I did even on that side of border. But we did discuss it, and it is most surprising that the Foreign Secretary who, I think, was present at that time, said that he knew nothing about those matters at all.” (PMSIR, Vol. 1 Indian Parliament, Part II; p. 87). On 7 May 1962 Nehru spoke at length, after the announcement of boundary talks between Pakistan and China on 3 May “the acceptance by the Government of Pakistan of the Chinese Government’s view that this boundary has never been delimited and demarcated in history and their willingness to demarcate it now is – I do not know – sounds CRITERION – October/December 2009 75 A.G. Noorani rather an opportunist attempt to take advantage of a particular position, even though this might involve changes in the well-known boundary which has been known to exist for a long time. Obviously in these high mountain ranges boundaries are not demarcated on the ground. There are some places which have not been reached by the human beings, some mountain peaks, and others have been reached occasionally. Therefore, they are not demarcated. They are divided by various features and various understandings like watershed, etc. We have made it perfectly clear even in the past both to the Pakistan Government and the Chinese Government about those parts of the frontier now in possession of Pakistan that we would not recognize any arrangements arrived at between them and Pakistan. I have stated the other day in the other House that a little more than a year and a half ago when I was in Pakistan I discussed this question or I raised this question with President Ayub Khan with his Foreign Minister and others present in a friendly way, because China was encroaching upon us and part of that boundary was at present under occupation of Pakistan. I wanted to know exactly where the Chinese were on that part of the boundary, and if they had given any trouble to Pakistan, what steps Pakistan had taken to meet the situation. There was an area – Hunza area – and the Mir of Hunza claimed it: he had called upon the Pakistan Government – and protested to the Pakistan Government that the Chinese had occupied some grazing areas there belonging to his original State, Hunza, which is part of Kashmir territory. “This matter had come up before us too before, and we had examined all the old papers and we had found that this was an old dispute between the then Tibet Government and the Government of India through the Kashmir Government. The British Government, after due enquiry, had not accepted the Mir of Hunza’s claim to that particular grazing area, and therefore had refused to intervene in this matter. That refers to a particular spot, the grazing area, and not to the whole frontier… “I wanted to know what Pakistan’s attitude was in this matter. Therefore, I raised it with President Ayub Khan and told him of the old papers we had. He agreed with that – that particular area – the grazing area of Hunza. He said we cannot lay claim to that in the circumstances 76 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement when the British Government had given it up. “Nevertheless, the major question remained about the border there, - what the Chinese authorities were doing to it. It seemed to me that both sides were not fully cognizant of the facts of the situation. Such facts as we knew were a little more than they knew. We knew that area. We discussed it. I showed them our maps and later they sent their maps which slightly, not much… “Anyhow, I have given this past history just to keep the House informed, that we treated the Pakistan Government in a friendly way in this matter because we thought that any action which they might take should be in line with the action we were taking in regard to this border, and should not conflict. Unfortunately for various reasons they have come to this agreement with the Chinese which is an interference on both sides with India’s legal rights in the matter.” (ibid. pp. 89-91). Nehru clearly wanted Pakistan to emulate India – and refuse to negotiate. In a statement in Parliament on the agreement on 5 March 1963 Nehru cited the very maps on which he had poured scorn to say “If one goes by these maps, Pakistan has obviously surrendered over 13,000 square miles of territory” – which, never belonged to it or to undivided India at all. He added “Running south of the traditional alignment the Pakistan line of actual control surrendered about 1,600 square miles to China” – surrendered is fundamentally is different from “ceded.” Waived is a more appropriate word as we shall see. (Sino Pakistan “Agreement” March 2, 1963; Some Facts; External Publicity Division, MEA 1963; pp. 32-34). This excellent brochure contains the texts of the protest notes exchanged between India and Pakistan and between India and China. It is unnecessary to study the polemics especially since they are conducted in execrable English. However, a Note on the “Historical basis for traditional frontiers of north Kashmir with Sinkiang (West of the Karakoram Pass)” is noteworthy for its inconsistencies and inaccuracies. “Both the upper valley of the Khunjerab river and the upper valley of the Shaksgam river, lying south of the Aghil mountains, have always been parts of Hunza. CRITERION – October/December 2009 77 A.G. Noorani The people of Hunza exercised various rights including cultivation and pasturage and grazing in this area. The Shimshalis of the Darwaza area in particular used the entire area up to the Shaksgam for grazing and extracted salt at various places in the valley. On the other hand, no one from China had ever used this area. The Mir of Hunza exercised authority in this region, maintained posts and collected revenue. … The Mir of Hunza, who became the feudatory of the Maharaja of Kashmir in about 1864, had been utilising regions north of the traditional boundary for grazing and cultivation. In some British maps a colour wash had been used reaching further north into Sinkiang and covering this area north of the traditional frontier where such grazing and cultivation took place. The British Government, however, recognized the correct traditional frontier in this area and in 1899 authorised Sir Claude McDonald, their Minister in Peking, to make proposals to the Chinese Government for a realignment. These compromise proposals envisaged the inclusion within Hunza of the Taghdumbash region, north of both Hunza and the traditional alignment, where the Mir had exercised grazing rights, in return for concessions south of the alignment between the Aghil and the Karakoram ranges. The Chinese Government refused to enter into such an agreement and preferred to abide by the traditional alignment. “In 1927 as a result of an examination on the ground by officials of the Government of India, it was reaffirmed that administration only extended up to the traditional boundary, and consequently in 1936 the Government of India asked the Mir to abandon his grazing rights in the Taghdumbash area.” The rectification of the alignment was duly carried out in all maps published by the Government of India after 1947. At the talks of the Officials of China and India in 1960 the Chinese side presented a map which showed their claim line as running well to the south of the traditional alignment and including an area of about 3,700 square miles of Kashmir. The Chinese, however, refused to discuss this matter on the plea that this area was not under India’s control. It was pointed out to the Pakistan Government that India had no claims to territories north of the traditional frontier in Sinkiang, but the Government of Pakistan continued thereafter to show an alignment far 78 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement north into Sinkiang, including about 11,000 square miles of territory. This alignment admitted that the frontier was “Undefined.” (ibid. pp. 1- 2). The record shows that the Mir had grazing rights while Curzon unilaterally created a loop over the Shimshal Pass. The New Delhi correspondent of the Times (London) then was Neville Maxwell. In two despatches he threw much light on why Pakistan revised its out-dated maps. Since they are hard to come by, they are quoted here in extenso: “Analysis of the terms of the border treaty shows, however, that in fact both sides have made concessions. The area in dispute from the overlapping borders shown on Pakistan’s and China’s maps was about 3,400 square miles. The compromise border now agreed upon leaves about two-thirds of it (2,050 square miles) on China’s side; but while Pakistan has given up only claims on maps. China will be withdrawing her frontier forces and administration from about 750 square miles. “The Chinese and Pakistan claims diverged from a point just south of the Khunjerab pass. According to China’s maps, the border there should run almost due south to the Karakoram mountains before turning eastward; Pakistan’s maps showed the border running roughly south-east from that point to the sharp bend in Mustagh (or Shaksgam) river. The agreed border will follow Pakistan’s claim, thus including in Pakistan territory to the west of the Mustagh river, where it bends sharply around the town of Sokh Bulaq. “In order to accommodate Pakistan in her desire for that pocket. China has diverged from the principle of the watershed on which she has based her claim in this area. For a stretch west of the Sokh Bulaq bend the compromise border will be the Muztagh river which runs into Yarkand river in Sinkiang. Then from the point at which the first significant tributary joins the Muztagh river the compromise border drops abruptly south to rejoin the Karakoram watershed. “It is at the point here the compromise border meets the Muztagh river where Pakistan begins to give up the claimed territory in her part of the compromise. Pakistan’s maps (which were given to her by India CRITERION – October/December 2009 79 A.G. Noorani in 1960) show the border crossing the river at that point picking up another crest line and running through Aghil Pass. “Unless the borders not yet formally delimited in these remote and desolate marches are to be considered precise and absolute, the settlement now reached between Pakistan and China would seem to be an equitable compromise. Pakistan was able to enter into these negotiations free of passionate rhetorical commitments to which the Indian Government has been tied since 1959. “Indian criticism today of Pakistan’s “surrender” of territory ironically and even tragically underlines the fact that just such a settlement as this would have been fully acceptable to India before the news of China’s furtive and deceitful occupation of territory which Peking knew that India claimed aroused a cry of “aggressive” here.” (The Times, 4 March 1963). In his book India’s China War published in 1970 Maxwell abandoned his assessment “of China’s furtive and deceitful occupation of territory which Peking knew that India claimed.” Two days later he explained why Nehru alleged that Pakistan surrendered more than 13,000 sq. miles of territory to China. “This suggestion is based on the fact that Pakistan was slower than India in correcting the official maps. In 1927 the British Government of India decided that a claim of the Maharaja of Kashmir that his domains were bounded to the north by the northern watershed of the Kuen Lun ranges was insupportable, but did not correct the survey of India maps accordingly. Finding that decision in the files after independence, the Indian Government acted upon it and corrected their maps. “As late as 1962, it appears from Mr. Nehru’s statement, Pakistan continued to use the maps showing the Maharaja’s old claim as the international frontier. According to these maps, as the Prime Minister pointed out, Pakistan would have surrendered about 13,000 square miles; but, in fact, Pakistan began negotiations on the border with China from the basis of corrected maps.” (The Times 6 March, 1963). Every reputable work on the subject relies on this report which was published much before the MEA’s brochure on the agreement which also referred 80 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement to the revision of the maps in 1927. W.F. Van Eekelen, a Dutch diplomat who served in New Delhi and London, delved into the archives in both places to write an excellent study Indian Foreign Policy and the Border Dispute With China (Martinus Nijhoff; The Hague, 1966) concurs with the view that while Pakistan waived claims on maps, China withdrew from 750 square miles (p. 131); (Vide also R.R.V. Prescott; Map of Mainland Asia by Treaty; Melbourne University Press, 1975; p. 230-237). Dr. B. N. Goswami of the Universities of Calcutta and North Burdwan opined, against the “patriotic” consensus that “to a limited but knowledgeable section of people, the agreement appears to be just and fair to both sides. … Neutral observers do not find much substance in the Indian allegations of Pakistani concessions to China” (B. N. Goswami, Pakistan and China; Allied Publishers; 1971; pp. 89-90). Significantly a few weeks after the announcement on 3 May 1962 of an agreement to commence negotiations, Major-General N.A.M. Raza was appointed Ambassador to China with full powers to negotiate a boundary agreement (Pakistan-China boundary agreement; Department of Films and Publications, Government of Pakistan, Karachi; August 1963; p. 5). In an interview in Peking on 8 April 1963 Raza made an authoritative exposition rich in details (Pakistani’s News Digest; Karachi, 15 April 1963, Vol. II No. 8). He rejected India’s charge that Pakistan ceded about 2,000 square miles Shaksgam Valley in the Tarim River Drainage System across the Karakorum Range in deciding the boundary question with China. The line, which Sir Claude McDonald suggested, followed the main watershed of the Karakorum Range dividing the Indus River System on the south from the Tarim River system in the north, except that it included 455 square miles of the western portion of the Taghdumbash Pamir and 470 sq. miles of Shimshal Valley, also in the Tarim River Drainage System, in the British India territory. CRITERION – October/December 2009 81 A.G. Noorani The McDonald proposal did not, however, include the 2,000 square miles of Shaksgam Valley, defined by India as lying between the Agil Range and the Karakorum Ranger in the Tarim River Drainage System. In any case the Chinese Government did not accept the proposal and never replied to the British communication. If the British proposal were examined, it would be very clear that the British made absolutely no mention of the Shaksgam valley while pitching their claim on the Tagdambash Pamir. Besides, the portion of Tagdambash claimed by the British was 455 square miles, while the area of the Shaksgam Valley is about 2,000 square miles. Following, however, of the non-acceptance of the McDonald proposal by China, the British Government continued correspondence with British India concerning the boundary which it would be best to propose to China. Subsequently, another proposal was made by the Political Agent of Gilgit, Maj. Galbraith, in 1939, which could not be presented to the Government of China due to the outbreak of World War-II. According to this proposal, Gujrab Valley and the Kutchin Salt Mines were added to the British claim of 1899 and the claim to the Tagdambash Pamir was again left out, as already suggested by the Viceroy in 1905. From these facts, he was clear, Gen. Raza said that: “Firstly, the original claim, which the British made on a portion of the Tagdambash Pamir in 1899, had definitely been dropped. Secondly Shaksgam Valley was never included in various British claims and on the contrary when the British wanted to go to the Shaksgam Valley for survey, they asked for a visa from the Chinese Government; and consequently there was never any idea of exchanging the Shaksgam Valley for Tagdambash Pamir. India did not claim the Tagdsambash Pamir in the line it gave to China during their talks in 1960. Raza asserted that the boundary now agreed upon between China and Pakistan coincided exactly with the line which covered the maximum territory which the British were to claim as late as 1939. On 28 November 1998 Agha Shahi, former Foreign Minister said, 82 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement as one involved in the negotiations, that a study of the archives failed to reveal credible evidence of any plausible claim to territory beyond the watershed of the Karakoram mountain range (News; 29 November 1998). The scholar Alastair Lamb subjected the Agreement to a rigorous analysis based on historical records. (The Sino-Pakistani Boundary Agreement of 2 March 1963; Australian Outlook; Vol. 18, No. 3; December 1964; pp. 299-312). The Agreement reconciles conflicting maps. Article 2 defined “the alignment of the entire boundary line” between the two in detail noting the discrepancies between the two maps. Para III of Article 2 read: “In view of the fact that the maps of the two sides are not fully identical in their representation of topographical features, the two parties have agreed that the actual features on the ground shall prevail, so far as the location and alignment of the boundary described in Section I is concerned; and that they will be determined as far as possible by joint survey on the ground.” A Joint Boundary Demarcation Commission was to be set up to conduct surveys and delineate the boundary line on jointly preferred maps. A protocol would be drawn up to define the agreed boundary with agreed maps attached to it (Art. 4). Lamb drew up a sketch map on which he plotted the 1963 boundary, based on the definition in Article 2, as well as the line offered to China in 1899 and opined that “the 1899 line coincided for much of its length with the 1963 alignment…. the 1963 line concedes to Pakistan some territory north of the Shimshal Pass which would have been excluded from British India by the 1899 line; but the tract in question was brought on to the British side by the modification of 1905. .. Thus by 1905 the British had accepted a boundary with Sinkiang which coincided almost exactly … with the alignment negotiated in 1963. … The 1899 line, by definition, began at the point on the Russo-Afghan border where the Anglo-Russian Boundary Commission left off in 1895. Its starting point, in fact, marked a meeting place of British, Chinese, Russian and CRITERION – October/December 2009 83 A.G. Noorani Afghan territory. To connect the terminal point of the 1895 Boundary Commission with the main Karakoram watershed, however, involved running the line north of the watershed and including within British India territory which the Indian Government had no intention of ever administering. By the end of the First World War the western end of the border had been pulled back on maps, as it always had been in fact, to the main watershed crossed by the Kilik and Mintaka Pasases. … therefore, the 1963 boundary coincides with the alignment in practice and in theory of the British Indian border from at least 1918 until 1947 and the transfer of power.” In 1937 or 1938 the Chinese authorities in Kashgar went so far as to send a patrol right up to Shimshal to expel cultivators who were subjects of the Mir of Hunza. During the Second World War the Indian Government evidently concluded that it was pointless to maintain the fiction of Hunza rights beyond the watershed, except for the Shimshal tract; and the Mir was persuaded to abandon his rights in the Taghdumbash Pamir and Raskam in exchange for a Knighthood. “By the time of the transfer of power in 1947, therefore, the Indian Government had abandoned any claims north of the Karakoram watershed, except in Shimshal; and had it been necessary in 1947 to draw a line which represented the real limit of the British Indian Empire here, that line would certainly have followed exactly the same alignment as did the line of the 1963 Sino-Pakistani boundary agreement.” Lamb wrote a further study on a wider canvas in 1973 entitled The Sino-Indian Border in Ladakh (Australian National University Press, Canberra). He held that in the agreement of 1963 “the area of Pakistani occupation has been increased considerably when compared to the 1898 proposals” (p. 47). The agreement “was little more than a confirmation of the western part of the 1899 line as it was unilaterally modified by Lord Curzon’s government in 1905” (p. 74). Curzon’s modification was based on Hunza’s needs. This fact prompted Pakistan’s negotiators, evidently in response to disquiet in Hunza, to seek a meeting with Prime Minister Zhou Enlai though the alignment had been agreed and finalised. The meeting was held well 84 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The SINO-PAK Boundary Agreement past midnight. Zhou’s first question was whether the visitors were otherwise satisfied with the deal. They replied that they were but sought a concession on humanitarian grounds. Zhou readily agreed. The veteran diplomat Abdul Sattar, who served as Foreign Minister records : “Pakistan remembers with gratitude an extraordinary gesture by Premier Zhou Enlai: after the alignment was agreed, the Pakistan government belatedly realized that some grazing lands along the Mustagh River in the Shimshal Pass on the other side of the watershed were historically used by inhabitants of Hunza. It then appealed for an exception to the watershed principle to save hardship to the poor people. Zhou generously agreed to the amendment of the boundary so that an area of 750 square miles remained on the Pakistan side. (Pakistan’s Foreign Policy 1947-2005: A Concise History, Oxford University press, Karachi, 2007; p. 71). The agreement of 1963 is, thus, based on a history that stretched to the 19th century. If India had consulted the records in the spirit as Pakistan did, an accord could have been reached in April 1960. For India, as it did for Pakistan in 1963, the McDonald’s Note of 14 March 1899 provides a key to the resolution of the India-China boundary dispute. CRITERION – October/December 2009 85 THE AFGHAN TURMOIL FROM 1747 TO 2001 S. Iftikhar Murshed* Abstract Since the establishment of the kingdom of Afghanistan by Ahmad Shah Abdali in 1747, the country has seldom known peace. It has been ravaged by conflict before the emergence of the Taliban, during their harsh rule from 1996 to 2001 and after their ouster. Afghanistan is a multi-ethnic country and it is the quest for national cohesion in a heterogeneous population that defines the Afghan problem. The 20 August 2009 presidential election was fraud-tainted. Whatever dispensation finally emerges, it is essential that it should reflect the ethnic composition of the country or else durable peace and stability will not return even if the Al Qaeda-supported Taliban insurgency comes to an end. Author). Through history, Afghanistan has seldom known peace. Its ethnic heterogeneity has shaped and influenced its violence-ridden past. Peaceful coexistence among the ethnic groups has been alien to the Afghan experience. The ethnic map of the country, with the groups separated and confined to clearly defined areas, has also militated against national unity. The Hindu Kush range, which translates as the “slayer of Hindus,” has served as the rough divide. In the historical context, the term “Afghan” was probably first used in the fifteenth century during the reign of Mahmud of Ghazni, a ruler of Turkish descent, while the name of the country, “Afghanistan,” was coined in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries by the Moguls. History contains no record of an Afghan state before 1747. Eastern Afghanistan * Iftikhar Murshed is the publisher of Criterion. Email: simurshed@yahoo.com. The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 formed part of the Mogul Empire while its west was controlled by the Safavids of Iran. Kabul became the capital of Mogul territory west of the Indus. The second major Afghan town, Kandahar, was contested between the Mogul and Persian empires till it was taken by the latter during the reign of the Mogul emperor, Shah Jahan. The shahs of Iran continued to treat Afghanistan a province of their empire till the nineteenth century. The quest for national cohesion in a heterogeneous population defines the Afghanistan problem. The difficulties are compounded because the disparate groups of the country were brought together, through the centuries, more by accident rather than any shared desire to live together. The urge for unity was absent from Afghan society because one group, the Pushtuns, imposed itself on the others. The ethnic minorities were subjugated and treated as second class citizens. The Pushtuns monopolized economic and political power with the encouragement of imperial Britain in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Thus uni-racial rule in a multiracial society, and its attendant backlash, unleashed violence among a people who had never wanted to be united into a single nation. The Great Game In 1747, Ahmed Shah Abdali founded the Kingdom of Afghanistan and extended it up to Kashmir, Punjab, Sindh and Baluchistan of present day Pakistan. He was conferred the title Durr-i- Durran (Pearl of Pearls) and from this his tribe, which was to play so prominent a role in Afghan history, became known as the Durrani. After Abdali’s death in 1773, the empire fragmented into independent city states and spurred rivalry between the British and the Russians for dominance of the country. The emergence of Afghanistan as a state in the last two centuries owed itself more to Britain’s imperial ambitions than any desire among its peoples to forge national identity. British writers claimed that their country had contributed significantly to give “a national unity to that nebulous community which we call Afghanistan (which the Afghans never called by that name) by drawing a boundary all round CRITERION – October/December 2009 87 S. Iftikhar Murshed it and elevating it into a position of buffer state between ourselves and Russia.”1 External compression was, therefore, applied by the advancing empires of Britain and Russia to foster effective cohesion among the Afghan groups.2 The conflicting interest of the two imperial powers did not permit either to establish itself in Afghanistan. The alternative to an armed clash over the territory was to transform it into a buffer state. It was also in their interest, if Afghanistan was to play this role, to ensure that chaos and anarchy did not prevail in it. A strong ruler was, therefore, needed in the country. Britain and, to an extent, Russia feared chaos in a leaderless Afghanistan more than the unfriendliness of an Afghan ruler.3 The British were also conscious that there was nothing to guarantee Afghanistan’s continued existence as a buffer between England and Russia as no other country cared about its survival.4 This generated a disproportionate British interest in Afghanistan which played itself out as the “great game” in the nineteenth century. The attempt to incorporate Afghanistan in the British sphere of influence led to two Anglo-Afghan wars from 1839 to 1842 and 1878 to 1880. The first resulted in defeat for the British while the second enabled them to control Afghanistan’s foreign policy and annex sizeable territory. These lands, stretched from the Indus to the Durand Line, which demarcates the present day border between Pakistan and Afghanistan. The result was the delimitation of the frontiers of Afghanistan in the west, south and east by the British, and in the north by the Russian and British governments. After bringing Afghanistan into existence, the need for a strong ruler to hold the country together thus became of paramount concern to the British who, on occasions, played a decisive role in the selection of the amir. So deep was their involvement that British support became essential to ensure any particular amir’s continued occupation of the Afghan throne. They provided him the subsidies and weapons to build an army and consolidate power. Furthermore, the subjugation of the ethnic minorities by the Pushtun amirs was carried out with the encouragement and support of the British. In the words of a Russian historian “after 1849 Dost Muhammad turned to the conquest of non-Afghan peoples living north of the Hindu Kush (Uzbeks, Tajiks, and Turkmen) with the support of the British India Company.”5 88 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 With British subsidies, amir Abdur Rahman, who ruled from 1880 to 1901, sought to establish an absolute monarchy. He was succeeded by his grandson, Amanullah Khan, who tried to modernize the country in the ten years that he reigned from 1919 to 1929. He won Afghanistan’s independence in the third Anglo-Afghan war in 1919 but lost the subsidy as a consequence of which he failed to establish a resource base or build a reliable army. An insurrection supported by extremist clergy ensued and Kabul was taken by the rebels in January 1929. An ethnic Tajik rebel ruled for the next nine months when the capital fell, yet again, in October 1929 to the Pushtun tribes led by Nadir Khan, a member of the royal family. As was perhaps inevitable under the circumstances, the power base in Afghanistan has constantly remained extremely narrow. Its exercise has been the privilege of the Pushtuns, within the Pushtuns of the Durranis, and within the Durranis of the Barakzais. For almost half a century during which power rested with the Mohammadzai branch of the Barakzai clan, Afghanistan was controlled by an inner cabinet consisting of important members of the royal family and a few of their trusted associates. Command positions in the army were invariably held by members of the royal family and, in some instances, by staunch supporters of the monarchy. The successful coup by Sardar Mohammad Daud Khan in July 1973 against his cousin, King Zahir Shah, merely ended the monarchy but did not result in any diffusion of power. In effect, power was transferred from the former oligarchy to a single individual. These factors which included the imperial rivalry of Britain and Russia, geographical separation of the Afghan ethnic groups and a traditionally narrow power base, combined to prevent the peaceful growth of Afghanistan into a state in the true sense of the word. Founded, as it was, as a loose confederation of Pushtun tribes under Ahmad Shah Abdali, the Afghan national identity became synonymous with Pushtun nationalism. Despite the presence of other ethnic groups, Afghanistan has been a country run by the Pushtuns and for the Pushtuns. The other groups have, with considerable justification, been described as “the victims of an internal colonisation.”6 Afghan governments have been CRITERION – October/December 2009 89 S. Iftikhar Murshed generally preoccupied with exclusively Pushtun issues such as the Afghan irredentist campaign and the advancement of Pushtu as the state language. The latter has included “the required learning of Pushtu in the schools, support for research in Pushtu literature, and the enshrining of Pushtu as the national language in article 35 of the 1964 constitution.”7 Without exception, Afghan cabinets have been dominated by Pushtuns completely out of proportion to the population ratio. For instance, in a cabinet of sixteen, the number of non-Pushtuns hardly exceeded one and very rarely two. Even this meagre representation was not always ensured. Pushtuns were appointed governors in most provinces, even where the population was predominantly of other ethnic groups “but a non-Pathan has never been appointed governor of a Pathan province.”8 It is, therefore, interesting that when the Taliban were in control over the major part of Afghan territory from 1996 to September 2001, they appointed eleven non-Pushtuns as governors, some of them in Pushtun provinces, and included four or five members of the minority ethnic groups in the cabinet. Economic development was equally unbalanced. Practically all development projects were concentrated in the Pushtun areas. Agricultural programmes were to be found in Khost and the Helmand Valley, forestry schemes at Ali Khel, hydroelectric power generation and irrigation in Nangarhar - all Pushtun provinces. Even when development took place in regions where other groups were dominant as with cotton ginning and processing in the north at Kunduz and along the Oxus, it was “often in an area with a Pushtun settler population dating from the government’s deliberate shifting of Pathans to these areas before the Second World War.”9 Similarly, the great majority of Afghan industrial workers were “often members of those families who were moved into the non-Pushtun provinces and were never quite able to fit happily into the local community.”10 Thus the growing industrial elite was as Pushtun-dominated as was the administrative elite. The Process of Pushtun Domination The most comprehensive accounts of Pushtun subjugation of the Tajiks, Uzbeks, Turkmens and the Hazaras of Afghanistan are mainly to 90 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 be found in the works of Soviet historians. This process, which involved conquest followed by persecution and ethnic cleansing, reached its peak under amir Abdur Rahman who is often described as the Bismark of Afghanistan.11 The enormity of the Afghan tragedy, both historical as well as contemporary, cannot be overstated. It raises fundamental questions such as whether the people of Afghanistan can, and in particular the minority groups, be expected to forget the past and begin a process of genuine reconciliation, or will the legacy of interracial disharmony and hatred continue to define the country’s post-Taliban future? The Tajiks lost their state with the fall of the Samanids, but continued to fight stubbornly to preserve their independence. It was only in the eighteenth and the first half of the nineteenth centuries that the Afghan feudal lords defeated the Tajik peasants of the Kabul, Kandahar and Ghazni regions. In the 1830s a bitter struggle between the Tajiks and the Pushtuns began, which culminated in the 1880s when Abdur Rahman succeeded in finally breaking the Tajik resistance. The establishment of Pushtun authority in the Tajik areas was accompanied by the confiscation of land from the local aristocracy, the forcible seizure of small holdings from the peasantry, and the transfer of un-worked lands to the state. The vast state holdings thus acquired were distributed among the Pushtun immigrants who formed military colonies in these areas. The indigenous population was strangulated economically through the imposition of exorbitant taxes from which the Pushtuns were exempted. Crippled economically and ostracized politically, a sizeable number of local Tajiks were forced to move to Turkestan in search of a living. The process was repeated with the Uzbeks. In the first half of the nineteenth century the Uzbeks, who were settled in northern Afghanistan, constituted the feudal khanates of Kunduz, Mazar, Shibberghan and Maimena. They were dependent to a greater or lesser degree on the amir of Bokhara. However, as early as the accession of Dost Muhammad, the Afghan government began to conquer southern Turkestan including the Uzbek khanates. The bloodshed continued for several decades till Abdur Rahman was able to capture all the territory between the Amu Darya (the Oxus) and the Hindu Kush. Again excessively high taxes were imposed on the local population forcing them to migrate. Their CRITERION – October/December 2009 91 S. Iftikhar Murshed land holdings were proclaimed state property and an intensive process of Pushtun colonization of the area commenced.12 The Turkmen experience was no different. At the dawn of the nineteenth century, the greater part of their principalities had become vassals to Bohkara and it was not till the conquest of Andkhoi, Shibberghan and Maimena by Abdur Rahman that these areas were assimilated into Afghanistan. This was in fact facilitated by the RussoEnglish demarcation of 1885-1887. Property was again confiscated from the local population thus making them wholly dependent on the mercy of the Pushtun aristocracy. Many reverted to nomadic ways while others became shepherds and herded the flocks of the new landowners.13 However, it was the Hazaras who suffered the most because, as Shiias, they were detested not only by the Pushtuns but also by the other ethnic minorities. This sectarian bias against them has always been and continues to be one of the most shameful aspects of Afghan society. Jealousy and envy also played a role because, unlike the other ethnic groups, the Hazaras had guarded their independence and did not submit for a prolonged period to any outside power for six centuries. The people of the Hazarajat accepted only their own leadership till the 1890s when they were finally subjugated, after a long and fierce conflict lasting several decades, by Abdur Rahman. Not only did they lose a considerable portion of their land to the Pushtun feudal lords but also suffered persecution, the barbarity of which has few parallels even by Afghan standards. The heads of slaughtered Hazaras were placed on pillars along the highways as a warning to those contemplating rebellion. The bazaars of Kandahar and other major towns were filled with Hazara prisoners who were sold at cheap prices as slaves. A foreigner who happened to be in Kabul in the 1890s observed: “a short while ago a Hazara baby was bought for halfa-crown, and the purchaser got the mother for fifteen shillings.”14 On other occasions, prisoners were traded for guns, ammunition and horses. The possession of Hazara slaves became a status symbol for prosperous Pushtuns.15 Even after slavery was abolished by king Amanullah, the Hazaras continued to live as outcasts possessing neither wealth nor any rights. 92 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 In the 1960s, a second infiltration of the Hazara areas took place when about sixty thousand Pushtuns from the plains were settled in the Hazarajat. The local population meekly accepted this as they were too weak to offer any resistance. In this period they also became the victims of wealthy Pushtuns who lent them money at interest rates that verged on extortion. Seldom have minority communities in any society suffered so much. This aspect of Afghan history will continue to cast a shadow on the prospects of sustainable peace in the country. But the problem is far more complicated because the ethnic minorities also distrust and even despise each other as the tragic tale of Afghanistan has so frequently demonstrated. The Afghan Political Structure and the non-Pushtun Groups After their “colonization,” which was completed by Abdur Rahman, the non-Pushtuns became mere bystanders as their country underwent political change. They were unable to even express their grievances. Their subdued anger at Pushtun political, economic and social predominance became increasingly pronounced and instilled parochial rather than national loyalties. The indignities and the persecution that the Hazaras suffered made them particularly bitter. The subjugation of the ethnic minorities of Afghanistan was, in a sense, also a conflict between Pushtun tribesmen and the non-Pushtun urban population. The conquest of the towns, which had previously been controlled by merchants and artisans, resulted not only in the loss of urban political influence, but also in “the collapse of organization, skills, and economic activity. Their markets constricted and they suffered from plundering and heavy taxation imposed by tribally and rurally oriented rulers...The picture presented until the late nineteenth century was that of dying urban communities. The subsistence orientation of the peasant and the nomad made them virtually independent of the towns economically, while their numbers and organization gave them political control in both town and countryside.”16 CRITERION – October/December 2009 93 S. Iftikhar Murshed Contemporary writers have described the effects of the “rapacity” of the victorious Barakzai forces. The burden of their demands fell mainly on the Tajik section of the population with the result that “in the immediate vicinity of towns no human voice greets or curses the visitor. Once rich vineyards are dried up and all around is desolation. This is specially the case in the Qandhar district where every fresh change of rulers has only brought increased taxation, until the population has been decimated and tax gatherers, enraged at not being able to squeeze money out of the mud walls, seized and sold into slavery the last inhabitants of once prosperous towns and villages.”17 The urban centres of eastern and southern Afghanistan, rather than the Afghan tribes, were the worst sufferers of the two Anglo-Afghan wars of the nineteenth century as well. While the country’s meagre economy as a whole was undoubtedly damaged seriously, the urban population was badly hit by inflation and the scarcity of basic commodities. The population and the economy of Kabul and of the Kandahar regions declined sharply; the province of Herat also suffered enormous material losses. No relief was in sight for the non-Pushtuns because the amirs of Afghanistan faced difficulties of their own. The consolidation of power was never an easy task for them. The threat to their position came mainly from their own kinsmen or other Durrani chiefs. Amir Habibullah Khan and King Zahir Shah have been the only two rulers to ascend and occupy their thrones (the latter for four decades) without a challenge. Whenever the throne was contested, which was generally the case, the issue was decided by the Pushtun tribesmen. In the conditions prevailing at the time, involvement in these dynastic contests represented the only form of political activity in the country. The non-Pushtuns were in no position to play any role in these contests and had no influence on their outcome. Thus they were denied all means for political advancement. Furthermore, the evolution of Afghanistan’s international personality also militated against the interests of the ethnic minorities. With the demarcation of Afghanistan’s international frontiers and the guarantee of its territorial integrity by Britain and Russia, the Afghan 94 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 rulers became relatively free from worries about foreign intervention and they used this breathing space to deal with their people. The amirs had always suspected Persia of irredentist designs in the western part of Afghanistan, and Russia of expansionist interests in the north. In the perception of the Afghan rulers, these were the two areas most vulnerable to foreign ingress. To an extent, they could now count on British support in containing these threats. Despite this, the amirs were unable to break away out of a mind set that the country’s neighbours were inherently hostile and sought to annex Afghan territory. They, therefore, deliberately chose an isolationist foreign policy as that would not only reduce external threat but also enable them to pursue vigorous domestic measures. This helped them in particular to insulate the nonPushtun areas in the north and the west, and consolidate their grip on these regions. This could not have been achieved without the help of the Pushtun tribesmen. Thus, the authority of the state was identified with the rule of the Pushtuns and opposition to it with the ethnic minorities. The latter were, therefore, to remain suspect in the eyes of the Pushtun rulers of Afghanistan. Reform Measures The Afghan political structure has undergone fundamental changes since 1747. Though the amir has always been at the top of the power pyramid, his support base has varied under different rulers. Ahmed Shah Abdali’s “election” represented tribal consensus and his kingdom was, in essence, a Pushtun tribal confederation. Incessant dynastic struggles and internecine warfare within the Durranis and between them and other Pushtun tribes, particularly the Ghilzais, dominated events in Afghanistan after Abdali’s death till amir Dost Mohammad Khan finally succeeded in uniting the country. He was able to rally national support largely because of the British invasion and occupation of Afghanistan from 1839-1842. However, after his death internal conflict resurfaced and continued with ferocity till Abdur Rahman seized Kabul and declared himself amir in 1880. It was during his reign, which lasted till 1901, that Afghanistan began to acquire the semblance of a nation state. Till his ascension the central government was dependent on support, in descending order of importance, from the Pushtun tribes, the religious CRITERION – October/December 2009 95 S. Iftikhar Murshed leaders, the settled population in both rural and urban areas and the economic interest groups. Abdur Rahman took consequential measures to alter the power structure by trying to make the government less dependent on tribal support. Besides keeping the tribes under control, he institutionalized the bureaucracy, the army and the monarchy. Till then, provincial governments were primarily organized along tribal lines with each tribe ruling in its own area autonomously. Whatever little control the government was able to exercise was usually through the army. To strengthen central authority, Abdur Rahman demarcated provincial boundaries that cut through tribal territory and doubled the number of provinces. Subsequent rulers stabilized the new system so that pure tribal government was done away with. Abdur Rahman further weakened the authority of the tribal chiefs by appointing them to seemingly important but innocuous posts in Kabul. Claiming to rule by divine right, Abdur Rahman virtually eliminated the influence of the religious leaders by incorporating them into government service and appropriating their endowments. On a parallel track, measures were taken to establish a professional army loyal to the central government and insulated from tribal influence. This experiment was entirely new to the Afghan experience. The tribal levies, who constituted the backbone of the army, were encouraged to pledge fealty to the amir rather than their own tribes. Abdur Rahman also introduced western military technology and organization. The modernization process was continued by his son, amir Habibullah, who set up a military academy for the officer corps. These efforts were only partially successful because tribal rather than national loyalty continued to be the dominant impulse within the army. This was evident from the successful revolt against Amanullah, which was led by the Shinwaris of eastern Afghanistan, while his successor, king Nadir Shah, was able to capture Kabul only with the assistance of the Wazirs and the Mahsuds from the British-India side of the frontier. Thus the supremacy of the tribes had never really been diminished. The new rulers, the Muhammadzais, were conscious of the influence 96 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 of the tribes and also recognized the need for eliminating the dependence of the government on tribal military support. They understood only too well that a well-equipped and disciplined army, which could protect the state from the tribes, was desperately required. However, such a force was eventually only to emerge, with Soviet military assistance, during Sardar Mohammad Daud Khan’s first tenure as prime minister from 1953 to 1963. Thus for the first time in Afghan history, the central government had acquired the capability to respond decisively to any tribal or religious insurrection. Two primary elements are identifiable in the complex relationship between the government in Kabul and tribesmen on the east. First, urban economic weakness and the autocratic and feudal character of the monarchy itself made the Afghan amirs increasingly dependent on the Pushtun tribes for the defence of the country and the preservation of their dynasty. The tribes were also the only obstacle in the way of British incursions into Afghanistan. Thus those in the British-India side of the frontier not only played a decisive role in determining who among the various Durrani contestants was to hold power in Kabul, but also provided the surest guarantee of Afghanistan’s territorial integrity. The amirs, therefore, wanted to at least influence, as they could not control, the movement and direction of tribal enterprise. Second, despite the support that they derived from the tribes, the amirs, conscious of their own weakness, did in fact welcome British control over the tribesmen as that provided them the opportunity to consolidate internally without tribal interference. With the departure of the British from South Asia, Afghan rulers feared that the attention of the tribesmen east of the Durand Line would be diverted towards Kabul. Managing the relationship with the tribesmen in British-India was a major preoccupation of the rulers in Kabul. The process for the imposition of the central government’s authority over the tribal chiefs, which was started by Abdur Rahman, ended during the first premiership of Sardar Mohammad Daud Khan. The changed political structure was incorporated into the Afghan constitution of 1964. Article 2 of the constitution, which abolished tribal territory, stated: “all territories and localities which are under the sovereignty of the king constitute a homogenous whole, and CRITERION – October/December 2009 97 S. Iftikhar Murshed in no respect can any distinction be made between parts of the country.” Article 9 was directed against the membership of tribes and read “all persons residing within the kingdom of Afghanistan are to be treated as Afghan subjects.” Article 13 proclaimed the equality of all Afghan subjects. Article 26 dismantled tribal administration and forbade the collection of duties or taxes by anybody except the government. The methods introduced by Abdur Rahman were used for the implementation of these constitutional provisions. Tribal chiefs were appointed to harmless posts in the executive, the upper house of the legislature or the judiciary. In other instances, they were made governors of provinces far from their own regions. Tribal administration was replaced by new regional organizations under government appointed officials. This process started at the top of the tribal hierarchy and stretched down to the smaller administrative units. However, in the more remote and smaller centres the administration was left to the local chiefs. The modernization efforts were primarily focussed on the armed forces. However, the military reforms spilled over into other sectors and contributed to the establishment of a bureaucracy, an educational system and a few basic political institutions. In time, the bureaucracy was restructured and expanded to play a more assertive role in Afghan society. The civil servants exercised a liberalising influence. Like them, the intellectual elite which included teachers, doctors and college students also gave voice to the need for political liberalization, broadening of the base of government, and the establishment of an egalitarian socioeconomic system. Thus modernists were pitted against traditionalists and the former became more influential after Daud Khan’s retirement 1963. Through all this, the most significant political force to emerge was the military. It became the only organization in the country capable of acting effectively on a nation-wide scale. Its command positions were, however, held by members of the royal family and by its most loyal and trusted supporters. But that was as far as the reforms were intended to go. To an extent the reform programme of the Afghan rulers was helped by the influence of Islam on Afghan national life. Though the disparate Afghan groups had little in common, the sense of community and brotherhood instilled by Islam provided a much needed unifying force. 98 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 It was used by the Afghan rulers to mobilize opposition first against the Sikhs and later the British. However, although the principles of Islam permeated the 1964 constitution and it was declared the state religion, official policy emphasized nationalistic rather than religious ideology. Unfortunately, the former continued to be equated with Pushtun supremacy. In the early 1950s, king Zahir Shah declared publicly that “the strength of the Muslim faith did not necessarily guarantee stability and national unity.”18 As a result, the country’s traditional institutions were progressively secularized through the years. It was not till the early 1970s that employment opportunities in government were opened up for non-Pushtuns as a measure to promote national unity. Though recruitment into the armed forces was mainly from the Pushtun tribes, representatives from other ethnic groups were also gradually taken into the military. Conscription helped to bring persons from different communities together and contributed to the lowering of barriers between them. Simultaneously, even economic development projects were initiated in various non-Pushtun regions. Substantial investments were made in industry and agriculture north of the Hindu Kush and in areas far away from the capital such as Herat. A special effort was made to improve the overall infrastructure particularly the up-gradation of roads and modernization of communications. The Afghan Dilemma Well into the twentieth century, the framework within which the rulers of Afghanistan tried to promote unity before the communist revolt was a combination of two major but contradictory principles. The first was encouraging the gradual growth of a national Afghan, rather than as in the past, a Muslim identity. This was to be achieved by overriding ethnic and linguistic divisions, through legal and administrative reforms and by increasing the participation of non-Pushtun groups in the government and bringing economic development to their regions. The second was preserving the strength of traditional forces, in other words, respecting Pushtun domination. CRITERION – October/December 2009 99 S. Iftikhar Murshed Pushtun dominance continued to be equated with national and cultural unity, and in this sense there was no change from the past. The army, modernized and equipped with the latest weapons, remained the principal instrument for imposing national unity and maintaining the authority of the central government. However, it was totally under the control of the Pushtun leadership. There was also no change in the approach towards the cultural autonomy of the other groups. In fact, for the first time in the basic law of the country itself, Pushtu was declared the national language. It was made compulsory in schools and proficiency in the language was required for appointment to senior government positions. The Pushtun Academy and Afghan Historical Society were set up to sponsor research in Pushtun history and culture. Although Darri was also the official language, Pushtu was allowed to develop at its expense. Only limited reforms were thus carried out through a modernized bureaucracy and military but these did not have any impact on the political power structure. The reforms were imposed from above and did not originate from the masses. Political activity was generally suppressed or at best severely restricted as the formation of political parties was prohibited. After the promulgation of the 1964 constitution, a political parties bill was passed by parliament. King Zahir Shah, however, withheld his consent on the ground that political parties would emerge from the ethnic groups and militate against national unity. Thus the continuance of Pushtun domination could only be ensured if the other ethnic groups were kept away from any organized political activity. The irony is that the absence of legitimate party organizations encouraged parochial loyalties and by the 1970s resulted in the formation of political parties along ethnic lines. The rivalry between the imperial powers of the earlier centuries, the cruel process of Pushtun domination and the superpower rivalry in the Cold War period ensured that peace and stability would elude Afghanistan. The turmoil of today has its roots in the past. Previously, external powers were to an extent responsible for the chaos, but in the contemporary era the Afghans themselves are mostly to blame. The competition for power and wealth between the Pushtuns and the 100 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 ethnic minorities continued to generate violence in Afghan society and became alarmingly pronounced by the time the Taliban captured Kabul in September 1996. When the on-going post-9/11Taliban insurgency comes to an end, the deeper problem of promoting reconciliation among a people who have always refused to be reconciled will have to be addressed. II. THE FOUR PHASES OF RECENT AFGHAN HISTORY At another level, religious extremism coloured by the conservative traditions of tribal Afghanistan has always been resistant to change and at variance with contemporary values. Thus the socialist Afghanistan of the PDPA encountered domestic violence for attempting to transform the country through progressive reforms while the Taliban, during their rule from 1996 to 2001, faced international condemnation for clinging senselessly to tribal customs which were often far removed both from civilized conduct as well as from the spirit and the true teachings of Islam. Centuries of conflict, internal upheavals and dislocations thus brought unparalleled misery to the Afghan people who, it seemed, had become accustomed to suffering. Four distinct phases in recent Afghan history have also singly and collectively contributed towards the unending turmoil in the country. The first, the coup by the PDPA on 27 April 1978; the second, the Soviet invasion and occupation from 29 December 1979 to February 1989; the third, the prolonged resistance against the Moscow-installed Najibullah regime till 28 April 1992 and; the fourth, the emergence and rule of the Taliban from 1996 to 2001. The post 9/11 Al Qaeda-supported Taliban insurgency is influenced by the four previous phases. Phase one: After the PDPA Coup Zahir Shah succeeded his assassinated father, Nadir, as king of Afghanistan in 1933. He ruled for almost forty years till his overthrow in 1973 by prince Daud. In 1953 Daud, then Prime Minister, launched a CRITERION – October/December 2009 101 S. Iftikhar Murshed modernization programme that was later to prove consequential, albeit, in the negative sense. Daud resigned in 1963, prompting Zahir Shah to promulgate a new constitution that sought to encourage political freedom and envisaged an elected consultative parliament. With the ouster of Zahir Shah, Daud abolished the monarchy, established a republic and proclaimed himself president. He was assassinated on 27 April 1978 by the same officers who were behind him in the 1973 coup. However, this time they handed over power to the Marxist-Leninist PDPA. With Daud ended two hundred and thirty-one years of rule by the Durranis of Kandahar. The cause of Daud’s downfall lay in his own reforms. He depended heavily on assistance from the United States and the Soviet Union without developing domestic consensus. This phase in Afghanistan’s history saw the development of the infrastructure, the strengthening of the army and the expansion of education. The elite went to the academic institutions of the West, the military officers were sent to the Soviet Union while the Islamists were trained in Egypt’s Al-Azhar University. This was to bring about a transformation of the country’s political structure. Previously, the struggle for autonomy by ethnic minorities had dominated Afghan politics. The Persian speaking Tajiks and Hazaras as well as the Turkish speaking Uzbeks and Turkmen had been equally active in ridding themselves of Pushtun domination. Actual power even among the Pushtuns, however, vested only with the tribal elite and this resulted in a loose unity of the underprivileged. The marginalized and frustrated intellectuals thus joined radical groups ranging from the Marxists to the Islamists. The stage was thus set for a power struggle between the two which led to the Soviet invasion of Afghanistan. The conflict that ensued would hasten the collapse of the Berlin Wall and bring the Cold War era to an end. The PDPA was created in January 1965 in Kabul at the residence of Nur Muhammad Taraki. Its thirty-three founding members elected Taraki, a Pushtun, secretary general and Babrak Karmal, a Persianspeaking Kabul resident, his deputy. Serious differences, however, developed between the Taraki-led Khalq (masses) faction and the urbanized Persian-speaking group, the Parcham (flag), under Karmal. 102 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 By 1967 the party had split. Though both factions were staunchly pro-Soviet, Moscow was partial to the Parcham which it found more pliable and receptive to advice. The Khalqis were considered self-opinionated and unpredictable. Ideologically, they were orthodox Marxist-Leninists representing the economically and socially under-privileged Pushtuns. Taraki, a tenthgrade drop out, was projected by his group as a man of letters because he spoke English which he had learnt in the early 1930s while working for an Afghan merchant in Bombay. In contrast, many among the Parchamites, with their upper class backgrounds, had received higher education abroad while Karmal, the son of an army general, had graduated from the Kabul University’s faculty of Law and Political Science. The next twelve years saw the rift between the Khalq and Parcham factions widen into pervasive enmity. The former derided the Parchamites as bourgeois and, therefore, unfit to represent the proletariat. During his days in parliament, Karmal was said to have had connections with the king and thus all Parchamites were described by their rivals as “royal communists.” In turn, the latter looked upon the Khalqis with ill-disguised contempt because of their low social standing, lack of education and their inability to comprehend the intricacies of statecraft. To pre-empt the Khalq-Parcham tensions from exploding into street violence, the Communist Party of the Soviet Union intervened in May 1977. The two factions were merged and Taraki once again became Secretary General and Karmal, his deputy. The new thirty-member unified central committee was divided equally between the two groups. However, this new found PDPA unity was cosmetic and proved shortlived. Each faction acted independently of the other. They recruited their own men to the army and police, a task which the Khalq entrusted to the ruthlessly ambitious US-educated Hafizullah Amin and the Parcham, to Mir Akbar Khyber. The April 1978 coup resulted in Hafizullah Amin’s emergence as the second most powerful man in the Khalq group. His rise undid the CRITERION – October/December 2009 103 S. Iftikhar Murshed feeble Soviet attempt of the previous year to restore PDPA unity. Karmal, as the party deputy secretary general, became increasingly sidelined. Amin claimed that the coup had been masterminded and executed by the officers that he had recruited, therefore, Karmal was not entitled to occupy the number two slot in the new dispensation. For the same reason, he also rejected, with the support of the newly established Khalqdominated Revolutionary Council, Karmal’s demand that cabinet posts and key military positions be shared equally between the two factions. The Soviets attempted yet again to restore PDPA unity. In April 1978 a high-level KGB delegation led by Vladimir Khrychov arrived in Kabul and persuaded Amin to accept equal Khalq-Parcham representation in the cabinet. The trade-off was that the office of president and prime minister would vest in Taraki. Karmal was thus relegated to the backwaters and appointed deputy president of the Revolutionary Council. Amin became foreign minister and the first deputy prime minister. Even this arrangement did not last long. With Taraki’s support, Amin secured the approval of the PDPA Politburo to send Karmal and six of his close associates to ambassadorial exile. On Moscow’s request, Karmal was assigned to Prague. However, despite this, tension between the Khalq and Parcham groups continued to simmer beneath the surface till August when the Parchamite defence minister and two generals were arrested on charges of plotting a coup that was to have taken place on 4 September. The purge of the Parchamites thus began with a vengeance. They were dismissed from government and hundreds were imprisoned. Orders were issued to Karmal and the other recently appointed ambassadors to return home immediately to face trial. As expected, they sought political asylum. Karmal continued to live in Prague till October 1979 when he moved to Moscow. Thus the Parchamites were, at least temporarily, side-lined. Like the Taliban, the Khalqis did not take easily to enlightened educated opinion particularly of those who had attended academic institutions of the west. They went even further and persecuted men of 104 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 learning, whom they looked upon as counter-revolutionaries. Intellectuals were hounded on flimsy pretexts and even the possession of an English dictionary was enough to invite the wrath of the establishment. Educated Afghans, especially those who were not members of the PDPA prior to the coup, were branded anti-proletariat and excluded from government. Amin, Mansoor Hashmi and Salim Masudi were the only US-educated ministers in the first communist cabinet. The rest, barring three who had studied in Soviet institutions, were either graduates of the Kabul University or had merely completed high school education. Abdul Karim Mesaq, the finance minister, had only attended primary school. The semi-literate and inexperienced Khalq government then embarked on ill-thought-out reforms which were to have disastrous consequences. These socialist measures were far removed from the religious beliefs, customs and traditions of the Afghan people and generated a violent reaction. Thus, even those whom the reforms were meant to benefit turned against the government. The starting point of the reform process was the implementation of the Basic Lines of the Revolutionary Duties of the Democratic Republic of Afghanistan, a thirty-point programme, that had been announced a fortnight after the coup. Its stated purpose was to “transform the traditional Afghan society into a new flourishing one based on the principles of socialism and equality.” Towards this end, eight revolutionary decrees were hastily issued. Of these, three - the sixth, seventh and the eighth - dealt with social and economic reforms. Decree six had two aims. The first provided debt relief to peasants by exempting them from repayment of loans incurred prior to 1974. The second sought to restore mortgaged land to owners in return for a small payment. Contrary to expectations, these measures led to resentment among the peasants because the repayment of debt is obligatory in Islam. Furthermore, those in desperate need of money could not even secure a small loan. CRITERION – October/December 2009 105 S. Iftikhar Murshed Decree seven, promulgated in October 1978, aimed at the emancipation of women. Taraki proudly announced: “The Afghan women from now are free in the real sense of the word and have equal rights with men.” Despite its progressive spirit, the decree contained clauses which alienated not only the conservative elements of society but also, surprisingly, women. The feminists were embittered by article three which fixed the maximum amount for dowry or mahr at three hundred Afghanis. The article read: “The girl or her guardian shall not take cash or commodities in the name of the dowry in excess of ten dirhams according to Shariat.” The decree also gave the right of divorce to women. The result was that the stability of the family structure in a traditional society was ruined while women were deprived of financial security in the event of divorce. Article four of the same decree permitted women, contrary to Afghan traditions, to terminate their engagements if they so decided. This dealt a further body blow to the family unit. The social reforms also obliged Afghans to send their women to the newly established adult literacy institutions. This caused commotion in many parts of the country notably Herat where it was first introduced. In March 1979, massive demonstrations were held in the streets of the city and resulted in two weeks of violent clashes with the law enforcement authorities, particularly the army. Thus, apparently well-intentioned reforms, ignited rebellion because of the perception that they were contrary to tribal Afghanistan’s obscurantist interpretation of Islamic doctrines. The Khalq regime came down with a heavy hand. Disappearances, torture, custodial killings and summary executions were carried out with abandon by Amin’s secret police which was controlled by his nephew and son-in-law, Assadullah Amin. This intensified the resistance forcing the regime to move even closer to the Soviet Union. The latter’s presence in government became all pervasive. In December 1978, a treaty of friendship and cooperation was concluded with the Soviet Union under which Moscow was to provide assistance to Kabul in the event of internal instability or external threat. 106 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 Though the resistance to the Khalq regime in Kabul was inspired by the single objective of restoring an Islamic government in Afghanistan, it was divided into seven Sunni Muslim groups based in Peshawar, Pakistan, and eight Shiia parties headquartered in Iran. The latter were united, under Iranian pressure, into the Wahdat-e-Islami (later to be known as the Hizb-e-Wahdat) while the former continued to operate individually as distinct groups. These parties were to have a profound impact on subsequent events in Afghanistan. Among the seven Peshawar-based parties, four were fundamentalists and three moderates. The former consisted of: (i) Jamiat-e-Islami: a Tajik party formed by Burhanuddin Rabbani, the subsequent leader of the Northern Alliance, in 1970. Ahmed Shah Masood was, till his assassination on 9 September 2001, the head of its military component known as the Shura-e-Nazar; (ii) Hizb-e-Islami (Hikmatyar Group): a Pushtun-dominated party created by Gulbadin Hikmatyar. It sought to initiate an Iranianstyle revolution and to establish a one-party fundamentalist state (Hikmatyar was subsequently associated off and on with the Northern Alliance); (iii) Hizb-e-Islami (Khalis Group): a splinter group of the Hizb-eIslami (Hikmatyar) established by Yunis Khalis in 1979. Most of its fighters later joined the Taliban; and (iv) Itehad-e-Islami: a Saudi-backed party, again primarily Pushtun, formed in 1980 by Professor Abdul Rasool Sayyaf (he is also associated with the Northern Alliance and is said to have brought Osama bin Laden back to Afghanistan during the four years that the Rabbani regime controlled Kabul). The moderates included: (i) Harakat-e-Inqilab-e-Islami: a Pushtun-dominated party founded by Muhammad Nabi Muhammadi in 1978. It also included a sizeable CRITERION – October/December 2009 107 S. Iftikhar Murshed number of Uzbeks. It advocated free elections, agricultural reform and non-alignment; (ii) Mahaz-e-Milli: It emerged in 1979 under Pir Syed Ahmad Gillani. It was Pushtun-dominated and monarchist (Gillani’s was represented by his son, Hamed, at the UN-sponsored meeting of Afghan groups in Bonn and signed the agreement of 5 December 2001 establishing an interim post-Taliban administration under Hamid Karzai); and (iii) Jubba-e-Nijat-e-Milli: a Pushtun party established in 1978 by Professor Sibghatullah Mujaddadi. It favoured representative government based on Islamic principles and Afghan traditions. It did not oppose the participation of the monarchists in any future government. The fundamentalists were inspired by the political teachings of Hasanul Bana and Sayyid Qutub of Egypt as well as Maududi of Pakistan. Their objective was to restructure Afghan society in accordance with Quranic injunctions and the Sunnah or Islamic traditions. They were anti-west and, in particular, anti-US because of its support for Israel. Though they received American assistance for their fight against Soviet and Afghan communism, they did not conceal their hatred of Washington. Hikmatyar, who was later to join the anti-Taliban Northern Alliance, refused to meet President Reagan when he was in New York in 1986 to address the UN in his capacity as the president of the resistance alliance. The moderates, in contrast, were conservative nationalists who favoured a role for the monarchy and whose objectives included the safeguarding of national independence and the defence of Islam. They were inclined to establish a strong relationship with the West, particularly the United States. The fundamentalists and the moderates remained apart throughout the war despite attempts to bring them together. Their differences contributed to the chaos that engulfed Afghanistan long after the communists were ousted from Kabul. 108 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 The repression of the Afghan people by the regime in Kabul resulted not only in the intensification of the resistance but also led to divisions within the PDPA. Taraki and a number of PDPA leaders, encouraged by the Soviets, wanted to slow down the pace of reforms and to also include non-communists in the government. This was, however, staunchly opposed by Amin. Because of his independent approach, Amin alienated the Soviet Union. He not only rejected Moscow’s advice on slowing down the reforms but also blocked further Soviet involvement with the running of the secret police and the military. The Kremlin began to suspect him of pro-Washington leanings because of his American educational background. During Taraki’s meeting with Brezhnev in Moscow on 10 September 1979, it was widely believed that he was asked to eliminate Amin. Taraki lost no time in carrying out the assassination plan on his return to Kabul the following day. He summoned Amin to the presidential palace but the latter refused to comply because he had been forewarned by his protégé, Taroon, Taraki’s aide-de-camp. Amin was, however, prevailed upon to change his mind on being assured of his personal safety by Ambassador Pazanov of the Soviet Union. On reaching the palace there was a shootout resulting in several deaths. Amin, however, escaped but Taroon, who shielded him during the firing, was killed. Shortly afterwards Amin returned to the palace with his supporters, arrested Taraki and later strangled him despite reported appeals from Brezhnev to spare his life. The stage was thereby set for the Soviet invasion of Afghanistan and thus began the second phase of the Afghan conflict. The Second Phase: the Soviet Invasion On 27 December 1979, the Soviet Union invaded Afghanistan with an initial eighty-five thousand troops. Amin was killed and Babrak Karmal, whom they brought from exile in Moscow, was installed in his place. The anti-Khalq insurgency which had spread to the entire country CRITERION – October/December 2009 109 S. Iftikhar Murshed rapidly transformed into a full-fledged war of liberation. A jihad or holy war was declared. Moscow justified its incursion into Afghanistan by declaring that it was “entirely defensive” and designed to provide security to a friendly neighbouring Marxist regime as well as to protect its southern flank from Islamic fundamentalists and American imperialism. Karmal’s mission was to slow down the pace of the Amin-Taraki reforms, to correct the mistakes of the past, to broaden the political base of the regime and to reorganize the armed forces and the secret police with the active involvement of the Soviets. To fulfil his mission, Karmal initiated several measures. One of his first acts was the release of all political prisoners who numbered in the tens of thousands. He also announced the abolition of all antidemocratic and anti-human rights regulations, declared a ban on arrests and persecution, decreed respect for Islamic principles and freedom of conscience, promised the protection of lawful property, upheld the right of individual and collective security and guaranteed the restoration of peace to Afghanistan. On advice from Moscow, Karmal also pledged not to change Afghan society rapidly and to broaden the base of his government by including non-communists. He proclaimed a provisional constitution titled, the Fundamental Principles of the Democratic Republic of Afghanistan, in April 1980. It defined the rights and duties of the citizens as well as the functions of the branches of state. In the face of the Islamic resistance, the constitution guaranteed “complete freedom in the performance of Islamic religious rites.” Drafted by the Soviet advisers, translated by their Tajik specialists and refined by the Legislative Department of the Ministry of Justice, the provisional constitution was in form and substance similar to those of the Soviet Republics of central Asia. Another Karmal initiative was the creation of the National Fatherland Front (NFF) in 1981 which, his regime claimed, was a coalition of “nationalist, patriotic, democratic and progressive forces.” Its primary 110 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 objective was the mobilization of support against the opposition and it was projected as “an important step to give the masses of the people a say in running the affairs of the country.” The provincial branches of the NFF tried to establish offices in the countryside but no one dared come near them for fear of reprisal by the Islamic resistance. A sizeable public sector-led economic revival programme involving an investment of about thirteen billion Afghanis was also launched. The major part of the funding was to come from the Soviet Union and the rest from its East European allies. These economic and social measures further intensified the determination of the Afghan people to resist the occupation and the communization of their country. Except for Kabul, the provincial capitals and a handful of centres in some of the provinces, the country was in the control of the resistance. Militarily the Soviets employed all the might at their disposal short of using nuclear weapons to eliminate the opposition. Moscow soon realised that the deeply entrenched hatred among the masses for communism was reinforced by their determination to free their country from foreign occupation which no amount of military force could defeat. Accordingly, pressure on Karmal to fulfil his promise of broad-basing the regime was increased. His reluctance to deliver, prompted the Soviets to oust him and to establish a government which was not outwardly communist. This, they felt, would also give an impetus to the Geneva proximity talks which had begun in June 1982 because Karmal was considered the symbol of Soviet occupation of Afghanistan. Furthermore, by the mid-1980s the Soviets were convinced that their intervention into Afghanistan had been a major blunder. They wanted an exit but Karmal would not even hear of it and this provided yet another reason to get rid of him. Thus six years after he was installed as the General Secretary of the communist party of Afghanistan, he was replaced on 4 May 1986 by Dr. Najibullah, the chief of the notorious secret police. The latter also had the advantage of belonging to the CRITERION – October/December 2009 111 S. Iftikhar Murshed majority Pushtun community. Najibullah was instructed to facilitate the withdrawal of Soviet forces from Afghanistan by including non-communists in the government. Dr. Hassan Sharq was accordingly appointed Prime Minister and other noncommunists were also included in the cabinet. Najibullah also launched a programme of national reconciliation. He invited the leaders of the opposition to join the PDPA in a coalition government and made concessions to the armed groups operating in different parts of the country. Only an insignificant few took the bait. Otherwise these overtures had no impact on lessening the strength of the resistance. To appease the feudal elements in the opposition, Najib suspended the land reforms. This again was of little consequence as the reforms had no significance in the face of the conflict and chaos that had gripped the entire country. Thus Najibullah failed to restore peace to Afghanistan which continued to bleed from the lashes of internal turmoil. Nothing had changed with the replacement of Karmal. The resistance continued to control almost the entire countryside. All the highways except the one from Kabul to the north were inoperative. The Soviets and their protégés controlled, as before, only Kabul and the provincial capitals as the resistance became progressively strong. The Soviet losses were heavy. There was also the financial crunch. Thus the only option available to them was to withdraw from Afghanistan. This process which began, under the Geneva Accords, in the summer of 1988 was completed by 15 February 1989. According to one estimate, the Soviet misadventure in Afghanistan cost them US dollars 29 billion. About 26, 000 Soviet soldiers died and 1,200 aircraft and helicopters and tens of thousands of armoured vehicles were destroyed. The Islamic resistance was vigorously supported by the US, the west and moderate oil-rich countries of the Islamic world, particularly Saudi Arabia. In addition to Afghans, thousands of Arabs, including Osama 112 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 bin Laden, were indoctrinated in madrassas or religious seminaries in Pakistan and provided military training by the CIA and Pakistan’s Inter Services Intelligence (ISI). They were regarded by all, including the west, as the mujahideen or holy warriors who were waging a “heroic” jihad to rid their country of foreign occupation and the “ungodly” communists who controlled Kabul. After the defeat of the Soviet forces, the world abandoned Afghanistan and forgot its people who had struggled so valiantly and sacrificed so much in the cause of the free world. Pakistan was left alone with more than three million refugees on its soil and thousands of highly motivated and militarily trained Islamic extremists. The Geneva Accords on Afghanistan signified the end of the Brezhnev and the Reagan doctrines which had dominated the final years of the Cold War. The former sought to protect neighbouring communist regimes while the latter was built around support to insurgencies against such governments. In Geneva the Soviets undertook to end their presence in Afghanistan in support of the Najibullah regime while the US agreed to end its assistance to the mujahideen. The Third Phase: after the Soviet withdrawal The Geneva Accords were flawed in as much as the Afghans were left out of the proximity talks which had dragged on for years. Therefore no agreement was reached on a successor government in Kabul. The Soviets were soon to begin their withdrawal from Afghanistan but continued to support Najibullah for whom they left behind huge quantities of weapons and ammunition for the fight against the mujahideen. In this period there were frequent Afghan Scud missile attacks on the North West Frontier Province (NWFP) of Pakistan. The seven Peshawar-based mujahideen parties, who had resisted the Soviet occupation of Afghanistan, formed an anti-Najib interim government in exile with Pakistan’s backing and encouragement. The most powerful person in this setup was Gulbadin Hikmatyar. It was Islamabad’s hope that the leaders of the mujahideen parties would CRITERION – October/December 2009 113 S. Iftikhar Murshed sit together and work out the modalities for establishing a post-Najib government in accordance with the wishes of the Afghan people. Pakistan, which was under the military rule of general Zia-ul-Haq through the decade-long Soviet occupation of Afghanistan, was staunchly supported by the US-led west and became the third largest recipient of American economic and military assistance after Israel and Egypt. Islamabad’s clandestine nuclear weapons development programme and the reality that the country was under a military dictatorship were ignored. The conclusive defeat of communism was considered far more important than pious concerns about non-proliferation and democracy. With the Soviet withdrawal from Afghanistan, the expectation was that the Najib government would collapse and to hasten this, the mujahideen intensified their attacks against the regime. Their first target was Jalalabad, the capital of the eastern province of Nangarhar. It was expected that the city, which is near the Pakistan border, would be captured with ease. Some seventy soldiers of the regime defected to the mujahideen who, instead of receiving them with open arms, slaughtered them and mutilated their bodies which they sent back to Jalalabad in sacks. The barbarity convinced the city’s defenders that they would meet the same fate and strengthened their resolve to fight. The mujahideen laid siege to the city which continued for three months and ended in their defeat. This boosted the morale of the regime which launched counter-offensives in which the mujahideen suffered further setbacks. The fortunes of the Najib regime continued to rise till an abortive coup attempt in March 1990 by general Tannai, the Khalqi Defence Minister. Thus the old rivalry between the Khalqis and the Parchamites surfaced again. Several Khalqi officers subsequently fled Kabul and many of them sought and were given asylum in Pakistan. There were two immediate consequences of the attempted coup. Najib could no longer trust the Khalqis regardless of whether they had been associated in the coup attempt. They were accordingly purged from the army. This created confusion in the defence forces and destabilized 114 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 the regime even further. The second consequence was that it prompted the Karmal loyalists who were furious at his ignominious ouster to resume their intrigues against the regime. Kabul thus became a hotbed for intrigue and tension which was to continue till the capture of the city by the Taliban. Najib’s position became progressively weaker. His principal supporter, the Soviet Union, was on a steep nosedive to elimination. Thus, he could no longer count on Moscow’s military and economic assistance. The powerful ethnic Uzbek warlord, Rashid Dostum, who had hitherto extended support for purely selfish reasons, also abandoned him. Whereas previously Najib had been willing to take non-communists into the government, he was now ready to step down and transfer power to the mujahideen. Accordingly, in April 1992, he informed the UN of his intentions and the latter devised a mechanism for the transition. It envisaged an interim dispensation consisting of a fifteen-member committee of non-controversial Afghans, living in the US, Europe, the Middle East, Pakistan and Afghanistan. The committee, in turn, would transfer power to the mujahideen within six months. In mid-April 1992, the UN asked the committee members to assemble in Pakistan from where they were supposed to move into Afghanistan. Most of the committee members thus gathered in Islamabad and were about to proceed to Kabul when on 18 April a coup, backed by Ahmed Shah Masood and Abdul Rashid Dostum, was staged by Karmal loyalists. A number of Najib’s supporters, including the Minister of National Security, were killed. Najib, however, managed to escape and took asylum at the UN office in Kabul. The organizers of the coup, all of whom were Persian speaking Parchamites, requested Masood, who was at the time in Charikar sixty-five kilometres to the north of Kabul, to take over. Masood instead asked the seven leaders of the mujahideen factions, who were in Peshawar evaluating the committee’s nominees, to form a government in Kabul. The leaders, however, could not agree on its composition or even what the next step should be. The Peshawar Accord. To facilitate the formation of the government, Pakistan intervened. Prime Minister Nawaz Sharif went to Peshawar on CRITERION – October/December 2009 115 S. Iftikhar Murshed 24 April 1992 and invited the Afghan leaders for talks at the Governor’s house. The six mujahideen groups led by Mujaddadi, Rabbani, Sayyaf, Gillani, Nabi Muhammadi and Yunis Khalis attended. The proceedings were, however, boycotted by Hikmatyar who was considered the most important of the resistance leaders because of his military strength and his extensive control of Afghan territory. The talks nevertheless resulted in an agreement which provided a mechanism for a peaceful political transition in three phases. Under the first phase, Mujaddadi, the head of the weakest mujahideen party, became president for two months from 28 April. In the second phase Mujaddadi was to be succeeded on 28 June by Rabbani who was to remain in office for four months. Phases one and two were successfully implemented albeit with difficulty. The third phase envisaged the drafting of a constitution to be followed by election in the six-month combined presidential terms of Mujaddadi and Rabbani. If the interim government failed to accomplish these tasks within the stipulated time-frame, Rabbani was to step down and hand over power to a Jihadi Council consisting of the leaders of the seven resistance parties. Hikmatyar was furious that minor leaders had been chosen to lead Afghanistan in the six month interim period. He also suspected, and in hindsight he was right, that Rabbani would not relinquish power when his term expired. He, therefore, entered Kabul, captured key positions including the presidential palace and the Ministry of Interior. Ahmed Shah Masood retaliated by immediately attacking the capital with a combined force of his own men, the remnants of the communist elements and Dostum’s Uzbek militia. Hikmatyar was driven out of Kabul but he established himself in Charasiab, a district some twelve kilometres to the south of the capital. Charasiab was to remain his headquarters till it fell to the Taliban two years later. Thus began another sad and violent episode of Afghan history. Hikmatyar’s expulsion from Kabul enabled Mujaddadi to move to the capital on 28 April 1992, four days after the conclusion of the Peshawar Accord, to become the first president of the Islamic Republic of Afghanistan. 116 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 The replacement of the communist regime with an Islamic government was a cause for which the Afghan people had fought for fourteen long years. The cost was enormous. More than a million and a half people were killed, half a million were maimed, a third of the population became refugees and about two hundred thousand faced even more hardship as internally displaced persons. Thousands more were to die from the land mines planted by the Soviet occupation forces. The infrastructure of Afghanistan had been completely destroyed. There was hardly a building that had not been hit during the brutal conflict. There was no longer any irrigation system and agricultural production, the mainstay of the economy, was at a standstill. The tragedy had few parallels in human history. The violence, which was now being inflicted on the country by the Afghans themselves, continued. The peace that was breaking out worldwide did not visit Afghanistan. The government in Kabul existed only in name. The state structure had broken down. The institutional collapse was demonstrated by the disappearance of the army virtually overnight. Huge quantities of weapons which included tanks, aircraft, armoured personnel carriers and massive ammunition dumps were left by the departing Soviet forces for their protégés. In the eastern zone alone, Najib’s corps commander abandoned 633 tanks and thousands of vehicles. Weapons, therefore, were never to be in short supply for the power-hungry Afghan factions. The authority of the interim government did not extend beyond Kabul as the warlords established their own centres of power in the provinces. The Tajik, Ismail Khan of Rabbani’s Jamiat-e-Islami, governed eight south-western provinces from Herat. Dostum, who had previously supported Najib with his Uzbek militia, established himself in the six northern provinces with headquarters in Mazar-e-Sharif. Haji Qadeer, a Pushtun, ruled the three eastern provinces adjacent to Pakistan. Hikmatyar was entrenched in Charasiab. Other local commanders were dominant in Kandahar and the southern provinces. The Shiias, in turn, became the masters of Bamyan and a few central regions. The warlords accepted neither instructions nor advice from the feeble coalition in Kabul and administered their areas as personal fiefdoms. CRITERION – October/December 2009 117 S. Iftikhar Murshed This was accompanied by a countrywide breakdown of law and order. Rape, brigandage, theft and murder brought yet more suffering to ordinary Afghans. The commanders, down from the warlords to the local chiefs, ruled as though by divine right. Each was the law unto himself. During his two month tenure, Mujaddadi tried but failed to have his term of office extended. Rabbani’s assumption of power on 28 June 1992 began with intense shelling of Kabul by Hikmatyar on the pretext that remnants of the communist army including those loyal to the famous Parchamite general, Baba Jan, as well as Dostum were in control of the city. This was denied by Masood and Rabbani. Severe sectarian violence soon erupted in Kabul. Ali Mazari’s Shiias Wahdat-e-Islami based in the western part of the city and the Saudi backed Ittehad-e-Islami of Professor Sayyaf attacked each other. This resulted in thousands of deaths and the destruction of the western part of the capital. As Hikmatyar had anticipated, Rabbani refused to step down at the end of his four month tenure and had his term extended for a further two years through a council he convened on 29 December 1992 with the support of Nabi Mohammadi, Sayyaf and Pir Gillani - the three principle leaders of the mujahideen coalition. It was claimed that the council was attended by 1,335 delegates from all over Afghanistan and was, as such, genuinely representative. This was roundly rejected by Hikmatyar and other non-partisan Afghans. Radio Message of Freedom, run by the Hizb-e-Islami of Hikmatyar, described the proceedings as a “declaration of war against the nation.” Hikmatyar resorted to intense rocket attacks on Kabul and the regime retaliated by strikes against Charasiab. This continued for two months resulting in thousands of civilian deaths and the complete destruction of the southern and eastern part of the capital. Tens of thousands fled the city to take refuge in camps established by the UN in the eastern province of Nangarhar. 118 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 Hikmatyar, who had earlier rocketed Kabul on the flimsy pretext of the presence of communist remnants in the armed forces, now had an excuse to resume his attacks. He claimed with good reason that Rabbani had fraudulently usurped power through a non-representative council and vowed to oust him through military means. The Islamabad Accord. Pakistan intervened again. Prime Minister Nawaz Sharif invited Hikmatyar, Rabbani and the other leaders to Islamabad and the talks resulted in a power-sharing agreement on 7 March 1993 under which Rabbani continued as president and Hikmatyar was appointed Prime Minister. The new arrangement was to last till July 1994 and in this period the regime was to draft a constitution, hold parliamentary and presidential elections and create a national army and police force. The leaders went to Mecca and, in front of Islam’s holiest shrine, the Kaaba, pledged to honour the agreement. However, shortly afterwards differences broke out between Hikmatyar and Rabbani on the formation of the cabinet and the distribution of ministries. In this period Pakistan, which had been preaching the need for political stability to the Afghans, was itself in chaos. President Ghulam Issaq Khan dissolved the national and provincial assemblies on 18 April but the decision was overturned by the Supreme Court and Nawaz Sharif was reinstated on 26 May only to be dismissed again by the president on 18 July because of corruption. Moin Quershi, who had served for many years in the World Bank, headed the interim government till Benazir returned to power for her second term on 19 October 1993. Her government was, in turn, dismissed by President Farouk Leghari three years later and Nawaz Sharif became prime minister again, with a huge parliamentary majority, in February 1997. The Jalalabad Accord. The inability to form a government under the Islamabad understanding led to a resumption of fierce fighting till 29 April 1993 when the leadership of nine mujaheeden groups including Rabbani and Hikmatyar met in Jalalabad at the initiative of the Nangarhar shura led by governor Haji Abdul Qadeer. After protracted negotiations and under pressure of the Nangarhar shura an accord was signed on 20 May which involved some modifications to the Islamabad understanding. CRITERION – October/December 2009 119 S. Iftikhar Murshed The government thus formed included each of the seven Peshawarbased Sunni parties and the Shiias groups. However, despite being the prime minister, Hikmatyar did not dare enter Kabul as he feared that he would be killed by his archenemy, Ahmed Shah Masood, who had become Defence Minister. He, therefore, established himself in Charasiab and ministers were thus obliged to shuttle between the two cities. Cabinet decisions were never implemented. Hikmatyar soon realised that he was prime minister only in name and that actual power vested with Rabbani and Masood. He initially remained silent but when Rabbani refused to endorse a cabinet recommendation that an agreement with Russia under which the latter printed the national currency be abrogated, he reacted sharply and the ill-disguised tensions within the government came into the open. At this point in time Hikmatyar, who barely eighteen months earlier had rocketed Kabul on the mere presumption that Dostum was in the city, reconciled his differences with the latter. The two seemingly implacable ideological enemies thus became allies and forged an anti-government alliance which also included the Shiia Wahdat party of Ali Mazari and the Islamic National Liberation Front of Mujaddadi. The new alliance, which was called the Shura HamAhangi ( the Supreme Coordination Council of the Islamic Revolution of Afghanistan), thus started a war against the Rabbani regime on the first day of 1994 which continued sporadically till February 1995, when the Taliban overran Hikmatyar’s headquarters at Charasiab. Rabbani was to hold office till July 1994. However, he secured a decision from the Afghan Supreme Court, while the chief justice was out of the country, extending his term to December 1994. Even this decision was not respected by him and he continued in office till the Taliban takeover of Kabul in September 1996. The impression that Pakistan was partial to Hikmatyar in this period is not borne out by the extent of financial support disbursed by Islamabad to the individual mujahideen factions. For instance, between 1990 and April 1992, the largest recipient of this assistance was in fact the Jamiate-Islami of Burhanuddin Rabbani. He was paid rupees 460 million (the 120 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 value of the rupee was approximately thirty to the US dollar) for the Jamiat while Ahmed Shah Masood, who headed the military wing of the party, received 142 million rupees. Thus the total assistance given by Pakistan to the Jamiat was 602 million rupees. The Hizb-e-Islami of Younis Khalis was given 496 million rupees. Next in line was Gulbadin Hikmatyar whose party was provided 366 million rupees; professor Sayyaf was paid rupees 244 million; Pir Gillani rupees 241 million; Nabi Mohammadi rupees 240 million; Mujaddadi rupees 160 million and Mohseni rupees 60 million. During the period of Soviet occupation of Afghanistan five to ten times this amount was paid to the factions annually in addition to weapons, ammunition and other supplies. This was, of course, in coordination with the US, Saudi Arabia and other countries who had supported the mujahideen in their struggle against the communists. Phase Four: The Emergence and the rise of the Taliban The Taliban movement was a reaction to the prevailing anarchy after the Soviet withdrawal from Afghanistan and the subsequent misrule of the Rabanni regime. The assumption that they first emerged in the summer of 1994 is erroneous. The Taliban are the product of madrassas or seminaries that have existed in Afghanistan since the coming of Islam into that country. In Afghan history, students from these seminaries have always risen at the time of national crises either to fight invaders or to oppose unpopular regimes within the country. The brunt of the resistance to the British during the Afghan wars of the nineteenth century was from the Taliban of the time. Similarly, the struggle to rid the country of Soviet occupation through the 1980s was spearheaded by the Taliban and, in the second half of 1994, it was again the students from the madrassas who set forth to restore order in the country. In previous times the Taliban always returned to their seminaries after achieving their objectives. This was not to be so after 1994 because on defeating the local warlords, they decided to form the government themselves. In the last week of August 1994, Mulla Omar Akhund set out with forty-five followers from a madrassa in Maiwand, Kandahar, to punish a commander who had molested a local family. It was neither ideology CRITERION – October/December 2009 121 S. Iftikhar Murshed nor religious fervour that accounted for their subsequent success. It was the war-weariness of the populace which made them welcome any force that could deliver them from the hands of brigands. They hungered for the restoration of peace and the semblance of an honest administration no matter how harsh its system of justice. Local warlords had created fiefdoms owing nominal loyalty to one political leader or the other, but imposing in fact their own arbitrary fiat in the areas that they controlled. In Kandahar, the main road to Herat on the one hand, and to Chamman in Pakistan on the other, had toll posts and barriers at virtually every kilometre, where local commanders exacted fees and whatever other extortions they decided upon on any passing traffic. The lives and honour of ordinary citizens were at their mercy. Initially even Rabbani sought to use the Taliban to eliminate his opponents and to quell the unrest that had been generated by his failure to abide by the Islamabad Accord. He offered them assistance and there is sufficient evidence to show that his emissaries frequently contacted the Taliban to offer financial and other support. Rabbani is on record as saying: “The Taliban and some mujahideen from Kandahar asked us to help them to open roads and improve law and order in their province. We supported them.”19 The Taliban, however, did not need such assistance. The local commanders who surrendered brought with them substantial quantities of weapons and ammunition. With each success the ranks of the Taliban swelled with veterans who had fought against the Soviets. However, it was not through force of arms but the persuasiveness of their message that the Taliban were able to triumphantly sweep first the eastern and then the western part of Afghanistan. This was accompanied by surprisingly few casualties. By late October 1994, the Taliban movement gained victories one after another in their war against the mujahideen and, within a short time, captured the whole province of Kandahar, from where they spread their influence to the other parts of the country. During this phase, the Taliban 122 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 were loosely allied to Dostum who controlled six provinces in the north, Hikmatyar who was in place in a small area in eastern Afghanistan, the Hazara Shiias who were predominant in central Afghanistan and also other small groups who had little control of territory. Rabbani declared “jihad” against Dostum and persuaded the grand mufti of Saudi Arabia to issue a “fatwa” or religious injunction against him. The Afghan situation in mid-1994 was very different from what Pakistan had expected after the collapse of the communist regime in Kabul and the disintegration of the Soviet Union. The peace accords between the resistance factions attempted by Islamabad had come to naught and Afghanistan remained in the grip of turmoil and factional fighting. Islamabad was understandably anxious to see the centuries old trade routes to the resource-rich central Asian region reopen. Soon after the establishment of the mujahideen government in Kabul, Pakistan sent a survey team to examine the possibility of reactivating the KabulSalang Pass-Hairatan road to Uzbekistan. However, this route was found to be unfeasible because of the fighting between the Afghan groups. The other route available, the Quetta-Kandahar-Herat-Ashgabat road, was considered more viable. A delegation headed by General Naseerullah Babar, the minister of interior in Benazir Bhutto’s second government, embarked on a journey along this route on 21 September 1994 and completed its travel via Ashgabat, Tashkent, Almaty, Kashghar and Gilgit on 5 October. Special security arrangements were made by Amir Imam, a retired army colonel who was serving as Pakistan’s consul general in Herat. This task was assigned to him because he was known to most of the mujahideen commanders. He claimed that he had trained about eighty thousand of them during the Soviet occupation of Afghanistan. The entire route inside Afghan territory that Babar used was under the control of warlords. The delegation was able to confirm that there was an absence of central authority except in Herat where commander Ismail Khan, who was loyal to the Rabbani regime in Kabul, controlled the road from Dilaram onwards. The delegation met all the major power groups who assured safe passage. Colonel Imam’s assessment, which was rejected by Babar, was that it would be difficult to use this route on a regular basis because of the war lords. CRITERION – October/December 2009 123 S. Iftikhar Murshed Immediately after returning to Islamabad, Babar decided to send a good will caravan which would deliver medical supplies to hospitals along the route. He wanted the caravan to reach Ashgabat in time for Benazir Bhutto’s visit to Turkmenistan from 30-31 October 1994 for that country’s independence day celebrations. What Babar did not realize was that the situation had completely changed since his own transit through Afghanistan the previous month. Kandahar was about to be captured by the Taliban. The convoy consisting of thirty 5-ton military trucks was delayed and was only able to leave Pakistan on 31 October. The journey was hazardous and the convoy was captured on several occasions by local warlords only to be rescued by the Taliban who had taken Kandahar around the time that the caravan reached the city. The despatch of the convoy was an ill-advised decision by the publicity-hungry Babar. The drama and fanfare that went into the whole episode was for no better motive than to project this foolhardy venture as an achievement of the Bhutto government. The lives of the caravan members were unnecessarily risked and their safe return to Pakistan can only be attributed to luck. The same gifts to the four south-western provinces of Afghanistan could have been sent through the traders and would have earned enormous goodwill. Furthermore, the sending of a military convoy at a time when the Taliban were ascendant was interpreted as support for the movement. The erroneous belief that emerged was that the Taliban were a Pakistan-created entity. Islamabad was never able to live down this ill-founded reputation. Babar’s visit to the area just thirty days before Kandahar fell to the Taliban lent further credence to the assumption that they were sponsored by Pakistan. Babar also did little to dispel the rumours at the time that the Taliban owed their existence to him. In actual fact, Babar had never met the Taliban and was surprised to learn about their emergence. His reference to them as “our boys” after their initial successes fuelled vicious and unrelenting propaganda against Pakistan and resulted in regional tension which was to last several years. Lastly, though the Rabbani regime had long outlived its legality, it was still recognized by Pakistan. However, Babar did not think it necessary to obtain Kabul’s permission for sending the convoy. This was clearly a violation of Afghanistan’s sovereignty and 124 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 was justifiably resented by the Rabbani government. In 1994 and 1995 there were several international initiatives aimed at promoting a political settlement in Afghanistan. Pakistan supported the idea of proximity talks which was proposed during 7th Islamic Conference of Foreign Ministers (ICFM) in Islamabad from 7-9 September 1994. The first round of such talks was held during the ICFM between the different Afghan groups and the secretary general of the Organization of the Islamic Conference (OIC). This was followed by a second round in Tehran from 29 November to 7 December in which Pakistan, Iran and the UN participated. These meetings like so many others achieved nothing. In March 1995, Mehmoud Mestiri, the UN secretary general’s special envoy for Afghanistan proposed the establishment of a council to discuss the modalities of a peace settlement. He envisaged that the council would consist of two representatives from each of Afghanistan’s thirty-two provinces and, to balance its composition, also include fifteen to twenty eminent personalities both from inside as well as outside Afghanistan. The proposal remained on the drawing board and never got off the ground. Rabbani, however, visited Pakistan from 1315 March to attend a summit meeting of the Economic Cooperation Organization.20 The participants did nothing more than take “serious note” of the situation in Afghanistan and unanimously agreed to support a UN-sponsored peace process. On 10 March 1995, Pakistan’s ambassador to Afghanistan, Qazi Humayun, assumed charge of his post but the mission was temporarily relocated to Jalalabad the following day because the embassy had been ransacked by the Rabbani regime the previous year. The mission finally reopened in Kabul on 3 May 1995. Around this time, the unrepresentative nature of the Rabbani regime was acknowledged by Mehmoud Mestiri, when he declared: “General Masood, Professor Rabbani and others associated with him have been arguing that by pushing the Taliban out of Kabul they have achieved victory all over Afghanistan. In fact, the reality is that the base of the government has become narrower and could be said to represent only the Tajik ethnic group. The Pushtuns, Uzbeks CRITERION – October/December 2009 125 S. Iftikhar Murshed and Hazaras have been alienated. These three ethnic groups represent about 60 percent population of Afghanistan.”21 The special representative on Afghanistan of the OIC secretary general, Ibrahim Saleh Bakr, visited Pakistan from 11-12 June 1995 and proposed the formation of a group of a hundred persons representing all the provinces of Afghanistan as well as representatives of political parties and neutral personalities which would meet in Jeddah to discuss the establishment of a transitional government. This proposal was preceded by a visit to the region by prince Faisal Al-Turki, the Saudi minister for intelligence services (several years later he became the Saudi ambassador to Britain), in the last week of May. Again, like the Mestiri proposal, it was a non-starter. General Abdul Wali, the son-in-law of ex-King Zahir Shah, arrived in Pakistan on 29 June 1995 for a six-week visit. He proposed the convening of a grand assembly, known in Afghan traditions as a loya jirga, for the transfer of power to a transitional government. The proposal for a loya jirga has been made time and again, as well as after the 11 September 2001 terrorist attacks in New York and Washington, to resolve the problems of Afghanistan. However, the three requirements for a loya jirga are that it can only be convened by a head of state recognized by all Afghans, it can only be held on Afghan soil and it is called at a time of grave national crisis. The first of these preconditions posed a serious problem as, for the past several decades, the country did not have a leader acceptable to all segments of Afghan society. On 6 September 1995, the Pakistan embassy in Kabul was burnt by a mob of three thousand instigated by the ruling junta. A Pakistan-based sanitary worker, who the crowd mistook for ambassador Humayun, was killed. The ambassador, the defence attaché, other diplomats and embassy personnel received serious injuries. The defence attaché was stabbed several times and was left bleeding on the floor because it was assumed that he had died. Despite this, which was the second attack on the embassy in a year, Pakistan did not break diplomatic relations with the Rabbani regime. Islamabad’s policy has always been to recognize the entity that controlled Kabul. Thus Pakistan recognized the regimes 126 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 of Sardar Daud, Tarakki, Hafizullah Amin, Karmal, Najibullah and Rabbani long after the latter had lost its legitimacy and even after it had ransacked and burnt the Pakistan embassy. The reason is Pakistan’s porous and more than two thousand kilometre-long border with Afghanistan, makes it impossible not to have dealings with any regime in Kabul, no matter how hostile. In the case of the Taliban, however, Pakistan withheld formal recognition for nine months, even though the movement had taken Kabul and was in control of most of Afghanistan. The reason for this was that Islamabad hoped to encourage the Taliban to include all other ethnic groups in its government using the bait of recognition to achieve such an outcome. Nevertheless, regular contact and day-to-day dealings with the Taliban continued unhindered. In the winter of 1995-96, the Tajik-dominated regime took a strategic decision to broaden its base by inviting other leaders to join it. In January, Rabbani’s representative, Dr. Abdul Rahman, met Hikmatyar in Sarobi, Dostum in Mazar-e-Sharif and the Shiia opposition groups in Bamyan. These initial meetings achieved nothing. Instead, in February, all the opposition groups with the exception of the Taliban established a tenmember council for negotiating with Kabul. In the interim, the other groups began to gravitate towards Kabul. On 27 March the council of the Hizb-e-Islami gave Hikmatyar the power to negotiate a power-sharing agreement with Kabul. By the first week of May approximately one thousand Hikmatyar troops arrived in the capital to help in its defence against the Taliban. On 26 June, Hikmatyar entered Kabul to assume the post of Prime Minister and his party was given nine portfolios in the new coalition. The same day the Taliban launched a massive rocket attack on the capital in which sixtyone people were killed and more than a hundred injured. The political breakthrough induced Rabbani to visit Jalalabad in an endeavour to persuade its shura which controlled the three eastern provinces to abandon its policy of neutrality and to join his government. Rabbani offered to step down in favour of any moderate leader and proposed a meeting of all Afghan groups to elect a new head of state. CRITERION – October/December 2009 127 S. Iftikhar Murshed On a parallel track, negotiations were intensified with Dostum while Masood kept the Taliban at bay outside Kabul. Through December 1995, Dostum came under considerable Iranian pressure, which included financial inducements, to reconcile with Rabbani. The Iranian expert on Afghanistan, deputy foreign minister Alaeddin Broujerdi, visited Dostum several times during the month to persuade him to receive Rabbani in Mazar-e-Sharif. Dostum was double minded. He was half inclined to meet Rabbani through Iranian good offices because he had been promised financial support but feared that such a move might not be in his interest. Rabbani, he felt, was isolated and this militated against any compromise with him. On the other hand Dostum also thought that he could gain political mileage if Rabbani came to Mazar-e-Sharif to apologize to him for the Saudi “fatwa” and the declaration of the “jihad.” Iran’s efforts achieved some success as Dostum agreed to a truce at the end of August1996 and the Salang highway connecting Kabul to the north was opened for civilian traffic for the first time in over a year. However, Dostum refused to join the government till greater autonomy was guaranteed to the provinces. There were also problems within the Shiia Hizb-e-Wahdat which had split into two factions headed respectively by Karim Khalili and Akbari. Broujerdi, therefore, visited Bamyan in December 1995 and established a commission to reconcile the differences between Khalili and Akbari. Iran’s obvious objective was to get the ethnic minorities to unite under the Shiias and the Persian speaking groups of the north in support of Rabbani. For their part, the Taliban refused to negotiate with anyone nor did they come forward with any power-sharing proposal of their own. They adamantly insisted on the overthrow of the Kabul regime and convened a meeting of more than a thousand notables in Kandahar on 20 March 1996 to chalk out the future strategy while they continued to shell and rocket Kabul. The meeting, which ended on 4 April, nominated Mulla Omar as amirul momineen (the commander of the faithful) and the undisputed leader of the “jihad” against the Rabbani regime. This confirmed that the 128 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 Taliban had no intention of returning to their seminaries after achieving their objectives because the amirul momineen, like absolute monarchs, continues in office for his entire life unless he becomes mentally or physically incapacitated. In April 1996 alone the Taliban fired 866 rockets on Kabul killing 180 civilians and injuring an estimated 550. Their onslaught resulted in the fall of Jalalabad with less than twenty casualties. In Sarobi, where Rabbani and Masood had sent their own commander to strengthen its defence and mine the approaches, the local Ahmadzai tribe joined the Taliban, and the commanders around Sarobi either surrendered immediately or fled to Kabul. It had been claimed that the capital could sustain a siege for more than a year but its surrender came virtually overnight on 27 September 1996 with only 200 casualties. Almost immediately after entering Kabul, the Taliban killed Najibullah and kept his body hanging for several days in the centre of the city. The capture of Kabul by the Taliban and the retreat of the Rabbani government north of the Hindu Kush resulted in the formation of the Northern Alliance and threw Dostum into prominence. He emerged as the strongman and the leader of the minority ethnic groups. The factions within the Northern Alliance decided to set aside their differences which, nevertheless, continued to simmer beneath the surface as subsequent events would demonstrate. Their immediate priority was to work out a joint political and military strategy against the Taliban. On 4 December 1996, a parallel government was set up in Mazar-e-Sharif by the Northern Alliance. Though it consisted of many parties, the alliance was dominated by three elements which, in descending order of importance at the time, included Dostum’s Uzbek Jumbish-e-Milli, the Tajik Jamiat-e-Islami led by Burhanuddin Rabbani, and the Shiia Hizbe-Wahdat headed by Karim Khalili. Initial International Reaction to the Taliban. The US reaction to the Taliban soon after they had taken Kabul was one of cautious support. The first formal American pronouncement on them came on 18 November 1996 during a UN conference in New York of countries with interest in Afghanistan. Three elements in the statement of the US delegate, CRITERION – October/December 2009 129 S. Iftikhar Murshed assistant secretary Robin Raphel, were particularly interesting. She said: ( i ) the Taliban were purely an indigenous movement; (ii) their success had little to do with military prowess (implying that they were preferred by the Afghan people to the chaos that had been prevailing); and ( iii ) some of the policies pursued by the Taliban were extreme but this could be moderated by engaging with them. The Russians also wanted to establish contact and develop relations with the Taliban. Deputy foreign minister Mamedov, who attended the same UN conference as Raphel, requested the Pakistan delegate to facilitate a meeting between senior Taliban functionaries and representatives of the Russian government. Moscow had earlier told Washington that it would never again repeat the mistake it had made in 1979 of intervening into Afghanistan. Russia had no problems with Taliban control of Kabul and 75 percent of Afghan territory so long as the movement did not advance north along the borders of Uzbekistan and Tajikistan because Moscow feared the export of extremist religious ideology, the influx of refugees and the spill-over of the conflict into these central Asian states. Tehran alone was bitterly opposed to the Taliban. One of the reasons for this was that the Sunni majority areas of Iran were contiguous to Afghanistan. Iran feared that the Taliban might instigate a Sunni uprising on its territory. This apprehension turned to hysteria after the capture of Herat by the Taliban. Furthermore, Tehran considered the Taliban an impediment to its own ambitions in Afghanistan. Perhaps the greatest initial external success which the Taliban met, due to no effort of their own, was the decision of the OIC to adopt the vacant seat formula in respect of Afghanistan. This entailed the expulsion of the Rabbani regime from the OIC where Afghanistan would not be represented till an internationally recognized government was in place in Kabul. After their capture of the Afghan capital, the Taliban leadership repeatedly affirmed that their agenda was purely domestic and that they posed no threat to any country and in particular their neighbours. For 130 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 The Afghan Turmoil From 1747 to 2001 their part, they expected external powers not to interfere in Afghanistan’s internal affairs. This was never to be because some of the neighbouring countries were determined to replay the great game of the nineteenth century in order to carve out their respective areas of influence inside Afghanistan. Instead of engaging with the Taliban, as Robin Raphel had recommended in the UN conference, the international community isolated their regime. The vacuum was filled by Al Qaeda and Afghanistan became the breeding ground for terrorism. With the post-9/11 ouster of the Taliban, the Karzai regime was installed in Kabul under the Bonn Accord of December 2001. The government was dominated by the Tajiks. Though Karzai himself is a Pushtun, he was rejected by his own ethnic group. Despite the elections in 2004, the Al Qaeda-supported Taliban insurgency spread like wildfire through the country. The fraud tainted 20 August 2009 presidential election, which Karzai is said to have won, has further deepened the political crisis and the violence is likely to continue. References: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. G.P. Tate, “The Kingdom of Afghanistan”, p 111. Sir Thomas Holdich, “The Indian Borderland,” Methuen, 1901, quoted in J.C. Griffiths “Afghanistan, p 20. Ludwig W. Adamec, “Afghanistan, 1900-1923, A Diplomatic History,” pp. 4 and 10. Griffiths p.16. Richard S. Newell, “The Politics of Afghanistan,” p.48. Griffiths, op.cit. p.66. Newell, op.cit. p. 185. Griffiths, op.cit. p.66-67. Griffiths, op.cit. p.68. Griffiths, op.cit. p.125. M.G.Aslanov, E.G. Ghaffarbeg, N.A. Kisliakov, K.L. Zadykhin, and G.P. Vasilyeva, “Ethnography of Afghanistan, a Study,” translated by Mark and Greta Slobin in “Afghanistan, Some New Approaches,” published by the Centre for Near Eastern and North African Studies, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, 1957. Aslanov, et.al,op.cit; pp.44-45 and 69-77. Aslanov, et.al, op.cit., pp. 44-45 and 69-77. Quoted in Gregorian, op.cit., footnote, p.34. CRITERION – October/December 2009 131 S. Iftikhar Murshed 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. Holdich, “Gates of India,” quoted in Gregorian, ibid. Newell, op.cit., p.33. Lumsden, H.B.Major, “Mission to Candahar,” quoted in Tate, op.cit. p.154. Interview to the “Middle East Journal” (winter 1952 edition). “Afghan News” of May 1995, published by the Jamiat-e-Islami of Rabbani. The ECO was established in 1985 by Pakistan, Iran and Turkey as a successor to the Regional Cooperation for Development. It was expanded in 1992 to include Afghanistan, Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, Kyrgystan, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan. 21. Speech at the Afghan Support Group meeting in Stockholm, 2 June 1995. 132 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 INTERNAL SECURITY CHALLENGES FOR PAKISTAN Shahwar Junaid* Abstract Pakistan has faced serious internal security challenges since its inception, therefore any review of the present situation must be considered in a historical perspective. Several security problems were embedded in various dispensations at the time of Partition and were never resolved satisfactorily. A number of security challenges Pakistan has faced, and will continue to face, are a result of fault lines created by the nature of the geographical and administrative division of the sub-continent into two independent states. The administrative machinery, physical assets and economic and human resources available to Pakistan, as well as the manner in which they were utilized by successive political and military governments, have been an important factor impinging on internal security. The discourse that follows should reveal how cleverly the future of the Muslims of the sub-continent was shackled to the limitations within the dispensations of Partition and how astutely the limited potential of the political leadership that would be available to Pakistan after the physically frail Quaid passed away, was judged. Author. Pakistan has faced serious internal security challenges since its inception therefore any review of the present situation must be considered in a historical perspective. The forces that contributed to the evolution of a national character after Partition must also be considered for they continue to influence the security environment: the internal security problems encountered by Pakistan today have been compounded * The writer is a former Communications and Media Consultant to the Pakistan Government. Her book, Terrorism and Global Power Systems, was published by the Oxford University Press in 2006. Email waqil42@hotmail.com Shahwar Junaid by the weaknesses and the vagaries in its leadership. Some of the internal security problems Pakistan faced at the outset were the result of the environment created by the Partition of the sub-continent into two independent dominions, and had to be dealt with urgently. These problems included the influx of about two million refugees, lawlessness, loot and arson, killing and civil disturbance by those displaced as a result of the boundary awards. The civil administration lacked the competent personnel to deal with the situation. Disorderly accession and delays in the division of assets meant severe economic limitations that made it extremely difficult to deal with the immediate needs of the population. Defence capability was almost nonexistent. Soldiers assigned to protect the trains and convoys of refugees moving towards Pakistan often ran out of ammunition when fending off attackers while the civil authorities of the Indian Union in the areas through which these refugees were passing did not extend any help to them.1 This is illustrated by the following report datelined Amritsar, 23 September 1947: “Another Muslim Refugee Train…At about 5 p.m. the second train went through but was halted near Khalsa College as it was found that the lines had been removed by the mob. Immediately the train had halted a Sikh-Hindu Jatha of about 8000 in number made determined attacks on the train with rifles, Stens, kirpans, spears and other weapons. The military picket with the help of escort…..were able to hold them off, but it was soon found that the picket was running short of ammunition, so they had to withdraw after expending all but one Sten magazine. “A Dogra company of the Baluch Regt. was sent out as soon as possible but by the time they had arrived at the scene the mob had overpowered the escort…attacked the evacuees, killing and injuring almost all. “It may be noted that the civil authorities here had done absolutely nothing in the way of organising medical aid or giving the few remaining live evacuees any water….I and another officer assisted. I do not think I have ever witnessed such cold-bloodedness by any human beings as I witnessed last night from the civil authorities.”2 134 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Internal Security Challenges for Pakistan This was the situation at the time of Partition.3 At the time Pakistan was governed by the amended Government of India Act of 1935.4 This amended version was called the India Independence Act of 1947.5 It provided for a Governor General and head of state to succeed the British Viceroy. This Governor General was to have authority over both the newly independent countries. The Constituent Assembly of each country was given the task of preparing a constitution and was to serve as the federal legislature until the new constitutions of each country became effective. Quaid-i-Azam Mohammed Ali Jinnah was of the view that the British Viceroy would not be able to secure the interests of Pakistan while serving as Governor General of India. One concern was that adjustments advantageous to India might be made after Independence under such a Governor General. He was a statesman and he had learnt during negotiations leading up to Partition, that any territorial or other demands he made had to be carefully calculated and timed otherwise the entire plan for the creation of a nation state for the Muslims of the subcontinent could be called off at any point prior to the actual announcement of Partition. Mr. Jinnah enjoyed a unique position by virtue of having spearheaded the political movement that led to the creation of Pakistan within a short while. He decided to become Governor General as well as the President of Pakistan’s first Constituent Assembly and the Commander-in-Chief of the Armed Forces of the country in order to safeguard its interests. Because he was discreet about his intentions his demand shocked the British. Under the India Independence Act of 1947, a plebiscite was held to decide the future of areas directly administered by the British (British Provinces) but the 562 princely states were at liberty to accede to either of the two independent dominions in the sub-continent. They were expected to be mindful of the wishes of their people. However, their decisions were influenced6 by many other considerations including the advice of the British Agents assigned to them. By August 1947 nearly all of these had formally opted for either India or Pakistan. However, the princes of Hyderabad, Junagadh and Kashmir had not. Under the law in CRITERION – October/December 2009 135 Shahwar Junaid force they also became independent on 15 August 1947. A month later Junagadh, with a predominantly Hindu population, opted for Pakistan - India annexed the territory pending a plebiscite. Hyderabad Deccan, with a predominantly Hindu population, postponed a final decision and began negotiations with both India and Pakistan; it was asking for a semi-independent status with direct links to the Commonwealth when it was annexed by India in September 1948. The Hindu ruler of Jammu and Kashmir, which had a predominantly Muslim population (85%) decided to opt for India after signing letters of accession to both India and Pakistan: Pakistan objected and war broke out. On 24 October 1947 Muslim volunteers, including those from the North West Frontier Province, announced the establishment of a ‘Provisional Government of Kashmir.’ The United Nations intervened and resolved to hold a plebiscite under UN auspices. India agreed to a plebiscite. Subsequently, New Delhi refused to honour its pledge and continued to occupy twothirds of the state.7 This and a number of other disputes that were born with the territorial dispensation at the time of Partition, created a regional environment in which the destabilisation of civil order and the manipulation of the internal security situation in Pakistan became possible. A boundary commission was established prior to Partition but a rough outline of the swathes of territory that were to be a part of Pakistan, was on official maps and being studied long before that. Mr. Jinnah was aware of all this and appeared to go along with the plans being made. He kept his counsel while developing a strategy to safeguard the future of Pakistan. Plebiscite or no plebiscite, regardless of the expressed future intentions and the negotiations of the princely states with representatives of the Muslim League and Congress, the territories assigned to Pakistan were initially in three large patches that were separated from each other by Indian territory.8 The status of the Northern Areas and Kashmir was, ostensibly, not decided: theoretically the princely states were free to opt for either country. However, there was no doubt that the British could, and would, use their influence and advise the princes to go one way or the other in order to create a new power equation in the independent sub-continent. The princely states of Dir, Chitral, Amb and Hunza were well-advised by the British agent there and acceded to Pakistan 136 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Internal Security Challenges for Pakistan promptly. They retained substantial autonomy in administration and customary law and continue to be a bulwark against conspiracies against Pakistan. According to off-the-record accounts, it did not appear to be the intention of the British government to allow these areas, particularly Kashmir, to become part of Pakistan as this would have strengthened the new state territorially and politically to an extent that did not fit in with their plans for the future of the sub-continent. According to the territorial dispensation at the time of Partition the source of rivers supplying water to argi-based Pakistan’s vital irrigation system was to remain under Indian control. During the first few years, waters were apportioned under the 4 May 1948 inter-dominion accord which met immediate needs: after intense negotiations that were broken off several times, the World Bank facilitated dialogue, a limited settlement of the water dispute was reached and the Indus Basin Waters Treaty was signed (16 September 1960).9 The terms of the Treaty were such that without building a number of medium-sized dams and reservoirs at strategic locations, West Pakistan could not safeguard its interests with regard to water security. Instead of building medium-sized dams and reservoirs, Pakistan built the mammoth Tarbela Dam, which besides being a drain on the economy for decades, is a security risk: according to one calculation, if anything were to happen to it a large part of Pakistan would be under water. East Pakistan was surrounded by Indian territory on three sides and buffeted by Bay of Bengal cyclones on the third. Bahawalpur and Khairpur also acceded to Pakistan. The people of the North West Frontier Province voted for Pakistan in the plebiscite that was held there but the Congress government in the province was hostile to the concept of Pakistan: it had even asked its followers not to take part in the plebiscite. Afghanistan and the Indian government cultivated hostile elements within the province and to this day, they continue to use the remnants of such elements to destabilise the area and weaken Pakistan from within. The only country to cast a vote against the admission of Pakistan to the United Nations in 1947 was Afghanistan. Afghanistan was a problem. Its claims on Pakistani territory were based on the ethnic proclivity of tribes on both sides of the border. Pakistan upheld the treaties that Afghanistan and Britain had signed and refused CRITERION – October/December 2009 137 Shahwar Junaid further discussion on the Durand Line. The issue of a porous western border with an ethnically related population has plagued Pakistan since it came into existence: there appears to be little doubt that it has been used by a number of external forces, both national and sub-national, to influence the security environment in Pakistan. In Balochistan the Khan of Kalat exploited some clauses of Kalat’s 1876 treaty with the British and declared independence on 15 August 1947. His real objective in doing so appeared to be the negotiation of favourable terms with Pakistan. A number of other sardars followed suit. In 1948 the matter was settled when the Khan signed formal merger documents. This was followed by his final removal from power and abolition of the state’s boundaries in 1955. In 1958 the Sultan of Oman sold Gwadar, which had been given to one of his ancestors by the Khan of Kalat, back to Pakistan.10 After Partition the Quaid sent official emissaries and then travelled to Balochistan to meet the erstwhile sardars himself. These included Nawab Akbar Bugti, with whom he was photographed shaking hands. Those government officials who went to Balochistan for the first time after Partition and were more familiar with the developed provinces of the sub-continent, were shocked by the inertia and total lack of economic activity in the province and resolved to do something about it: it was not by chance that the Quaid spent his last days in Ziarat. The development of Balochistan with its rich natural resource base, unspoiled coastline, sparse, economically weak population and feudal environment, has remained problematic. The sardars have enduring personal and political links with the states of the Gulf, Afghanistan and Iran and informal trade with all three which is an important source of income in the area.11 This continues to create foreign policy issues for the federal government. It also makes policing the area difficult. The recommendations of the Boundary Commission were a refined version of earlier maps and met little opposition in Bengal, where Mahatma Gandhi was present and used his influence to control communal violence. He hoped that by avoiding bloodshed there would be a chance 138 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Internal Security Challenges for Pakistan for some degree of reunification of the sub-continent at some point in the future. Mahatma Gandhi could not be in two places at the same time: demarcation in the Punjab was resented by the Sikhs. Although the actual boundaries of the two states were not known until the 17 August announcement by the boundary commission, large scale violence began soon after the announcement of the date for independence. Muslim majority areas were expected to go to Pakistan and Hindu majority areas were to be merged with the Indian Union but the demarcation lines left large segments of the Muslim population in India and Hindu and Sikh population in territory that was to be Pakistan. Vicious communal rioting, massacres and a mass movement of population began shortly after the 3 June 1947 announcement of the date of the transfer of power on 14-15 August 1947. The administrative machinery, physical assets and economic and human resources available to Pakistan, as well as the manner in which they were utilized by successive political and military governments, have been an important factor impinging on internal security. The division of the assets of British India between Pakistan and the Indian Union was at a ratio of 5:17 respectively by decision of the Viceroy’s Council in June 1947.12 Division was difficult to negotiate and implement. Although an agreement was reached in December 1948, the actual settlement of various financial disputes went on till 1960. Division of the Indian Civil and Police service was also hard on Pakistan: only 101 of the 1157 officers of the Indian civil service were Muslims. Of these just 95 opted for Pakistan. One Christian, eleven military officers transferring to the civil service and fifty British officers also came to Pakistan as did a small number of professionals. Most had less than ten years of experience.13 The weakness of the administrative setup, relative lack of oversight and poor possibility of recourse to the law due to the chaotic conditions prevailing in the new country, was tempting for the corrupt. In the civil disorder that followed the migration of about two million Muslims from the territories of the Indian Union to Pakistan and the departure of Hindus and Sikhs for Indian Union territories, the plunder and unauthorized occupation of evacuee properties came to the notice of the Quaid, who warned civil servants not to succumb to greed. CRITERION – October/December 2009 139 Shahwar Junaid There were few Muslim officers in the British Indian army. One major-general, two brigadiers and six colonels opted for Pakistan. Including the middle and junior ranks there were just 2500 officers. 500 British officers were retained by Pakistan during the period of transition. Most of those in the technical services were under qualified. The first two commanders-in-chief of the Pakistan army were British. Similarly the navy and the air force were commanded by British officers until 1953 and 1957 respectively. There were only nine regular officers in the navy and sixty-five pilots in the air force. The army was expected to be 150,000 strong. Most of the ordnance factories were in areas that became part of the Indian Union. Pakistan’s share of military material had to be wrested from India despite the division of assets agreement. There were no ships and only two of the ten squadrons of the Royal Indian Air Force were given to Pakistan. In fact, during the first few months after Partition, Pakistan had no armed forces to speak of and was not really in a position to counter India’s aggressive takeovers of territory, hence the need to call for volunteers to counter Indian aggression in Kashmir. Prior to Independence, the police and paramilitary forces of British India were used to further the political objectives of the government besides being responsible for the maintenance of law and order. Their duties were specified in Article 23 of the Indian Police Act of 1861 with revisions made in 1888 and the Police Rules of 1934. By and large these legal instruments continue to be the basis for internal security services in Pakistan.14 Law and order continues to be the responsibility of the provincial governments and there is no doubt that the police is still used to further the political objectives of sitting governments. Centrally administered areas and the tribal areas in the north and northwest are under the Frontier Crime Regulations that have been amended recently.15 The central government controls a number of forces such as the railroad police and airport security force, anti-corruption and anti-narcotics force. The central government also has a number of paramilitary organizations such as frontier corps, frontier constabulary, rangers and other paramilitary organizations that have a link with government intelligence agencies and the military, and these tend to serve the political interests of governments in power. 140 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Internal Security Challenges for Pakistan Traditions in law enforcement handed down by the British colonists of the sub-continent continued in the worst possible form in Pakistan, an independent state: protection of the public and law enforcement have taken second place to enforcement of the political agenda of the government in power. Successive governments have established police agencies with special powers, such as the FSF (Federal Security Force) set up by Z. A. Bhutto and the National Accountability Bureau (NAB) set up by Musharraf in order to intimidate any opposition to their rule and further their own political agenda under the guise of law enforcement. Each successive military government was more brutal than the previous one in its efforts to break the spirit of the civilian public - and all used the police and paramilitary forces to intimidate and harass the people. This was the strength of the administrative core that had to deal with complex internal and external security problems in the new state of Pakistan. At the outset there were severe economic, logistic and administrative challenges since the territorial dispensation did not allow for complementarities in the division of assets. Food security was an enormous issue. Excess wheat produced in West Pakistan was traditionally used in areas that were now part of the Indian Union. Cotton produced there was used by mills in Bombay and other Indian cities. Out of the four major ports in British India, Pakistan got only Karachi. Commodities were in short supply. Initially, Pakistan and the Indian Union allowed the free movement of goods, persons and capital for a year but this agreement broke down in November 1947. Pakistan levied export duties on jute, India on other items. When the British Pound was devalued in September 1949, India followed suit but Pakistan did not; India severed trade relations with Pakistan. There was a rise in the prices of commodities produced in Pakistan after the outbreak of the Korean War in 1950. These commodities included jute and cotton. Pakistan quickly constructed jute and cotton mills and established trade relations with new partners. Although trade relations with India were restored in 1951 they were never critical to Pakistan’s existence. Those early years saw the construction of a powerful, self-sufficient economic base - but restraint and self-sacrifice was required to strengthen it. Similar opportunities to strengthen the CRITERION – October/December 2009 141 Shahwar Junaid Pakistan economy have arisen during the past three decades as a result of changes in the global and regional security environment. Unfortunately, politicians working with the military in the country have only used such opportunities to increase their own personal wealth, not the wealth of the nation. The common civilian has been left with a bankrupt economy where only occasional pockets of prosperity exist. Several security problems were thus embedded in various dispensations at the time of Partition and were never resolved satisfactorily. A number of security challenges Pakistan has faced, and will continue to face, are a result of fault lines created by the nature of the geographical and administrative division of the sub-continent into two independent states. Studies reveal that, from time to time, these fault lines have been activated, exploited and manipulated to create crises and security issues. This has been done by highly motivated and ambitious individuals and groups working with external forces in order to seize control of and exploit the country, its resources and the geo-strategic environment in their own interest: the poor quality and moral corruption of the leadership has been, and continues to be, a major cause of security problems in Pakistan. The discourse that follows should reveal how cleverly the future of the Muslims of the sub-continent was shackled to the limitations within the dispensations of Partition, and how astutely the limited potential of the political leadership that would be available to Pakistan after the physically frail Quaid passed away, was judged. The economic, political and external security challenges faced by Pakistan during the early years were compounded by the swift degradation of the political environment after the death of the Quaid. By that time about 50 percent of the population in urban areas consisted of Muslim refugees. Even before the assassination of the first Prime Minister of Pakistan, his Muslim League was losing control of the country and was unable to meet the expectations of the people. The politicians and bureaucracy alike had become absorbed in enjoying the trappings of office and power instead of pursuing the public weal. As early as 1949 the need to use laws of preventive detention and those prohibiting the gathering of more than five persons were being used again. In 1949 the Public and Representative Office Disqualification Act 142 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Internal Security Challenges for Pakistan (PRODA) was enacted to allow the government to disqualify persons found guilty of ‘misconduct,’ a broad term that could be interpreted in many ways. In 1952, the Security of Pakistan Act expanded the powers of the government in the interests of public order. The first attempted military coup d’etat in Pakistan took place in March 1951. The Chief of General Staff of the Army and fourteen other officers were caught in Rawalpindi, conspiring to overthrow the government. They were tried and convicted but subsequently set free. By April 1953, in a wrangle over limitations on executive power, the Governor General had installed a cabinet in which one serving General and one Major General on civilian duty, were ministers. This provided the military with an opportunity to play a direct role in politics. Twenty days after his appointment on 7 October 1958 as Chief Martial Law Administrator, General Ayub replaced Iskander Mirza and took control of the country. Thereafter a cycle of long periods of oppressive, spiritshattering military dictatorship followed. These were interspersed by intervals of managed democracy characterised by carefully engineered crises and chaos. The results of the indirect presidential elections of 2 January1965 were revealing because only the younger sister of the Quaid-e-Azam, Miss Fatima Jinnah, was the candidate of the Combined Opposition Parties (COP) and was seen to enjoy overwhelming support in both East and West Pakistan. But she had to be defeated, one way or other (she eventually died in mysterious circumstances in Karachi on 8 July 1967) in order to keep Ayub Khan in power. This was done by rigging the elections. Language riots during the 1960s targeted the so-called Mohajir community which had sided with the Miss Fatima Jinnah and the COP during the 1964 election campaign.16 The September 1965 war with India, for which the ground had not really been prepared in Kashmir, and from which few expected results by way of territory in Kashmir, was aimed to win goodwill for the Ayub regime and bolster support for the armed forces. However growing discontent compelled Ayub Khan to step down and he handed over power to General Yahya Khan who organized elections in 1970. However he CRITERION – October/December 2009 143 Shahwar Junaid refused to allow the Awami League of East Pakistan which had won a majority of the seats in the National Assembly to form the government. This and the unpopularity of the regime paved the way for the uprising in East Pakistan that would eventually lead to war and an ignominious defeat at the hands of the Indian army that landed more than 90,000 Pakistanis, including approximately 60,000 hapless soldiers, in Indian prisoner of war camps and the break-up of the country. During the 1950s and 1960s Pashtun nationalist elements continued to be active in the NWFP and the Federally Administered Tribal Areas (FATA). Some elements on both side of the Pak-Afghan border favoured the creation of a Pashtun state regardless of the impractical nature of such a proposal. However, Pashtuns were well represented in the civil service as well as the armed forces and succeeding generations had relatively moderate political views.17 The collapse of the Afghan state, its invasion by the Soviet Union, the influx of 1.5 million Afghan refugees, the cross-border US war with the Soviets, the radicalization of the Jihadis and the disorder they created in the area, as well as India’s increasingly intrusive policy created an environment in which the most radical demand in recent years has been for a change of name for the province. Nationalist elements themselves are in power, and they are now responsible for controlling the activities of militants in the area. The military operations in the tribal areas, as well as Swat and Dir have been viewed with scepticism in some quarters. Many locals are of the view that the problem was created by elements within the military itself, as a strategic diversion within the war on terror. Others believe that the radicalization of Islam in this area has taken place under military patronage. About two million people were displaced as a result of the military operation in Swat and Buner and are now moving back to rebuild their shattered lives.18 In Baluchistan there were periods of armed conflict in 1948 and 1958. Between 1973 and 1977 there was a nationalist insurgency that was subdued by the army and this resulted in thousands of deaths. India and Afghanistan were accused of providing support to the nationalists. 144 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Internal Security Challenges for Pakistan The Baluchistan Liberation Army established in 1980 by Khairbux Marri has re-surfaced recently. All this should never have happened. Once the gas fields had been discovered the local population should have been closely involved in their development and subsequent operation. A settlement on royalty should have been based on formulae acceptable to all parties: in many parts of the world electricity, oil and gas produced in one region is utilized at subsidized rates in other parts of the country but exported at higher rates. The construction of the Gwader port was another opportunity to provide the fruits of development to the people of Baluchistan but that opportunity was also lost when even the semiskilled labour for the task was brought in from other provinces and the local population was ignored. The same thing happened when deep sea fishing contracts were awarded to foreign firms. This not only depleted the marine resources, but also impoverished the local population still further because they were deprived of their traditional source of food and income. This intolerable situation has been compounded by repression and even target killing of those who voiced their opposition and sought redress of their grievances. The killing of Nawab Akbar Bugti resulted in bitter resentment among the people of the area against the Pakistan government. Tensions continue to simmer and a war-like situation prevails. The Lal Masjid operation in Islamabad was another avoidable episode. The religious seminary attached to the mosque had been constructed with the knowledge of the government. It was surrounded by the armed forces and hundreds of its resident students, men, women and children died in the subsequent firing. The two men running the seminary had obviously been brainwashed over a period of time and did not appear to be in their senses. The intervention of religious scholars who had offered to mediate was rejected just as it was about to bear fruit. There was a spate of suicide bombings after the tragedy. The people who came to collect the bodies of their dead children were mostly from the NWFP and FATA. Most were very poor. They were broken and shattered. This again generated bitterness and the society was further radicalized.19 Sectarian tension was exacerbated and found expression in bomb attacks time and again on Shia and Sunni mosques, as well as target CRITERION – October/December 2009 145 Shahwar Junaid killing of scholars and religious leaders of both sects. It was suggested that the Ulema of the two sects should, without reservation, condemn any such incident and be seen standing together for instance, at funeral prayers for the victims of sectarian violence to pre-empt serious civil disorder. This did not materialize. The Islamic Revolution of Iran had an enormous impact on the political psyche of the West Asian region. In essence, the region moved out of the effective sphere of influence of Western governments. Afghanistan became a crucible of international intrigue during the late 1970s and 1980s. The Soviet Union had occupied Afghanistan and the United States launched cross-border operations from Pakistan to dislodge the Soviets. This cross-border military activity radicalized the culture of the tribal belt and the Muslim mercenaries entering to wage Jihad under the United States acquired the military sophistication and the technical know-how that they never could have acquired in any other way. After the Soviet withdrawal from Afghanistan, Pakistan was left in the lurch and had to contend with armed jihadis who sought to impose their own interpretation of Islam in the region. This continued till the fateful events of 9/11. September 11, 2001 was a heaven-sent opportunity for the military rulers who seized power in 1999 from the elected government of Nawaz Sharif. The Musharraf regime had been shunned by the Clinton Administration. 9/11 provided the military-dominated government an opportunity to ingratiate itself with the Bush Administration by offering unconditional support for its war on terror and invasion of Afghanistan. The regime could now ask for restoration of assistance that had been blocked when the country conducted nuclear tests in May 1998, in response to those of India earlier in that month. It could also look forward to years of fruitful and rewarding cooperation in security in the style of Zia-ul-Haq. The beneficiaries were the members and associates of the regime. The cost, of course, would be paid by the demonising the tribal belt and Islam. The new regime was ruthless in enforcing corporate values in governance for ‘profit maximisation’ and returns that it then applied in its own interest. However, their activities discredited the armed forces in the eyes of the civilian public. 146 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Internal Security Challenges for Pakistan In an introduction to a research paper on Pakistan’s political and security challenges 20 (House of Commons Library, London), the authors state, ‘Pakistan has had a central role as an incubator of militant Islam since the 1980s. Equally, despite the fact that there have been several periods of civilian rule, democracy has failed to put down roots in the country. The military has been a powerful player within the polity and economy since independence.’ The truth of the matter is that the people of Pakistan have, time and again, dislodged military dictators through street power only to find a new one prepared and ready in the wings. The desire for justice, a democratic dispensation and a belief in representative rule, one vote for one person, is very powerful in Pakistan and has enabled the public to strive for these goals under the most oppressive conditions. What we need to check is who, or what, emboldens adventurers who create internal security crises in Pakistan. In the same research paper (quoted above) the authors observe, ‘The US and EU member Governments have been strong supporters of President Musharraf since September 11, 2001, donating billions in military, humanitarian and development assistance….’ Since a record numbers of civilians live below the poverty line today none of the humanitarian and development assistance appears to have reached the civilian public in Pakistan. According to one report virtually all the money, USD 5 billion, was routed through the Department of Defence Coalition Support Funds to reimburse key allies in the global war on terror and there is little documentation of how the money was used.21 There are several other US programs with little oversight, under which the Pakistan military leadership is said to have benefited enormously. The answer to internal security challenges in Pakistan lies in identifying a statesman who has never taken anything from Pakistan, who needs nothing from Pakistan, who has everything and who is only interested in the public weal. In fact the real answer to Pakistan’s internal security challenges is another Quaid. Only then will the games that lesser men have been playing in this country stop. References: 1 Tuker, Lieut- General. Sir Francis, While Memory Serves: Cassell & Company LtdLondon:1950. P.481-484. CRITERION – October/December 2009 147 Shahwar Junaid 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 148 Tuker, Lieut- General. Sir Francis, While Memory Serves: Cassell & Company LtdLondon:1950. The Transfer of Power Documents, 1942-1947,India Office Library: London Parliament and India, 1858-1947, U.K. Parliament: 2008.06.02, Indian Independence Act 1947 (c.30). Revised Statute from the Uk Statute Law Database, Office of Public Sector Information, National Archives, UK. Retrieved 2008.06.02 (subsequent enactments and amendments to the text are incorporated with annotations). V.P.Menon: The Transfer of Power in India; 1957:Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey. UN Security Council Resolution 47 (1948) of April 1948; 51 (1948) of June 3 and 80 (1950) of March 14, 1950 and the UN Commission for India and Pakistan Resolution of 13 August 1948 and 5 January 1949 and 91 0f 30 March 1951.. V.P.Menon: The Transfer of Power in India; 1957:Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey. Michel Aloys Arthur, The Indus Rivers: A Study of the Effects of Partition; Yale University Press: New Haven, 1967 Hasan, Mushirul, ed. India’s Partition Porter, Gareth (June 21, 2007) US-Iran Arms Claim reveals Cheney-Military Rift. Inter Press Service. Library of Congress: Country Profile Pakistan, Retrieved August 24, 2009 Library of Congress Country Profiles: Pakistan. Retrieved September 02, 2009 Kantikar, V.P. Partition of India: East Sussex: Wayland, 1987 Philips and Wainwright:eds.The Partition of India: Policies and Perspectives 1935-1947. Cambridge, MA: MIT, 1970 August 13, 2009 Mohajirs, Karachi and Pakistan Politics (part 1). www.gbytes.gsood.com: 2007-07-25. Retrieved September 01, 2009 C.Jaffrelot (ed), Nationalism Without a Nation? New Delhi (2002) P.25 A Job Well Done, Editorial, The Nation, July 20, 2009 International Crisis Group, Discord in Pakistan’s Northern Areas, Asia report No.131, 2 April 2007. House of Commons Library, Research Paper 07/68; 13 September 2007. The Center for Public Integrity: Billions in Aid With No Accountability Pakistan receives the most post 9/11 U.S military funding; 5/31/2007. CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 REFORMING A CULTURE OF POLITICAL AMBIGUITY: PROMOTING POLITICAL PARTIES AND AN INDEPENDENT LEGISLATURE IN AFGHANISTAN1 Niloufer Siddiqui* Abstract Effective and democratic political parties have failed to develop in Afghanistan as a result of legal and constitutional constraints instituted in the post-Bonn era. Already shrouded with a historical burden of illegitimacy, political parties are held responsible by the Afghan populace for the destruction unleashed during the communist and muhajideen eras. The Single Non-Transferrable Voting (SNTV) System under which the Wolesi Jirga and Provincial Councils operate today has simply served to worsen this situation. This system has ensured the persistence of political patronage. Despite the relatively successful parliamentary elections of 2005, the Wolesi Jirga has retained an ultimately conservative, undemocratic outlook due to the predominance of personality-driven ‘proto parties’ associated with previous eras’ power-brokers. However, the relationship of these parties to the legislature is tenuous – Members of Parliament continue to vote and act as individuals, resulting in the atomization of the parliament. The need for a cohesive and representative legislative agenda is particularly critical in a transitioning democracy; the impression that little is being achieved by Parliament simply diminishes the legitimacy of the government. Failure to provide the appropriate legal channels for political parties to air their views or * Niloufer Siddiqui is a scholar and works in an Islamabad-based international organization. Email niloufersiddiqui@gmail.com Niloufer Siddiqui be represented carries the risk that sub-state actors and more extreme groupings could begin to dominate the system. Afghanistan is in the nascent years of its democratic endeavor; yet as it struggles to maintain security in the face of a growing insurgency, priority must be given to halting this trend towards personalistic politics and simultaneously moving towards internally democratic, issue-based politics. Introduction In establishing a democratic framework for Afghanistan, the 2004 Constitution provided answers to years of debate surrounding how best to initiate a new era of governance in this conflict-ridden country. In doing so, however, it was recognized that the system being selected was – at least in part – a product of its time. When Karzai stated, “If five or ten years down the line we find that stability improves, proper political parties emerge, and we judge that a parliamentary system can function better, then a Loya Jirga can at a time of our choosing be convened to adopt a different system of government,”2 he was implicitly suggesting that the decisions being made were dictated by circumstance; the Constitution, therefore, did not necessarily represent the best longterm political system for Afghanistan. Inherently, as in other postconflict situations, there was a choice to be made between security and governance, representation and stability. This dichotomy has proven particularly relevant to the debate surrounding the role of political parties in Afghanistan’s future, and how best to encourage the development of these parties. With one set of elections firmly under its belt, Afghanistan is looking ahead to presidential elections scheduled for August 2009, and parliamentary elections likely to take place in 2010. While the 2005 parliamentary elections were widely hailed as a success, they also served to isolate the teething problems that Afghanistan faced in the nascent years of its new government. Not least of these was the realization that the Single Non-Transferrable Voting (SNTV) System that had been chosen was not suited to the development of political parties, and was leading Afghanistan down a path of individualistic, personality-driven politics rather than issue-based, party politics. Few would disagree today that political parties form an integral part of the democratic endeavor; yet, in 150 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan transitional democracies, the question of sequencing plays a key role. In an ethnically divided nation such as Afghanistan, many policy-makers fear that political parties will form along ethnic and religious lines, their presence, thereby, working merely to exacerbate existing societal tension and sectarian strife. Case studies of post-conflict situations have suggested that, particularly in situations where ethnic divides overlap with unequal distribution of economic resources, the presence of political parties can, in fact, harden existing cleavages.3 Nonetheless, as political parties have been formally excluded from the political system, elites and power-brokers from previous eras have continued to dominate the political scene in Afghanistan. In this way, the existing system has not so much dissuaded the creation of political parties as it has worked to strengthen existing factions and benefited armed factions-turned-parties, mostly led by warlords. The fractious nature of politics in Afghanistan has ensured the historic absence of a space in which political parties can effectively develop. Nonetheless, it is possible to trace the development of political parties through Afghanistan’s various periods of turmoil leading up to the post-Bonn era. The parties currently operating in Afghanistan are not conventional parties in the sense that Western countries are accustomed to – Thomas Ruttig refers to them instead as “proto parties,” a term which captures their lack of institutionalized mandate, hierarchy and consistent system of membership.4 While their existence provides a template from which further mobilizing along democratic lines may be possible, these parties face a severe crisis of legitimacy and are distrusted by most segments of society. Many Afghan citizens view them as having wrought destruction during the communist era, or as having been mere fronts for warlords during the contentious years under the mujahideen. This distrust is compounded by the parties’ linkages to external players; in the 1980s, regional intervention by countries with vested strategic interests in Afghanistan helped prop up political parties – Pakistan’s involvement resulted in the creation of the “Peshawar Seven” and Iran’s in the “Tehran Eight.” That these parties lack legitimacy is clear from local discussions taking place within the country, which indicate resentment at the “mushrooming” of political parties. Detractors argue that their steep increase in society is an indication that they are “nothing CRITERION – October/December 2009 151 Niloufer Siddiqui more than NGOs in political disguise.”5 A study conducted in 2005 quoted a Provincial Council candidate as stating, “The word ‘parties’ is hated by Afghans. People keep themselves away from parties.”6 Political parties thus face both institutional and pragmatic constraints in Afghanistan, made even more difficult by a system which has inadvertently favored undemocratic parties that have caused contention in the legislature and halted the democratic endeavor. As the country moves forward, it must, with international support, seek to provide the legal and institutional basis necessary for the development of centrist, inclusive parties. In the absence of such parties, politics in Afghanistan will remain personality-driven and merely serve to harden, rather than ease, societal cleavages. The undemocratic and largely conservative parties and blocs which have started to stamp their authority in the legislature must face effective competition from forward-looking, moderate parties, before the former become increasingly entrenched. Existing political parties must be provided incentives in order to moderate their discourse and work effectively towards a democratic Afghanistan, particularly as – in the short run at least – they are likely to continue to determine the course of events. 152 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan Democracy and Political Parties: Is the Multi-Ethnic Afghanistan Ready? Map taken from Strategic Forecasting, Inc. (Stratfor).Accessed March 23, 2009. <http:// web.stratfor.com/images/middleeast/map/Afghan_ethnic_800.jpg.> E.E. Schattschneider has argued that “political parties created democracy and modern democracy is unthinkable save in terms of parties,”7 a claim that has been supported in one form or another by theorists ranging from Alexis de Tocqueville to Seymour Lipset to Larry Diamond. Samuel Huntington has similarly argued that “violence, rioting and other forms of political instability are more likely to occur in political systems without strong parties than in systems with them.”8 The existence of an organized opposition, functioning within the governmental apparatus, provides an avenue through which to institutionalize dissent, restrain incumbents9 and establish democratic norms through conflict between parties. When examining future prospects for political party development in multiethnic countries searching for a unifying national identity, the question of how to prevent fractionalization along ethnic or sectarian lines becomes increasingly important. Lipset has argued CRITERION – October/December 2009 153 Niloufer Siddiqui that parties must have an “almost permanent base of support among a significant segment of the population if they are to survive electorally. Parties in new electoral democracies will be inherently unstable unless they become linked to deep-rooted sources of cleavage .”10 In Afghanistan, these sources of cleavage are largely ethnic and sectarian. Although recent statistics are difficult to obtain, data from the CIA World Factbook indicates an ethnic composition in which Pashtuns form the majority with 42% of the population, Tajiks 27%, Hazaras 9% and Uzbeks 9%.11 Sunni Muslims make up 80% of the population, while Shia Muslims make up about 19%. The question in a political context such as Afghanistan’s remains one of whether stable and internally-democratic political parties will emerge when an electoral system which caters to them is in place, or whether the choice for an electoral system should be dictated by the type of parties that are currently in existence. A conference examining the development of political parties in post-conflict scenarios found the following: Traditionally, constitutionalists have attempted to avoid political parties, the assumption being that parties should be left to develop freely. . however . . unbridled party formation in conflict-prone societies may contribute to the emergence of ethnic parties and . . the formation of aggregated interests, bridging societal groups, is a long process.12 Thus, political parties “have the capacity to bridge or worsen cleavages in societies” and can act as either instigators or managers of conflict.13 Given their role, it becomes apparent that managing the activities of political parties is essential, and harnessing their advantages for the benefit of the country should remain a priority of the government. Marvin Weinbaum agrees that the strongest affinity in Afghanistan would inevitably be along ethnic lines; however, while the strengthening of parties along these schisms might be potentially dangerous to the creation of a stable national state, it is essential to recognize that ethnic 154 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan parties will not necessarily be monolithic.14 Manipulating the electoral system in a way which prevents a ‘natural’ movement towards the formation of parties or blocs simply makes these blocs “unaccountable, less democratic and less able to respond to voters’ interests.”15 As the results of the 2005 parliamentary elections have demonstrated and as discussed in the following section, the official absence of political parties has not prevented association along ethnic lines in Afghanistan – if anything, the fractionalization or atomization of the parliament has been broken largely by ethnic alliances. The current Parliament’s ethnic composition is largely equivalent to the ethnic distribution of Afghan society, a situation which may work to replicate society’s divisions but ultimately ensures the Parliament’s legitimacy. With Pashtuns, at 47.4%, forming the largest individual ethnic grouping, the Parliament has also not been dominated by any one ethnic group.16 Andrew Wilder argues, “The main way political parties in Afghanistan today have to mobilize support, other than through intimidation or financial incentives, is through appeals along religious or ethnic lines.”17 Nonetheless, where party fractionalization exists on the grounds of ethnic fractionalization, the preponderance of political parties in Afghanistan may not be helpful for future development. Benjamin Reilly argues that democracies can prove problematic for ethnically divided societies as candidates attempt to “outbid” one another in displaying loyalty to their own groups, thereby further exacerbating ethnic tension. However, he explains that electoral engineering has become a popular way by which to decrease ethnic tensions in emerging democracies; this includes the provision of electoral incentives for politicians to reach out to other parties, the presence of an area for bargaining, and the development of centrist and inclusive parties.18 This can prevent the outbreak of violence among different segments and groups in society – a destructive manifestation of ethnic divisiveness. Thus, it is ultimately electoral incentives at both the local constituency level and national level, and the way these interact, which determine both where and when ethnic violence against minorities will occur and the way in which the state chooses to respond to it. The presence of ethnic violence in only certain areas of India is CRITERION – October/December 2009 155 Niloufer Siddiqui particularly illustrative for the purposes of this paper. In arguing that the key factor in preventing ethnic violence is the central government’s capacity and willingness to do so, Wilkinson states, “democratic states protect minorities when it is in their governments’ electoral interest to do so.”19 This is particularly the case if the government has to negotiate or form a coalition with parties supported by minorities, or when minorities are an important source of support for the government itself. What Horowitz refers to as “vote-pooling” ensures that parties are provided an incentive to moderate their policies and make appeals along cross-ethnic lines.20 Additionally, Wilkinson argues that the greater the level of party competition in a region, the greater the incentives to appeal to minority votes, especially when victory depends on votes from the margins. This is particularly the case when the minority group is large enough to count politically – as is the case with Muslims in India, and with many of the ethnic and sectarian groups in Afghanistan. This argument requires a moderate leadership and electorate-at-large and works most effectively when operating in a Single Transferrable Vote or Alternative Vote system. Still, it demonstrates that ethnically heterogeneous societies and ethnic parties do not necessarily imply greater levels of ethnic discontent or division, and could be consistent with the greater goal of democracy. As Wilkinson argues, “politicized ethnicity depends on a whole range of factors, such as federal boundaries and government policies, and not just on underlying census categories.”21 An equally grave problem faced by Afghanistan is its lack of party system institutionalization at all levels, which is necessary for parties to be perceived as legitimate by the general populace. As Mainwaring explains, “more institutionalized party systems are ones in which parties have strong roots in society, . . enjoy considerable stability” and in which “patterns of party competition manifest regularly.”22 Afghanistan lacks many of these preconditions – its electoral market is unstable since parties are not supported by the electoral system, few people know which candidates belong to which parties, and there is little faith in the long-term continuity of elected candidates. In order for political parties to become widely established and widely known, so there “is stability in who the main parties are and how they behave,” Afghanistan needs more than just a change in law.23 A civil servant interviewed by 156 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan AREU explained, “Setting up parties has become a business here. Some people just set up parties to make money.”24 This trend towards political parties being viewed as NGOs or as indistinct from civil society must be arrested. Like other facets of state-building, building the legitimacy of political parties will take time; as political parties begin to operate more effectively in parliament, they will be able to develop greater support and linkages.25 The role of political parties is greatly different from that of civil society, precisely because the latter works outside of the political establishment and legislatures. Ivan Doherty argues that civil society cannot be perceived as a substitute for political parties, and that in fact, “strengthening civic organizations, which represent the demand side of the political equation, without providing commensurate assistance to the political organizations that must aggregate the interests of those very groups, ultimately damages the democratic equilibrium.”26 Legal and Constitutional Constraints: The Best Electoral System for Afghanistan? While analysts can not agree on whether the greater problem facing the development of political parties in Afghanistan is the electoral law or more pervasive sociopolitical factors, such as the lack of party legitimacy, most, however, tend to agree that the first step is doing away with the SNTV system. Andrew Reynolds argues that an appropriate electoral system is the single most important institutional factor in the success of transitioning democracies.27 Carol Riphenburg, on the other hand, while acknowledging the powerful role of parties in democracies, concludes that electoral systems should not be viewed as a “panacea” for deep-rooted cleavages in society.28 The SNTV system, which was the electoral system chosen for the 2005 Wolesi Jirga29 and Provincial Council elections and is likely to still be in effect for the next set of elections, permits individuals to stand for elections only as independent candidates and not as members of a party list. While candidates can stand for election in multi-member constituencies (provinces), voters can only vote for one candidate – even if the constituency has more than one seat allocated to it. This creates a situation whereby parliamentary elections are effectively “popularity CRITERION – October/December 2009 157 Niloufer Siddiqui contests,”30 with the more well-known personalities proving victorious, but not being held accountable to anyone or any party. Candidates are elected merely by winning the most votes; thus, if a district has 33 seats allocated to it – as was the case in Kabul – the top 33 vote-getters will gain a seat, even if they have only received a miniscule proportion of the vote. Because candidates only require a small number of votes in certain provinces, there is no incentive for them to join parties or appeal to a broad base of voters. In this way, the SNTV system does not produce a clear relationship between a political party’s vote share and their seat shares in parliament, causing a “lottery effect” and a high percentage of “wasted vote.”31 Prior to the elections, Barnett Rubin argued, “This system, in fact, virtually guarantees the formation of an unrepresentative parliament of local leaders with no incentive to cooperate with one another or the government.”32 He was proven right as the 2005 Afghan legislature brought in individuals who did not campaign on an ideological basis, but rather were well-known personalities or allied with regional strongmen. In addition, a remarkable 68% of the votes were cast for candidates who ultimately lost. Thus, the notion that the SNTV system would create a more representative system, where voters would feel directly linked to their representatives, failed in its implementation. That this rarely-used system with such obvious failings was chosen warrants some analysis in itself, pointing as it does to deep-seated prejudices within the Afghan political scene. Reynolds argues that the decision-making process was rooted “in the transitional government’s own interests and presented to the public largely as a fait accompli.”33 The ostensible reasons for the choice were simplicity, transparency and direct representation. A report by constitutional experts published at the time stated, “Given the factionalized nature of Afghan politics, the primary goal should be to produce reasonable proportionality . . voting procedure will also need to be simple and transparent; illiteracy and innumeracy limit the complexity of possible voting systems.”34 Yet, political commentators have pointed towards a fear of political parties shared by both Karzai and the Afghan populace, stemming from their experiences with communist parties during the Soviet era and foreignsupported parties following the Soviet defeat, which influenced the electoral choice. Cythia Maass outlines three possible explanations for 158 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan Karzai’s vehement opposition to political parties: “election tactics; the desire to keep several options open and a fundamental power preservation strategy.”35 Marvin Weinbaum agrees with the latter argument, stating that the choice of electoral system was largely a result of President Karzai’s calculation on how best to retain unrestrained power and his fear that the opposition would be able to organize against him in the parliament.36 It is essential to recognize at the outset that the SNTV system in Afghanistan does not achieve what it sets out to in preventing the establishment of political parties or in dissuading ethnic factionalism. Islamist parties, including the Jamiat-e-Islami and the Hezb-i-Islami, as well as other similarly conservative former mujahideen groupings, were able to “out-maneuver the constraints of the system” through coercion or vote-buying in the 2005 elections, and created blocs in the legislature.37 Additionally, voting blocs during the 2005 elections did form along ethnic lines, despite the purported absence of parties; even those parties which were not explicitly ethnic in nature received the majority of their support along ethnic and regional lines. The NDI argues that most parties had “limited reach beyond narrow ethnic, linguistic, or geographical boundaries.”38 While this was less pronounced for leftist and communist parties – which received a surprising number of seats in parliament – even these parties were aided by tribal and ethnic linkages.39 Support within the Parliament also remains ethnically-determined: Karzai’s support today stems primarily from Pashtuns and Tajiks. According to Wilder’s categorization of the parliament, none of the 20 Uzbek MPs, and less than 20% of Hazaras, are categorized as pro-government.40 Even if one were to make the case that the SNTV system has not exacerbated divisions along ethnic lines, it still fails to encourage cooperation across these lines, thereby working within a status quo rather than making any progress towards changing it. While a system of party competition could provide the grounds from which to build cross-cutting coalitions or provide the need to appeal to multi-ethnic constituencies, the SNTV system requires no such thing. Wilder argues that ethnic minority groups in particular found that political parties helped them in organizing for the elections. In nonCRITERION – October/December 2009 159 Niloufer Siddiqui Pashtun areas, a high percentage of winning candidates were affiliated with political parties.41 For example, the endorsement of candidates by the leader of the Hazara party, Hezb-i Wahadat, reportedly played a large part in these candidates’ victories. Where official political parties did not exist, the Shi’a community banded together and functioned as a type of party in itself; community members met and agreed together on the candidates which would stand for election in the WJ and Provincial Council elections.42 However, that these groups were ultimately unable to strategically take advantage of the SNTV system is indicative of the extent to which newer parties were at a disadvantage relative to groups with pre-existing networks. Thus, older parties affiliated with the conflicts over the preceding years were able to take advantage of their organizational apparatus, resources and internal communication to succeed in a manner in which post-Bonn groupings were unable to. The SNTV system also appears to violate the 2003 Political Parties Law, as Article 12 of the law gives parties the right to introduce candidates at all elections. While many political party leaders argue that problems exist not with the law but with the implementation, there are nonetheless certain lacunae which allow for the law to be interpreted in a manner which works against the development of parties. For example, the law’s prohibition of political parties which are “opposed to the principles of the holy religion Islam” creates a situation whereby influential Islamists are able to block the formation of parties to which they are opposed.43 The vague nature of the article leaves too much space for interpretation, and therefore limits the independent nature of political parties, particularly new groupings. Similar problems exist with paragraph 3 of Article 6 which states, “Political parties shall not incite violence on ethnic, racial, religious or sectarian grounds.”44 While this article goes some way to tackling the fear of factionalism along ethnic and religious lines – a fear that has to a large degree dictated the legal architecture of the country – it, nonetheless, leaves room for influential politicians to limit the creation of new parties. Additionally, as Riphenburg argues, despite this law, “internal fragmentation remains in evidence as the country’s ethnic groups, tribes, and local warlords exercise power in their respective 160 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan localities.”45 By attempting to prevent a situation which is already in existence, the law is therefore not merely ineffective but works to discourage political parties from organizing on the grounds of ‘national unity.’ Over 80 parties had nonetheless registered under this law between 2004 and 2005. Parties are obliged to register with the Ministry of Justice, under the Office of Political Party Registration (OPPR). They are required to have a constitution and a minimum of 700 members.46 The ICG has expressed concern with the Ministry of Justice’s role in registering parties and requesting their dissolution, as this system doesn’t guarantee due process and leaves the parties at the whim of the ministry.47 Controversy surrounded the decision to register parties led by former warlords which maintained links to armed elements. Parties that were formed in opposition to Karzai, such as the Hezbe-Afghanistan Naween, led by interim Education Minister Mohammad Yonus Qanooni, also encountered difficulties while registering, but were eventually permitted to do so. Thus, while a comprehensive law is in place, it is clear that the influence of political strongholds, including the former warlords and President Karzai, remains strong. The Political Parties Law should thus be clarified in order to prevent it from being manipulated by power elites and to eliminate unnecessary curbs on party formation.48 Arendt Lijphart has argued that the most attractive electoral combination for emerging democracies, particularly those with religious and ethnic minorities, is a combination of parliamentarianism and proportional representation (PR). Such a system, Lijphart argues, facilitates better minority representation and less economic inequality.49 While there is little chance of a switch away from the current presidential system, and the advantages and disadvantages of this are beyond the scope of this paper, a system of proportional representation with open lists, which has been proposed by electoral experts, would work to prevent some of the problems created by the SNTV system. In a PR system, voters cast ballots for party lists which then gain seats in proportion to their vote. The seats are allocated to candidates with the most votes on the list.50 As opposed to closed lists, where the parties assign the seats to the candidates, this system enables voters to reject CRITERION – October/December 2009 161 Niloufer Siddiqui corrupt individuals. According to Rubin, this system “creates incentives for cooperation among candidates and ethnic groups across a province.”51 It also limits the use of bribery and intimidation. Changing from the SNTV to proportional representation system should be a goal set by the Afghanistan government, with assistance from the international community. Political Parties: Historically and Today The historical development of political parties in Afghanistan points towards a situation of sustained and deliberate stifling; this inheritance is significant to the political landscape in existence today. While it would be unfair to suggest that no significant political parties have existed over the course of Afghanistan’s fractious history, these parties have faced legal constraints under successive regimes in the 20th century, which have prevented the creation of national constituencies and an organizational apparatus. This absence is being felt today, as “no leader [can] validate a claim to represent a national constituency through past electoral results or through any other form of activity.”52 King Zahir Shah’s failure to legalize political parties under his tenure – despite having introduced a more representative form of government in 1963 – simply served to make more difficult the task of party building. The nascent years following the adoption of the 2004 constitution are eerily reminiscent of those following the 1964 constitution, and should be referred to in garnering lessons for the future. Writing in 1972, Weinbaum explained that “a persistent fear in government circles is that the freedom to organize political parties will most benefit the country’s extremist political groups, offering them respectability and an unrestricted opportunity to proselytize.”53 Thus, while Article 36 of the 1964 Constitution emphasized the importance of political parties, a law to institutionalize them was never passed; rather, it was deferred to give time to “incipient parties . . to formulate policies and groom responsible leaders,” an argument that has been echoed by Karzai in recent years. Zahir Shah’s actions ultimately proved disastrous, as leftists and Islamic radicals continued to be active, upsetting the political order and bringing about its downfall. By keeping these parties out of the political 162 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan system, the King gave them no incentive to work within established boundaries or moderate their views. In fact, potentially moderate parties, including a social-democratic party, ceased to be active when the Political Parties Law remained unsigned, indicating that these parties paved the way for extremist ones with which the government was no longer able to effectively interact.54 A variety of communist parties were formed in the 1960s, most significant of which proved to be the People’s Democratic Party of Afghanistan (PDPA), or Hezb-e Demokratik-e Khalq-e Afghanistan. The party could not refer to itself as a party publicly and many of its actions had to be clandestine in nature. In its secret party constitution, the PDPA described itself as the Marxist-Leninist party of the working class of Afghanistan.55 The legal restrictions on the party’s functioning did not prevent a PDPA-assisted coup overthrowing Zahir Shah in 1973, and then ultimately, the Saur Revolution of 1978. PDPA leaders had feared that Mohammed Daoud Khan was planning to exterminate them all, which led them to organize an uprising and overthrow him. The system of non-party parliamentary democracy evident in the 1960s and 1970s is similar to what we are seeing today. Weinbaum wrote in 1972 that “the Wolesi Jirga, in effect, houses 216 distinct parties – one for each member,”56 resulting in disorganization and chaos and a failure to conform to legislative programs. In 2007, he similarly argued (referring to the legislature’s 249-seat lower house) that: “what you have in effect are 249 different parties so it [parliament] has not functioned as a legislature, but as a forum to register complaints.”57 During the course of the 1970s and 1980s, external interference by neighboring countries worked to prevent the creation of legitimate parties and hardened distrust; parties were now seen by the public as mere proxies for foreign powers or fronts for warlords. Mujahideen parties formed with the goal of resisting Soviet rule were assisted by antiSoviet international powers. The Iranian revolutionary regime that came to power at the end of the 1970s trained and armed Hazara Islamists; it merged the various Shi’a parties into Hizb-i-Wahdat (Unity Party) after the Soviets withdrew in 1988. Similarly, in 1980, the Pakistani military regime under General Zia ul-Huq propped up seven mutually CRITERION – October/December 2009 163 Niloufer Siddiqui hostile Islamic parties (the “Peshawar Seven”) as the representatives of Afghani refugees in Pakistan and the mujahideen.58 It was made explicit that membership in these parties was a precondition for assistance from the ISI. A system of interparty rivalry served Pakistan’s goals; “a unified Loya Jirga would threaten Pakistan’s control over Afghan refugees and over the military and political conduct of the war.”59 In an attempt to prevent growing Pashtun nationalism, Pakistan did not recognize the Afghan Millat, a Pashtun nationalist party still operating today, and together with Saudi Arabia and other Arab states, provided aid and weapons only to the recognized Islamist parties, none of which had large followings among the local populace. Rubin describes the patronage: Commanders could belong to several networks at once, and no party corresponded completely to a particular social network. Opportunism and pragmatism played a role in party membership, and each network was also segmented by language and qawm. If a prominent leader of one organization belonged to a particular qawm, members of that qawm tended to join that group.60 When the Soviets were ousted in 1989, most of these factions became hardened rivals in the resulting civil war. Alliances which did evolve between these groups were seen as avenues to military success; they had little to do with clear-cut ideological goals.61 Sometimes alliances were formed along ethnic lines, even when the parties were politically at odds with one another; for instance, alliances between former communist groups and Islamist parties helped create power centers along geographic or ethnic lines.62 Although the parties began initially as military factions, they soon established organizational structures and communication apparatuses.63 This structure and experience proved significant after the Taliban fell, as these parties were able to take advantage of the new political space through their pre-existing access to resources. Many analysts contend that there have been three large categories within which political parties in Afghanistan can be grouped historically. These categories remain to this day: politico-religious or Islamist parties; the communist left; and ethno-nationalists or ethnic 164 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan and sectarian groups.64 Within each broad category exist numerous cleavages, and often there is little that ideologically distinguishes one party from another, other than the leadership. Each category of groups has dominated, and proved problematic, at different times in Afghanistan’s history. The debates in the current parliament, thus far, suggest that parties with a conservative outlook have emerged as the strongest contenders, as is indicated by the table to the left. [Table taken from Wilder, Andrew. “A House Divided. Analysing the 2005 Afghan Elections.” AREU. December 2005. Page 7.] Most accounts indicate that the post-Bonn period was accompanied by the emergence of a whole host of new pro-democracy parties, whose activities were dampened once the SNTV system was chosen. Given the institutional constraints, these parties were unable to develop. Parties that had existed prior to the Taliban’s rule, however, found their way out of the woodwork and have come to dominate the Wolesi and Meshrano Jirgas. In particular, Rabbani’s Jamiat party, Dostum’s Junbesh party, and the Mahaz-e-Milli party have all received a large number of seats in the WJ. The NDI estimates that there are approximately 15 preTaliban parties represented in the WJ, and that these members have approximately 93-123 seats. Post-Taliban parties are 10 in number and CRITERION – October/December 2009 165 Niloufer Siddiqui only account for between 19-31 seats.65 The Role of Parties in the 2005 Parliament: Irreconcilable Cleavages or Experiment in Alliance-building? The September 18, 2005 elections brought candidates from a wide political, religious and ethnic spectrum to power in the WJ and Provincial Councils. The Parliament has been described alternatively as an atomized, fragmented institution and one in which numerous parties with fluid and often indistinguishable membership and platforms operate; the Parliament exists somewhere between the two descriptions.66 Estimates indicate that there are anywhere from 22 to 33 parties represented in the parliament, with additional parties looking to organize for the upcoming elections.67 While some heralded the surprising success of political parties against all odds during the elections, their relationship to the legislature is at best tenuous.68 Firstly, the lack of an official acknowledgment of political parties has ensured that only larger, more well-established parties with strong internal communication have been able to influence their Members of Parliament (MPs). Secondly, the lack of a “functional structure” has prevented the parliament from forming or maintaining legislative majorities, which are essential both for necessary political discussion as well as quick and effective legislating. Instead, the plethora of small factions and individuals with no constituency to answer to has resulted in “an environment of constant deal making and horse-trading.”69 Attempts were made early on at establishing a Parliamentary Groups system, where individual MPs were invited to form issue-based groups, rather than those based on religion, ethnicity, or language. The Parliamentary Groups were required to have a minimum of 21 members, and each MP was to be a member of only one group. However, the system failed to take off largely due to leadership struggles between various members of the parliament and because the decision to join parliamentary groups was based on who the other members were rather than on the group’s platforms. Thus, each MP continues to effectively function, and vote, as an independent. This provides ample room for vote-buying and intimidation within the legislatures. The Afghanistan 166 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit (AREU) highlights a “self-perpetuating problem” here: “while the functioning of parliament is highly limited by the lack of political parties, the ways in which it does operate provides no incentive for parties to consolidate their connections to it, or to form in the first place.”70 MPs’ votes are not recorded and as they have no public to whom they are accountable, there is no incentive to “formalize their connection with Parliament.”71 Since a culture of political parties has eluded Afghanistan throughout its history, there is no system in place whereby parties disseminate information about their goals and mandates. Most parties operate simply as underground groups bent on organizing and mobilizing, rather than working within a system which would provide them the space in which to operate and mobilize. In fact, interviews conducted by the AREU demonstrate that MPs which are members of newly-formed political parties are unwilling to name the party with which they are affiliated. The AREU suggests that this hesitancy may be a result of parties continuing to operate as vehicles of patronage; that is, MPs may agree to represent a party in exchange for some concession.72 Thus, membership to a party is contingent upon personal gain and not upon the desire to put forward certain issues or instill social change. Equally significant is that membership to parties is not formalized which allows MPs to attach themselves to “successful” parties as they wish. According to AREU findings, respondents view parties “outside” the WJ, as “separate entities from the workings of parliament,”73 a sentiment which is supported by that fact that many MPs, despite being members of a certain party, are free to make their own alternative coalitions within the parliament. In a detailed assessment of the backgrounds of candidates elected to the Wolesi Jirga of 2005, Andrew Wilder divided the parliament into progovernment, pro-opposition and non-aligned (or uncertain alignment) groupings. This division demonstrates little by way of actual common interests, and has not pointed towards the actual voting pattern in the parliament. Party policy does not dictate voting behavior, and one can not accurately determine an individual’s political leanings by the party to which they belong. Wilder explains, for example, that the Jamiate-Islami, a traditionally Islamic fundamentalist party with Muslim CRITERION – October/December 2009 167 Niloufer Siddiqui Brotherhood linkages, now includes members with a leftist orientation. The Jamiat faction led by former president Burhanuddin Rabbani currently has ten seats in the Wolesi Jirga, but about 10 related factions and off-shoots have members represented in the WJ as well. “It appears that any ‘politics of ideas’ is overruled by a politics of ethnic identity and personal interest, in spite of measures . . to counteract this.”74 Karzai’s decision to operate independent of a political party has itself backfired. By holding the Presidential and Parliamentary elections at separate times, despite the initial joint timetable, Karzai began his presidency with a weak legislative base of support. While he received 55% of the presidential vote, less than a third of the Wolesi Jirga can be categorized as pro-Karzai – and this percentage is further reduced by the tenuous nature of political allegiances.75 Thus, one of the most significant results of the composition of the 2005 Parliament has been the extrajudicial and undemocratic means that Karzai has had to resort to in order to exert control. This has occurred despite the presence of a system that was created in order to bolster his position and disable effective opposition mobilization. The lack of a presidential party, which could potentially have brought in a broad support base from myriad sectors of society, has instead left a gaping void in the center. The Mahaz-eMilli led the campaign for Karzai in the presidential election, and he was supported by a number of other smaller parties, but no effective alliances have been formed in parliament since.76 Karzai stated in an October 2003 BBC interview, “Afghanistan was destroyed, tormented, put through lots of suffering because of the infighting, because of the political agendas of the parties that were not national. Afghanistan needs to have a day off on that.”77 However, Karzai made no attempt at creating this national party which, even if it had resulted in single-party dominance along the lines of India’s Congress Party post-independence, could have prevented the currentday fractionalization. In 2005, Wilder predicted, “President Karzai’s skill at being all things to all people – to appear relatively moderate or liberal to the liberals, respectful of the jihad to the Islamic conservatives, and to have at least some support from within most ethnic groups – will certainly help in this regard.”78 Instead, today Karzai finds himself 168 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan appealing to extremist parties at all ends of the ethnic and ideological spectrum; his recent signing of the Shia family law, which regulates personal matters among the Shia minority community and effectively “legalizes the rape of a wife by her husband” according to the UN, is indicative of this trend.79 A prominent Shia leader was quoted as saying, “It’s electioneering. Most of the Hazara people are unhappy with Mr. Karzai.”80 Additionally, a female MP argued, “There are moderate views among the Shia, but unfortunately our MPs, the people who draft the laws, rely on extremists.”81 Hence, parliamentary debate and discussion has excluded more moderate voices, with the more conservative ideas finding their way into the law. Karzai can be seen to be operating more as a tribal chief than as the head of a modern democratic state. The former mujahideen – while initially, and still largely, proponents of Karzai – have nonetheless demonstrated their willingness to band together in opposition to Karzai if so needed. The opposition alliance in the Parliament, composed of 12 members and called the National Understanding Front of Afghanistan (NUF), was initially headed by Qanooni who sought to “crystallize the anti-Karzai opposition around his own person.”82 This multi-ethnic alliance aimed to run together for the elections and eventually merge into one reformist party. This pact failed, both in running joint candidates for parliament, and in providing a common front in Parliament. Qanooni was eventually replaced by Rabbani as the opposition leader in the WJ. This period was marked by shifting allegiances between parties and the creation of new offshoots. The presence of these groups nonetheless has ensured a harsh conservative streak, with Qanooni advocating for the implementation of Shariah Law. The NUF vowed to weaken the grip of Karzai and give more influence to political parties. Their first attempt in challenging the presidency took place in September 2005 as the Parliament voted overwhelmingly to oust the foreign minister “on the grounds of incompetence.”83 The vote proved ineffective, as Karzai deemed it illegal and politically motivated; Foreign Minister Spanta had alienated the warlords by opposing a blanket amnesty for war crimes committed during the years of conflict. Members of the NUF threatened to quit the Parliament. One of the members stated, “If the executive doesn’t pay attention to our decisions, what can we do? If 60 M.P.’s resign, definitely CRITERION – October/December 2009 169 Niloufer Siddiqui Parliament will collapse,”84 indicating the degree to which coalitionbuilding was proving effective for certain members of the Parliament. That this ultimately failed to take off demonstrates the difficulty of ensuring an independent and sovereign Parliament. In March 2006, after the Parliament ruled that a 41-year old Christian convert should not be allowed to leave Afghanistan to seek asylum abroad, as doing so would have violated Shariah law and the Constitution, Western pressure on the new government to honor freedom of religion halted this ruling.85 Both Karzai and the international community must balance the need for an independent legislature and one which promotes moderate, democratic ideals – which at the moment, appears irreconcilable. A system that encourages the formation of political parties would assist in promoting this independence, by encouraging groups to mobilize around specific issues. Former Mujahideen, New Democrats and the ‘Unaligned’: Competing for Legislative Control Wilder argued in 2005 that the major political divide that would be witnessed in the functioning of the new parliament would be between “religious conservatives” and “liberal, left-leaning members, allied with some independents and members from the more secular, ethnicbased nationalist parties.”86 The events of the last four years have demonstrated that the religious conservatives have largely won this battle. Former mujahideen groupings form a stronghold in the parliament; these warlords have created their own parties, in an attempt to reassert their legitimacy and to assert their right to national prominence and to bear arms. Candidates with “jihadist” credentials had a 60% success rate in the 2005 elections in the Wolesi Jirga and an 80% success rate in the provincial councils.87 Despite representing different factions and parties, “each of these commanders remain unified in a shared sense of privilege and a right to rule.”88 Thus, while the former mujahideen are admittedly a diverse group, and are divided along ethnic lines, they nonetheless possess a similar conservative outlook. A law which banned the broadcast of Indian soap operas as un-Islamic, as well as the prohibition of music and dance performances, indicates the type of socially conservative agenda which is being promulgated.89 Recent 170 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan news reports further indicate that the type of issues with which the Parliament has been involved have remained largely trivial and “out of touch” with the needs of the populace.90 In Afganistan’s war dominated history political parties have often changed shape, oscillating between armed militias governed by warlords to parliamentary parties with ostensible party mandates and agendas. Political-military parties have tended to dominate post-war politics for a number of reasons: these armed groups possess greater organizational capabilities than other groups, their role in previous armed resistance imbues them with a sense of entitlement, and more “traditional” elements have lost legitimacy through their affiliation with the previous regime.91 The presence of these parties has done little by way of increasing their legitimacy in the eyes of the public, the majority of which continue to view parties with suspicion and as remnants of either the communist or jihad era. Whether or not the presence of warlords and drug commanders in the Parliament should be used as a reason to marginalize the body is a question many pondered over immediately after the 2005 elections. Bhatia argues that while some commanders attempt to retain the mythology of the mujahideen’s fight against the Soviets, lower-ranked members are looking to break from the party leaders.92 And the former mujahideen are not homogenous in their own right. Bhattia distinguishes between three types: the political-military parties, strongmen-warlords and community militias. “Here, there is a clear divide between those commanders linked to (and drawing their power from) communities or solidarity groups (qawms), and those that draw their power from political parties.”93 Certain parties have indicated a willingness to transform from parties dominated by a single warlord to political parties with a relatively progressive social agenda. Dostum’s Junbesh party has been one such example.94 Dostum is an Uzbek warlord and former communist militia commander who allied with the mujahideen to help them take control of Kabul in 1992. He played an active role in the U.S.-led campaign against the Taliban, and held the position of Deputy Defense Minister briefly.95 According to a report by the Jamestown Foundation: CRITERION – October/December 2009 171 Niloufer Siddiqui [Given] Dostum’s role as a popular secularist leader in the north (he is generally well liked by the Uzbek, Turkmen, and Hazara population of the north who are grateful to him for protecting their liberal mini-state of six northern provinces . .), his multi-ethnic Junbish Party might actually play a positive role in the prevention of the reemergence of Islamic extremism in northern Afghanistan.96 Junbesh is said to consist of members from both ends of the ideological spectrum - both leftist and Islamist. Thus, international actors looking to promote democratic parties in Afghanistan should recognize that while parties led by former warlords may not always be amenable to change and that while their presence does point towards a conservative political orientation, in the short-run, working with them to push certain agendas could prove effective. Working to reform the existing system is a policy path that should be adopted along with providing support to new and upcoming democratic parties. An Afghan analyst further indicates the folly of dismissing these parties in an ad hoc manner: “When we talk about the typology of the Mujahedin parties, there are the liberal and open-minded parties among them, the parties that are able to place the national interest of Afghanistan at the top of their political agenda, and the parties which see Islam as entirely compatible with modernism.”97 172 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan Map Taken from Global Security. Accessed March 5, 2009. <http://www.globalsecurity.org/ military/world/afghanistan/images/afghan-map_warlords_2004.gif> Nonetheless, the influence of these warlords has prevented newer, more moderate parties from exercising control or expressing their views in the WJ. The presence of women – who, before 2005, had a limited, if not non-existent, role in politics – showed that lesser-known, and generally more liberal, parties had been able to enter the WJ. However, when these women attempted to challenge the legitimacy of these warlords, they have been silenced and dismissed. This was the case with Malali Joya, an MP from Farah province, at the first session of the new parliament, when she referred to the former mujahideen as “criminal warlords” and said that their hands were “strained with the blood of the people.”98 Joya was subsequently suspended from the Wolesi Jirga, on the grounds that she had violated Article 70 of the Parliament which banned WJ members from openly criticizing one another. A discussion of the success of the quota for women in the WJ is beyond the scope of this paper, but it is important to emphasize here that the women, while present, have failed to effectively function as a united caucus.99 Many of the women were elected with the backing of an influential male figure, and have not united on issue-specific grounds. The atmosphere of intimidation, further, remains a major hurdle to successful politics. Shukria Paikan Ahmadi, a deputy from Kunduz, explained: “The mujahedin are always intimidating us and we can’t say what we want. When one of the women was speaking, a commander from Herat told her to be quiet, otherwise they’d do to her what they did to Malalai… The warlords are a majority in parliament. And even though they are all from different factions, in this they are together. They are all against us, against the women.”100 Recently, political activists – mostly from the leftist camp, but also including members of the former mujahideen – have formed into a grouping now being referred to as the New Democratic Parties (NDPs). The new democrats belong to distinct parties, but 13 of these have formed a tentative coalition, the New Democratic Front, which recent reports CRITERION – October/December 2009 173 Niloufer Siddiqui indicate may potentially prove to be powerful in the next Parliament. Many of these parties consist of young activists who are distanced from the bloodshed and trauma of the wars of the last few decades. These parties possess a commitment to democratization, and a professed “anti-fundamentalist” stance.101 Candidates from these parties failed to capture any seats in Parliament during the 2005 elections – partially a result of class cleavages, with most NDPs consisting of the educated elite – losing out to the former mujahideen and Islamists. Nonetheless, their presence and efforts at organizing provide an appropriate template from which further mobilizing is possible. Looking Ahead: Parliamentary Elections 2010 and the Long Road Forward While in-depth analysis on the manner in which the parliament had functioned over the last four years still remains to be done, the general consensus appears to be that it exposed structural deficits rather than introduce a process of legislative democracy in Afghanistan. It retained an ultimately conservative, undemocratic outlook as a result of the predominance of personality-driven parties associated with previous eras’ power-brokers. Nonetheless, it is important to analyze these developments in the context of the overall security and sociopolitical impact. A praiseworthy development is that the Parliament is making key appointments and operating in a generally free and fair environment. Younger members of society have also benefited and their participation in parties is a promising sign for the future. The importance of the Parliament as a legislative and democratic body cannot be overemphasized. With the political environment in Afghanistan evolving at a critical time, the legislature can alter the political landscape. Ensuring the strength of these key institutions is integral to long-term development. As the ICG points out, “in the absence of legal channels for political representation, sub-state actors could once again resort to violent means to further the interests of the communities they represent.”102 A general sense of dissatisfaction with the current parliamentarians means that the next elections may see a vote against the incumbents, which would bring in new actors.103 While the New Democratic Parties 174 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan are being trained by international organizations as a means by which to promote internally-democratic and progressive parties, a mix of power politics, lack of expertise and resources and unfavorable legal and constitutional constraints nonetheless indicate that they are unlikely, in the short run, to become major power brokers in Afghan society. Rather, power is likely to remain with parties dominated by former warlords.104 However, this in itself may not be an irresolvable problem – some warlords have transformed their political groupings into political parties with socially progressive agendas. Much depends on the upcoming presidential election, which current President Karzai is expected to win. Karzai’s resistance to political parties is “fundamental and not merely tactical in nature,” with some indication that he is choosing to govern Afghanistan like a traditional tribal leader rather than along Western lines.105 Karzai’s own lack of desire to form a political party on the basis of which he could act and mobilize support indicates a personalistic rule, based on client-patron relations. He must recognize that his power is dwindling, due to, amongst others, a lack of support base in the legislature. If Karzai wants to effect change along the democratic ideals that he has been espousing, he must discontinue making deals with conservative elements in the legislature, or, alternatively, using his executive authority to prevent bills from being passed. Ultimately, electoral incentives are key to crossing ethnic lines in a democracy. Until the President himself operates from a centrist and inclusive position, this void will continue to be filled by extremist parties. The following policy recommendations are intended for both the international community and the Afghan government. Both must continue to work in partnership to tackle this issue. Andrew Wilder explained in an interview that ultimately, the problem of political parties is more political than technical in nature. Thus, the policy approach must be two-pronged. On the one hand, technical assistance must continue to be provided to individual parties and blocs to help them develop into progressive and internally-democratic political parties that will aid in the independent and successful functioning of the Parliament. On the other hand, the SNTV system must be replaced and electoral incentives CRITERION – October/December 2009 175 Niloufer Siddiqui must be provided to give parties a reason to reach out across societal divides. POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS For the Afghan government 1) Change the SNTV electoral system to a proportional representation system. The development of political parties in Afghanistan faces historical, legal and pragmatic constraints, of which changing the SNTV system is merely a first – albeit important – step. The SNTV system has shown itself unsuited to Afghanistan not only because it has retarded the development of democratic political parties along the lines of Western parliamentary systems, but also because it has inadvertently benefited conservative blocs and personality-driven parties. The SNTV system must be replaced as soon as possible with a proportional representation system, with open lists. As opposed to a closed-list system which could benefit potentially corrupt leaders. An open-list system ensures that voters know precisely who they are electing. Under this system, candidates can stand as independents or as part of a party list. Seats would be allocated to lists in proportion to the vote, ensuring that Afghan voters would be represented better.106 This system would also encourage candidates and groups to cooperate across regions and ethnicities. Afghanistan will no doubt experience initial difficulty in instilling this change, as voters will have to be re-educated about the electoral system, but long-term democratic and political development will not be possible without it. 2) Amend the Political Parties Law and the registration process to prevent powerful elements from manipulating the system. The Political Parties Law should be amended as soon as possible to clarify any vague wording which could be used to prevent the formation of new and important political groupings. In particular, the Afghan government should clarify Article 6 of the law which prevents the formation of parties on the grounds of national unity. 176 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan In addition, the government should simplify the registration process and move it from the purview of the Ministry of Justice to an independent commission, which would prevent the politicization of the process.107 The Ministry lacks the legitimacy and the means to verify that parties are adhering to the law, particularly in areas outside of Kabul. 3) President Karzai should consider forming, and operating on the basis of, a centrist, inclusive political party. President Karzai lost an opportunity to form, and stand for election on the basis of, an issue-based, multiethnic political party at the time of the first election. He must recognize the importance of political parties for the democratic future of the country and for an effective functioning of the Parliament. Importantly, his own support base could be cemented were he to fill this centrist void, and ensure that it is not filled by voices from the margins. For the International Community 4) Continue to provide technical training and assistance to political parties in Afghanistan. The international community must assist with the development of parties and alliances, through technical assistance and training. The New Democratic Parties provide the opportunity for engagement, and organizations such as the National Democratic Institute (NDI) and International Republican Institute (IRI) have already begun providing them training and support. However, in providing such training, organizations should continue to reach out to parties across the political spectrum and at all levels of party membership. This would ensure that particular parties aren’t seen as too closely associated with foreign actors (which could discredit them with sectors of the populace) and also ensure that democracy is being generated from the ground. Emphasis should be placed on creating internally democratic parties, and thus support should be provided to more than a few key leaders. This support and training should include both short-term and longCRITERION – October/December 2009 177 Niloufer Siddiqui term assistance. Helping with message and platform development so parties can effectively convey their mandates to the voters, and assisting with the 2010 election campaigns and fundraising are necessary, but so is helping party leaders develop strategic visions for where they want their parties to be in 5 to 10 years.108 Thus, while focusing on the 2010 elections will be a necessary part of the training for political parties, international organizations must recognize that political party development is a long-term goal which will require both time and finances. A USAID report states, “Assistance programs need to be strategic. Different parties are at different points along the development continuum, or have different interests. Providing a one-size fits all recipes across the board for all parties may be efficient, but it is neither appropriate nor appreciated.”109 Working to support parties at the local and regional levels, where resources and expertise are even scarcer, is also essential. Given that the SNTV system is likely to still be in place by during the next parliamentary elections, currently scheduled for 2010, it is imperative that political parties looking to gain power attempt to work within the system. The benefits of this are limited, and long-term change will only come through a change in the electoral system, but the New Democratic Parties can learn forming alliances and presenting candidates strategically to ensure that they populate the WJ and Provincial Councils from the former mujahideen groupings. 5) Improve the legitimacy and reputation of political parties among the general populace. As political parties continue to be viewed with suspicion, particular attention must be paid to improving their reputation and legitimacy. This can be achieved in part by ensuring that the parties rely on legitimate party financing, which will have the additional benefit of weeding out “unworthy political players.”110 Building stronger parties based on ideas stabilizes the political system, as representation is based on shared beliefs and values that do not change with a single person’s situation or reflect only one person’s values. 178 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan At the same time, more political parties should not be confused with greater democracy. Wilkinson has found that the most effective party politics take place when there are three parties competing for electoral success. The plethora of political parties in Afghanistan indicates the formation of groups not along ideological grounds, but often based on personality and power-driven mandates; Kit Spence refers to these as “vanity projects.”111 Given this scenario, the international community should be wary of encouraging ad hoc and general party formations. They should provide targeted aid and assistance to parties. 6) Begin a media campaign to educate voters on the importance of political parties. International organizations should work with the political parties in utilizing media sources to explain their goals and mandates. Additionally, assistance should be provided to improve the capacity of the media itself to better discuss and participate in the democratization of the country. Bibliography Bhatia, Michael. “The Future of the Mujahideen: Legitimacy, Legacy and Demobilization in Post-Bonn Afghanistan.” International Peacekeeping. Vol. 14, No. 1, January 2007, Page 90 -107. Coglan, Tom. “Afghan MP says she will not be silenced.” BBC News. January 28, 2006. Doherty, Ivan. “Democracy Out of Balance: Civil Society Can’t Replace Political Parties.” Policy Review. April and May, 2001. Goodson, Larry P. “Lessons of Nation-Building in Afghanistan.” Nation-Building Beyond Afghanistan and Iraq. Ed. Francis Fukuyama. Johns Hopkins University Press, 2006. International Crisis Group. “Afghanistan’s New Legislature: Making Democracy Work.” Asia Report No. 116. May 15, 2006. International Crisis Group. “Political Parties in Afghanistan.” Asia Briefing No. 39. Kabul/ Brussels. June 2, 2005. King, Orla and Jeroen de Zeeuw. “Political Party Development in Conflict-Prone Societies.” Seminar Report, Netherlands Institute of International Relations. December 2006. Page 5. Accessed April 12, 2009. <http://www.clingendael.nl/publications/2006/20061200_cru_conf_ppd.pdf> Kippen, Grant. “Elections in 2009 and 2010: Technical and Contextual Challenges to Building Democracy in Afghanistan.” Afghanistan and Research Evaluation Unit. November 2005. Kucera, Joshua. “New Movement in Afghanistan Strives to Offer Ideological Alternative to the Taliban.” Eurasia Insight. March 8, 2007. Accessed March 22, 2009. <http://www.eurasianet.org/departments/insight/articles/eav020807.shtml> CRITERION – October/December 2009 179 Niloufer Siddiqui Larson, Anna. “Afghanistan’s New Democratic Parties: A Means to Organize Democratisation?” Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit (AREU). March 2009. Lijphart, Arendt. “Constitutional Choices for New Democracies.” In The Global Resurgence of Democracy. Eds. Larry Diamond and Marc Plattner. The Johns Hopkins University Press. 1996. Lipset, Seymour. “Indispensability of Political Parties.” Journal of Democracy. Vol. 11, No. 1, 2000. Mainwaring, Scott. “Party Systems in the Third Wave.” Journal of Democracy. Vol. 9, No. 3. 1998. Pages 67-81. Maass, Cithia. “Afghanistan without Political Parties: Can the New Parliament Function?” German Institute for International and Security Affairs. March 2006. MacKenzie, Jean and Wahidullah Amani. “Afghanistan’s Buzkashi Parliament.” Institute for War & Peace Reporting. Accessed March 30, 2009. <http://www.iwpr. net/?p=arr&s=f&o=261895&apc_state=henh> National Democratic Institute for International Affairs. “Political Party Assessment: Afghanistan.” Spring 2006. Parenti, Christian. “Who Rules Afghanistan?” The Nation. November 15, 2004. Reynolds, Andrew. “The Curious Case of Afghanistan.” Journal of Democracy. Vol. 17, No 2. April 2006. Pages 104-117. Riphenburg, Carol J. “Electoral Systems in a Divided Society: The Case of Afghanistan.” British Journal of Middle Eastern Studies. Vol. 34, No. 1. April 2007. Pages 1-21. Reilly, Benjamin. “Dealing with Divided Societies.” In Electoral Systems and Democracy. Eds. Larry Diamond and Marc Plattner. The Johns Hopkins University Press and the National Endowment for Democracy. 2006. Ruttig, Thomas. “Islamists, Leftists – and a Void in the Center. Afghanistan’s Political Parties and where they came from (1902-2006).” Konrad Adenauer Stiftung. 2006. Rubin, Barnett. “Afghanistan: The wrong voting system.” International Herald Tribune. March 16, 2005. Rubin, Barnett R. “Crafting a Constitution for Afghanistan.” Journal of Democracy. Vol. 15 No. 3. July 2004. Rubin, Barnett. The Fragmentation of Afghanistan; State Formation and Collapse in the International System. Yale University, USA. 1995. Semple, Kirk. “In Afghanistan, Anger in Parliament Grows as President Defies Majority’s Wishes.” The New York Times. September 26, 2007. Starkey, Jerome. “Afghan leader accused of bid to ‘legalize rape’: UN and women MPs say Karzai bowed to Islamic fundamentalists before poll.” The Independent UK. MARCH 31, 2009. Tarzi, Amin. “Afghanistan: Government Turns its Sights on Northern Warlords.” Radio Free Europe. August 21, 2006. Accessed April 17, 2009. <http://www.rferl.org/content/ Article/1070709.html> USAID Afghanistan. “Assessment of Political Party Programming by USAID in the Islamic Republic of Afghanistan.” May-June, 2008. Weinbaum, Marvin G. “Afghanistan: Nonparty Parliamentary Democracy.” Journal of Developing Areas. Vol. 7, No. 1. 1972. Page 57-74. Wilder, Andrew. “A House Divided? Analysing the 2005 Afghan Elections.” AREU. December 2005. Wilkinson, Stephen. Votes and Violence. Cambridge University Press, USA. 2004. Williams, Brian Glyn. “Rashid Dostum: America’s Secular Ally in the War on Terror.” 180 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan Terrorism Monitor. Vol. 1, No. 6. August 2003. Wordsworth, Anna. “A Matter of Interest: Gender and the Politics of Presence in Afghanistan’s Wolesi Jirga.” AREU. June 2007. “Afghanistan Parliament Bans Indian Soap Operas.” IBN Live. April 15, 2008. Accessed March 30, 2009. <http://ibnlive.in.com/news/afghanistan-parliament-bans-indian-soapoperas/63351-8.html> “As problems pile up, Afghan lawmakers debate words.” Reuters. August 11, 2008. Accessed April 2, 2009. <http://www.reuters.com/article/asiaCrisis/idUSISL208419> “Asylum-seeking convert must not escape: MPs.” Gulf Times. March 30, 2006. Accessed March 22, 2009. <http://www.gulf-times.com/site/topics/article.asp?cu_no=2&item_ no=79247&version=1&template_id=41&parent_id=23 References: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 The phrase “culture of political ambiguity” was used in a March 2009 report by the Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit (AREU) to describe the environment in which political parties operate in Afghanistan today. Larson, Anna. “Afghanistan’s New Democratic Parties: A Means to Organize Democratisation?” AREU. March 2009. Quoted in Rubin, Barnett. “Crafting a Constitution for Afghanistan.” Journal of Democracy. Vol. 15 No. 3. July 2004. “Afghanistan’s New Democratic Parties.” Ibid. Page 2. Ruttig, Thomas. “Islamists, Leftists – and a Void in the Center. Afghanistan’s Political Parties and where they came from (1902-2006).” Konrad Adenauer Stiftung. 2006. Ruttig. Ibid. Quoted in Wilder, Andrew. “A House Divided: Analyzing the 2005 Elections.” AREU. December 2005. Page 9. Quoted in Lipset, Seymour. “Indispensability of Political Parties.” Journal of Democracy. Vol. 11, No. 1, 2000. Page 48. Quoted in Wilkinson, Stephen. Votes and Violence. Cambridge University Press, USA. 2004. Page 69. “Indispensability of Political Parties.” Ibid. Ibid. Page 49. CIA World Factbook: Afghanistan. Updated March April 9, 2009. Accessed April 17, 2009. <http://www.cia.gov/library/publilcations/the_world_factbook/Geos?af.html> King, Orla and Jeroen de Zeeuw. “Political Party Development in Conflict-Prone Societies.” Seminar Report, Netherlands Institute of International Relations. December 2006. Page 5. Accessed April 12, 2009. <http://www.clingendael.nl/publications/2006/20061200_ cru_conf_ppd.pdf> Ibid. Page 4. Author interview with Marvin Weinbaum, Middle East Institute. March 23rd, 2009. Reynolds, Andrew. “The Curious Case of Afghanistan.” Journal of Democracy. Vol. 17, No. 2. April 2006. Page 104-117. Wilder. Ibid. Page 8. Wilder. Ibid. Page 10. Reilly, Benjamin. “Dealing with Divided Societies.” In Electoral Systems and Democracy. Eds. Larry Diamond and Marc Plattner. The Johns Hopkins University Press and the National Endowment for Democracy. 2006. CRITERION – October/December 2009 181 Niloufer Siddiqui 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 182 Votes and Violence. Ibid. Page 6. Ibid. Wilkinson. Ibid. Page 177. Mainwaring, Scott. “Party Systems in the Third Wave.” Journal of Democracy. Vol. 9, No. 3. July 1998. Page 69. “Afghanistan’s New Democratic Parties.” Ibid. Page 17. Ibid. Author interview with Andrew Wilder. April 5th, 2009. Doherty, Ivan. “Democracy Out of Balance: Civil Society Can’t Replace Political Parties.” Policy Review. April and May, 2001. Page 2. Reynolds. Ibid. Page 105. Riphenburg, Carol J. “Electoral Systems in a Divided Society: The Case of Afghanistan.” British Journal of Middle Eastern Studies. Vol. 34, No. 1. April 2007. Pages 1-21. The Wolesi Jirga (WJ), or the lower house, consists today of 249 members, all of whom are elected through the SNTV system, with 215 chosen at the provincial level in proportion to the various provincial populations and 34 elected to fill nationwide “compensatory” seats. 68 seats are reserved for women (2 from each province). Two-thirds of the members of the Meshrano Jirga, or upper house, are appointed by elected provincial and district councils, and the remainder are appointed by the President. Goodson, Larry P. “Lessons of Nation-Building in Afghanistan.” Nation-Building Beyond Afghanistan and Iraq. Ed. Francis Fukuyama. Johns Hopkins University Press, 2006. Page 163. Interview with M. Weinbaum. Ibid. Reynolds. Ibid. Page 112. Rubin, Barnett. “Afghanistan: The wrong voting system.” International Herald Tribune. March 16, 2005. Reynolds. Ibid. Page 106. Ibid. Maass, Cithia. “Afghanistan Without Political Parties: Can the New Parliament Function?” German Institute for International and Security Affairs. March 2006. Page 2. In examining the causal relationship between electoral systems and the formation of party systems, Riphenburg similarly argues that “politicians and parties will make choices about institutions such as electoral systems that they think will benefit themselves.” Riphenburg. Ibid. Interview with M. Weinbaum. Not everyone agrees with this interpretation. Reynolds explains that the SNTV system was ultimately chosen because it was the “least bad” of all other systems and that “it is important to note that Karzai did not choose SNTV with any understanding of its consequences of history.” Reynolds. Ibid. Page 106. Wilder. Ibid. Page 11. “Political Party Assessment: Afghanistan.” National Democratic Institute for International Affairs. Spring 2006. Page 12. Wilder. Ibid. Page 13. Wilder. Ibid. Page 8. Wilder. Ibid. Wilder. Ibid. Page 19. International Crisis Group. “Political Parties in Afghanistan.” Asia Briefing No. 39. Kabul/Brussels. 2 June 2005. Political Parties law, Article 6, paragraph 3. Riphenburg. Ibid. Page 6. CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 “Afghanistan’s New Democratic Parties.” Ibid. Page 8. “Political Parties in Afghanistan.” Ibid. Page 5. “Political Parties in Afghanistan.” Ibid. Page 1. Lijphart, Arendt. “Constitutional Choices for New Democracies.” In The Global Resurgence of Democracy. Eds. Larry Diamond and Marc Plattner. The Johns Hopkins University Press. 1996. Page 162-174. Rubin, Barnett. “The Wrong Voting System.” International Herald Tribune. March 15, 2005. Ibid. Rubin, Barnett. The Fragmentation of Afghanistan; State Formation and Collapse in the International System. Yale University, USA. 1995. Page 192. Weinbaum, Marvin G. “Afghanistan: Nonparty Parliamentary Democracy.” Journal of Developing Areas. Vol. 7, No. 1. Page 70. Ruttig. Ibid. Page 6. Rubin. The Fragmentation of Afghanistan. Page 85. Weinbaum. Ibid. Page 61. Kucera, Joshua. “New Movement in Afghanistan Strives to Offer Ideological Alternative to the Taliban.” Eurasia Insight. March 8th, 2007. Accessed March 22, 2009. <http:// www.eurasianet.org/departments/insight/articles/eav020807.shtml> These parties were the National Islamic Front of Afghanistan (NIFA), the Afghanistan National Liberation Front (ANLF), the Movement of the Islamic Revolution (HAR) the Islamic Party of Afghanistan, Hikmatyar (HIH), the Isalmic Party of Afghanistan (HIK), the Islamic Society of Afghanistan (JIA) and the Islamic Union of Afghanistan (ITT). Rubin. The Fragmentation of Afghanistan. Ibid. Rubin. The Fragmentation of Afghanistan. Ibid. Page 198. Rubin. The Fragmentation of Afghanistan. Ibid. Page 202. “Political Party Assessment: Afghanistan.” Ibid. Page 3 Ibid. Ibid. Ruttig. Ibid. “Political Party Assessment: Afghanistan.” Ibid. Page 7. Grant Kippen explains that this “resulted in a parliament comprised of numerous contending voices with limited formal organization of political interests, but with large parties informally represented in significant numbers nonetheless.” Kippen, Grant. “Elections in 2009 and 2010: Technical and Contextual Challenges to Building Democracy in Afghanistan.” AREU. November 2005. Page 7. “Political Party Assessment: Afghanistan.” Ibid. This NDI report argues, “While many observers were concerned that the parliament would be largely composed of independent candidates, the result has proved to be somewhat more complex.” Page 7. See also Reynolds. Ibid. “Afghanistan’s New Democratic Parties.” Ibid. Page 5. Ibid. Page 5. Ibid. Page 15. Ibid. Ibid. Wordsworth, Anna. “A Matter of Interest: Gender and the Politics of Presence in Afghanistan’s Wolesi Jirga.” AREU. June 2007. Page 19. Ibid. Page 24. CRITERION – October/December 2009 183 Niloufer Siddiqui 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 184 Reynolds. Ibid. Page 114. “Political Party Assessment: Afghanistan.” Page 6. Quoted in Ruttig. Ibid. Page 40. Wilder. Ibid. Page 5. Starkey, Jerome. “Afghan leader accused of bid to ‘legalize rape’: UN and women MPs say Karzai bowed to Islamic fundamentalists before poll.” The Independent UK. MARCH 31, 2009. Ibid. Ibid. Ruttig. Ibid. Page 20. Semple, Kirk. “In Afghanistan, Anger in Parliament Grows as President Defies Majority’s Wishes.” The New York Times. September 26, 2007. Ibid. “Asylum-seeking convert must not escape: MPs.” Gulf Times. March 30, 2006. Accessed March 22, 2009. <http://www.gulf-times.com/site/topics/article.asp?cu_no=2&item_ no=79247&version=1&template_id=41&parent_id=23> Wilder. Ibid. Page 6. Bhatia, Michael. “The Future of the Mujahideen: Legitimicay, Legacy, and Demobilization in post-Bonn Afghanistan.” International Peacekeeping. Vol. 14, No. 1. January 2007. Page 100. Wilder explains, “The terms mujaheddin or jihadi are now used to describe those jihad party leaders and their commanders and supporters who still politically and ideologically closely associate themselves with the jihad. They generally share a conservative outlook on social, cultural and religious affairs, and many have a shared objective of “defending the jihad” and establishing a more conservative Islamic state governed by Islamic laws.” Page 6. Bhatia. Ibid. Page 91. “Afghanistan Parliament Bans Indian Soap Operas.” IBN Live. April 15, 2008. Accessed March 30, 2009. <http://ibnlive.in.com/news/afghanistan-parliament-bans-indian-soapoperas/63351-8.html> A recent debate over which word to use for ‘university’ indicates the extent to which the WJ remains ineffective, and also the manner in which ethnic and linguistic divisions remain significant. “As problems pile up, Afghan lawmakers debate words.” Reuters. August 11, 2008. Accessed April 2, 2009. <http://www.reuters.com/article/asiaCrisis/ idUSISL208419> Bhatia. Ibid. Page 92. Ibid. Ibid. Page 95. Interview with Andrew Wilder. Ibid. Tarzi, Amin. “Afghanistan: Government Turns its Sights on Northern Warlords.” Radio Free Europe. August 21, 2006. Accessed April 17, 2009. <http://www.rferl.org/content/ Article/1070709.html> Williams, Brian Glyn. “Rashid Dostum: America’s Secular Ally in the War on Terror.” Terrorism Monitor. Vol. 1, No. 6. August 2003. Kabul Center for Strategic Studies. Interview with Sarwar Jawadi. July 2008. Accessed April 16, 2009. <http://www.kabulcenter.org/index_files/Page13477.html> Coghlan, Tom. “Afghan MP says she will not be silenced.” BBC News. 28 January, 2006. For a detailed discussion regarding gender politics in the Afghan Parliament, see Words- CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Promoting Political Parties and an Independent Legislature in Afghanistan worth. Ibid. 100 MacKenzie, Jean and Wahidullah Amani. “Afghanistan’s Buzkashi Parliament.” Institute for War & Peace Reporting. May 19, 2006. Accessed March 30, 2009. <http://www.iwpr. net/?p=arr&s=f&o=261895&apc_state=henh> 101 “Afghanistan’s New Democratic Parties.” Ibid. Page 6. 102 “Political Parties in Afghanistan.” Ibid. Page 13. 103 Interview with Andrew Wilder. Ibid. 104 Ibid. 105 Maass. Ibid. Page 2. 106 Rubin. “The Wrong Voting System.” Ibid. 107 “Political Parties in Afghanistan.” Ibid. Page 5. 108 USAID Afghanistan. “Assessment of Political Party Programming by USAID in the Islamic Republic of Afghanistan.” May-June, 2008. Page 26. 109 Ibid. Page 25. 110 “Assessment of Political Party Programming by USAID.” Ibid. Page 24. 111 Ruttig. Ibid. Page 17. CRITERION – October/December 2009 185 INTELLIGENCE AGENCIES OF PAKISTAN – INSTITUTIONAL ROLE BEHIND CIVIL-MILITARY EQUATION Muhammad Ismail Khan* Abstract In the political history of Pakistan, both civilian and military rulers have used intelligence agencies to further their goals. In this game of political snakes and ladders, the key players have employed intelligence outfits to spy on each other. Defining the purpose of an agency, this paper starts by identifying the main intelligence agencies of Pakistan which have played a role in the major developments of the country. These events, which are dealt with extensively in the next section, have tainted the image of the agencies. The focus is on the years following 1988 and the impact of developments in this period on the course of the country’s history. Author Introduction: Pakistan’s security agencies, not least its primary spy outfit the InterServices Intelligence (ISI), have caused grave international concern. Presently, the main worry of the global community is the on-going war against terror, where there is a perception of alleged ISI collusion with the Taliban. Just as President Barack Obama announced the new Af-Pak policy, the US Chairman Joint Chief of Staff, Admiral Mike Mullen, expressed his concerns over the perceived support of Pakistan’s main military intelligence agency to radical elements.1 Such allegations have repeatedly been voiced after the US-led invasion of Afghanistan in order to flush out the Taliban from Kabul. The fleeing militants, it is argued, * Muhammad Ismail Khan is a research scholar. Institutional Role Behind Civil-Military Equation found their way to the tribal areas of Pakistan where the country’s secret agencies helped them establish safe havens. Not only the United States, but nations within the south and central Asian regions are wary of alleged ISI support to militants inside their countries. New Delhi has repeatedly asked Pakistan to cut off ties with the militants which have supposedly carried out terrorist attacks in India. Similarly, in February 2009 Afghan intelligence officials blamed ISI for sponsoring the attack on the Justice Ministry in Kabul.2 Not only other countries, but also segments of domestic opinion in Pakistan have blamed the agencies for manipulating the political climate of the country in the past. Although their external role is not significantly different from those of other agencies of the world, it is their domestic activities that have imbued them with notoriety within the country. The political leadership as well as the intelligentsia has not, therefore, adequately defended the security services against external allegations. Given the secretive nature of spy agencies, there is little they can do to defend themselves publicly. The ground further muddies as new allegations of the agencies’ external activities are made. This creates an impression of “rogue” elements within the ISI who act unilaterally instead of following the directives of the state. It is even suspected that several ideological elements within Pakistan’s security agencies influence state policies. Army Staff (COAS), General Ashfaq Pervez Kayani, is lauded in the United States for his exemplary role in maintaining the army as a professional outfit. His gesture in resolving the confrontation between two of Pakistan’s political rivals has been termed as “the Kayani model.”3 Yet, it was during Kayani’s stint as Director General ISI4 that the escaping Taliban found safe havens in Pakistan’s tribal areas. While there has been sufficient material5 on the ISI’s alleged support to Islamists or political players in the past, there is little that touches the institutional role and structure of the organization. What and who makes CRITERION – October/December 2009 187 Muhammad Ismail Khan it collude with the Islamists or manipulate the elections? What divides and draws the sympathies of these security services? This paper looks beyond the role of the ISI. It starts by identifying the institutional role of intelligence agencies during important national events and ends up concluding that the sympathies of these outfits in Pakistan are a manifestation of civil-military imbalance in the country. In a country with a tense past in the civil-military equation, intelligence agencies are often used to play off one player against another. Moreover, it is the action taken on the spying, and not spying per se, which has made the agencies a dreaded entity in the society. Lastly, since Pakistan’s main military intelligence outfit is an external agency, the tussle between civilian-military intelligence has been restricted to domestic affairs. For civilian intelligence agencies, foreign policy is unfamiliar ground. Thus, the internal role of a military intelligence agency comes from the civilmilitary imbalance; the edge is in its being an external agency. PAKISTAN’S INTELLIGENCE AGENCIES Intelligence Agencies The primary purpose of any country’s intelligence agency is founded on the “state’s awareness and understanding of its strategic environment, gained by way of gathering and analyzing secret and opensource information.”6 The main task involves gathering of information, which is then analyzed so as to secure the state against any threat. Since, external groups are involved in acts against the state, the intelligence agency (IA) also works on counter-intelligence. Despite their various activities, it is in two basic areas, namely, the collection and analysis of information that every IA concentrates. This overriding function of information gathering, research and analysis makes an IA almost like an academic institute. An IA’s involvement in covert actions often makes it a controversial organization. Pakistan’s IAs are, therefore, not exceptional. As with many other states, Pakistan’s IAs can be divided as per geography and specialization. IAs which can be divided along the geographical domain include: external agency which is concerned with 188 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Institutional Role Behind Civil-Military Equation intelligence regarding external security, and internal agency which is concerned with intelligence regarding internal security. There are also specialized IAs within Pakistan whose primary task include intelligence on crime, drugs, etc. The overlapping of interests requires coordination and cooperation yet inter-agency conflict is also part of the matrix.7 (See Appendix ‘A’ for the structure of IAs in Pakistan.) External agency The Directorate of Inter-Services Intelligence, shortened as ISI, is involved in intelligence gathering and analysis of external threats. It also coordinates with foreign agencies in combating terrorism. In the 1980s, together with the Central Intelligence Agency, it was actively involved in the covert operations against the Soviet occupation forces inside Afghanistan. After the Soviet withdrawal, the ISI retained its links with the Afghan fighters. It is for this non-severance of links that the ISI is being accused presently by the international community. Moreover, within Pakistan, it has been involved in political dealings. The political leadership, therefore, is equally skeptical of the agency. Recently, it appeared as a dreaded organization in the infamous “missing persons” case wherein it was revealed that people associated with ISI were involved in the abduction of several Pakistani nationals. In terms of line of communication, although the ISI comes under Prime Minister, its de facto status is under Chief of Army Staff (COAS). It reports to both the Prime Minister and the COAS. Reportedly, having a staff of more than 10,000(other than informants)8, the ISI has been mostly headed by a Lieutenant General though in its early days the head of the agency was an officer of the rank of Brigadier. It is divided into the following departments:9 1. Joint Intelligence X (JIX) – acts as a center which coordinates with other wings; it also provides intelligence and threat assessments. 2. Joint Intelligence Bureau (JIB) – considered as the most powerful bureau; one of its subsection was devoted to India. Since this bureau is also responsible for political intelligence, CRITERION – October/December 2009 189 Muhammad Ismail Khan 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. the possibility of this bureau being the infamous “political cell within ISI” cannot be denied. Joint Counter Intelligence Bureau (JCIB) – conducts surveillance of Pakistani diplomats stationed abroad; it is also responsible for conducting intelligence operation in the Middle East, South Asia, China, Afghanistan and the Muslim republics of the former Soviet Union. Joint Intelligence / North (JIN) – responsible for Jammu and Kashmir operations, such as infiltration, propaganda, and other clandestine activities. Joint Intelligence Miscellaneous (JIM) – is believed to be conducting espionage in foreign countries, including offensive intelligence operations. Joint Signal Intelligence Bureau (JSIB) – responsible for signal intelligence along the border with India, and to “provide communication support to militants in Kashmir.” The Special Wing – responsible for liaison with foreign intelligence and security agencies; it is this wing which is reported to have links with the Taliban. This wing may possibly be under JIM. Joint Intelligence Technical – responsible for technical intelligence such as gadgetry.10 Internal agency Intelligence Bureau, abbreviated as IB, is Pakistan’s internal IA. It was largely a police organization and still retains this character by and large. Although a part of the Ministry of Interior, it also reports directly to the Prime Minister. The primary job of IB is intelligence gathering within the country, which may include terrorists, foreign intelligence agents, etc. Nonetheless, it has also been used for political manipulations in Pakistan. SPECIALIZED AGENCIES Armed forces The Pakistan, army, navy, and air force have their own intelligence 190 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Institutional Role Behind Civil-Military Equation agencies. They are involved in intelligence gathering as per respective requirements. Military Intelligence is the army’s primary IA. Since Pakistan has for more than three decades been under military rule, this agency has often made headlines for political reasons. Crime Pakistan’s law enforcement outfits also have intelligence cells though these are normally described as “investigation” departments or agencies. Such IAs, which deal mostly with crime, are all civilian and come under the Ministry of Interior. Intelligence is gathered through the Central Investigative Department and the Federal Investigative Agency – both are policing organizations. Recently, they have been involved in probes against militants operating inside Pakistan. Narcotics There is also an intelligence unit within the Anti-Narcotics Force, which comes under the Ministry of Narcotics Control. The unit is tasked with gathering information in order to pre-empt drug trafficking. Law enforcement agencies Though the activities of law enforcement agencies (LEA), such as the police, should be confined to punitive action against criminals, they have also developed their own intelligence apparatus. In Pakistan paramilitary agencies notably the Frontier Corps and the Rangers also fall within the ambit of LEAs. While IAs have become notorious for their power and political interference, the role of the LEAs has been no less controversial. HISTORY AND ROLE OF PAKISTAN’S IAs Formation and growth (1947-1977): Given the tense equation between the rulers and the ruled during the colonial era, the British resorted to the use of stringent, if not repressive, internal surveillance. The intelligence apparatus which Pakistan inherited from the British came to be associated with internal intelligence. Along the lines of the division of other resources, the prepartition Intelligence Bureau (IB) was bifurcated between Pakistan and CRITERION – October/December 2009 191 Muhammad Ismail Khan India. During colonization, the IAs and the law-enforcement agencies, such as the CID, had become dreaded bodies. Almost immediately after partition, war broke out between Pakistan and India over Kashmir. The need for an agency to coordinate intelligence among the three branches of the armed forces was soon realized.12 Thus in July 1948, Pakistan’s then Deputy Chief of Staff, Maj. General R Cawthome, established the ISI as a small organization under the General Headquarters. Its placement below the GHQ ensured that from the very beginning it would be army-dominated and, as such, it reported to the commander-in-chief. In 1958, Pakistan experienced its first military rule. The ISI along with all other agencies fell under the authority of the President and C-in-C, General Ayub Khan. Most of the intelligence structure at that time was used for domestic spying, particularly against opposition politicians. There was a close surveillance on politicians during the 1964 elections; the ISI and the IB were growing “in stature and power.”13 This internal obsession proved detrimental to the focus on external concerns. Pakistan’s major intelligence crisis came in the form of the 1965 war with India. The war seemed to have been planned with pre-conceived notions instead of taking alternatives and fall-back positions into consideration. For instance, after the launch of operation Gibraltar into Indian occupied Kashmir, there was no revolt among the Kashmiris as had been anticipated. It was in the expectation that an uprising would spontaneously materialize that the war was started. Moreover, the possibility that India could open up the southern sector by crossing the international border in Sialkot or Lahore was also not factored. Setting aside the policy miscalculations, the ISI proved ineffective in locating an armored division of India during the war. Headed by Brigadier Riaz Hussain, the ISI’s assets in the Indian sector proved ineffective thereby “blinding”14 it to the developments. After the war, a committee was established under General Yahya Khan to look into the working of the agencies. The nominal control of the ISI shifted to the Ministry of Defense. 192 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Institutional Role Behind Civil-Military Equation By 1968 it became increasingly apparent that Ayub Khan’s days were numbered. He soon stepped down and was succeeded by General Yahya Khan. The latter organized general elections in 1970 but was reluctant to accept the outcome. Earlier, he had tried to use the ISI to infiltrate Bengali politicians but this did not work out. During the elections, Yahya’s cabinet regularly received “briefings”15 from the head of IB. His military operation in East Pakistan and the subsequent war with India proved disastrous as it ended in the creation of Bangladesh. From a purely intelligence perspective, it is obvious that this was another complete intelligence failure in correctly assessing the ground situation. Not only were the sympathies of Bengalis discounted but the success of military operation was overvalued. After Yahya Khan, Zulfikar Ali Bhutto became the President and later Prime Minister of Pakistan. Bhutto’s decision to appoint Zia-ulHaq as the army chief was influenced by General Ghulam Jilani Khan, his appointee as DG ISI. Interestingly, it is Bhutto who is credited with creating the notorious “political cell” within the ISI.16 For his opponents, the dread came from Federal Security Force (FSF,) a paramilitary organization formed by the government. Opponents of Bhutto decried the use of FSF for political manipulation. It is believed that the aim of the FSF was “to enable a civilian government to avoid seeking the assistance of the armed forces in dealing with its responsibilities and problems.”17 Whether or not the FSF was established to “counter the influence of ISI,”18 it became an instrument for the accretion of power in the office of the prime minister. The access to IAs and LEAs did not help empower Bhutto in the context of the civil-military equation. When Zia asked Bhutto to withdraw the surveillance of “civilian IB on army officers,”19 Bhutto complied by replacing an IB chief.20 Bhutto was removed from power in a military coup in 1977; two years later he was sent to the gallows. Zia retained Gen. Jilani after his retirement and dismantled the FSF. Spectacular rise (1980s): The emergence of the ISI as a larger-than-life agency is derived from CRITERION – October/December 2009 193 Muhammad Ismail Khan its role in key developments in the 1980s. It was during Zia’s rule (19771988) that the IAs, and in particular the ISI, became actively involved in changing the geo-political environment. Zia stage-managed the rise of certain politicians who, in turn, helped him stay in power. The IAs were used to garner support for Zia and his policy of Islamization as well as to demonize Bhutto’s Pakistan People’s Party (PPP.) Individuals who had fallen foul with Bhutto rallied around Zia. Thus the IAs played an active role in providing a joint political platform to the anti-Bhutto constituency. For instance, since Bhutto had nationalized industries during his tenure, the support of many industrialists was sought. Army and intelligence officers played a prominent role in this endeavour.21 What lead to the ISI’s spectacular growth was the war in Afghanistan. Soon after the Soviet invasion of Afghanistan, Pakistan came into the limelight. The ISI, with the help of the Central Intelligence Agency (CIA), funded the militants known as Afghan mujahideen. The initial secrecy maintained by the United States and the importance attached to Pakistan gave the ISI a free hand in Afghanistan. The Afghan war imbued the ISI with a decisive say on key foreign policy issues. It was during this period that the direct link between Saudi Arabia and the ISI was established.22 The latter was thus able to secure mind-boggling amounts of financial assistance to pursue the jihad without questions being asked. The free hand given to the ISI remains incomprehensible. The latter established close links with the mujahideen groups. All the funds, weapons and ammunition for the Afghan resistance were thus channeled through the ISI. Once the finances were secured, it was the “ISI and not Army that took on the principal role for the execution of the covert war against the Soviets.”23 This was fully endorsed by Zia whose protégé, General Akhtar Abdur Rehman, headed the ISI as its director general. General Zia-ul-Haq and General Akhtar Abdur Rehman both died in a plane crash in 1988. Zia was succeeded by General Mirza Aslam 194 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Institutional Role Behind Civil-Military Equation Beg as COAS; Rehman by General Hameed Gul. Democratic control or control of democracy? (1988-1999): The involvement of IAs, especially the ISI, in the affairs of the state has had a negative impact and according to author Shuja Nawaz: “The active involvement of the army high command and intelligence services, particularly the ISI, in the conduct of the Afghan war, the ISI’s direct and unfettered access to overseas financing from US CIA and private and official Saudi sources, and involvement in the making and breaking of domestic political parties and alliances, had changed the equation between the civil and military. This involvement and financial autonomy of sorts also gave the ISI a permanent role in foreign policy.”24 Bhutto wins After Zia-ul-Haq’s death, fresh elections were to be held. Zulfikar Ali Bhutto’s Pakistan People’s Party (PPP), led by his daughter, Benazir Bhutto, decided to take part in the polls. Already a mainstream force, Bhutto’s party had become even more popular despite years of persecution during the Zia-ul-Haq era. The assessment was that Benazir Bhutto would secure a landslide victory if the elections were free and fair. For this precise reason, the then DG ISI, General Hameed Gul, is said to have been against the holding of elections.25 Nevertheless, the Army chief, General Mirza Aslam Beg, and the President, Ghulam Ishaq Khan, decided to move ahead with the scheduled elections. This demonstrated that despite its growing stature, the ISI could still not always impose its will. However, in order to neutralize Bhutto’s popularity, an alliance of right-wing parties, known as the Islamic Democratic Front or the IJI26, was cobbled together through the active involvement of the DG ISI and the Army Chief.27 CRITERION – October/December 2009 195 Muhammad Ismail Khan It was during this election that Osama bin Laden, who at that time was known primarily as a wealthy Saudi businessman, is said to have provided funds, according to an English newspaper published from Lahore, through the ISI for disbursement to the IJI.28 The ISI’s links with key figures in Saudi Arabia had developed during the Afghan war. Despite these machinations, the PPP won sufficient votes to form the government at the center while the IJI became the main opposition party. The latter was, however, able to form the government in the Punjab, Pakistan’s largest province. Given the federal structure of the country this posed serious difficulties. Thus from day one, the journey towards democracy was anything but smooth. In this period the IJI asked the ISI for its support and this, in turn, pitted the latter against the PPP. Pakistan’s military strategy is India-centric and, because of this, it sought to establish strategic depth in Afghanistan after the Soviet withdrawal from that country. The perception was this was not supported by the PPP. Thus even after winning the elections, Benazir Bhutto was asked to take the COAS into confidence on all security matters and not to touch “sensitive” issues such as India, Afghanistan, nuclear and defence policy.29 Hence, despite being the prime minister, she had little say in foreign affairs. While Bhutto seemed to have accepted these restrictions, her problems did not end. Byzantine intrigues, with the connivance of the IA, to destabilize her government were engineered. One such event was the infamous “Operation Midnight Jackal” through which attempts were made to buy off her supporters. Under the circumstances the Prime Minister sought to set up a commission to reform the intelligence agencies. Benazir Bhutto was also convinced that most of her troubles emanated from one particular individual, General Hameed Gul, she therefore had him removed from the post of DG ISI and appointed, Shams-ur-Rehman Kallue, a retired General, in his place. Hameed Gul’s removal demonstrated yet again the pivotal role of DG ISI in the country’s politics. Kallue’s appointment was aimed to sever the links between the army and the ISI. 196 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Institutional Role Behind Civil-Military Equation It is interesting that at this juncture, the COAS started seeking advice from the DG of Military Intelligence, General Asad Durrani. Thus, MI became the “ears and eyes” of the army.30 On the other hand, the ISI under Kallue, who acquired the nickname “no clue,” proved ineffective and was of no use to the Prime Minister. Her government was unceremoniously dismissed in 1990 after remaining barely two years in power. Sharif leads – After the dismissal of the Benazir Bhutto government, fresh elections were held. Though the tables were turned the key players remained the same. The PPP became the main opposition party and Nawaz Sharif formed the government. The army and the intelligence agencies are said to have played a helpful role in clinching Sharif’s victory. During these elections, the COAS, General Mirza Aslam Beg, is reported to have given 140 million rupees to the new DG ISI, General Assad Durrani,31 for distribution among anti-PPP candidates. The funds were provided by the CEO of the Mehran Bank, Yunus Habib. Whether or not, bin Laden or any other rich mujahideen donated money to the IJI in 1990 (as they did in 1988) is not clear. In 2006, Qazi Hussein Ahmed, an IJI leader, said in an interview that when he was approached by bin Laden to support IJI in the 1990 elections, he “disagreed with his method.”32 Whether or not others also disagreed is not known; what is certain is that unlike 1988, the ISI did not act as a mediator. It was not till 1994 that General (Retd.) Naseerullah Babar, a PPP leader, revealed how the ISI had disbursed money among politicians. In 1997, a case was filed by Air Marshal (Retd.) Asghar Khan; during the hearing of the case, General Beg admitted the supply of funds to political leaders. Pakistani columnist, Ardeshir Cowasjee, quoted Beg’s confession to the Court in Dawn: “In 1990 when the money was donated by Younas Habib, ISI was CRITERION – October/December 2009 197 Muhammad Ismail Khan acting under the directions of higher authorities. As chief of the army staff at that time, when I was informed of this matter my only concern was that the money received by the ISI was utilized properly and an account was maintained and beyond that I had no concern with the money.”33 And that, “Although the director-general, ISI, is an officer in uniform but the chief of army staff has no authority to take action against him. The head of ISI was a person from army of which I was head at the relevant time.”34 However, Durrani later signed an affidavit that he was asked by General Beg to provide “logistic support”35 to the politicians through “businessmen of Karachi.”36 The case is still pending in the Court. After winning the elections, the IJI leader, Nawaz Sharif, became the Prime Minister of Pakistan. The President and the COAS, who had earlier colluded in the dismissal of Bhutto’s government in 1990, remained the same. General Beg retired soon afterwards and was succeeded by General Asif Nawaz as COAS. Though Nawaz Sharif had been supported by the military, his relations with both the army as well as the President were tense. For his part, General Asif Nawaz wanted to depoliticize the army and, as such, did not interfere in politics. After Kallue, General Durrani (DG MI) was made DG ISI. Sharif replaced him with General Javed Nasir a born-again Muslim with a pan Islamic worldview.37 Other than supporting Islamic groups in China and Philippines, he is also alleged to have supplied arms to the besieged Bosnians in the Serb siege.38 During his tenure the ambience at ISI was “a strange non-military atmosphere” where the “corridors were filled with bearded officers in civilian costumes.”39 The next DG ISI, General Qazi, revamped the ISI on the orders of the COAS – making its operations more professional. Earlier, General Nasir was removed after a new COAS, General 198 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Institutional Role Behind Civil-Military Equation Waheed Kakar, took over. Kakar’s predecessor, General Nawaz, had died mysteriously. Meanwhile, the rift between the President and the Prime Minister was growing, bringing in the army once again.40 In 1996, without taking over the country, General Kakar asked the President and the Prime Minister to quit and also called for fresh elections. In a country where the President can dismiss an elected Prime Minister, such an arrangement came to be known as the “Kakar formula.” BB returns – Benazir Bhutto won the general elections in 1994 and appointed a party-member, Farooq Leghari, as president. General Kakar was offered an extension by Bhutto, but he refused. Upon his retirement, General Jehangir Karamat took over as COAS. Since her first government was dismissed within two years, Benazir went the extra mile to keep the power brokers contented during her second term. Once bitten twice shy, she fully cooperated in the security vision of the country that consisted of deterring India by securing Afghanistan and the nuclear weapons. There were however some interesting differences between her first and second terms. For instance, the Ministry of Interior became more important. The Minister of Interior, Naseerullah Babar, although a retired general, was a party loyalist. Along with other key civilian IAs and LEAs, his ministry started an operation in the port city of Karachi. Moreover, it was during her second government that Taliban started receiving support from Pakistan. The question whether it was Pakistan that master-minded the creation of the Taliban remains unanswered. What, however, is relatively certain is that the moment Taliban emerged as a force, Pakistan established close links with the movement. Since the 1980s, Pakistan had supported the mujahideen and this continued even after the withdrawal of Soviet forces from Afghanistan. It was General Babar who sought the help of Taliban to secure the release of some Pakistani trucks that had been captured by the warlords. Later, particularly after 9/11 the mujahideen switched to the Taliban raising CRITERION – October/December 2009 199 Muhammad Ismail Khan suspicions that they were supported by the ISI. In her second term, Bhutto used the Interior Ministry to consolidate political power. The LEAs and IAs were thus made answerable to the Prime Minister. She appointed her trusted people to the Federal Bureau of Investigations43 and Intelligence Bureau. According to FAS, “the appointment [of DG IB] precipitated a major crisis in the Pakistani state apparatus, because Benazir then began using the IB chief to erode the once all powerful ISI’s base.”44 As events would show this did not help her. She was sacked in 1996 – this time, by her own handpicked President. Sharif returns – Sharif won the next general election. Not only did he appoint a loyalist as President, he also amended the constitution, as he had the required parliamentary majority. This was consequential because the President no longer had the power to dismiss an elected Prime Minister. To further consolidate his position, he appointed General Ziauddin, a non-professional army-man from the Engineering Corps, as DG ISI. During Sharif’s second term, Najam Sethi, editor of The Friday Times, a leading weekly, was picked up from his house. Earlier, Sethi, while in India, had criticized the Sharif government for corruption. While there was confusion over his abduction, he was interrogated by ISI. The Lahore High Court refused to take up the case as it was a military affair – something beyond the jurisdiction of the civil courts. When Sethi’s wife appealed to the Supreme Court, its response was that the case would be heard by first deciding the status of ISI “once and for all”46 and if it is a military affair then, the Court would have no jurisdiction under Article 199 (3). Nonetheless, it remarked that “prima facie, the ISI is not part of the army.”47 The highhandedness of the Sharif government was again apparent in the Rehmat Shah Afridi case. The latter, who was the editor of the Peshawar-based Frontier Post was nabbed on 1 April 1999 by the AntiNarcotics Force for allegedly being in possession of 20 kilograms of 200 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Institutional Role Behind Civil-Military Equation hashish. According to Afridi, he was arrested for his paper’s criticism of Sharif’s administration. After his release, he stated that his paper had published a report that then “DG of ANF and some army officers were involved in drug smuggling.”48 In 1999, Pakistan went to war with India in Kargil, causing serious rifts within the country’s polity. It is said that the DG ISI was unaware of the operations; MI was colluding with the Sharif-appointed COAS, General Pervez Muharraf. Later, Sharif was blamed for caving in to international pressure by agreeing to the withdrawal of troops. After the war, Sharif began to distrust Musharraf who, according to Sharif, had never informed him of the Kargil misadventure. Eventually the prime minister decided to dismiss Musharraf. On the evening of 12 October 1999, while Sharif was in the process of formalizing the appointment of General Ziauddin as the new COAS, General Musharraf took over the government through a coup. Military returns (1999 - ): With the October 1999 coup, the role of intelligence reverted yet again to supporting military rule. Musharraf appointed his favorites to the key intelligence slots – such as in the ISI and MI. These generals had been instrumental in staging the coup as Musharraf was returning to Pakistan from a visit to Sri Lanka at the time. Two years later 9/11 occurred and the United States became ever more assertive as it embarked on its global war on terror. The choice for Pakistan was stark. Washington had made it clear with the formulation “either you are with us or against us.” However, there were voices of resistance within the ISI. When Musharraf was confronted with intelligence officials who did not want to shun the Taliban, he purged the agency of such elements. These included DG ISI, General Mahmood who was considered a staunch Taliban supporter and was present with American Congressmen when 9/11 happened. On his return to Pakistan, Musharraf asked General Mahmood to convince Taliban to hand over bin Laden.50 However, it is CRITERION – October/December 2009 201 Muhammad Ismail Khan said that Mahmood asked Mullah Omer to resist the invading forces.51 There are also reports of Mahmood providing $100,000 to 9/11 mastermind, Muhammad Atta, through a middle man, Omer Sheikh.52 The Wall Street Journal reporter Daniel Pearl reported the call made by Mahmoud to Sheikh. Sheikh was subsequently arrested by the ISI for the murder of Pearl. Later on, the FBI is said to have interrogated Mahmood for his role.53 As the war raged in Afghanistan, the ISI became the front line player once again. Pakistan helped the United States in arresting and deporting Taliban leaders. The escaping Taliban found sanctuaries in the tribal areas of Pakistan and were said to be actively supported by the ISI. Later, the world would condemn the ISI for supporting the militants. This continued and General Musharraf acquired the reputation of being a “double dealer.” The resurgence of the Taliban in the tribal areas happened after 2004, when General Ashfaq Kayani was made DG ISI. Politically too, the ISI became increasingly involved. In 2002, parliamentary elections were held in which the pro-Musharraf parties won a majority. These elections, admitted later by ISI’s political cell head General Zamir, were rigged in favor of Musharraf’s favorites.54 According to General Zamir, he was asked by Musharraf to do so.55 The ISI’s alleged role in abducting civilians was no less controversial. Imbued with special powers, the agency picked up people on the pretext that they were terrorists. The case of missing persons was taken up by the Supreme Court. Much to the anger of General Musharraf, the top judge took keen interest in this issue. During hearings, it became apparent that many people were abducted for no good reason. A case in point was of a person named Imran. According to The News, a Lahorebased newspaper, “the counsel for Imran had told the bench that Imran had an affair with a girl who was a relative of a brigadier in the ISI.”56 This showed that the ISI had grown in size with an added responsibility of acting like paramilitary unit or LEA. 202 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Institutional Role Behind Civil-Military Equation Power blinds. This was as true of Nawaz Sharif during his second term as it was of Musharraf. In March 2007, Musharraf suspended the Chief Justice of the Supreme Court and this ignited a country-wide agitation for his restoration. This finally came about in March 2009 by which time Musharraf was no longer the president of the country. Prior to this Benazir Bhutto and Nawaz Sharif, who had both been in exile for several years, returned to Pakistan. Upon her return, the convoy of Benazir Bhutto was attacked. Although she survived the first attack, she died in the second one. When she was attacked the first time in 2008, she blamed some of the leaders of the then ruling PML (Q) as well as individuals associated within the intelligence.57 Post-Musharraf period– In 2008, fresh elections were held. Bhutto’s party won in the Center with Sharif’s party forming the government in the Punjab province. While the Punjab-Center setup was nearly the same, the only apparent difference was the absence of animosity between the two parties. Before Musharraf’s ouster, General Ashfaq Pervez Kayani was made COAS after taking the key political actors into confidence. That both Bhutto and Musharraf expressed confidence in his appointment showed his professionalism.58 The new civilian government unsuccessfully tried to rein in the ISI. On 26 July 2008, a notification was issued stating that the ISI would be under the Ministry of Interior.59 However, this was staunchly resisted by the army forcing the government to backtrack and announce that the original “notification has been misunderstood.”60 In November 2008, India’s port city Mumbai was attacked. As a gesture of cooperation, President Zardari asked DG ISI, General Pasha, to go to Mumbai. However, when this unleashed severe criticism in the media and also resulted in expressions of resentment within the military establishment, the ill-thought-through initiative was withdrawn. CRITERION – October/December 2009 203 Muhammad Ismail Khan As in previous civilian governments, the Ministry of Interior is again in the limelight. As for the fight against terrorism, the organizations associated with MoI, such as CID and other policing IAs, have also been active. Given the fact that policing IAs are mostly reactive outfits and without adequate means, such a division often results in wastage of time and resources. The present war against terrorism calls for close coordination between all IAs. The challenge is formidable as terrorism as the foremost external and internal threat that the country faces. As in the past, it is the civilian IAs and LEAs that are being misused for political ends. For example, the federal government imposed Governor Rule in the Punjab, a province ruled by Sharif’s party, to curb the lawyers’ movement for the restoration of the deposed judiciary. It is believed that the Lahore Chapter of the Intelligence Bureau played a key role in the imposition of the rule.61 MAKING A CASE Civil-military imbalance: The political activities of the intelligence agencies in Pakistan reflect the civil-military imbalance in the country. In this equation, civilian rulers have opted for civilian IAs while military rulers have used the military IAs. The case of ISI is most interesting; although known as a “semimilitary” organization under the authority of the Prime Minister, it is subservient to the COAS in reality. Most of ISI’s cadre also comes from the army. Whenever a case involving ISI has been heard in Court, the first concern has been over its status.62 It is for this reason that the civilian leadership had resorted to using civilian IAs as well as LEAs. Although they are subjected to parliamentary questions, the over-arching role of the Ministry of Interior or civilian intelligence units indicate the desire to curtail the influence of the ISI and indirectly, the military. Since the law-enforcement agencies (LEA), like the police force, also come under the Interior Ministry, this ministry often assumes a larger role under civilian rule. 204 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Institutional Role Behind Civil-Military Equation Politicians dread the ISI and call it a state within a state. In 1997, when the Mehran Bank scandal was being heard in the Supreme Court, former COAS Beg clearly said that he “cannot take action against DG ISI.” Since the ISI is technically under the Prime Minister, its activities without his approval and knowledge cannot be justified. Politicians often criticize the role of generals in the rigging of elections and are also suspicious of civilian intelligence for political manipulations. For instance, the PPP leaders disliked the former Director General of the IB for his role in the creation of a pro-Musharraf party and his ties with Islamists.63 At another level, while the perception was that the ISI was capable of generating independent revenues from sources such as narcotics, foreign financiers and domestic bankers, these lucrative avenues of funding were no less coveted by elements within the political leadership. On the other hand, critics accuse the civilians of misusing LEAs or IAs. This has included usage of CID to ANF for personal ends. Just as military rulers appointed favorites in ISI, civilians too have appointed their protégés in the civilian apparatus. Individuals associated with civilian and military IAs have admitted their involvement in politics. that emerges is that such agencies act independently. There is, nevertheless, a difference of opinion about this. Individuals associated with military intelligence institutions, like the ISI, maintain that they are merely “operators” and not “policymakers.” Internal-versus-external affairs: In its purest form, intelligence is concerned with information gathering based on which action is taken. Domestic intelligence is largely associated with LEAs, whose activities can at times be brutal, harsh and extreme. That the ISI became notorious for abducting citizens during Musharraf’s time shows the evolution of an IA into a semi-LEA outfit. CRITERION – October/December 2009 205 Muhammad Ismail Khan Civilians have used civilian agencies to ensure the writ of the state. Political governments have tried to curtail the ISI’s role by relying on civilian IAs and LEAs. While civilian intelligences have only remained within the domestic domain, the ISI’s domestic spying seems to be only an extension of its primary task of external intelligence. Theoretically, the ISI is an external IA and this gives it an edge over its civilian counterparts which are often crime-centric. Sources include: 1. 2. Background Paper on “The Structure and Role of Intelligence Agencies” by Lt. Gen Asad Durrani for Pakistan Institute of Legislative Development (PILDAT.) Websites of the ministries. References: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 206 Mark Mazzetti and Eric Schmitt, March 29, 2009. “U.S. Says Agents Of Pakistan Aid Afghan Taliban.” The New York Times. Sangar Rahimi and Carlotta Gall. March 20, 2009. “Pakistan Accused of Links to Kabul Attacks.” The New York Times. <http://www.nytimes.com/2009/03/20/world/ asia/20afghan.html> Jehangir Karamat, 2009. “The Power of People Power.” Spearhead Research. <http:// www.spearheadresearch.org/phpBB2/viewtopic.php?t=1420> From 2004 to 2007, Kayani was Director General ISI. It was during this time that insurgency started in tribal areas and Dr. AQ Khan Scandal was exposed. On general idea about Pakistan, see: Stephen Cohen’s The Idea of Pakistan. On books about the dominance of military and religion in Pakistan, see: Husain Haqqani’s Pakistan: Between Mosque and Military or Hasan Abbas’ Pakistan’s Drift into Extremism. On links with Islamists, see: Zahid Husain’s Frontline Pakistan: The Struggle with Militant Islam. On Afghan jihad, see: Steve Coll’s Ghost Wars: The Secret History of the CIA, Afghanistan, and bin Laden, from the Soviet Invasion to September 10, 2001; On Taliban, see: Ahmed Rashid’s Taliban: Militant Islam, Oil and Fundamentalism in Central Asia; Ahmed Rashid’s Descent into Chaos: The U.S. and the Disaster in Pakistan, Afghanistan, and Central Asia; On military, see: Shuja Nawaz’s Crossed Swords: Pakistan, Its Army, and the Wars Within. For personal memoirs of the key players, see: Musharraf’s In the Line of Fire: A Memoir; Benazir Bhutto’s Daughter of the East; Benazir Bhutto’s Reconciliation: Islam, Democracy and the West. DCFA Backgrounder, 2006. Intelligence Services; Democratic Control of Armed Forces, pp. 1. Full backgrounder on intelligence can also be accessed at: <http://www.dcaf.ch/ publications/kms/details.cfm?lng=en&id=18413&nav1=5> Such conflict may raise suspicion with regards to coordination. For instance, Pakistan’s CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Institutional Role Behind Civil-Military Equation external IA funded its war on drug money – against which a specialized IA works on. 8. See: http://www.fas.org/irp/world/pakistan/isi 9 See: http://www.fas.org/irp/world/pakistan/isi 10 Frédéric Grare. Reforming the Intelligence Agencies in Pakistan’s Transitional Democracy. Carnegie Endowment for International Peace (2009); pp. 16 11 Hassan Abbas. 2007. Pakistan’s Drift into Extremism. Pentagon Press; pp. 245 12 Sean P. Witchell, ‘Pakistan’s ISI: The Invisible Government’, International Journal of Intelligence and Counter-Intelligence, Vol 16(1), (Spring 2003) pp 374-375. 13 Nawaz, Shuja. 2008. Crossed Swords: Pakistan, its Army and the Wars Within. Oxford University Press; pp. 255. 14 Sean P. Witchell; Ibid, pp. 376. 15 Nawaz. Ibid. pp. 256 16 It was shared by a future COAS, General Beg, in a Supreme Court case in 1997. 17 Attributed to Bhutto; quoted by Ardeshir Cowasjee in his article. See: Cowasjee, “The missing chapter,” Dawn (June 28, 1997) 18 http://www.globalsecurity.org/intell/world/pakistan/isi.htm 19 Nawaz. Ibid. pp. 349 20 The replacement of a single person at top shows the strength associated with such a person. This would be repeated later on, too. 21 These industrialists included Nawaz Sharif, who was picked up by General Jilani, former chief of ISI. Sharif would later lead a mainstream political force. 22 Nawaz. Ibid. pp. 372 23 Nawaz. Ibid. pp. 373 24 Nawaz. Ibid. pp. 360 25 Nawaz; Ibid. pp. 412-413 26 Its original name in Urdu is Islami Jamhooria Ittehad. 27 Nawaz; Ibid. pp. 411-413. 28 Daily Times Monitor. “Nawaz Sharif met Osama three times: ISI officials.” Daily Times, Lahore (June, 23,2005) See: <http://www.dailytimes.com.pk/default.asp?page=story_236-2005_pg7_34> 29 Exact points included: no change in the Afghanistan policy, nuclear policy, defense policy, no administrative meddling in civil service and not harassing General Zia’s family. See: Nawaz; Ibid; pp. 415 30 Nawaz; Ibid. pp. 426 31 After Kallue’s exit, Durrani was called in to head ISI. 32 Editorial. “Qazi Hussein and Osama bin Laden.” Daily Times (March 20, 2008) See: http://www.dailytimes.com.pk/default.asp?page=2006\03\20\story_20-3-2006_pg3_1 33 Cowasjee, Ardeshir. “We never learn from history-3” Dawn (August 11, 2002) 34 Cowasjee, Ardeshir. Ibid. 35 Ardeshir, Cowasjee. Ibid. 36 Ardeshir Cowasjee. Ibid. 37 Abbas calls Nasir’s view as “worldview jurisdiction for ISI.” Abbas; Ibid. pp.148 38 Abbas; Ibid. pp. 148 39 Nawaz. Ibid. pp. 467-468 40 This power was bestowed to the President by General Zia. Benazir Bhutto was also a victim of same power. 41 Presently too, the then-Minister General Babar often takes credit for establishing peace in Afghanistan by nurturing Taliban. CRITERION – October/December 2009 207 Muhammad Ismail Khan 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 208 There is disagreement over who was the first to contact Taliban – ISI or Babar. Rehman Malik, the present MoI, was made chief of FIA. See: http://www.fas.org/irp/world/pakistan/ib/index.html ISPR, known as Inter-Services Public Relations Rafaqat Ali. “ISI status to be decided once for all: Saiduzzaman.” Dawn (May 22, 1999) Rafaqat Ali. Ibid. Staff Reporter. “Rehmat Shah Afridi freed on parole” Dawn (May 25, 2008) See: http:// www.dawn.com/2008/05/25/top14.html Rashid, Ahmed. 2008. Descent into Chaos: The United States and the Failure of Nation Building in Pakistan, Afghanistan, and Central Asia. Viking Adult Musharraf, Pervez. In the Line of Fire. Simon& Schuster (2006) Mir, Amir. The Fluttering Flag of Jehad. Mashal Books (2008) Meacher, Michael T. “The Pakistan Connection.” Guardian (2004) Mir. Ibid. 2008 Umer Cheema. “The man, who rigged 2002 polls, spills the beans.” The News (February 24, 2008) See: < http://thenews.jang.com.pk/top_story_detail.asp?Id=13159> Umer Cheema. Ibid. 2008. Muhammad Qasim. 2008. “Five more missing persons traced, SC told” The News (May 26, 2007) These included General Hamid Gul, former DG ISI, during Bhutto’s time from 1988 to 1990; and Brig (Retd.) Ejaz Shah, the then-DG of Intelligence Bureau. It is important to realize that in a bumpy journey of Pakistan’s political history where military has taken the driving seat, professionalism is associated with lack of desire to rule directly – even if the COAS has influenced on key political events. Raza, Syed Irfan. “ISI, IB put under interior division’s control.” Dawn. (June 27, 2008) See: http://www.dawn.com/2008/07/27/top1.html Report; “Notification regarding ISI has been misunderstood: PID.” The News. Tariq Butt. “Intelligence Bureau trying to catch multilingual terrorist chatter” The News (May 25, 2009) See: <http://www.thenews.com.pk/daily_detail.asp?id=179355> The cases involving hearing of Sethi’s abduction (1999) and missing persons (pending) revolved with the legal authority of ISI. Hamid Mir. “Why Benazir points finger at IB chief.” The News (October 20, 2007) See: <http://www.thenews.com.pk/top_story_detail.asp?Id=1069> As DG of FIA, he worked actively with Bhutto, when she was PM. He was hounded after Bhutto’s fall. Later on, he stayed in UK as security advisor of Bhutto. CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essays A STRATEGY TO FIGHT MILITANCY? Cyril Almeida* EIGHT years since 9/11 rendered debate on whether Pakistan needed a policy against militancy or not moot, the secondary question has still not been answered satisfactorily: what is the state’s policy against militancy? Despite notable successes against militants in Bajaur and Mohmand tribal agencies and the Malakand division over the past year, there are still serious questions about whether the state has a coherent, workable strategy to fight militancy and ensure a long-term future in which militants do not pose a threat to the writ of the state. The doubts are fanned by two facts: one, never has the state spelled out its strategy to fight militancy beyond the platitudes to protect the ‘national interest’ against ‘extremists’; and two, the rising arc of militancy inside Pakistan over much of the last decade suggests that the strategy, to the extent that it does exist, has not been an effective one. In the absence of a publicly articulated strategy to fight militancy, the numbers tell a story of their own. According to the South Asia Terrorism Portal, the total casualties from terrorist violence (civilian, security forces personnel and terrorist/militant) in 2003 was 189. By 2006, the total had climbed to 1,471 and to 6,715 by 2008. In 2009, by 21 Sept 8,175 people had died. In April 2009, a few days before Operation Rah-i-Rast was launched in the Malakand division against the Swat chapter of the Tehrik-iTaliban led by Maulana Fazlullah, Gen Ashfaq Parvez Kayani, the army chief, vowed that “victory against terror and militancy will be achieved * Cyril Almeida is an editorial writer and columnist with Dawn. Email cyril.a@gmail.com Essay at all costs.” Gen Kayani went on to say in his comments to top military commanders that the army “never has and never will hesitate to sacrifice, whatever it may take, to ensure safety and well-being of the people and country’s territorial integrity.” In the months since, the Pakistan Army has led operations that have decimated the Swat TTP, squeezed the TTP in its base in South Waziristan and seen Baitullah Mehsud killed by a drone strike that was likely aided by Pakistani intelligence. But do Gen Kayani’s words and the army’s recent actions add up to a coherent strategy to fight militancy? Not quite. The Pakistan Army — and it is very clear that the army dictates the overall approach to the fight against militancy — has what was described to the writer in a background conversation with one of the country’s best analysts a ‘set of priorities,’ not a strategy. Depending on the seriousness of the threat posed to the state by a particular group of militants or the pressure from outside to act against a particular network, the state as directed by the army has acted against it. The ‘prioritisation’ on those grounds is not very hard to detect. Broadly speaking, the army divides militants into different categories: Al Qaeda elements and those directly affiliated with the network; Pakistani militants; the Afghan Taliban; and various criminal gangs and networks that have latched on to pre-existing militant groups. Al Qaeda and its directly associated movements have been a target of the state the longest. In his 12 Jan 2002 speech to the nation, then president Gen Musharraf (retd) said: “We have been taking measures against terrorism from the beginning, not because of any outside pressure. We were already carrying out these measures when a terrorist attack was carried out in America on 11 September. After 11 September we joined the international coalition against terrorism and I am delighted that the majority of Pakistani people supported this decision.” It is questionable to what extent Pakistan was acting against Al Qaeda before 9/11, but successes since have been numerous. The roll212 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay call of Al Qaeda leaders captured or killed is lengthy and includes Saudi-born Palestinian Abu Zubaydah (Faisalabad, March 2002), Yemeni Ramzi Binalshibh (Karachi, September 2002), Khalid Shaikh Mohammad (Rawalpindi, March 2003), Abu Faraj al-Liby (Mardan, May 2005), Abu Hamza Rabia (North Waziristan, December 2005), Abu Laith al-Libi (North Waziristan, January 2008), Abu Khabab alMasri (South Waziristan, July 2008) and Abu Khabab al-Masri (Bajaur, August 2008). There is little doubt that the army and the state remain committed to finding and capturing or eliminating Al Qaeda leaders, intelligence and operational constraints permitting. There is absolutely no love lost between Al Qaeda and the Pakistan Army; Osama bin Laden and Ayman al Zawahiri have themselves called for strikes against the army and its leadership. Indeed, one of the above mentioned Al Qaeda militants, Abu Faraj al-Liby, is believed to have been the mastermind of the assassination attempts on Gen Musharraf (retd) in December 2003. Action against the other three militant ‘categories’ though has been limited, with the state ‘prioritising’ action against certain groups on the basis of its ‘threat’ and ‘pressure’ tests. Least likely to have drawn the state’s ire are the assorted criminal gangs and networks that have expanded their activities under the garb of religion. But when the threat has grown, the state has acted. Since June 2008, a series of operations have been launched in Khyber agency against three groups, the Lashkar-i-Islam led by Mangal Bagh Afridi, the Ansarul Islam led by Pir Saifur Rehman and a group called Amar Bil Maarouf Wa Nahi (the Promotion of Virtue and Prevention of Vice) led by Haji Namdar. The earlier operations were criticised and their effectiveness and the army’s strategy were questioned perhaps precisely because the army was acting according to its threat test; slaps on the wrist for the troublesome, a pounding for growing, recalcitrant threats. The latest operation launched in Khyber in September in the Bara region against Mangal Bagh and other criminal elements is believed to have been the most serious and the most effective partially because Peshawar itself was coming under threat from the activities of the criminal gangs operating in the area — the army thereby once again showing its willingness to act once certain CRITERION – October/December 2009 213 Essay ‘red lines’ have been crossed. Similarly, within the ‘Pakistani militants’ category a clear prioritisation is visible: militants who have crossed red lines and attacked the state directly and repeatedly and reneged on peace offers are the ones who have found themselves in the army’s crosshairs. Consider the most prominent targets in recent months: Baitullah Mehsud and Maulana Fazlullah. Baitullah Mehsud, who emerged as militant leader following the death of Nek Muhammad in 2004, was given the carrot-and-stick treatment on several occasions until his death in August. From March to July 2004, the security forces blockaded his base in South Waziristan and entered and fought inside the Mehsud strongholds, but a peace deal was reached in February 2005, which was renounced by Mehsud in July of the same year. Then in August 2007, he captured 242 soldiers, leading to the release of 24 militants in exchange for the return of the abducted soldiers. In January 2008, another military operation was launched in South Waziristan but it was called off within weeks and yet another deal was reached. What finally appeared to push the state irreversibly against Mehsud was the wave of suicide bombings and attacks on security targets inside Pakistan proper in the last 18 months that were almost invariably traced back to Mehsud’s network and allies in the Waziristan agencies. By the time a drone strike killed Baitullah Mehsud in August, likely aided by intelligence provided through Pakistani sources, he had become Public Enemy No 1 and was openly mentioned as an enemy of the state. Mehsud had crossed all the red lines of the Pakistan Army and its threat assessment of his network made it impossible to not act against him. The same ambivalence towards Maulana Fazlullah and his rapid rise to prominence in Swat after starting his illegal FM radio broadcasts in 2006 is also detectable. A nine-point peace deal in May 2007 and a 15point peace deal in May 2008 were interspersed with three moderately effective phases of Operation Rah-i-Haq, beginning in October 2007. 214 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay Then came the Malakand Accord of February 2009, which gave birth to the controversial Nizam-i-Adl Regulation, 2009 and seemingly gave the militants all that they had claimed to fight for. But the failure of Fazlullah’s Swat TTP to abide by the terms of the Malakand Accord was the last straw in the army’s analysis. With all the red lines having been crossed and the state and the security forces themselves having become a target of the Swat TTP, there was no choice but to place his organisation at the top of the list of priority targets and rout it. Other networks of Pakistani militants, however, have notably not met a similar fate and continue to survive, if not thrive. Consider the most prominent of the ‘Punjabi Taliban’ groups, the Lashkar-i-Taiba, a group that has drawn international attention once again following the terrorist attacks in Mumbai in November 2008. Led by Hafiz Saeed and currently known as the Jamaatud Dawa — periodic official ‘bans’ force such groups to routinely change their names — the group is opposed to fighting the Pakistani state, does not foment trouble against the security agencies and is avowedly focused on its fight against India. It is not high on the army’s list of priorities in the fight against militancy because it is not a direct threat. Following the Mumbai attacks, the organisation did become an embarrassment to the state and was the reason for considerable pressure being brought to bear on Pakistan, so the response was to act against those among its cadres based in Pakistan who were directly linked to the attacks and to leave the wider network relatively unscathed. Hafiz Saeed has recently been detained in his home once again, but the government continues to insist that India has not provided proof of his involvement in the Mumbai attacks and therefore cannot prosecute him. The Afghan Taliban appear to the lowest on the list of the state’s priorities, something which will come as no surprise to anyone who has heard the frequent and loud complaints of American, Afghan and ISAF officials. Here too the state’s calculation is apparent: the Afghan Taliban are primarily focused on the fight inside Afghanistan and they do not threaten Pakistan at present; therefore, they do not merit pressure CRITERION – October/December 2009 215 Essay from the state here. Gen Stanley McChrystal’s assessment of the war in Afghanistan clearly identifies the various components of the Afghan Taliban: “The major insurgent groups in order of their threat to the mission are: the Quetta Shura Taliban (QST), the Haqqani Network (HQN), and the Hezb-i-Islami Gulbuddin (HiG).” The general is also very clear about the significance of Pakistani terrain to those groups: “Afghanistan’s insurgency is clearly supported from Pakistan. Senior leaders of the major Afghan insurgent groups are based in Pakistan, are linked with Al Qaeda and other violent extremist groups, and are reportedly aided by some elements of Pakistan’s ISI. Al Qaeda and associated movements (AQAM) based in Pakistan channel foreign fighters, suicide bombers, and technical assistance into Afghanistan, and offer ideological motivation, training, and financial support. Al Qaeda’s links with HQN have grown, suggesting that expanded HQN control could create a favourable environment for AQAM to re-establish safe havens in Afghanistan. Additionally, the ISAF mission in Afghanistan is reliant on ground supply routes through Pakistan that remain vulnerable to these threats.” The Quetta shura, allegedly led by Mullah Omar, is a frequent source of tension between the US and Pakistan (an article in The New York Times on Sept 23 stated, “The issue of the Taliban leadership council, or shura, in Quetta is now at the top of the Obama administration’s agenda in its meetings with Pakistani officials.”) but there are genuine reasons to doubt its existence as an omnipotent network and the security establishment’s alleged support for it. What seems more likely is that the state is turning a blind eye rather than providing active assistance to Afghan Taliban members who are hiding out in and around Quetta and along parts of the Pak-Afghan border in Balochistan. Anne Patterson, the US ambassador to Pakistan, in an interview with McClatchy Newspapers in September spoke of the “different 216 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay priorities” of Pakistan and claimed that the state is “certainly reluctant to take action” against the leadership of the Afghan Taliban based in Pakistan. Ambassador Patterson went on the say: “Where we (the US) differ, of course, is the treatment of the groups who are attacking our troops in Afghanistan. And that comes down to Haqqani and Gul Bahadur and Nazir, to a lesser extent Hekmatyar, and yes, of course, there are differences there.” Pakistan will of course deny the ambassador’s claims, but the facts suggest otherwise. Gul Bahadur is a powerful warlord in North Waziristan and Maulvi Nazir a powerful one in South Waziristan; both have been courted by the state in its bid to isolate and defeat the Baitullah Mehsud network. Similarly, the fact that the Haqqani network and Gulbuddin Hekmatyar have bases in Fata is an open secret. Indeed, Ambassador Patterson was sympathetic to the state’s position: “In my view the Pakistanis don’t have the capacity to go after some of these groups. Some they do, let me stress. But say Siraj Haqqani holds territory, huge swathes of territory in North Waziristan, where he’s been implanted for years.” Given this rather clear pattern of prioritisation and sympathy for it extended by no less than the US ambassador to Pakistan, could it not qualify as the coherent strategy that the state requires to fight militancy effectively? Because the army publicly denies that prioritisation is in fact at play, the possible thinking behind it has to be deduced. First, there are clearly operational constraints at work. The state simply does not have the resources to fight on many fronts at the same time. Going after the Afghan Taliban in Balochistan where a low-level local insurgency is continuing, the Haqqani, Hekmatyar, Baitullah Mehsud, Hafiz Gul Bahadur, Maulvi Nazir networks in Fata, the Swat TTP in Malakand division, the criminal gangs masquerading as Islamic militants in Khyber agency, the Lashkar-i-Taiba, Jaish-i-Mohammad, Harkatul Mujahideen, etc., in the Punjab and elsewhere, Al Qaeda in the cities and in the tribal areas, and the foreign militants with an interest in CRITERION – October/December 2009 217 Essay China or the Central Asian Republics at the same is very difficult. The list of militant groups is seemingly endless, the targets spread out across the length and breadth of the country and the task of defeating them so complex (part counter-insurgency, part counter-terrorism in nature), so it is understandable to a degree that the state is working sequentially and dealing only with the ‘worst of the worst’ first. Second, the India factor. Adm Mike Mullen, chairman of the US joint chiefs of staff, told the US Senate Committee on Armed Services in September: “It’s my view they (Pakistan) are not going to lose their focus on India.” Explaining the Pakistan Army’s point of view further, Adm Mullen said: “They’ve got a challenge of literally two fights, a conventional fight or a conventional challenge and threat along with a counter insurgency challenge which they increasingly recognise.” That sums up the Pakistan Army’s approach: it can neither afford to commit 100 per cent of the resources at its disposal to fight militants nor zero per cent, but the percentage of resources it does commit to fighting militants is affected both by the severity of the threat from the militants as well as from India. Third, Pakistan’s stake in the Afghanistan of the future. The US’s strategic commitment to the region is far from clear; twice in his first 9 months in office, President Obama has re-evaluated his strategy for Afghanistan. However, there are other, regional powers — Iran, Russia, China, India — that are jockeying for influence in Afghanistan. In this environment of strategic uncertainty and competition, Pakistan cannot be expected to commit to a project — the elimination of the Afghan Taliban or at least their power to influence events in Afghanistan — when it isn’t clear if the other powers are committed to achieving that goal in the long term. Seen from that perspective, the Pakistan Army’s policy of fighting only those networks that persistently and implacably oppose the Pakistani state and have turned their guns on the state and the people appears to make strategic and political sense — fight only the ‘worst of the worst’ 218 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay and keep an eye on the neutral or friendly groups to in case events cause them to turn unfriendly. A coherent, practical and eminently sensible strategy to fight militancy, then, seems to be in hand. The problem is that the prioritisation approach ignores a grim reality: the various militant groups are far from discrete entities that are insulated from each other. Cross-pollination has occurred and the different groups work in concert and share resources to such an extent that it would be closer to the mark to describe the universe of militancy in Pakistan as a cocktail rather than readily identifiable discrete groups. The evidence of this has been available for years. On 25 Dec 2003, two suicide bombers struck Gen Musharraf’s (retd) motorcade in Rawalpindi. One of the attackers, Muhammad Jameel, hit the car carrying Nadeem Taj, who went from being Musharraf’s military secretary to DG Military Intelligence and finally DG ISI. A report in Dawn on 29 Dec 2003 explained Jameel’s background: “Dawn’s investigation revealed that Muhammad Jameel, 23, was affiliated with the banned Jaish-i-Mohammad, a militant organisation that had training camps in Rishkore near Kabul in the Taliban-ruled Afghanistan and was actively involved in the occupied Kashmir…. “Investigations revealed that Muhammad Jameel, resident of Androot, Police Station, Torarh in Poonch district, Azad Kashmir, had received only primary-level education and was a Hafizul Quran (memorised the Holy Book by heart). “Fired by fiery speeches by jihadi leaders, Jameel went to Jalalabad via Torkham in eastern Nangrahar province in January 2001 through an Afghan cloth merchant in AJ&K. Soon afterwards, he moved to Kabul and lived in Darul Aman area on the outskirts of the Afghan capital. “Jameel, however, was wounded and captured when the US-backed Northern Alliance attacked Kabul later that year. He was shifted to a CRITERION – October/December 2009 219 Essay hospital and remained under treatment for 15 days. The transitional government in Afghanistan led by President Hamid Karzai handed him over to Pakistani authorities along with 29 other militants that same month and they were flown to Peshawar in a military aircraft. “They were re-arrested by the Pakistani authorities and charged with entering Pakistan without travel documents. “Significantly, though, Jameel was declared ‘white’ by security agencies when interrogated by a Joint Interrogation Team in April last year. The JIT had concluded that the suspect was not involved in any anti-state activities and since nothing adverse had been found against him, the JIT had unanimously declared him ‘white’ implying that his custody was not required by the agencies.” More recently, following the death of Baitullah Mehsud, it is widely believed that Al Qaeda and the Haqqani network intervened in the succession crisis in the Tehrik-i-Taliban Pakistan and brokered a peace between the rival factions vying for power. Meanwhile, investigations into the spate of suicide bombings inside Pakistan suggest that Al Qaeda is providing the ideology and indoctrination, South Waziristan’s Baitullah Mehsud network the training resources and the Punjabi Taliban the ‘manpower’ to carry out the suicide strikes. All of this makes nonsense of a strategy to defeat militancy in Pakistan by prioritising which groups are to be fought against on the basis of their opposition to the Pakistani state. Furthermore, it cannot be overlooked that the present-day ‘strategy’ of defeating militancy is geared to fight groups that in the not-too-distant past were not considered to be a threat. And by the time they were considered to be a threat to the state and therefore tackled — such as Baitullah Mehsud’s network and Maulana Fazlullah’s Swat TTP — they had already caused tremendous damage to the state and the people. It is therefore difficult to avoid the conclusion that the Pakistan Army’s ‘red lines’ are worryingly deep, that by the time a serious threat is recognised and challenged the harm 220 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay caused is already intolerable. As mentioned earlier, there are in fact operational constraints limiting the state’s ability to open multiple fronts at the same time. However, as also indicated, some of those limits are self-imposed; were the army to alter its threat perception in Afghanistan and from India, more resources could be freed to fight militancy in earnest on several more fronts than it is being fought at present. The future could be made safer, but it remains hostage to the past. CRITERION – October/December 2009 221 BETWEEN DREAMS AND REALITIES Iqbal Ahmad Khan* Pakistan’s 62 year old tumultuous history has essentially been shaped by two factors, civil-military relations on the domestic front and our relations with India on the external front. The lop-sidedness of the civilmilitary equation in favor of the latter led to four military interventions and nearly 33 years of military and quasi-military rule in Pakistan. With generals as helmsmen, we fought two wars with India and have had to put up with its occupation of a huge portion of the Siachen Glacier. It was again the Chief of Army Staff who without “ formal approval by the political leadership at the highest level” plunged the country in a misadventure called Kargil. All these according to Sartaj Aziz were negative milestones or turning points in Pakistan’s history. In his book, “Between Dreams and Realities-Some milestones in Pakistan’s History,” former Finance and Foreign Minister Sartaj Aziz describes the 1965 war with India as “another negative milestone brought about by a series of ill-conceived and poorly executed strategies, (which) not only shattered that dream but also led to the eventual break-up of the country in 1971.” Contrary to what the succeeding generation has been led to believe, Sartaj Aziz opines that “the seventeen-day war was at best a draw….The longer-term economic and political consequences of the war were extremely damaging. In many ways the war represented the beginning of the end of the Ayub era. …In the wake of the 1965 war there was a widespread perception that West Pakistan could not really defend East Pakistan against an attack from India. (It) eventually led to the crisis that led to the break-up of the country.” * Iqbal Ahmad Khan is a former Ambassador of Pakistan. Email gazalakhan27@hotmail. com Essay Not prepared to learn any lessons from history and possessed of an insatiable greed for power, the rotund and promiscuous general, Yahya Khan, who snatched the reigns of government from self-styled FieldMarshal Ayub Khan plunged Pakistan into another war with India. The outcome of the war would have been obvious to the most casual student of military affairs. Sartaj Aziz writes that “The tragic turning-point of 1971, when East Pakistan became Bangladesh was essentially brought about by the failure of democracy in Pakistan….Sheikh Mujibur Rahman won 160 out of National Assembly’s 162 seats in East Pakistan in the 1970 elections, based on his six-point formula of maximum provincial autonomy. That gave him a majority in the National Assembly of 300 seats. Yet he was denied the opportunity to become prime minister….. The repression that followed after the arrest of Mujibur Rahman in March 1971, sent millions of refugees to India, giving it a good excuse to intervene militarily in November 1971 to ‘liberate’ East Pakistan and create the new state of Bangladesh.” In 1984 as the usurper-general, Zia-ul-Haq, was engaged in legitimizing his coup, consolidating his hold on power and doing America’s bidding in Afghanistan, India taking advantage of his preoccupations occupied “30,000 sq.km in Siachen Glacier where the Line of Control was not demarcated.” Yet another addition to this chronicle of failures was the adventure undertaken in Kargil by the Chief of Army Staff General Pervez Musharraf. “The Kargil operation,” Sartaj Aziz writes, “has become an extraordinary event in the country’s history because it not only prepared the ground for a prolonged military takeover in Pakistan in October 1999 but also derailed the peace process between India and Pakistan, which had started with such high hopes following Prime Minister Vajpayee’s historic visit to Lahore on 20-21 February 1999. It also caused irreparable damage to Pakistan’s principled and legitimate stand on Kashmir in the international arena.” To this negative fallout should be added the adverse impact of the Kargil operation on Pakistan’s image and its credibility and trustworthiness as a responsible member of the international community committed to regional and international peace and stability. Perhaps, it was such behavior and also that related to proliferation of weapons of CRITERION – October/December 2009 223 Essay mass destruction that prompted the former United States Secretary of State, Madeline Albright, to describe Pakistan as a case of international migraine. In this highly readable and lucidly written account of the major milestones in Pakistan’s history, the author, Sartaj Aziz, laments that those responsible for undermining the state and its national interests have invariably escaped responsibility. Tragically, the victims have been credible and legitimate personalities who have enjoyed the trust of the people of Pakistan. In this context he cites the execution of Zulfikar Ali Bhutto, Pakistan’s first popularly elected prime minister, and observes, “It is one of the many ironies of our history that one of the most outstanding political leaders, who secured a unanimous constitution for the country, was hanged while all the military generals who created circumstances that eventually led to the break-up of the country, lived on without much accountability.” If only General Zia-ul-Haq had been tried posthumously, along with some of his principal accomplices we might have been spared of 12 October 1999. It was Mr. Bhutto who chose not to publish and implement the strong recommendations of the Hamoodur Rahman Commission Report for the trial of General Yahya Khan and his cohorts. This was done in order to save the armed forces from further humiliations resulting from the 1971 debacle. He was repaid by a scheming and duplicitous general whose policies plunged the country into a morass from which we are still struggling to extricate ourselves. The author was the foreign minister in the cabinet of Prime Minister Nawaz Sharif who had assumed office in 1997 with a more than twothirds majority in the National Assembly. Little did the prime minister know at the time that he would barely have completed half his term before the army chief would have removed and imprisoned him. Without prior approval of the political leadership, the COAS launched the Kargil operation which turned out to be both a military and a political disaster. According to Sartaj Aziz, a retired army general was of the view that “Kargil was a very badly planned and poorly executed operation for which General Musharraf should have been court-martialed.” The 224 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay COAS who was the mastermind of the operation should have been held accountable and made to pay the price. But once again the irony was that as Sartaj Aziz puts it “The leader who saved Pakistan from a disastrous all-out war with India was deposed and then exiled from the country and the army general who overstepped his authority and caused irreparable damage to the Kashmir cause, became the undisputed ruler of the country for nine long years. It is difficult to imagine a more ironic and unjust episode in history.” In the 1950s and the 1960s a perennial feature of Greece’s politics was the repeated military incursions by army colonels into the prohibited civilian domain. The coups and counter-coups by these colonels had resulted in authoritarianism in politics, stagnation in the economy and confrontation with Turkey. Since Greece then was a frontline state in the containment of communism, the United States was not only indifferent to the overthrow of democracy, it in fact preferred to deal with military regimes rather than democratically elected bodies. The dawn of the 1970s brought a confident and popular civilian government in Athens which charged, tried, found guilty and sentenced some of these delinquent colonels. The trials were held in public and under the normal laws of the land. The purpose was to inform the public of the immense damage and suffering that military rule had caused to the country and the people. Three decades later Greece has remained coup free, economically and socially vibrant, an active member of the European Community and at peace with arch-rival Turkey. In Pakistan none of the four generals who forcibly threw out the established government of the time in violation of the constitution have been hauled up. Three of them are dead. The consensus among scholars, political analysts and the major political parties is that military rule has caused immeasurable damage to peace, prosperity and harmony in the country and is to be avoided like the plague. Sartaj Aziz subscribes to this consensus. In the epilogue he contends that “the net impact of such takeovers has been highly negative for the strength and unity of the federation and for the growth of a sustainable political process. Military rule invariably over-centralizes power in the executive to deliver ‘quick results’ and then seeks legitimacy by forcing the Judiciary to sanctify the CRITERION – October/December 2009 225 Essay takeover on grounds of state necessity. It further weakens the democratic process by weakening the role of the parliament and by manipulating certain political parties…” To keep the army out of politics the two major Pakistani political parties, the PPP and the PML (N) signed the Charter of Democracy under which they agreed to take a number of steps to safeguard democracy and to ensure that Bonapartism would be eliminated for ever from the politics of the country. Regrettably, one and a half years since the return of the democratic order, precious little has been done to give practical shape to their commitments in the Charter. Worse still, the army continues to call the shots in times of crises. In the war on terrorism the armed forces have been given a totally free hand, even though the civilian leadership does not tire of reminding the nation that to defeat terror much more than mere force is required. Similarly, the army chief had to step in when a violent confrontation between the government and lawyers supported by civil society demanding the restoration of Chief Justice Iftikhar Mohammad Chaudhry seemed imminent. The government finally caved in and accepted the populist demand for undoing the illegal acts of a military dictator. It is yet another sad irony that opposition to the restoration of the Chief Justice and to the trial of General Pervez Musharraf has come from the PPP government whose martyred chairperson, Benazir Bhutto, had hoisted the national flag at the residence of Iftikhar Mohammad Chaudhry and referred to him as the Chief Justice of the country. Likewise, the founder and chairman of the PPP Zulfikar Ali Bhutto was hanged by the most serpentine of military dictators General Zia-ul-Haq who then lashed and tortured workers of the party demanding democracy and justice. If, in the tradition of the earlier three military dictators, General (Retd.) Pervez Musharraf, violator of the fundamental law of the land, jailer of 60 judges of the superior courts and the Kargil mastermind is permitted to play golf and bridge in London and not brought before the courts, there will not be any disincentive for a future coup-maker. The main purpose of writing the book says Sartaj Aziz was to convey to the coming generations four important lessons from the country’s 226 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay history. Pakistan’s survival as a dynamic and viable political entity can only be ensured through a genuine democratic framework. This can “only be built on strong institutions and the rule of law under civilian supremacy. Military rule under a civilian façade can never become a substitute for genuine democracy……A democratic system and especially a parliamentary federal system can survive only if the three pillars of state: namely the parliament, the judiciary and the executive function within the parameters laid down by the constitution…..The vitality of a nation does not come only from its economic progress and the size of its military, but also from its shared values, cultural heritage and social energy. To these I would add an unwavering focus on the establishment of peaceful and cooperative relations with India.” The book couched in good English prose and containing unprecedented information on such significant and major turning points in Pakistan’s contemporary history such as Kargil, Indian and Pakistani nuclear tests, Kashmir and the October 1999 coup is a must read for anybody attempting to understand present day Pakistan. It is high time that the government of Pakistan, as provided for in the rules, systematically declassified all important official documents from 1947 to 1979 namely those which date back 30 years or more. This would kindle a renewed and vigorous interest among Pakistani and international scholars and hopefully result in high-quality publications enriching the curriculum in our academic institutions and providing the public with an authentic account of Pakistan’s internal developments and external relationships. In conclusion, we recall what was stated in the introduction; the domination of Pakistan’s history by two relationships, one between the civil and the military and the other between Pakistan and India. The lesson from six decades of turmoil and travail in Pakistan is that peace and stability in the country can only be established through subjecting the military to civilian control and establishing a cooperative and not a confrontationist approach towards India. It is military rule and wars with India that have undone Pakistan. Common sense and the overriding interests of the country dictate that we reverse course. The national security state must give way to a welfare state and war to peace with India. CRITERION – October/December 2009 227 COOPERATIVE MECHANISM TO SAVE KASHMIR ENVIRONMENT AND WATER WARS Iftikhar Gilani* Abstract The water issues between India and Pakistan may reach dangerous levels in the near future. With water resources drying up fast in Kashmir, the agriculture and economy of Pakistan will be badly hit. Pakistani authorities have, so far, consistently focused their efforts on making sure that India adheres to the provisions of the Indus Waters Treaty (IWT) without realizing that that their water banks, be it of Wullar Lake or Indus line glaciers, have receded inwards by several miles since the treaty was signed. Since these glaciers and water bodies have no significant economic importance for India, it would be naive to expect the Indian exchequer to invest in saving these resources which directly benefit the Pakistani farmer. It is time that both countries address this issue seriously by building a mechanism to save these water banks and investing in reversing climate change affects in Kashmir. This paper analyses the implications and attempts to sensitize experts on the potential environmental catastrophe and calls for evolving corrective measures.Author. BACKGROUND In an article published by the Washington Post on 28 January 2009, President Asif Ali Zardari described water as a major issue between Pakistan and India. He mentioned the serious consequences of an environmental catastrophe. He wrote: “The water crisis in Pakistan * Iftikhar Gilani is an Indian scholar and columnist. Essay is directly linked to relations with India. Resolution could prevent an environmental catastrophe in South Asia, but failure to do so could fuel the fires of discontent that lead to extremism and terrorism.” The Pakistan Indus Water Commission has been complaining of a reduced flow in the Chenab river at the Maralla headwork which has resulted in a loss of cropped areas in Lahore, Kasur, Okara, Sialkot, Hafizabad, Sheikhupura, Faisalabad and Jhang districts. While Indian experts consider this as merely another attempt by Pakistan to bring in another catalyst for conflict, both countries have preferred to ignore the basic issues that cause water scarcity and will eventually influence their respective economies and diplomatic relations. Furthermore, the water issues are directly linked with economic growth and the overall wellbeing of Pakistan which is indirectly linked with stability – the absence of which provides fuel for terrorism. It is believed that Pakistan’s water availability will plunge to 800 cubic meters per person by 2020 against the current 1,200 cubic meters per person. Just 60 years ago 5,000 cubic meters of water was available to a Pakistani citizen. India and Pakistan share six rivers of the Indus basin. These are grouped into two categories – the Western Rivers (the Indus, Chenab and Jhelum) and the Eastern Rivers (Sutlej, Ravi and Beas). Under the Indus Waters Treaty, India has comprehensive rights over the waters of the Eastern Rivers while Pakistan has the same over the waters of the Western Rivers. The treaty and its annexure are detailed technical documents which provide the guidelines to be followed on the usage of these waters. For instance, Pakistan can use the waters of the Western Rivers, however, India can also use them for irrigation purposes and is allowed to build run–of–the-river projects on them. Pakistan depends on the Indus river, which starts in Tibet and runs through Ladakh on the Indian side of Jammu and Kashmir, before reaching it. There it is fed by numerous tributaries from the mountain glaciers and swells out as it flows down towards the Arabian Sea. A U.N. report notes that more than three-quarters of Pakistanis live in the CRITERION – October/December 2009 229 Essay Indus basin and its water irrigates 80 percent of the nation’s cropland. DRYING UP OF WATER BODIES Without going into an academic debate to discuss the Indus Waters Treaty and its fallout, let us focus here on some practical aspects. Since the signing of the treaty, water bodies in Kashmir have receded to dangerous levels. A horrifying example of this is the pitiable condition of the Bari Nambal lagoon near Srinagar. Under the nose of the authorities this lake has turned into a marsh land. The absence of conservation measures has shrunk the area of this lagoon to just 0.50 sq kilometres during the past three decades. The only remnants of this once sparkling lagoon are an unending stretch of horrible weeds, agricultural fields and muddy waters. This problem has been enhanced by the accumulation of tons of garbage including non-biodegradable polythene, massive encroachment and the inflow of drains of the old city. Dumping of untreated sewage and garbage has changed this lagoon into dry mass. The Jammu and Kashmir state pollution control board had procured a sewage treatment plant (STP), which has been non-functional for a few years. A scientific study has confirmed rising phosphate levels which confirm the sub-standard operation of the STP. Besides pollution, the lagoon has been extensively encroached. Shops and hutments have been constructed illegally without any proper check and nearly 17 drains pour wastage into this lake. An identical fate haunts other nearby wetlands like Hokersar, Haigam, Shallabugh and Mirgund, which are the satellite wetlands of Wullar Lake and host thousands of migratory birds every year. The Haigam Wetland Conservation Reserve, an important refuge for migratory waterfowls, shorebirds and trans-Himalayan species in winters has shrunk considerably as people of adjoining the villages have 230 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay encroached on the land and started paddy cultivation. Environmentalists blame the government for it, as there are no conservation measures and monitoring mechanisms in place. In fact, the authorities constructed a road on the wetland’s boundary at Asthanpoora in 2007; disregarding the warnings by environmentalists that the vehicular traffic on the road will affect the habitat. Environmentalist Mian Altaf, acknowledges deterioration of the wetlands in the valley, many of which are under threat due to reclamation for agriculture, development activities, contamination by sewage, agricultural run-off and siltation. Most of the wetlands in the lower Himalayan region are infested with aquatic weeds. The Trans-Himalayan wetlands are becoming fragile due to anthropogenic activities, growing tourism and faulty land management. There is not a single water stream in Kashmir today which has not witnessed water depletion over the years. Analysis of the data collected from the eight districts of Kashmir, in a study sponsored by the Action Aid, shows that the water level in almost all the streams and rivers has decreased by about one-third, in some cases even by half, during the last 40 years. It is the water flow in the small streams and tributaries that finally determine the overall water availability in Kashmir’s three main rivers, namely, the Indus, Jhelum and Chenab, which finally flow into Pakistan. DEPLETING GLACIERS It has also been observed that the Himalyan glaciers are melting and receding faster than in any part of the world. Muneer Ahmad of the National Geophysical Research Institute in Hyderabad, reported that the nose of the Kolhai glacier in Kashmir, one of the largest glaciers in the Himalayas, had receded by almost 22 metres in 2007 while several smaller glaciers had disappeared completely. Ajit Tyagi, Director General of the Indian Meteorological Department, warned that the glaciers could disappear even sooner if the earth continues to warm at its current rate. Almost 15,000 Himalayan CRITERION – October/December 2009 231 Essay glaciers form a unique reservoir which supports perennial rivers such as the Indus, the Ganges and the Brahamputra which, in turn, are the main source of fresh water for billions of people in South Asian countries. Some scientists believe that clouds of pollutants - almost two miles thick - suspended over Asia may be a part of the problem. It was assumed that the clouds, caused mainly by domestic wood and dung fires and through the burning of forests and fields for agriculture, helped cool the land by filtering out sunlight. However, it is now known that soot particles in the cloud actually absorb the sunlight and magnify solar heating on the ground by almost 50 percent. While India has taken tough measures restricting tourist and pilgrim traffic to save the Gangetic glaciers, it tends to sidestep the Kashmir glaciers which are a source of water to the Indus and Jhelum. To whip up communal passions on land allotment to the Amarnath Yatra Board in Kashmir Valley last year, India’s Hindu nationalist Bhartiya Janata Party (BJP) overlooked a report prepared by its own NDA member, Dr. Nitish Sengupta, in 1996 asking to regulate the Amarnath-bound pilgrims in order to preserve the fragile ecology and environment of the region. The forest land handed over to the Shri Amarnath Shrine Board (SASB), at Baltal near Sonamarg, houses the Nehnar and Thajwasan glaciers. Ironically, the BJP government in the north Indian state of Uttrakhand applied Dr. Sengupta’s report in Gangotri, where in May 2008 they issued a notification restricting the number of pilgrims and tourists visiting Gomukh, the source of the holy river, Ganga, to 150 a day. Gomukh is as important a holy shrine for Hindus as Amarnath is in the southern mountains of Kashmir. Last year over 500,000 pilgrims visited the Kashmir Shrine over a period of two months and over 20,000 pilgrims were at the cave shrine against the recommended 3,000 per day. Glaciologists have also warned of environmental degradation, ecological imbalance and adverse impact on the Nehnar glacier, situated 232 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay at a height of 4200 meters around Baltal near Sonamarg, being caused by the heavy rush of pilgrims. A paper presented in 2005 by Prof M.N. Kaul, a former principal Investigator on glaciology in the Department of Science and Technology in India, stated: “The ecology, the environment and the health of the glacier can be under severe threat in case the Baltal route to the holy cave was frequented by thousands of pilgrims.” Elaborating, he said, “there are 6500 glaciers in the Himalayan regions in India and out of which 3136 glaciers were in the mountain belt of Jammu and Kashmir… these glaciers constitute 13 per cent of the state’s total land and if allowed to assume strength year after year we can generate 80,000 MWs of electricity.”Referring to the Amarnath pilgrimage, he said “it is for the first time the Baltal route has been exposed to heavy pilgrim traffic which is likely to affect the ecological balance and the health of the Nehnar glacier.” Environmentalists have often raised concern that pilgrims not only defecate on the banks of the Indus river but throw tonnes of nondegradable items, such as polythene, directly into the river. This has resulted in the deterioration of its water quality. One expert, M R. D Kudangar, observed that the chemical oxygen demand of the river has been recorded between 17 and 92 mg/l which is beyond the permissible level. Such enriched waters with hazardous chemical levels can in no way be recommended as potable. It has crossed all permissible limits due to flow of sewage and open defecation. It has been estimated that 55,000 kg of waste is generated on a daily basis during the pilgrimage. Apart from this waste, the degradation caused by buses and vehicles carrying pilgrims, trucks carrying provisions and massive deployment of security forces contribute further to air pollution. Another fallout is the threat posed to local inhabitants from crowding of the ecologically fragile area where they have to compete to retain their access and rights to resources. Most countries have regulated tourist inflows into their mountainous regions. India’s National Environment Policy itself calls for measures CRITERION – October/December 2009 233 Essay “to regulate tourist inflows into mountain regions to ensure that these remain within the carrying capacity of the mountain ecology.” A UN sponsored study, ‘Mountains of Concrete: Dam Building in the Himalayas,’ has also predicted a dramatic decrease in flows in the Indus basin within 100 years. The study undertaken by Sripad Dharmadhikari of Manthan Adhyayan Kendra for International Rivers predicts extreme changes in river flows due to global warming. As glaciers melt, water levels in the rivers will rise and dams would be subjected to much higher flows, thereby, raising concerns of dam safety, increased flooding and submergence. Furthermore, with the subsequent depletion of glaciers, annual flows would be much lower which would inevitably affect the performance of dams. These environmental issues and their impact should have been assessed in the planning stage before huge investments were made in the construction of these dams. Half a billion people in the Himalaya-Hindu-Kush region and a quarter billion downstream who rely on glacial melt waters could be seriously affected. The current trends in glacial melt suggest that the Indus and other rivers may become seasonal rivers in the near future which will be harmful for the economies in the region. Last year, a team of “The Energy Research Institute of India” (TERI) visited Kashmir to study some of these glaciers. The team, which was led by Professor Iqbal Hassnain, included an expert from Iceland. The University of Kashmir also collaborated in the study. They concentrated their studies on the Kolahoi glacier in the Pahalgam area, the largest in the valley. They also reported accelerated melting of glaciers and said it would be another tragedy in this environmental downslide. An Action Aid report has also warned that melting of the Kashmri glaciers could trigger massive food security problems in the near future. According to the report, some of the glaciers have already disappeared as a result of which the discharge in streams has been significantly reduced. The report which was basically a study that identified the impact of climatic change at the micro-level mentioned that a 21 percent 234 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay overall reduction had been found in the glacier surface area of Chenab, a sub-basin of Indus. Of the major 327 glaciers in the Himalayas, 60 are in Kashmir and Ladakh. The report said while some of the glaciers have vanished, the surviving ones are fast shrinking. In Sindh valley, for instance, the Najwan Akal glacier has disappeared while the surviving trio - Thajwas, Zojila and Naranag – have shrunk considerably. The one feeding the Amarnath cave has been reduced by over 100 meters in a year. Similarly the Afarwat glacier near Gulmarg does not exist though once it happened to be 400 meters long. The report further mentions that this phenomenon is not area specific but exists everywhere from north to south. As per the locals, almost all the major glaciers in south Kashmir – Hangipora, Naaginad Galgudi and Wandernad – are shrinking. It carries no supporting data which, in certain cases, was available with certain official agencies. The report says that while snowfall and rainfall has reduced, the temperatures have risen. Barring certain water bodies that are spring fed, most of the streams are glacial-fed. Early-melting triggers massive discharge in rivers. However, the water bodies lack the adequate quantity once the peasantry starts tilling the fields. Further, early-melting triggers flash-floods and the fall in water discharge impacts agricultural production that, according to the report, is already affected by arbitrary land use. The report has tried to link the possibility of heat-trapping gases in Kashmir’s “almost closed environment” with the melting of glaciers and other indications of climatic change. Kashmir’s forest area has also been considerably reduced from 37 percent to merely 11 percent. Barely 20 years ago, the snow line in the Kashmir valley’s east was just above areas like Pahalgam and Sonmarg (3200m). “Currently the line has receded to Shiashnag area which is at an altitude of 5000m only. Same is true of the Pirpanjal mountain range in the west where the snow line was above Kongwatan and Zaznar (3000-3500m).” Most of the glaciers of the Great Himalayan range, from Harmuk CRITERION – October/December 2009 235 Essay to Drungdrung including Thajiwas, Kolahoi, Machoie, Kangrez, Shafat, have receded (4000-5000m) during the last 50 years. According to testimonies of villagers in Choolan area located in the Shamasbari mountain range in North Kashmir, the nearby glacier, namely Katha, has reduced from 200 feet to 80 feet during the past 40 years. Similarly, people living around Tangmarg and Gulmarg in North Kashmir say the height of the Budrukot glacier in the area has been reduced from 16 feet to only 5 feet. The Khujwan glacier in the mountains of the Kichama area has shrunk from 40 feet to only 20 feet. The Afarwat glacier around Nambalnar Hajibal area, which used to be 300 feet long 40 years ago has completely disappeared. Fifty years ago, 8000 sq km of the Chenab basin was under glaciers. Permanent and ephemeral snow cover would contribute huge quantities of water during the summer to this river through numerous perennial tributaries. Now it has only 4100 sq km of snow covered area. In the Pirpanjal range there is hardly any remnant of glaciers. The terminal morains at Akhal(Rajpora) in Romshi river, Dubjan in Rambiyara river and Gurwatan in Veshuv river bear the testimony that the glaciers once extended up to these places. If this situation continues then all rivers flowing from Pirpanjal range will lose their perenniality and become ephemeral. WATER POLLUTION Another source of concern along with receding water levels is the increased level of pollutants. Gypsum mines operational in Uri, the last station of River Jheulum before crossing LoC, have polluted the water to such an extent that 30 percent of the population has been plagued with water borne diseases including tuberculoses. Besides Gypsum the series of toilets constructed on the banks of Naloosa stream by the Army has added further woes. A scientific study on the river Jhelum has found waters turning acidic. When one moves from Verinag to Baramulla (downstream) there 236 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay is a gradual increase of sodium, potassium, sulphates, nitrates, nitrogen containing substances and iron. This is accompanied by a massive depletion of essential chlorides. The river water has accumulated all the harmful chemical compositions which are not only affecting the human population but also the flora and fauna that exist within the two banks. One species of fish has already vanished and the factors put forward by the experts do not exclude the pollution crisis. Out of Jhelum’s 997.79 Kms length, 241kms are in the Kashmir Valley. The volume of contaminants added to it in this small length are enormous. A crude assessment reveals that millions of tons of solid waste, municipal garbage and sewage from human settlements flow directly into the river. The valley lacks tanneries, however, the wastes from brick kilns and other small scale industrial units are more hazardous to the health of the river. Hospital wastes are also being directly added to the river in all the major towns. These hospitals and nursing homes are continuously evading the installation of systems which would decompose and destroy bio-degradable and other hazardous wastes. Besides the main urban settlements - Anantnag, Bejbehara, Pampore, Srinagar, Pattan, Baramulla, Sopore and Uri – the villages are also adding a considerable amount of sewage. This excludes the pollution tapped by 17 of its tributaries which jointly drain a sprawling area of 11,353 Sq Kms in south, north and the central Kashmir. Human excretions and agricultural wastes are the main contribution to the water-body from villages. Investigations have revealed that pesticides, insecticides, weedicides and fertilizers have definitely added to the change of water chemistry of the river. In Srinagar, the Urban Environmental Engineering Division (UEED) operates 52 de-watering units. 35 of them flow directly and the rest indirectly into Jhelum. Usually these pumps run for five hours daily and in wet seasons for 20 hours. Each of these units adds 3,000 cfts of sewage to the river every second. CRITERION – October/December 2009 237 Essay A research scholar at the Department of Environmental Science in the University of Kashmir had found that 525-575 cubic metres of solid waste in a 35 kms area in Srinagar was drained into the river Jhelum. In Anantnag town, 10MLD of liquid waste is pumped into the river .The town generates 25 cubic meters of solid water every day of which only 18 cm is being treated by the authorities. Other major towns like Sopore and Baramulla towns pour 20 and 10 MLDs, respectively, of waste water into the river. A survey conducted by the Jammu and Kashmir State Pollution Control Board (JKPCB) found that the chemical oxygen demand (COD) value was beyond permissible limits over the entire stretch due to untreated sewage through various drains. The average COD value does not even confirm the designated best-used criteria for drinking purposes. Another study by the Central Soil and Water Research and Training Institute reveals that the Jammu & Kashmir state losses over 5,334 million tones of soil, annually. While 29 percent of the eroded land is being permanently lost in the sea, 10 percent is deposited as silt in water bodies and 61 percent is displaced. Only 34 percent of the overall soil has negligible erosion. DRYING WULLAR For over 30 years India and Pakistan have been engaged in discussing the Wullar Barrage or Tulbul Navigation project. They have, however, ignored the basic health of the Wullar lake which is a major water bank and vital reservoir for Pakistan. The Wullar Lake is the main source of water to the river Jhelum which is the lifeline for the Punjab and Sindh plains. India and Pakistan are engaged in settling the disputes over the Wullar barrage and Tulbul navigation lock, however, the health of the lake, despite the alarm bells ringing from a shocking report prepared by the International Water Management Institute (IWMI) in collaboration with TATA, has been completely ignored. 238 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay Wullar Lake is one of the largest fresh water lakes located at 34°16’N - 74°33’E, between the Sopore and Bandipur townships in north Kashmir. It plays a significant role in the hydrographic system of the Kashmir valley by acting as a huge reservoir and absorbs the high annual floodwater of the river Jehlum. In recognition of its biological, hydrological and socio-economic values, the lake was included in 1986 as a Wetland of National Importance under the Wetlands Programme of the Ministry of Environment and Forests, Government of India for intensive conservation and management purposes. Subsequently in 1990, it was designated as a Wetland of International Importance under the Ramsar Convention. The IWMI report says sewage disposal, weed infestation, catchment problems, sedimentation and excessive willow plantation have badly damaged this lake which is a life line for Pakistan’s water reservoirs. Recommending more funds to preserve the lake, the report points out that it yields a benefit to the tune of Rs 2.19 billion per annum. It is the only source of water for approximately 60,000 villagers in Jammu and Kashmir and helps in paddy cultivation in the catchment area of 83,000 hectares. The report underlined that Jhelum, Kashmir’s main river, is bringing dirt and refuge from adjoining towns and habitations to the entire south and central Kashmir route spanning 140 km and dumping it into the Wullar lake. Similarly, 12 different rivulets of north Kashmir that are adding tonnes of organic and inorganic waste in the lake every day. Moreover, the Indian navy’s only outpost in the form of highly skilled Marine Commandos (Marcos), an elite Special Forces unit, is located in this lake for counter-insurgency operations since 1995 but it too has never bothered to clean up the lake. Experts believe that the condition of the lake has already reached a dangerous stage that stimulates the growth of aquatic plants resulting in the depletion of dissolved oxygen. They say it is high time that both India and Pakistan join their efforts and resources to conserve this crucial water reservoir. CRITERION – October/December 2009 239 Essay While the Wetland Directory published by the Indian government puts the lakes area at 189 sq Kms, the Survey of India maps reduce it to 58.7 sq kms. At the highest flood level of 1579 metres the lake area is 173 sq kms. Revenue records, however, show 130 sq kms as the lake area, of which around 60 sq kms are under agricultural use. When out of power, Union Minister for Water Resources Prof. Saifuddin Soz, who had led a campaign to save this lake, divulged that the lake had shrunk from its earlier area of 200 sq kms to barely 24 sq kms. Through satellite imagery, the Jammu and Kashmir Directorate of Environment and Remote Sensing (DEARS), found that the lake has shrunk from 202 sq kms to 65 sq kms of which 30 sq kms are witnessing massive vegetation and may result in eutrophication. Of the solidified lake, 35 sq kms stand encroached by the state government alone. CONCLUSION The on-the-ground picture may be more horrific than what is portrayed in this paper. The paper has also deliberately avoided taking up environmental concerns emanating out of the increasing military activities along the Siachen glacier. The paper primarily focused on issues that have yet to be dealt with but can easily be a part of future India-Pakistan diplomatic deliberations. Terrorism may be a biggest threat devouring innocent lives in the region, however, the environmental catastrophe affects generations and costs more lives than any other calamity. Therefore, it is surprising that these issues have not received much attention. It is imperative for both India and Pakistan to evolve a mechanism beyond the Indus Waters Treaty (IWT) and water sharing negotiations to save the actual sources of water. There is greater need to set up a cooperative mechanism to govern and protect resources across the LoC. One cannot expect the Indian exchequer to invest on protecting resources that do not directly benefit India. It is the Pakistani farmer who has a vested interest in the protection of resources in Kashmir. 240 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay SAARC’s mandate could also be expanded to include greater cooperation on environmental issues. Monitoring committees for resource management should be set up, and knowledge and data sharing mechanisms should be enhanced in order to foster greater environmental cooperation. Security can no longer be confined to national security threats or international relations. Environmental changes have now been listed as security threats. Richard Ullman has defined threat as “…anything which can degrade the quality of life of the inhabitants of a state, or which narrows the choices available to people and organizations within the state.” It is time, therefore, for both India and Pakistan to re-define their strategies and attend to this issue which, if not addressed, will have a devastating impact on the lives and wellbeing of their people. References: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. P. Stobdeon, IDSA papers Pakistan Raises Water Issues Indus Water Treaty: Zardari ups the ante on Water Issues Arvind Gupt January 30, 2009 Uttam Sinha, “India and Pakistan: Introspecting the Indus Treaty,” Strategic Analysis, vol. 32, issue 6 November 2008, p. 963. From Encroachments, Pollution, Constructions, Official Apathy ARIF SHAFI WAN, Greater Kashmir Log Jam Street Ecological costs can deflate the GDP’s bounce Perennial Floods in South Asia: Need for Environmental Diplomacy Avinash Godbole Research Assistant India would make Pakistan barren by 2014, says Jamaat Ali Shah, Daily Times Himalayan glaciers ‘could disappear completely by 2035’, Daily Times [editorial-Greater Kashmir- November 13, 2008] Notification of Uttrakhand Government, May 28, 2008 A paper by Prof M.N. Kaul, 2005. A study ‘Mountains of Concrete: Dam Building in the Himalayas,’ Action Aid report on Kashmir glaciers Gypsum mining in Uri, Shabir Ibn Yusuf,, Kashmir Times Shahid Ahmad Wani Research scholar in the Department of Environmental Science University of Kashmir. A survey conducted by the J&K State Pollution Control Board (JKPCB) A report by Central Soil and Water Research and Training Institute Richard Ulhmn Redefining Security CRITERION – October/December 2009 241 THE PRICE OF ‘SEA BLINDNESS’ Muhammad Azam Khan* Pakistan’s military history is littered with sacrifices by the nation’s valiant young officers - soldiers, sailors and airmen alike. But these sacrifices could do little to avert the final outcome of conflicts since at the strategic tier there was a universal lack of understanding on the prosecution of war duly exacerbated by misconstrued concepts. One small exchange narrated to this scribe by no less than a four star Admiral goes to explain the level of military leadership’s discretion and insight as it prevailed shortly before the outbreak of the 1971 war. The Admiral, then a middle rank naval officer, had met the Commander Eastern Command (General A.A.K. Niazi) at the height of military action in the then East Pakistan. He asked the latter as to why should it be necessary for the military government to resort to such brute force against a hapless population particularly when they happen to be co-religionists. “You don’t have an idea; there is a sea difference between your record and mine; I have earned one of the highest grading in my ACRs and you stand nowhere near me,” General Niazi mockingly responded. But, the former Admiral retorted “Sir, wars are not fought by way of ACRs but rather with Emaan (Faith).” Just months later, Pakistan faced the worst military ignominy in its checkered history. Pakistan inherited a maritime legacy whose foundation rested on what could be called ‘sea blindness.’ Here was a population; a martial race that had neither any knowledge nor penchant for maritime issues but held an intrinsic fondness for land battles. The British established their empire and ruled the far reaches of the world by enriching themselves through sea commerce, protected and preserved by their navy. What * Muhammad Azam Khan, Commander Pakistan Navy (Retd), Pakistan Navy War College Essay started as small time trading by the British traders in India in the early 17th century soon grew into a phenomenal trans-oceanic commerce. The East India Company, seeking slow but sure concessions from the Mughal rulers, took away choicest Indian merchandise thereby draining the Empire. The British traders delighted in the delicate craftsmanship and attractiveness of Indian manufactures particularly textiles and took good advantage of their growing popularity in Britain and France. Aurangzeb, who perhaps saw a connection between growing European trade privileges and falling revenues in overland trade, attempted to reduce these. No other Mughal ruler could grasp the machinations of the East India Company, much less control its activities. The diminishing land trade revenues eventually weakened the Mughals who were unable to resist centrifugal forces. The empire crumbled rapidly. The decline of the Mughal Empire and the concomitant ascendency of the British in India is attributable to the former’s fixation with landward concerns; developing outsized armies for land battles at the expense of ignoring the Indian shores or the large coastline (7,500 Km) which provided an ideal Mahanian strategic position in relation to major trade routes. It was ‘sea blindness’ unsurpassed. The vacuum provided outside powers maintaining strong merchant fleets and navies to exploit the Indian riches, accrue advantage and establish a foothold in India. The Portuguese were followed by the Dutch and finally the English enslaved India. Clever and crafty as they were, the British did not assemble any valuable maritime infrastructure along India’s vast coast. Instead, they relied on the previous set up established by the Portuguese and the Dutch. Earlier, the Portuguese had sustained their Empire through a combination of supremacy at the sea along with a chain of well-fortified settlements on land. Goa, their capital, was linked with Malacca in the Far East and Hormuz in the Persian Gulf in a strategic command of the Indian Ocean. The British Raj investments in industrial and technical infrastructure in the areas that today constitute Pakistan were equally worthless. This was done on purpose. The first aim was to expand crop production CRITERION – October/December 2009 243 Essay particularly cotton in Indian Punjab in order to sustain the ever growing textile industrial empire of Europe and secondly, to rear a soldierly race that could be requisitioned to fight the imperial wars in Burma, Africa and elsewhere. Yet how well the British understood the strategic value of Karachi and its adjoining Baluchistan (Makran) coast is summarized in an unsigned memorandum of Lord Mountbatten dated 19 May 1948. ‘The Indus valley, western Punjab and Baluchistan(the northwest) are vital to any strategic plans for defense of (the) all important Muslim belt----the oil supplies of the Middle East.--------Only through the open ocean port of Karachi could the opponents of the Soviet Union take immediate and effective countermeasures. The sea approaches to all other countries will entail navigation in enclosed waters directly menaced by Russian air fleets---not only of the sea lanes of approach, but also the ports of disembarkation. If the British Commonwealth and the United States of America are to be in a position to defend their vital interests in the Middle East, then the best and most stable area from which to conduct this defense is from Pakistan territory. Pakistan (is) the keystone of the strategic arch of the wide and vulnerable waters of the Indian Ocean.’ As the partition drew near, such views had gained much currency. Lord Mountbatten, the last British viceroy in India was a cousin of King George VI who married, in July 1922, one of the richest heiresses in England. Edwina Ashley was the most sought after girl in London, admired as much for her brilliance as for her elegance. Mountbatten’s father, Admiral Prince Louis of Battenberg, was a German migrant. He held the top post in the British navy till the beginning of the First World War, when he was asked to resign on account of his German birth. An ambitious man, Mountbatten was commanding a destroyer, HMS Kelly, which received a direct hit from German bombers in May 1941. The ship capsized. Instead of serving as a curtain call, the incident further benefitted Mountbatten in his naval career. The well connected sailor was rewarded and sent to the United States on a lecturing tour to recount British naval exploits against Germans and to cultivate useful contacts. Mountbatten’s rise in ranks was purely by virtue of his links with 244 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay the Royal family and it was not on grounds of professional competence that he was appointed by the British Raj to oversee the fate of their most important colony in Asia. Born in a state of insecurity and under the shadows of a large and inimical neighbor that had forcibly annexed Kashmir, Hyderabad and Goa, Pakistan’s defense concerns were but natural. The country’s post partition geography with its two wings separated by India placed it in a unique position. An unaccommodating Afghanistan to the west and an ambitious USSR further complicated Pakistan’s security apprehensions. The 1948 Kashmir war proved to be the proverbial ‘icing on the cake.’ Thus, external security concerns assumed an overwhelming precedence for the fledgling state. The Pakistan Navy started its journey with an assortment of just sixteen ships and 92 commissioned officers. Even so, the service was never short of stout hearts. Admiral H.M.S. Chouhdri who took over command of the Pakistan Navy in January 1953 as the first Pakistani C-in-C was a sagacious and erudite sailor. He wanted to lay the foundation for a formidable naval force; a versatile armada that could operate both in the North Arabian Sea as well as Bay of Bengal with much flexibility and fearsome firepower to strike terror in the heart of the enemy on whose flanks the Pakistan navy was to extend national maritime security umbrella. Admiral Chouhdri strongly believed that in order to safeguard the national maritime interests including the 3000 mile sea route between the two wings of Pakistan, (the only reliable and economical means of communication for transportation of men and material both in peacetime as well as in the event of hostilities), a strong navy was an indispensable national need. It was also Admiral Chouhdri who stressed the urgency of acquiring submarines by the Pakistan navy. But this dream could only be realized in May 1963 when the U.S government leased a Tench class submarine, USS Diablo to Pakistan, long after Admiral Chouhdri had relinquished charge as C-in-C, Pakistan navy. On 1 June 1964, the submarine was commissioned into Pakistan navy as PNS Ghazi. CRITERION – October/December 2009 245 Essay Admiral Chouhdri’s dream could not be realized during his term of office because of the doctrinal concept ‘the defense of east lies in the west.’ Coined by the Army Chief, General Ayub, the concept ruled out any need for keeping the sea lines open in the event of war with India. Ayub, who as a junior officer had fought in Burma during WWII conceptualized that since war with India would be short and fought from within the existing stockpiles, keeping sea lines open protecting nearly 3000 miles of sea lines was not vital. It was then generally believed that with a hard hitting and well trained standing army, Pakistan would quickly reach Delhi and Indian resistance would collapse. A man of pride and integrity, Admiral Chouhdri resigned in protest. The premise on which the Admiral stepped down was to later to be proved by events and the faulty reasoning on which Ayub’s defence concepts was based was exposed. Admiral Chouhdri and later Admiral Ahsan, who between them shared sterling qualities of leadership, saw the Pakistan navy surface as a formidable force during the 1965 war against India. As the sole submarine PNS Ghazi stalking outside Bombay harbor effectively pinned down a large and numerically superior Indian navy inside its home port, the PN surface fleet pounded Dwarka that housed important radar facilities. An effective maritime control over the Arabian Sea was fully established by the Pakistan navy. The awe-inspiring role of PN submarine Ghazi later led to the expansion in the submarine fleet and a deal for the purchase of three French Dauphines submarines was inked in February 1966. Consequently, these submarines played a crucial role during the next Indo-Pak encounter in 1971. But for the flawed notion and all pervading national ‘sea blindness,’ a more balanced and vibrant Pakistan navy could have once again, to all intents and purposes, effectively taken on a numerically superior Indian navy in the Bay of Bengal. The valiant journey of PNS Ghazi ended in tragedy off Vishakapatnam harbor on 4 December 1971. Nearly 44 years after the Pakistan navy held uncontested command in the North Arabian sea during the September 1965 war, the country once again stands at the cross roads. This time absence of a sea based 246 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay strategic deterrence and the want of a nuclear second strike capability compounds national security problems. Sadly, once more it was a tangled doctrinal concept; the ‘strategic depth’ being sought in a neighboring country, that came in the way and held back a timely development and deployment of the most reliable arm in the nuclear triad with inbuilt features of mobility and stealth. Shrouded in secrecy and after denying its existence for years, ATV (Advance Technology Vehicle), the project name of India’s locally designed SSN (nuclear powered attack submarine), was finally officially confirmed by the Indian navy chief, Admiral Suresh Mehta, in the fall of 2007. On 26 July this year the sluice gates of the naval dockyard at Vishakapatnam were opened by the Indian Prime Minister to commission the country’s first locally constructed SSN, INS Arihant. The 6,000 tonne, 124 m long ATV, a derivative of the Soviet 670 A Skat class SSN (NATO designation Charlie I class) was under development since the mid-1970s. Powered by a miniaturized 85 megawatt nuclear reactor the SSN can reach a top underwater speed of 24 knots (44Km per hour) and can be armed with a mix of torpedoes and ballistic missiles. With an onboard crew of 95, INS Arihant will now undergo sea trials for about two years. Upon completion of the trials, the SSN is expected to enter service with the Indian navy in 2010 as a ‘technology demonstrator.’ The fielding of a nuclear powered submarine makes India the sixth SSN operating country after China, France, Russia, the UK and the US. In addition to the ATV, is yet another important Indian project involving the lease from Russia of a Type 971 Akula II (Bars) class nuclear powered submarine. The under-construction 12,000 tonne submarine rechristened as INS Chakra was to be completed and leased to India for 10 years under a $ 650 million deal signed in 2004. It was to be inducted into the Indian navy on 15 August 2009 but was delayed by a year following technical snags. ‘Project India’ as the classified lease program is called, now seems to be back on track after being seemingly caught in last year’s freeze in Indo-Russian ties over the escalating costs of the aircraft carrier, Vikramditya (former Gorshkov) undergoing refit in Russian yards. The 44,500 tonne ex-Russian carrier was negotiated by India in 2004 at a cost of $ 2.5 billion and has since been subjected to CRITERION – October/December 2009 247 Essay steady price increases because of the technical glitches usually associated with used naval platforms. Due to its design commonality with ATV, INS Chakra is being leased by the Indians primarily to train crews to man ATVs. Accordingly, over the past two years three Indian navy SSN crews of around 300 personnel have undergone training at a dedicated facility near St Petersburg. Now expected to be delivered by the end of this year, INS Chakra together with INS Arihant will constitute the third strand of India’s strategic deterrence supplementing air-delivered and mobile land-based missile systems. In partnership with private industry, India’s Defense Research and Development Organization (DRDO) plans to locally construct three to five more SSN’s to expand its strategic deterrence capability. India is also vigorously engaged in developing a strategic missile for integrating with SSN’s weapon systems suite. Designed too by the Indian Defense and Research Development Organization, the enigmatic two stage missile dubbed K-15 or Sagarika (Oceanic) was successfully tested in April 2007. The test was described as a technological breakthrough. Rapidly ejected from the submarine’s launcher by igniting an underwater gas booster, the missile rises nearly 5 km above the Ocean. Upon reaching a pre-determined height, it ignites a solid booster and travels to a range of nearly 750 km to deliver its lethal pay load. Sea-launched nuclear missiles are at the core of second strike capability and function as a stabilizer in nuclear strategy since it reduces the necessity for a first strike. A single nuclear submarine can carry at least 12 missiles with Multiple Independently Targetable Reentry Vehicles which could mean as many as 96 warheads. When one such submarine goes out to sea, that many missiles are thus removed from the country’s soil and cannot be targeted by the enemy. Enunciated in 1999, India’s nuclear doctrine calls for its nuclear forces to be effective and responsive to the requirements in accordance with the concept of credible deterrence. The doctrine demands high survivability against surprise attacks and a rapid punitive response. A nuclear submarine, that can remain submerged almost indefinitely 248 CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Essay can attain and sustain high speeds underwater without being detected. It therefore meets all these criteria and offers an almost invulnerable launch platform to India for nuclear weapons. The launch of INS Arihant (Destroyer of Enemies) signals the nuclear militarization of the Indian Ocean. It poses a formidable challenge to Pakistan’s brown water navy. In the years ahead this potential will reinforce India’s capability to blockade and choke the flow of trade from the Gulf via the Suez Canal in the west and the Strait of Malacca in the east. In a drawn out period of coercion, Pakistan’s predominantly sea-based commerce and in turn its national economy could be dealt a crippling blow. In the wake of the launch of INS Arihant, Pakistan duly expressed concern and said that the move will jeopardize the security paradigm of the entire region. It was further stated that India’s nuclear submarine would have far-reaching destabilizing effects on the security environment not only for Pakistan but also for all the littoral states of the Indian Ocean and beyond. Indeed, with one province now engulfed in war and another in a state of political turmoil, spatial options for deployment of land-based strategic weapons by Pakistan stand grossly reduced. The problems of the Pakistan army, deployed on two axes, are further intensified given the precarious internal security situation. In October last year, the Chief of Staff of the Pakistan navy, Vice Admiral Asif Humayun, had declared that the Pakistan navy is fully capable of deploying strategic weapons at sea but added that the government is yet to take a clear decision in this context. It is now well established that Pakistan is on track to ensure such a capability onboard its conventional French submarines of the type Agosta 90B fitted with AIP (Air Independent Propulsion). However, the AIP technology while allowing enhanced submerged periods is not in any way a substitute for a nuclear submarine’s underwater potential. In order to ensure nuclear balance, Pakistan will have to respond to this ominous development rapidly and in earnest. Like the overt demonstration in May 1998, this time too Pakistan CRITERION – October/December 2009 249 Essay would only be reactive. Sagacity, backed by a proactive strategy, could have provided the Pakistan navy the lead time to steadily integrate and mature the weapon systems as well as shape national nuclear doctrinal concepts including Command and Control of sea-based strategic weapons. Had the Pakistan navy been fielding sea-based deterrence in the North Arabian Sea, the security complexion in the region would not have registered such an enormous strategic tilt in favor of India. Pakistan’s nuclear parity at sea would have effectively matched India visà-vis the security paradigm in the Indian Ocean Region. Furthermore, the availability of such a platform at sea could have provided the Pakistan army the much needed resilience and psychological ascendancy in its battles on multiple fronts. But for the unceasing ‘sea blindness,’ Pakistan’s national security potential would have been far more robust. Disclaimer The views expressed herein are those of the author and not necessarily of Pakistan Navy or the Pakistan Navy War College, Lahore Notes: 1. 2. 3. 250 The British government recently declassified Mountbatten papers. The unsigned Memorandum is part of those papers. It is documented and titled “The Strategic and Political Importance of Pakistan in the Event of War with the USSR”. Ref: Mountbatten papers, Hartley Library, Southampton. See also, ‘The Shadow of the Great Game’, by Narendra Singh Sarila, ADC to Lord Mountbatten. Statistical data on Pakistan navy obtained from, ‘Story of the Pakistan navy, 19471972’. For the statement of Chief of Staff, Pakistan navy, Vice Admiral Asif Humayun, refer to daily Dawn of October 15, 2008. CRITERION – Volume 4 No.4 Back Issues Available. Price per issue is Rs. 200/- (Inclusive of postage) Payments can be made by cross cheque payable to Criterion and sent to House 16, Street 15, F-6/3, Islamabad Volume 1 Number 1 October-December 2006 The Contemporary Challenge to Global Peace and Security – S. Iftikhar Murshed Bilateral Negotiations on Kashmir: Unlearnt Lesson – A.G. Noorani Interview with Qazi Hussain Ahmad – Navid Zafar Islamic Polity and the Constitutional Process in Pakistan – Walid Iqbal Post-9/11 Foreign Policy of Pakistan – Shamshad Ahmad Pitfalls and Economic Prospects of Pakistan - Dr. A.R. Kemal Education in Pakistan: Some Reflections – Dr. Manzoor Ahmad Volume 2 Number 1 January-March 2007 My Vision for Pakistan – Shaukat Aziz Problems and Prospects of Peace and Development in the SAARC Region: A Perspective from Bangladesh – Mohammad Mohsin Baluchistan: Pakistan’s Existential Dilemma – Tanvir Ahmad Khan Search for a Viable Solution to the Jammu and Kashmir Problem – Anwar Kemal On Economics and Civil War & Terrorism – Syed Mansoob Murshed Emerging Monopolies in the Pakistani Media – Muzaffar Abbas Iran’s Nuclear Programme – Challenge and Response – Javid Hussain Volume 2 Number 2 April-June 2007 Causes of the Rebellion in Waziristan – Khalid Aziz Globalization: Its Lures and Discontents in the Muslim World – S.M. Naseem Madrassas: The Potential for Violence in Pakistan – Dr. Tariq Rahman The Death of Zia-ul-haq – Khalid Ahmed Pakistan and the Convention on the Elimination of all forms of Discrimination Against Women – Sabrina Khan Current Afghan Ground Realities – Rustam Shah Mohmand Role of Media in National Development in the 21st Century – Javed Jabbar The Kashmir Dispute: A Kashmiri Viewpoint – Abdul Hameed Karimi Volume 2 Number 3 July-September 2007 Using Trade as a Driver of Political Stability: Prospects in Indo-Pak Context – Moeed Yusuf Pakistan: On or Off? Examining the Future of US-Pakistan Relations in the War on Terror and Beyond – Farhana Ali The Parliamentary System in South Asia – A.G. Noorani Fundamentalism, Extremism and Islam – Dr. Anis Ahmad OIC – Retrospect a Prospects – Tayyab Sddiqui The Shia of Iraq and the South Asian Connection – Khaled Ahmed Turning on the Faucets of Thought – Anjum Niaz Volume 2 Number 4 October-December 2007 Political Uncertainty and Extremist Violence – Editorial The Politics of Economic Policy Reforms – Ishrat Hussain Kashmir Dispute: Is there a Viable Solution? – Zamir Akram The Roots of Sectarianism in Pakistan – Khaled Ahmed Need for a Pak-Afghan Treaty on Management of Joint Water – Khalid Aziz Defining Moments: The Political Implication of State Policy – Shahwar Junaid Iran, the United Stated and Regional Stability – Iqbal Ahmad Khan Some Reflections on Islam and Governance – Dr. Manzoor Ahmad Volume 3 Number 1 January-March 2008 The Broken Pledge – Editorial Pakistan Peoples Party and the War on Terror – Iqbal Ahmad Khan Pakistan – US Relations and the War on Terror – Zamir Akram Balti Tandoori and Chicken Tikka Masala: Culture as National Power – Toheed Ahmad Militancy in the Pashtun Belt; Perspective of a Peace Jirga –Khalid Aziz Meeting Pakistan’s Energy Needs – Mukhtar Ahmad Should Islam Modernize Itself? - Dr. Khalid Zaheer Stock Market Performance in Pakistan: A Scrutiny – Inayat A. Mangla Musharraf’s Kashmir Policy: An Appraisal – Tayyab Siddiqui Combating Terrorism through Film – Mushfiq Murshed Volume 3 Number2 April-June 2008 New Government, Old Problems – Editorial Governance Reforms in Pakistan – Ishrat Hussain A Liberal Islam in South Asia – A.G. Norani Muslim Radicalism, Western Concerns – Tanvir Ahmad Khan The Bomber Under the Burqa – Farhana Ali The Law of Aerial Bombardment and Civil Casualties: Kosovo and Afghanistan – Prof. Hayatullah Khan Security Alliances and Security Concerns: Pakistan and NATO – Shahwar Junaid Zulfiqar Ali Bhutto’s Legacy and the Rebuilding of Pakistan – Iqbal Ahmad Khan Of Tongues and Languages: The Tao of Translation – Toheed Ahmad Dimensions and Consequences of NATO Expansion to Eurasia: Reviewing Iran’s Security Environment – Arif Kemal Volume 3 Number 3 July-September 2008 Impeachment of President – Editorial Interview with Justice Khalil-ur-Rahman Ramday – Criterion Team Jinnah’s Worldview/Outlook on World Affairs – A.G. Noorani The MQM and Identity Politics in Pakistan – Niloufer Siddiqui Transformation of Al Qaeda – Khaled Ahmed Patterns of Regional Cooperation: Options for Pakistan – Shahwar Junaid Nations of Saints and Scholars: a Portrait of Ireland – Toheed Ahmad The Status of Women in Pakistan: A Ray of Hope – Talat Farooq FATA at the Crossroads – Ayaz Wazir Volume 3 Number 4 October-December 2008 Suicide Terrorism at the Islamabad Marriott – Editorial How to Develop the Afghan-Pakistan Tribal Belts – Shahid Javed Burki Jinnah & Muslims of India – A.G. Noorani The Haroon Report - A.G. Noorani Notes on Pakistan’s Trade and Industry Policy – Faizullah Khilji Some Thoughts on Democracy – Kazi Anwarul Masud Pakistan Muslim League: a Reality Check – Talat Farooq Pakistan: Religion, Terrorism and Democracy – K.S. Dhillon Volume 4 Number 1 January-March 2009 The Mumbai Attack – Editorial Liberation Tigers of Tamil Eelam (LTTE) – Syed Rifaat Hussain Jinnah & the Nizam of Hyderabad-A Tragic Liaison – A.G. Noorani A Critical View of the Political Developments in Pakistan – Kazi Anwarul Masud War and State Expansion: A Theoretical Framework – Talat Farooq Drugs, Counter Narcotics & State Building in Afghanistan – Nazia Hussain Economic Governance in Pakistan – Ishrat Husain The Muslim World in a Bind-Whither the Ummah? – Khalid Saleem Volume 4 Number 2 April-June 2009 Terrorism and Political Turmoil– Editorial Jihad vs. Terrorism – A.G. Noorani The USSR’s Last Gamble – The Why and Wherefore – Khalid Saleem Islam and Western Modernism: Is There a Way Forward? – Talat Farooq Mumbai Attacks and the North Arabian Sea – Muhammad Azam Khan Education: the Perennial Questions – Mahvesh Khan Navid Zafar – S. Iftikhar Murshed India – Emerging Global Power – Tayyab Siddiqui Minorities and Human Rights – Raja Tridiv Roy