International Relocation of Production and Growth
Transcription
International Relocation of Production and Growth
International Relocation of Production and Growth Francisco Alcalá⇤and Marta Solaz†‡ November 2015. Preliminary draft Abstract The process of international relocation of production from high to lowincome countries is a central feature of economic globalization and, potentially, an important determinant of the recent dynamics of output and employment across countries. So far, studies of this phenomenon focus on particular products and regions or countries. This paper contributes to the analysis in two ways. First, using very disaggregated trade data, the paper examines the direction and intensity of this relocation process across all sectors between 1995 and 2007. Second, it analyzes how this process has a↵ected growth across countries. We find that countries that were specialized in 1995 in products that, on average, relocated towards low-income (high-income) economies over the following years exhibited significantly lower (greater) growth over the 1995-2007 period. This impact is statistically significant and economically important: a di↵erence of one standard deviation in the country’s relocation impact index resulted in a di↵erence of about 0.7 percentage points in the country’s average annual growth. Keywords: trade; export sophistication; o↵shoring; growth. JEL Classification: F14; F43; O47. ⇤ Universidad de Murcia and Ivie. Contact: alcala.paco@gmail.com Universitat de València. Contact: marta.solaz@uv.es ‡ Financial support by the Spanish Ministerio de Economı́a y Competitividad, project ECO2014-53419-R is gratefully acknowledged. Marta Solaz also thanks the Spanish Ministerio de Educación for the FPU grant AP2010-0596. † 1 1 Introduction Over the last decades, the process of the international relocation of production from higher to lower-income countries has been a central feature of the increase in economic globalization. This process is likely to have considerably influenced the dynamics of output and employment across countries. The importance of this phenomenon has motivated numerous studies on specific sectors, regions, and countries (e.g., Lall, Albaladejo and Zhang (2004); Marin (2006); Sturgeon, Van Biesebroeck and Gereffi (2008); Ebenstein et al. (2014), Timmer et al. (2015)). However, to the extent of our knowledge, this phenomenon and its impact has not been analyzed systematically across all sectors and countries for which the relevant data are available. How important is the international relocation of production across the di↵erent sectors? What is the growth impact of this process across countries? This paper studies the process of international relocation of production between 1995 and 2007, the direction and intensity with which each sector has been a↵ected, and its impact on cross-country growth. An early analysis of the dynamics of the reorganization of production across countries with di↵erent levels of development is the product life-cycle theory put forward in Vernon (1966). According to this theory, new products are invented and developed in the advanced economies, from which they are initially exported. Then, as the production process becomes increasingly standardized, the lessdeveloped countries become attractive locations for their production because they o↵er competitive advantages in terms of cost-saving. At this later stage of the product life-cycle, part or all of their production shifts to less developed countries. These dynamics lead to a continuous process of international relocation of production that has been reinforced in recent times by production fragmentation and o↵shoring (see, for example, Feenstra (1998), Hummels, Ishii and Yi (2001), Yi (2003), Koopman, Wang and Wei (2014), among a large and growing literature).1 However, although the literature tends to contemplate international production relocation as unidirectional (from rich countries to low-wage coun1 The analysis of the product life-cycle and the nature and limitations of o↵shoring has been extended in numerous directions, among others, by Krugman (1979), Dollar (1986), Jensen and Thursby (1986), Grossman and Helpman (1989 and 1991a), Antràs (2005), Acemoglu et al. (2012), and Baldwin and Evenett (2015). 2 tries), this is a bidirectional process as we observe it in the international trade statistics: while some product categories (at the 6-digit level) exhibit a relocation trend towards low-wage countries, other product categories experience an overall relocation trend towards more advanced economies. These upward relocations are the likely result of increasing innovation and technical sophistication in particular industries and product categories. This paper’s approach deals symmetrically with the relocation movements in either direction. Our analysis builds on the work by Hausmann, Hwang, and Rodrik (2007) (henceforth HHR). These authors argue that specializing in some goods is more growth promoting than specializing in others (what you export matters). More sophisticated products generate more knowledge externalities (as in Hausmann and Rodrik, 2003) and provide better opportunities for growth. Sophisticated products are identified by being produced by more advanced economies. HHR associate to each product an index of sophistication (called P RODY ), which is defined as a weighted average of the per capita GDPs of the countries exporting the product. Then, they associate to each country an index of export sophistication (called EXP Y ), which is defined as a weighted average of the P RODY s of the products exported by the country. They find that the countries’ EXP Y help predict their future growth.2 However, as we explain in detail below, the HHR’s EXP Y indices capture two elements: countries’ initial sophistication and shocks to products in the sub2 Another approach to the countries’ export sophistication and its implications for growth is the one based on the concepts of complexity and the product space (Hidalgo, Klinger, Barabasi & Hausmann (2007), Hidalgo & Hausmann (2009), Hidalgo (2009)). According to this approach, goods are produced with collective-coordinated capabilities, knowledge, and skills. Using the ubiquity of each good’s production and the diversity of each country’s exports, the authors construct an index of goods’ complexity and an index the economies’ complexity. Given initial per capita GDP, more complex economies have better opportunities to grow. This approach has a number of specific virtues, such as the identification of key signs of a country’s economic capabilities (such as diversification) and the provision of a diagnosis of each country’s development prospects on the basis of the product space and the families of connected goods. Still, the complexity approach’s measures and results are highly correlated with those of the HHR’s approach (Hidalgo, 2009) and reaches these results at the cost of loosing some of the simplicity and intuitive appeal of the latter. It is also unclear how the complexity approach can be reinterpreted to analyze the international relocation of production; for example, if o↵shoring reduces the diversification of advanced economies, does that mean that it also reduces their complexity? In most respects, the HHR (2007) and the complexity approaches do not appear to be substitutes but complementaries. 3 sequent period. In this paper, we develop and reinterpret HHR’s indices by separating these two elements and isolating the relocation shocks from the latter shocks to assess their growth impact. More specifically, in this paper we use the change over time in the P RODY index as a measure of the product’s international relocation across countries at di↵erent stages of development. An increase (reduction) in the P RODY of a product implies a relocation of its production towards more advanced (less developed) countries. Thus, we use the rate of variation of the P RODY s to study the aggregate dynamics of the international relocation of production between 1995 and 2007 as well as the direction and intensity with which each sector has been a↵ected by this process. Then, we construct country measures of the intensity with which the relocation process has a↵ected the particular export basket of each country. Using these country measures, we estimate the impact of international relocation on the countries’ economic growth. We find that countries that were specialized in 1995 in products that, on average, experienced a relocation process towards lower-income (higher-income) economies over the following years, exhibited lower (greater) growth over the 1995-2007 period. The impact is statistically significant and economically important. Before this latter analysis, we set forth a simple theoretical framework that helps guiding the empirical analysis and interpreting the results. The model explores shocks simultaneously leading to international production relocation and income changes. As long as the production of each good involves product-specific knowledge and skills, the model predicts that countries initially specialized in the goods that relocate towards higher-income countries will tend to experience income increases. The opposite will be true for countries initially specialized in the goods experiencing standardization and relocation towards lower-income countries. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 analyzes the dynamics of the relocation process at the sector and 6-digit product level. Section 3 sets out our simple theoretical framework. Section 4 studies the impact of the relocation process on cross-country growth. Section 5 concludes. 4 2 International Relocation of Production 2.1 Measuring product relocation HHR define the P RODY measure of good k’s sophistication at period t as: P RODYkt = J X j=1 RCAtkj P GDP pctj , t j RCAkj where RCAtkj is country j’s revealed comparative advantage in product k at period t, J is the number of countries, and GDP pctj is country j’s per-capita GDP. Thus, the P RODY index is a weighted average of the exporting countries’ GDP per capita, where the weights are given by the countries’ specialization in the product. We also consider the sophistication index of sector s, which is defined as the weighted average of the 6-digit products’ P RODY s included in sector s, using the value-shares of each product in each sector as weights. Thus, we define: P RODYst = X k2s P RODY t !kW , t !sW (1) t t where !kW and !sW are the value-shares of product k and sector s, respectively, in world trade. Note that if the production of a good moves from rich countries to developing countries,this good’s P RODY will decrease. Conversely, an increase in a good’s P RODY indicates that its average exporter is now a more developed country. Thus, we use the rate of variation in each good’s P RODY to measure the international relocation of its production across countries at di↵erent stages of development. Note that all the P RODY s tend to grow over time as GDPs per capita tend to increase. However, the phenomenon we want to capture is the bidirectional migration of production between richer and poorer countries. Thus, we define good k’s (annual average) relocation index between periods 0 and T , R0,T k , as the di↵erence between the growth of product k’s P RODY and the weighted average growth for all the products, using the value-shares of each 5 product in world trade as weights: R0,T k 1 = log T ✓ P RODYkT P RODYk0 ◆ ✓ ◆ K 1 X !k00 W + !kT0 W P RODYiT log . T k0 =1 2 P RODYi0 Hence, a positive R0,T indicates that the average exporter of k at time T has k relatively higher income than at time 0, whereas a negative value indicates the opposite. In turn, we define the relocation index of sector s as the weighted average of the 6-digit products’ R0,T indices included in the sector: k R0,T = s X k2s P R0,T k 0 T !kW + !kW . 0 T k2s (!kW + !kW ) (2) Note that the change over time in a product’s P RODY has two components: the potential change in the RCA of the exporting countries (e.g., lower income countries increase their RCA in the product, while higher income countries decrease their RCA), and the change in these exporting countries’ per capita GDP. The first component can be interpreted as the pure relocation e↵ect because it only depends on the shift of production across countries with di↵erent income levels, whereas the second component does not involve a migration of production. To measure this first component, we first define a variant of the P RODY index that we call the new shares-P RODY , nsP RODY , which is computed using initial-period per capita GDPs and final-period RCAs: nsP RODYk0,T = J X j=1 RCATkj P GDP pc0j . T j RCAkj By keeping constant per capita GDPs, the di↵erences between the nsP RODY s and the P RODY s are exclusively due to changes in RCA, that is, to changes in the location of production. Second, we define the good k’s (annual average) pure relocation index P R0,T as: k P R0,T k 1 = log T nsP RODYk0,T P RODYk0 ! K 1 X !k00 W + !kT0 W log T k0 =1 2 6 nsP RODYi0,T P RODYi0 ! . The P R0,T is positive or negative depending only on changes in the RCAk across k exporters with di↵erent initial incomes. A negative (positive) P R0,T means that k production is moving from previously richer (poorer) countries, which are decreasing (increasing) their RCA in product k, to poorer (richer) countries whose RCAk is increasing. The intensity of the international production relocation process at a given point in time can then be assessed by measuring the dispersion of the R0,T or k P R0,T indices. To measure this dispersion, we use the mean absolute deviak tion (MAD) of the relocation indices, using as weights the average share of each product in world trade (the formula is analogous for the P R0,T indices): k M AD ⇣ R0,T k ⌘ = K X R0,T k k=1 0 T !kW + !kW . 2 (3) A higher dispersion of the relocation indices reflects a more intense relocation across the exporting countries’ income groups. 2.2 Data To construct the P RODY indices, we use the data in the BACI (Base pour l’Analyse du Commerce International, Gaulier and Zignago (2010)), which is a database provided by CEPII (Centre d’Études Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales). The original data of BACI come from the United Nations Statistical Division (COMTRADE database), over which an harmonization procedure is applied for reconciling the data reported by the exporting and importing countries in order to generate a single figure consisting of each bilateral flow in FOB values. We use the Harmonized System (HS)-1992 classification, which comprises more than 5,000 goods. Data on GDP per capita, measured in 2005 prices PPP, come from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators (WDI). The trade data used for the calculations of the P RODY indices corresponds to a group of 136 countries. This group responds to a consistent sample of the countries o↵ering trade information over all the reference period (1995-2007) and having 7 a population of at least 500,000 inhabitants.3 The P RODY s are calculated using average trade data of three years to attenuate the potential distorting e↵ect of atypical values that may arise from unusual exports in a given year. Therefore, we calculate initial P RODY s averaging trade data for 1995-1997 and final P RODY s averaging data for 2005-2007. Our analysis ends in 2007 to avoid the impact of the Great Recession. The list of 6-digit products for which we use their P RODY s is reduced to 4,873 products from the original list of 5,036 products in the HS92 classification. This is because we look for a consistent sample of products that were exported every year by at least one country over the whole reference period (i.e., we exclude the products that do not appear in the statistics of world trade in one or more years between 1995 and 2007). These 4,873 products represent the 98.4% of all the world trade during these years. In turn, the 18 sector classification that we consider results from amending the 21 sections in the HS92 classification as follows in order to break into two sectors some sections that are quantitatively very important while merging other sections that encompass a very small share of international trade. Specifically, we split section 6 into pharmaceuticals and the rest of the chemicals; section 15 into iron and steel on the one hand and the rest of metals and its manufactures on the other; section 17 (machinery) into electrical equipment and mechanical appliances; section 17 (transport equipment) into motor vehicles and the rest of transport equipment. Conversely, we group together sections 8, 11 and 12 (leather, textiles and footwear); sections 9 and 10 (wood and paper); sections 13 and 20 (furniture and other manufactures and stones); and sections 3, 14, 19 and 21 (fats and oils, pearls, arms and works of art). We call the last sector miscellanea. 2.3 Relocation dynamics over 1995-2007 We now analyze the dynamics of the international relocation of production over the period 1995-2007 using the relocation indices. Figure 1 compares the growth 3 As emphasized in HHR (2007), it is essential to use a consistent sample of countries to avoid index changes due to a changing composition of the sample. Moreover, since non-reporting is likely to be correlated with income, constructing P RODY for di↵erent countries could introduce serious bias into the index. 8 rate of the P RODY s, World GDP per capita, and World trade, and Figure 2 shows the evolution of the intensity of the international production relocation over the period as measured by the MAD of the annual relocation indices (see expression (3)). Although the analysis in this paper is based primarily on trade data at the 6-digit level of disaggregation, Figure 2 also shows the evolution over time of the MAD of the relocation indices calculated at lower levels of disaggregation. This highlights the importance of using highly disaggregated data in order to capture the intensity of the relocation process. The 1-digit lines are obtained after computing the P RODY s for the 18 sectors defined in Subsection 2.2., whereas the calculations for the 2-digit and the 6-digit lines use the P RODY s of the 96 industries and the 4,873 products, respectively, corresponding to the HS92 classification.4 The intensity of the relocation process calculated at the 6-digit level more than triples, on average, the intensity at the 2- and 1-digit level. This is due to the heterogeneity of the dynamics of the 6-digit products within each sector, which is likely to increase as a consequence of production fragmentation. As numerous products within a the same sector move in opposite directions along the exporters’ income ladder, their movements cancel out and disappear when we use data at the sector level to measure international relocation. Thus, using data at the sector level to measure the intensity of the relocation of production misses most of the process. It may also be noted that the intensity of the relocation process appears surprisingly constant over the 1997-2006 period. Table 1 shows the relocation indices together with the initial P RODY s (the average for 1995-1997). The sectors are ordered according to the P R index. Negative indices indicate sectors that are moving downwards in the exporters’ income ladder. Omitting the miscellanea group, the sectors with the greatest relocation towards lower-income countries over the period 1995-2007 are textiles/footwear, electrical equipment, metals and manufactures excluding iron, and motor vehicles. Some of these sectors are well-known examples of industries that have experienced intense production fragmentation and o↵shoring processes such as electrical equipment. On the other side of the spectrum, the sectors showing the greatest relocation towards high-income exporters are pharmaceuticals, transport 4 Figure 2 also depints the evolution of the nsP RODY s at the 6-digit level, which exhibit values almost identical to those of the corresponding P RODY indices. 9 equipment excluding motor vehicles, and chemicals. These sectors are moving upwards along the exporters’ income ladder and are, thus, likely to be experimenting relatively intense innovation. The relocation indices R show very similar patterns. The correlation between the relocation indices R and the pure correlation indices P R of the 6-digit products is extremely high: 0.985. The rankings of sectors according to these two indices is also very similar (see Table 1). The main di↵erences between the two indices occur for the minerals and textile sectors. Note that the P RODY index of minerals is the most exposed to to changes in commodity prices (which would a↵ect the exporters’ income and, therefore, the R index) without the production of minerals undergoing any reorganization across countries (which is the only possible source of changes in the P R index). This can explain that the greatest di↵erence between the RI and the R indices corresponds to the minerals sector. In turn, the P RODY index of some sectors such as textiles could increase as well without any geographic relocation of production if low-income countries are relatively specialized in this sector and there is income convergence across countries over the period (i.e., low-income countries grow relatively more than rich countries). This again could explain the discrepancy between the P R and the R indices. Can we predict the sign of the future international relocation of each product or sector? The future direction of the international relocation, both at the sector and at the 6-digit product level, appear largely unpredictable on the basis of their export sophistication at the beginning of the period. Among the sectors with high initial P RODY we can find both industries with very positive P R indices (e.g., pharmaceuticals and chemicals) and industries relocating towards lower-income countries (e.g., machinery and motor vehicles). Conversely, among the sectors with low initial P RODY s, we find industries moving upwards along the exporters’ income ladder (e.g., food and beverages) as well as industries moving downwards (e.g., textiles) (see Figure 3). At the 6-digit level, production relocation is only very weakly negatively correlated with the initial P RODY (see Figure 4). The relationship is statistically significant but the coefficient is very small, and we can find about as many 6-digit products with high P RODY s moving up than moving down (the same is true if we examine 6-digit products with 10 low P RODY s)..5 This means that the current level of a product’s or sector’s sophistication is of no real help in predicting whether the product or the sector will relocate towards richer or poorer countries in the following years. Consequently, industrial policies aimed at promoting those industries with better prospects for future innovation and regional policies aimed at anticipating the dangers of future relocations of the local industry towards lower-income regions face the potentially unsolvable difficulty of identifying which industries are those. The contribution of each sector to the global transformation of international trade not only depends on the intensity of the sector’s international relocation but also on the sector’s weight in world trade. Table 2 shows each sector’s contribution ⇣ ⌘ to the global intensity of production relocation as measured by M AD R0,T and k ⇣ ⌘ M AD P R0,T , where these contributions are calculated as follows (the formula k is analogous for the P R0,T indices): k Contribution of s to M AD ⇣ R0,T k ⌘ P k2s R0,T k k=1 0 T R0,T (!kW + !kW ) k = P K 0 T !kW + !kW . (4) The highest contributions to the overall international relocation of production come from machinery and mechanical appliances, textiles and footwear, electrical equipment, minerals, and chemicals excluding the pharmaceutical industry. These contributions measure each sector’s role in the reorganization of world trade flows across country income groups that took place over the 1995-2007 period. 3 A simple theoretical framework (preliminary) Which are the shocks leading to the international relocation of production as captured by the R and RI indices? How can they a↵ect cross-country growth? In this section we build a simple model (without fully developing its general equilibrium details) that links exogenous technological shocks to production re5 Moreover, this negative coefficient could be due, at least in part, to temporary shocks to the exporters of particular products at the beginning of the period and measurement errors (instrumenting initial P RODY reduces further the coefficient to a half). 11 location and cross-country di↵erences in growth. The model will help interpret our empirical work. The model assumes that goods are produced using a combination of generic knowledge and skills (which are relatively abundant in rich countries) and productspecific knowledge and skills (which are relatively abundant in the countries that exported each product in the recent past). Generic and product-specific knowledge and skills are relatively good substitutes. The production of di↵erent goods involves di↵erent degrees of sophistication. Higher-sophistication goods are relatively intensive in knowledge and skills. In other words, higher sophistication means that countries that have higher general and product-specific knowledge and skills are relatively better endowed to produce the good. Technical shocks can increase or reduce product sophistication. Increased sophistication is likely to be the consequence of intense innovation in a given product category, which makes more important the use of knowledge and skills. The opposite occurs if a good’s sophistication decreases: as production standardizes, it requires less knowledge and skills. Changes in product sophistication will a↵ect the value and incomes of the production factors. If a product category experiences intense innovation, the relative value of the skills and knowledge comparatively better suited to produce these goods increase. Conversely, if the production of a good experiences increasing standardization. Therefore, countries that were specialized in the products experiencing a wave of innovation will be better o↵ and grow faster, whereas countries that were specialized in products experiencing intense standardization will be negatively a↵ected and grow slower. These ideas can be formalized in a simple way as follows. Goods are produced using product-specific knowledge and labor with varying levels of generic human capital. Country j’s product-specific knowledge in product k is the result of learning by doing and, therefore, of some discounted sum of the production of k t 1 6 in previous periods, which is denoted by Xjk . In turn, we assume that all the 6 We assume that this knowledge (or, more importantly, the value of the increased productivity that it can generate) is appropriated by the firms producing k and not by the specific workers producing k. This makes simpler the equilibrium of the labor market, which assumes that all the workers in each country have the same human capital and, therefore, are homogeneous. 12 workers in country j have the same generic human capital, which is denoted by hj . The production function is: ⇥ ⇤1/ t 1 xjk = (Sk ) + hj + Xjk dk Aj (`jk )1/2 , < 0, (5) where xjk is country j’s output of good k, Sk denotes the sophistication of product k, dk is a product-specific technological parameter common to all the countries, Aj is country j’s aggregate TFP that captures productivity factors such as its institutional quality, size, and density, and `jk is the labor input used in j to produce k. Note that we simplify by assuming that generic human capital and product-specific knowledge are perfect substitutes.7 In turn, the assumption that sophistication, on the one hand, and generic human capital and product-specific knowledge, on the other hand, behave as gross complements is important for our results (which are based on that generic and product-specific knowledge and skills have a comparative advantage at producing higher-sophistication goods). We consider four types of shocks: (a) country-specific shocks corresponding to shocks in Aj ; (b) technological shocks to product k a↵ecting its sophistication Sk , which can be positive (innovations) or negative (standardizations); (c) technological shocks not changing the productive sophistication of product k, which correspond to shocks in dk and are be called sophistication-neutral technological shocks; and (d) product demand shocks a↵ecting pk . Product shocks hit all the countries with the same intensity. The question is how much each of these four shocks a↵ects RCAkj and income across countries, thereby leading to mutually connected international relocations of production and cross-country di↵erences in growth. We assume perfect competition. Whenever we consider a country or a product, we assume that it is small relative to the world economy, so that we can ignore general equilibrium e↵ects when analyzing the consequences of shocks that are specific to the country or to the product category. However, a product category could have an important weight in a country’s production and, therefore, shocks 7 The results hold exactly the same if we assume that generic human capital and ⌘product⇣ t 1 specific knowledge are combined according to a positively valued function f hj , Xjk satisfying fh > 0 and fX t 1 > 0. However, assuming perfect substitutability lightens the exposition. 13 to this category can a↵ect the country’s GDP. Still, although this perfect competition setting is the general framework of our analysis, we make some comments on how results would change if a country had a significant weight in the world market of a particular product. From (5), the value of the labor’s marginal productivity in country j when ⇥ ⇤1/ t 1 producing k is pk (Sk ) + hj + Xjk dk Aj 12 (`jk ) 1/2 , where pk is the price of k. Hence, the equality of the marginal productivity of labor across products implies, for each country j and any two products k and k 0 : ✓ `jk `jk0 ◆1/2 ⇥ ⇤1/ t 1 pk dk (Sk ) + hj + Xjk = ⇥ ⇤1/ . t 1 pk0 dk0 (Sk0 ) + hj + Xjk 0 (6) Therefore, for any two countries j and j 0 , and any two products k and k 0 , revealed comparative advnatage satisfies: " t 1 (Sk ) + hj + Xjk xjk xj 0 k / = t 1 xjk0 xj 0 k0 (Sk0 ) + hj + Xjk 0 / (Sk ) + hj 0 + Xjt0 k1 (Sk0 ) + hj 0 + Xjt0 k10 #2/ . (7) Thus, country-specific shocks in shocks in Aj , as well as product-specific neutral shocks in dk and demand shocks pk do not a↵ect the countries’ RCAs, whereas sophistication shocks to do a↵ect RCA. Taking derivatives with respect to Sk to analyze how innovation and standardization a↵ects RCA, yields: d dSk ✓ Hence, xjk xj 0 k / xjk0 xj 0 k0 d dSk ⇣ ◆ = xjk xj 0 k / xjk0 xj 0 k0 fore, because ⌘ " (Sk0 ) + hj 0 + Xjt0 k10 #2/ " t 1 (Sk ) + hj + Xjk #(2/ 2 t 1 (Sk0 ) + hj + Xjk (Sk ) + hj 0 + Xjt0 k1 0 ⇥ ⇤ t 1 (Sk ) 1 hj 0 + Xjt0 k1 hj + Xjk · . (8) ⇥ ⇤2 (Sk ) + hj 0 + Xjt0 k1 0 if and only if hj 0 + Xjt0 k1 t 1 hj + Xjk . There- < 0, if the sophistication of k increases, then the country with higher human capital and previous specialization in k will increase further its RCA in k. More specifically: (i ) conditional on previous specialization, coun14 ) 1 tries with higher human capital will increase their RCA in k; and (ii ) vice versa, conditional on human capital, countries with higher previous output of k will increase further their RCA in k. In sum, innovation in a product category (as captured by an increase in the product’s sophistication parameter Sk ) will tend to raise the RCA of countries with relatively high human capital (which are likely to be the countries with higher income), and reduce the RCA of countries with lower human capital, thereby leading to a relocation of production towards higher income countries. Simultaneously, the income and RCA in the countries that already were specialized in that product will also increase, thereby creating a positive link between the positive international relocation of a good and the growth of the countries that already had a specialization in the good. The opposite will tend to occur in the case of the standardization of a product, as captured by a reduction in the product’s sophistication parameter Sk . However, the other three types of shocks that we considered (product-specific demand, neutral technological, and country-specific shocks) lead to di↵erences in growth across countries but do not tend to lead to the international relocation of production. Returning now to the P RODY indices, recall that changes over time in a product’s P RODY have two components: changes in the exporting countries’ RCAs across countries with di↵erent income levels and per capita GDPs. The first component is the pure relocation e↵ect that is captured by the P R index, whereas the second component is the increase in the exporters income. Thus, we interpret the first component within our our theoretical framework as the consequence of sophistication shocks Sk , whereas the second component could be the consequence of any of the four shocks (product-specific demand shocks on pk , neutral technological shocks on dk , and country-specific shocks on Aj , as well as sophistication shocks on Sk ). The pure relocation indices P R will be the base of our analysis of the impact of sophistication shocks Sk on growth. In turn, we will also construct country specific P RODY s (cs P RODY s) that exclude in the construction the data for a particular country (see the Appendix). These cs P RODY s, which are used as instruments in 2SLS regressions, are not a↵ected by the country-specific shocks on Aj and are the basis of our analysis of the joint impact of the three product-specific shocks (i.e., on dk , pk , and Sk ) on 15 cross-country growth. 4 International Relocation and Growth 4.1 Measuring the impact on income growth To measure export sophistication and how international relocation a↵ects each country, we build again on HHR (2007). HHR define the EXP Y index of country j’s export sophistication at time 0 as a weighted average of its exports’ P RODY , as follows: X hhrEXP Yj0,T = 0 P RODYkT !kj . k Note that the hhrEXP Y , as defined by HHR, combines data from two di↵erent 0 periods: on the one hand, product shares in country j’s exports !kj refer to the initial period 0, while, on the other hand, the P RODYkT s refer to the final period T .8 In this paper, we define an initial EXP Y , denoted by iEXP Yj0 , that is calculated using the data of the initial period for both the export shares and the P RODY s: iEXP Yj0 = X 0 P RODYk0 !kj . k Then, we use the ratio between the HHR’s EXP Y and the iEXP Y to capture the impact of the international production relocation on country j. We call this ratio the country j 0 s relocation impact index between periods 0 and T: RIj0,T = log hhrEXP Yj0,T iEXP Yj0,T P 0 P RODYkT !kj = log Pk . 0 0 k P RODYk !kj (9) Note that the di↵erence between hhrEXP Yj0,T and iEXP Yj0 originates exclusively from the change in the P RODY s , which in turn are the result of the 8 HHR constructed the P RODY measures using 6-digit trade data for the 1999-2001. Then, they used these P RODY s together with income information for each year to construct their initial EXP Y measures used in their growth regressions for the 1991-2003 and 1994-2003 periods, respectively. As we define another variation of the EXP Y index, we denote the original HHR index by hhrEXP Y to highlight the distinction and include the superscript T to highlight that the P RODY s being used in the calculation for the index corresponding to period 0 are the final period P RODY s. 16 international relocation of production. A high (low) value of the relocation impact index RI means that the country’s export basket is made up of products whose production, on average, has moved towards higher (lower) income countries (i.e., their P RODY s have increased). Next, recall that the change in the P RODY indices is, in turn, the result of a pure relocation e↵ect, which is captured by the new shares P RODY s and P R indices, and the potential increase in the exporters’ income. Thus, we can identify the pure relocation impact on the countries’ export sophistication by defining a country j’s pure relocation impact index between periods 0 and T, P RI 0,T j , as: P RIj0,T P 0,T 0 k nsP RODYk !kj = log P . 0 0 k P RODYk !kj In terms of the theoretical framework set in Section 3, this index captures the impact of the sophistication shocks Sk , which are those leading to international relocation of production. Then, we define the residual from the HHR’s EXP Y as: hhrEXP Y residual0,T j P = log P k k 0 P RODYkT !kj 0 nsP RODYk0,T !kj ⇣ P PJ k RCAT kj T P T GDP pcj j=1 j RCAkj = log P ⇣P J k RCAT kj 0 P T GDP pcj j=1 j RCAkj ⌘ ⌘ 0 !kj . 0 !kj This index is capturing other shocks a↵ecting the exporters’ income (such as product-specific demand pk and neutral technological dk shocks) that do not lead to international production relocation. Including this latter index in the regression can help avoid omitted variable biases. We can summarize our approach to the impact of international relocation on the countries’ export sophistication as a pair of decompositions on the HHR’s EXP Y index, as follows: log hhrEXP Yj0,T = log iEXP Yj0,T + RIj0,T = log iEXP Yj0,T + P RIj0,T + hhrEXP Y residual0,T j (. 10) 17 These two decompositions are the basis of the econometric specifications that follow. 4.2 Econometric procedure We now proceed to the econometric analysis on the relationship between initial export sophistication, product relocation and economic growth within the framework of growth regressions (Barro & Sala-i-Martin (2003)). Our first specification uses the first decomposition in expression (10): GDP per capita growth is regressed on initial per-capita GDP, iEXP Y , the relocation impact index RI, and a vector of controls Xj0 that include human and physical capital and measures of institutional quality: 1 GDP pcTi log = T GDP pc0i 0 0 1 logGDP pci + 0 2 log(iEXP Yj ) + 0,T 3 RI j + + 0 4 Xj + uj , (11) where uj is the error term. The second specification substitutes the RI index with the P RI index: 1 GDP pcTi log = T GDP pc0i 0 + 0 1 logGDP pci + 0 2 log(iEXP Yj ) + 0,T 3 P RI j + 0 4 Xj + uj . (12) The third specification uses the second decomposition in expression (10): 1 GDP pcTi log = T GDP pc0i 0 + 0 1 logGDP pci + 0 2 log(iEXP Yj ) + 0,T 3 P Rj + hhrEXP Y residual0,T + j 0 4 Xj + uj (13) We estimate several variations of the preceding equation by OLS as well as 2SLS. Using instrumental variables is important to deal with the potential problem of circularity that can arise from the use of the P RODY and EXP Y indices. Note that the P RODY s are a weighted average of exporting countries’ per capita income. These P RODY s are used to construct the EXP Y measures of export sophistication, which in turn are then used to explain the country’s per capita income at the end of the period. Thus, a country-specific shock (Aj in our theo18 retical model) could create a correlation between growth and the relocation index that is not due to any world-wide technological shock leading to international production relocation but only to the country-specific shock. To break the potential circularity and avoid this potential problem, we calculate specific P RODY s and nsP RODY s for each country that are constructed excluding all the data relative to the country (i.e., the country’s exports and GDP per capita). Then, we use these country specific P RODY s and nsP RODY s to construct instruments for the country’s EXP Y and relocation indices (see the Appendix for the specific formulas of these instruments, which are denoted by adding a csp prefix to the instrumented variable). 4.3 Data and descriptive statistics The EXP Y and relocation impact indices are constructed using the P RODY s from the previous sections and the 6-digit vale-’ shares in each country’s exports from BACI. We consider four alternative measures of institutional quality from the World Bank’s World Governance Indicators: rule of law, regulatory quality, government e↵ectiveness, and corruption control. Our main measure for human capital is years of schooling from Barro and Lee (2013). We also conduct robustness checks using the percentage of population over 25 years with the secondary education complete (denoted as secondary), also from Barro and Lee (2013), and the index of human capital per person from Penn World Tables 8.1 ( denoted as PWT; Feenstra, Inklaar, and Timmer (2015)), which is also based on Barro and Lee and returns to education from Psacharopoulos (1994). Capital intensity is defined as the country’s capital stock per person engaged in production, which is also obtained from PWT 8.1. We also consider some additional controls: share of oil exports in total exports (from PWT 8.1), and population and land area (from the World Bank’s WDI). The sample of 136 countries used to construct the P RODY s is reduced to 113 countries when we consider human and physical capital variables. Furthermore, a number of countries su↵ered important shocks in the 90s such as civil wars, large ethnic conflicts, and the sometimes traumatic dismemberment from the Soviet Union. Thus, economic fundamentals may not be the main driver of some 19 countries’ economic performance over the 1995-2007 period or during the 19951997 years that we take as the initial reference for income growth. Moreover, these countries are potential outliers that could distort the econometric analysis. To check for these potential outliers in our sample we identify the countries whose output gap (actual GDP over Hodrick-Prescott filtered GDP) at the beginning of the period (1995-1997) deviate from the sample median more than three times the interquartile range. This filter selects six countries: Liberia, Rwanda, Moldova, Ukraine, Tajikistan, and Kyrgyz Republic. We also applied the same criterion (a deviation from the sample median of more than three times the interquartile range) to the distribution of the pure relocation impact index and identified Sierra Leona as an additional outlier. All of these seven countries either went through civil wars during the period of analysis or su↵ered major upheavals as a result of the break down of the Soviet Union. Thus, we run the regressions using, first, the whole available sample of 113 countries and, then, excluding from this sample the cited seven outliers.9 Table 3 reports the main variables’ descriptive statistics and correlations. Figure 5 shows the high correlation between the RI and P RI indices. Figures 6 and 7show the scatterplots of initial GDP per capita against the RI and P RI indices. Poorer countries exhibit higher relocation indices (i.e. the correlation is negative) as well as larger indices’ dispersion. Figures 8, 9, 10, and 11 show the correlations between per capita growth and initial EXP Y , relocation impact, pure location impact, and the hhhEXP Y residual, respectively. 4.4 4.4.1 Results Relocation impact We estimate equations (11), (12), and (13) using data for the period 1995-2007. Table 4 shows the OLS estimates of equation (11) with robust standard errors in parenthesis. The first column replicates the main specification in HHR (2007) and confirms their results using our sample, which contains about 50-percent more countries than their sample. Their hhrEXP Y measure of export sophis9 The list of countries can be found in Table A1 in the Appendix. 20 tication, initial per capita GDP and human capital have the expected signs and are significant at the 1-percent, though, our point estimate for the coefficient on hhrEXP Y es smaller and, contrarily to their estimates, we find human capital to be highly significant. We decompose hhrEXP Y into our measures of initial export sophistication (iEXP Y ) and the relocation impact index (RI) in column 2. Both variables have a positive and statistically significant at 1-percent impact on growth. In columns 3-7, we consider alternative measures of institutional quality and additional controls: the share of oil products in total exports, the country’s population–in thousands of millions–, and the log of the country’s area. The coefficient on the relocation impact index increases and keeps its statistical significance, while the opposite occurs with the coefficient on initial export sophistication. In turn, regulatory quality is the only measure for institutions that is positive and statistically significant at the 5-percent level. As our controls for institutions followed this same heterogenous pattern of statistical significance in all the specifications that we estimated, we prefer and always report in our tables the estimates that use regulatory quality as the control for institutions. All the additional controls included in columns 3-7 are statistically significant at 1-percent, implying that oil exporters and countries with large and high-density populations10 experienced higher growth over the period. The specification in the last column of Table 4 excludes from the sample the seven outliers that were experienced very large exogenous shocks over the period of analysis, as explained in the data section. The coefficient on the relocation impact index increases further as well as the significance of the control for institutional quality, whereas the significance of iEXP Y drops below 10-percent. Table 5 reports the 2SLS estimates using as instruments the EXP Y s and relocation impact indices constructed with country-specific P RODY s (see the Appendix for the details on their construction). Each one of these instruments is a good predictor of the instrumented variable with very large F statistics, as shown in Table 8 (in the Appendix), which reports the first-stage regressions. As in Table 4, we replicate the HHR’s (2007) main specification in the first column and again confirm their qualitative results with our instruments and sample. In 10 We find a negative coefficient for country area that combined with the positive coefficient on population implies a positive e↵ect of population density. 21 column 2, we use our measures of initial export sophistication and relocation impact and find again both variables positive and statistically significant. Hence, the previous results hold when using instrumental variables that control for the potential circularity of the measures of export sophistication and international production relocation. Compared with the OLS estimates, the coefficient and statistical significance of iEXP Y decreases while those of the RI index stay constant or even increase slightly. This same pattern is apparent in all of the following specifications, in which we include the additional controls and consider four di↵erent measures of institutional quality (columns 3-6), two additional measures of human capital (columns 7-8), and exclude the outliers (column 9; see the section on data for details on the additional controls and alternative measures of institutions and human capital). The relocation impact index is always very significant, while initial export sophistication is only significant at 10-percent o no significant at all. The estimated coefficient for the RI index in our most complete specification (column 9) implies an economically very important impact: an increase along the distribution of the relocation impact index from the first quartile (0.13) to the third (0.22) implies an increase in the average annual growth rate of about 1.1 percentage points. Initial per capita GDP, years of schooling, export share of oil, population size, and country area have the expected signs and are always significant at the 1-percent. Regulatory quality is also always significant at the 1-percent except in one specification for which significance is 5-percent. Overall, these results lend ample support to the hypothesis that being specialized in those products that exhibited a production relocation towards higher (lower) income countries was very positive (negative) for per capita GDP growth over the 1995-2007 period. At the same time, the results suggest that once we isolate this relocation e↵ect, the remaining component of the countries’ export sophistication (i.e., iEXP Y ) had, at most, a very limited e↵ect. 4.4.2 Pure relocation impact We now analyze the results of using the narrow (pure) definition P RI of the relocation impact index. Tables 6 and 7 display the OLS and 2SLS estimates, respectively. In Table 6, we only consider our preferred specification, which includes 22 all the controls, the years of schooling measure of human capital, and regulatory quality for institutions. We consider, alternatively, the whole sample (columns 1 and 3) and the one excluding the seven outliers (columns 2 and 4). Columns 1 and 3 report the results of estimating equation (12), whereas columns 2 and 4 report the results estimating (13), that is, including the hhrEXP Y residual variable. In Table 7, we consider all the alternative measures of institutional quality and human capital. Estimates in this table are the most reliable ones as we instrument iEXP Y and the relocation impact indices with the measures that exclude each country information (see the Appendix). We use as a benchmark for our comments our preferred and most complete specification in Table 7, which is in column 9. At any rate, the alternative specifications lead to very similar results. In this preferred specification, as in almost all the previous estimates, the controls for initial per capita GDP, human capital, regulatory quality, share of oil exports, population, and land area (or, conversely, population density given that we already control for population) are all statistically significant. Focusing on our key regressor, we find that the pure relocation impact is significant at the 1-percent The estimated impact is economically very important: taking a country from the 1st quartile (-0.121) to the 3rd quartile (-0.036) along the distribution of the P RI index implies an increase in the annual rate of growth of 0.8 percentage points, whereas a rise of the size of one standard deviation (which after excluding the outliers is 0.073) implies an annual growth increase of 0.7 points. Thus, countries that were specialized at the beginning of the period in product categories showing a relocation process towards advanced (low-wage) economies over the following years, exhibited significantly greater (lower) growth over the period. The coefficient on initial export sophistication ( iEXP Y ) is positive but not statistically significant. This confirms the previous results suggesting that the growth e↵ect ofinitial export sophistication along the 1995-2007 period is uncertain once it is dissociated from the relocation e↵ect and what we have called the hhrEXP Y residual.. In turn, the coefficient on hhrEXP Y residual is positive, statistically very significant, and quantitatively important. However, as previously discussed, this component is the one most likely to capture the impact of potentially omitted shocks common to exporters of similar baskets of goods. Its 23 inclusion in the specification has only an econometric purpose as it controls for those potential shocks that are common across similar exporters but did not led to a relocation of production and exports across countries. 5 11 Concluding Comments The process of international relocation of production has been a central feature of economic globalization over the 1995-2007 period, which is likely to have had notable consequences for output and employment across countries. This paper has explored the broad numbers of this process and its consequences on cross-country growth. We find that countries that were specialized in 1995 in product categories that, on average, relocated towards low-income (high-income) economies over the following years, exhibited significantly lower (greater) growth over the 1995-2007 period. This impact is statistically significant and economically important: a difference of one standard deviation in the country’s pure relocation impact index resulted in a di↵erence of about 0.7 percentage points in the country’s average annual growth. Conversely, once we identify and isolate the impact of the product-specific shocks (such as those leading to relocation) during the period, initial sophistication appears to have a weak e↵ect, if any, on subsequent growth. Thus, what you export matters not so much because of the definite prospects that a country’s current export basket creates, but because products experience continuous specific (and, apparently, unpredictable) technological and demand shocks that have a significant impact on the country’s growth performance. As already noted, product relocations appear to be largely unpredictable. At the six-digit level, we find that product relocation is only weakly (negatively) correlated with the product’s initial sophistication index. Thus, the fact that a product is currently an export of a low- (high-) income countries is of no real help in predicting whether the product will relocate in the future towards higher or lower income producers. Similarly, at the sector level, we find industries with high 11 The fact that the IV estimates for the coefficient on hhrEXP Y residual are significantly lower than the OLS estimates (unlike the estimates for the coefficient on the pure relocation impact index) is consistent with this idea of hhrEXP Y residual capturing country-specific shocks (which do not a↵ect our instruments), besides capturing the common shocks to exporters of similar products. 24 initial sophistication relocating towards higher-income countries (e.g., pharmaceuticals and chemicals), as well as industries relocating towards lower-income countries (e.g., machinery and motor vehicles). Conversely, we find industries with low initial sophistication moving upwards along the exporters’ income ladder (e.g., food and beverages), as well as industries moving downwards (e.g., textiles). This leaves little room for industrial policies aimed at promoting those industries with better chances of moving up along the exporters’ income ladder and for regional policies aimed at anticipating the dangers of future relocations of the local industry towards lower-income areas. Still, the time profile of the relocation processes within each industry and the analysis of the global relocation process along other periods deserve further research. References [1] Acemoglu, D., Gancia, G., & Zilibotti, F. (2012). Competing engines of growth: Innovation and standardization. Journal of Economic Theory, 147(2), 570-601. [2] Antràs, P. 2005. Incomplete Contracts and the Product Cycle. American Economic Review, 95(4), 1054-1073. [3] Balassa, B. (1965), Trade Liberalization and Revealed Comparative Advantage. Manchester School 33(2), 99-123. [4] Baldwin, R. E., & Evenett, S. J. (2015). Value creation and Trade in 21st Century Manufacturing. Journal of Regional Science, 55(1), 31-50. [5] Barro, R. & Lee, J.W. (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. Journal of Development Economics, 104, 184-198. [6] Barro, R., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (2003). Economic growth (2nd ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT. [7] CEPII (Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales). Base pour l’analyse du commerce international (BACI). Paris 2010. Database available at http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/bdd/baci/access.asp 25 [8] Dollar, D. (1986). Technological innovation, capital mobility, and the product cycle in North-South trade. American Economic Review, 177-190. [9] Ebenstein, A., A. Harrison, M. McMillan, & S. Phillips (2014). Estimating the Impact of Trade and O↵shoring on American Workers using the Current Population Surveys. Review of Economics and Statistics, 96:4, 581-595. [10] Feenstra, R. C. (1998). Integration of trade and disintegration of production in the global economy. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 31-50. [11] Feenstra, R. C., R. Inklaar, & M. P. Timmer (2015). The Next Generation of the Penn World Table. American Economic Review, 105(10): 3150–3182. [12] Feyrer, J. (2009). Trade and Income–Exploiting Time Series in Geography (No. w14910). National Bureau of Economic Research. [13] Gaulier G. & S. Zignago (2010). BACI: International Trade Database at the Product-level. The 1994-2007 Version. CEPII Working Paper 2010-23. [14] Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1991a). Endogenous product cycles. Economic Journal, 101(408), 1214-29. [15] Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1991b). Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge: MIT Press. [16] Hausmann, R. & D. Rodrik (2003). Economic Development as Self-Discovery. Journal of Development Economics, 72(2), 603-33. [17] Haussman, R., Hwang, J., & Rodrik D. (2007). What you exports matters. Journal of Economic Growth, 12(1): 1-25. [18] Hidalgo, C. (2009). The dynamics of economic complexity and the product space over a 42 year period. Center for International Development Working Paper, (189). [19] Hidalgo, C., Klinger, B., Barabasi, A.L., & Hausmann, R. (2007). The product space conditions the development of nations. Science, 317(5837), 482-487. 26 [20] Hidalgo, C., & Hausmann, R. (2009). The building blocks of economic complexity. Proc. National Academic Association, 106(26),10570-10575. [21] Hummels, D., & Klenow, P. (2005). The variety and quality of a nations exports. American Economic Review, 704–723. [22] Hummels, D., Ishii, J., & Yi, K. M. (2001). The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade. Journal of International Economics, 54(1), 7596. [23] Jensen, R., & Thursby, M. (1986). A strategic approach to the product life cycle. Journal of International Economics, 21(3), 269-284. [24] Koopman, R., Wang, Z., & Wei, S. J. (2014). Tracing Value-Added and Double Counting in Gross Exports. American Economic Review, 104(2), 459-494. [25] Krugman, P. (1979). A model of innovation, technology transfer, and the world distribution of income. Journal of Political Economy, 253-266. [26] Lall, S., Albaladejo, M., & Zhang, J. (2004). Mapping fragmentation: electronics and automobiles in East Asia and Latin America. Oxford Development Studies, 32(3), 407-432. [27] Lederman, D., & Maloney, W. (2012). Does what You Export Matter?: In Search of Empirical Guidance for Industrial Policies. World Bank Publications. [28] Marin, D. (2006). A new international division of labor in Europe: outsourcing and o↵shoring to Eastern Europe. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(2-3), 612–622. [29] Schott, P.K. (2008). The Relative Sophistication of Chinese Exports. Economic Policy, 23(53), 5-49. [30] Sturgeon, T., Van Biesebroeck, J., & Gereffi, G. (2008). Value chains, networks and clusters: reframing the global automotive industry. Journal of Economic geography, 8(3), 297-321. 27 [31] Timmer, M. P., Dietzenbacher, E., Los, B., Stehrer, R., & Vries, G. J. (2015). An Illustrated User Guide to the World Input–Output Database: the Case of Global Automotive Production. Review of International Economics. [32] Vernon, R. (1966). International investment and international trade in the product cycle. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 190-207. [33] Wang, Z., Wei, S. J., & Wong, A. (2010). Does a leapfrogging growth strategy raise growth rate? Some international evidence (No. w16390). National Bureau of Economic Research. [34] World Bank. World Development Indicators (WDI). Washington. Database available at http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-developmentindices [35] World Bank. World Governance Indicators (WGI). Washington. Database available at http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.asp [36] Yi, K. M. (2003). Can vertical specialization explain the growth of world trade?. Journal of Political Economy, 111(1), 52-102. 28 Table 1: International Relocation of Production by Sector Textiles, footwear, leather Miscellanea Electrical equipment Metals and manuf. exc. Iron Motor vehicles Machinery and mech. appliances Plastics Furniture and other manufactures; ston Minerals Vegetable products Instruments Iron and manufactures thereof Food, beverage and tobacco Wood and paper Animal products Chemicals exc. Pharma Transport equip., exc. Motor vehic. Pharmaceuticals Total economy Initial PRODY Relocation index (R) 8.803,54 8.156,48 17.084,87 13.820,73 19.266,84 19.315,33 16.914,22 14.230,03 11.944,21 8.573,63 19.482,27 13.221,75 10.768,08 15.237,37 13.130,50 17.560,97 14.621,00 17.130,54 -0,44% -1,18% -0,33% -0,43% -0,42% -0,17% -0,24% 0,16% -0,59% -0,19% 0,22% 0,81% 0,59% 0,94% 0,73% 0,81% 1,27% 2,72% Pure relocation index (PR) -0,79% -0,65% -0,51% -0,44% -0,31% -0,24% -0,18% -0,13% -0,06% 0,09% 0,32% 0,48% 0,58% 0,63% 0,84% 0,89% 1,34% 2,42% Difference R-PR 0,34% -0,53% 0,18% 0,01% -0,11% 0,07% -0,06% 0,29% -0,53% -0,28% -0,09% 0,33% 0,01% 0,31% -0,11% -0,08% -0,07% 0,30% Table 2: Sector contributions to the global relocation of production Sector Machinery and mech. appliances Textiles, footwear, leather Electrical equipment Minerals Chemicals exc. Pharma Metals and manuf. exc. Iron Iron and manufact. thereof Motor vehicles Transport equip. exc. Motor vehic. Food, beverage and tobacco Plastics Wood and paper Furniture, stone and others Pharmaceuticals Animal products Miscellanea Vegetable products Instruments Total economy Contribution to Contribution to MAD (R) MAD (PR) Weight in world trade 1996-2006 1996-2006 1996-2006 11,6% 10,3% 9,2% 12,5% 7,0% 5,6% 5,3% 4,8% 3,9% 4,2% 3,9% 4,5% 2,8% 3,4% 2,9% 3,1% 2,5% 2,3% 100,0% 13,0% 11,2% 10,4% 8,4% 7,0% 5,9% 5,3% 5,0% 4,1% 4,1% 4,0% 4,0% 3,2% 3,1% 3,0% 2,9% 2,8% 2,5% 100,0% 14,8% 7,8% 12,3% 11,7% 6,5% 3,6% 4,8% 9,8% 2,4% 3,4% 4,6% 3,8% 3,4% 2,0% 2,3% 1,4% 2,7% 2,8% 100,0% 29mean absolute deviations of the 6-digit Note: M AD(R) and M AD(P R) are the relocation indices. The contribution of each sector s to M AD(R) and M AD(P R) are calculated using expression (??). Table 4: Impact of relocation on cross-country growth. OLS estimates Dependent variable : Growth rate of GDP per capita (1) log hhrEXPY Relocation Impact index Rule of law (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) 0.0239*** (0.0083) 0.0789*** (0.0251) -0.0119** (0.0053) 0.0004 (0.0024) 0.0157** (0.0076) 0.0936*** (0.0282) -0.0139** (0.0053) 0.0021 (0.0024) 0.0135* (0.0072) 0.0878*** (0.0254) -0.0201*** (0.0058) 0.0143* (0.0072) 0.0930*** (0.0275) -0.0151*** (0.0055) 0.0155** (0.0076) 0.0939*** (0.0285) -0.0132** (0.0053) 0.0130* (0.0072) 0.1280*** (0.0248) -0.0185*** (0.0054) 0.0282*** (0.0081) log initial EXPY log initial GDPpc (2) -0.0176*** (0.0049) 0.0024 (0.0024) Regulatory Quality 0.0099** (0.0038) Government Effectiveness 0.0095** (0.0037) 0.0042 (0.0030) Control of Corruption log Human Capital (years sch) log Capital Intensity -0.1137** (0.0500) 0.0148*** (0.0049) 0.0021 (0.0033) 0.0224*** (0.0084) 0.0374*** (0.0099) -0.0024*** (0.0009) -0.0356 (0.0446) 0.0138*** (0.0045) 0.0046 (0.0035) 0.0332*** (0.0095) 0.0402*** (0.0087) -0.0025*** (0.0009) 0.0135 (0.0451) 0.0154*** (0.0049) 0.0022 (0.0032) 0.0258*** (0.0090) 0.0380*** (0.0096) -0.0025*** (0.0009) -0.0139 (0.0445) 0.0010 (0.0020) 0.0147*** (0.0049) 0.0022 (0.0033) 0.0211** (0.0083) 0.0380*** (0.0094) -0.0024*** (0.0009) -0.0404 (0.0456) No No No No No 0.0174*** (0.0051) -0.0001 (0.0035) 0.0153*** (0.0047) -0.0014 (0.0035) -0.1118** (0.0511) No Oil exports (share) Population log area Constant Excluding outliers Observations R2 0.0145*** (0.0046) 0.0039 (0.0033) 0.0385*** (0.0088) 0.0407*** (0.0088) -0.0025*** (0.0008) 0.0026 (0.0433) Yes 113 113 113 113 113 113 106 0.326 0.362 0.437 0.473 0.442 0.436 0.512 Notes: Results from estimating equation (11) using OLS. The dependent variable is the annual average growth rate of GDP per capita over 1995-2007. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The excluded outliers in the regression in column (7) are Liberia, Rwanda, Moldova, Ukraine, Tajikistan, Kyrgyz Republic, and Sierra Leona. Significance levels: *** 10-percent, ** 5-percent, * 1-percent. 30 31 9,931.7 -0.08 0.25 Pure Reloc. Impact Index (PRI) hhr EXPY residual 0.25 -0.10 0.16 0.04 0.08 0.09 5,014.1 4,397.0 Max 0.13 -0.23 -0.09 0.33 0.23 0.48 3,008.1 21,147.5 2,503.7 18,117.6 138.7 68,975.7 Min 118 118 118 118 118 118 Observations l_gdppc0 reguqual l_hk_yrsch l_capintens oilsh pop l_area l_iEXPY RI PRI hhrEXPYresid -0.09 0.05 0.24 0.03 -0.11 0.23 -0.07 0.08 0.43 0.23 0.57 0.83 0.72 0.92 0.15 -0.07 -0.15 0.87 -0.32 -0.43 0.10 0.64 0.75 -0.17 -0.05 -0.18 0.71 -0.10 -0.27 0.31 0.79 -0.07 -0.03 -0.13 0.66 -0.02 -0.20 0.37 0.05 -0.09 -0.09 0.84 -0.16 -0.31 0.25 g_gdppc l_gdppc0 reguqual l_hk_y~h l_capi~s -0.04 0.16 0.23 -0.51 -0.30 -0.61 oilsh 0.37 0.10 -0.03 -0.06 0.05 pop -0.02 -0.06 0.05 -0.25 l_area Note: GDP per capita, initial EXP Y and the hhrEXP Y are measured in US$. 0.17 St. Dev. 5,652.2 11,854.1 Median 11,487.3 11,440.4 9,785.4 10,429.1 Mean Reloc. Impact Index (RI) hhr EXPY Initial EXPY per capita GDP Statistic -0.27 -0.38 0.12 l_iEXPY Table 3: Descriptive statistics and correlations 0.91 0.55 RI 0.16 PRI 32 0.326 0.362 113 No -0.1038* (0.0534) -0.0012 (0.0033) 0.0152*** (0.0045) 0.0221** (0.0087) 0.0804*** (0.0254) -0.0113** (0.0053) 0.0003 (0.0023) 0.437 113 No 0.0022 (0.0031) 0.0235*** (0.0085) 0.0384*** (0.0095) -0.0024*** (0.0008) -0.0277 (0.0476) 0.0147*** (0.0046) 0.0142* (0.0080) 0.0975*** (0.0286) -0.0133*** (0.0050) 0.0020 (0.0023) 0.473 113 No 0.0046 (0.0033) 0.0343*** (0.0097) 0.0412*** (0.0083) -0.0025*** (0.0008) 0.0210 (0.0479) 0.0138*** (0.0042) 0.0099*** (0.0036) 0.0120 (0.0077) 0.0912*** (0.0275) -0.0196*** (0.0054) 0.442 113 No 0.0023 (0.0030) 0.0270*** (0.0092) 0.0390*** (0.0092) -0.0024*** (0.0009) -0.0053 (0.0478) 0.0154*** (0.0046) 0.0042 (0.0028) 0.0128* (0.0078) 0.0962*** (0.0281) -0.0147*** (0.0052) (5) 0.435 113 No 0.0023 (0.0030) 0.0221*** (0.0083) 0.0390*** (0.0089) -0.0024*** (0.0009) -0.0324 (0.0482) 0.0011 (0.0019) 0.0147*** (0.0046) 0.0140* (0.0080) 0.0967*** (0.0287) -0.0128** (0.0050) (6) 0.444 113 No 0.0056 (0.0035) 0.0311*** (0.0099) 0.0415*** (0.0084) -0.0024*** (0.0009) 0.0208 (0.0518) 0.0058** (0.0024) 0.0108*** (0.0039) 0.0110 (0.0080) 0.0905*** (0.0283) -0.0186*** (0.0058) (7) 0.475 113 No 0.0346*** (0.0094) 0.0050 (0.0034) 0.0346*** (0.0098) 0.0440*** (0.0075) -0.0026*** (0.0008) 0.0291 (0.0509) 0.0091** (0.0036) 0.0105 (0.0080) 0.0904*** (0.0283) -0.0198*** (0.0058) (8) Notes: Results from estimating equation (11) using 2SLS. The dependent variable is the average growth rate of GDP per capita over 1995-2007. The variables log (hhrEXP Y ), log (iEXP Y ) and RI are instrumented using the country specific P RODY variables log (csp hhrEXP Y ), log (csp iEXP Y ), and csp RI, (see the body text and the Appendix for details and first-stage regressions). Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The excluded outliers in the regression in column (9) are Liberia, Rwanda, Moldova, Ukraine, Tajikistan, Kyrgyz Republic, and Sierra Leona. Significance levels: *** 10-percent, ** 5-percent, * 1-percent. R 113 Observations 2 No -0.1036* (0.0541) 0.0001 (0.0034) 0.0174*** (0.0049) -0.0174*** (0.0049) 0.0024 (0.0023) 0.0269*** (0.0086) Excluding outliers Constant log area Population Oil exports (share) log Capital Intensity log Human Capital (PWT) log Human Capital (secondary sch) log Human Capital (years sch) Control of Corruption Government Effectiveness Regulatory Quality Rule of law log initial GDPpc Relocation Impact index log initial EXPY log hhrEXPY Dependent variable : Growth rate of GDP per capita (1) (2) (3) (4) Table 5: Impact of relocation on cross-country growth. IV estimates 0.510 106 Yes 0.0043 (0.0033) 0.0389*** (0.0091) 0.0427*** (0.0082) -0.0025*** (0.0007) 0.0264 (0.0433) 0.0147*** (0.0044) 0.0098*** (0.0035) 0.0094 (0.0068) 0.1221*** (0.0285) -0.0179*** (0.0050) (9) Table 6: Impact of pure relocation on cross-country growth. OLS estimates Dependent variable : Growth rate of GDP per capita (1) (2) (3) (4) 0.0151* (0.0080) 0.0454* (0.0269) 0.0136 (0.0083) 0.0727** (0.0336) -0.0245*** (0.0062) 0.0112*** (0.0040) 0.0155*** (0.0049) 0.0066* (0.0038) 0.0237** (0.0098) 0.0397*** (0.0089) -0.0028*** (0.0009) 0.0357 (0.0499) -0.0235*** (0.0063) 0.0112*** (0.0042) 0.0173*** (0.0052) 0.0063 (0.0038) 0.0254** (0.0099) 0.0413*** (0.0089) -0.0028*** (0.0009) 0.0428 (0.0500) 0.0097 (0.0068) 0.0414* (0.0240) 0.3853*** (0.0507) -0.0151*** (0.0056) 0.0075** (0.0032) 0.0097** (0.0040) 0.0013 (0.0030) 0.0530*** (0.0088) 0.0302*** (0.0076) -0.0012 (0.0008) -0.0491 (0.0415) 0.0078 (0.0061) 0.0720** (0.0281) 0.4012*** (0.0538) -0.0121** (0.0047) 0.0078** (0.0032) 0.0099** (0.0042) 0.0001 (0.0025) 0.0558*** (0.0086) 0.0318*** (0.0075) -0.0010 (0.0007) -0.0500 (0.0372) Excluding outliers No Yes No Yes Observations 113 106 113 106 0.408 0.402 0.613 0.65 log initial EXPY Pure Relocation Impact index hhr EXPY residual log initial GDPpc Regulatory Quality log Human Capital yrs sch log Capital Intensity Oil exports (share) Population log area Constant 2 R Notes: Results from estimating equation (12) in columns 1-2 and equation (13) in columns 3-4 using OLS. The dependent variable is the average growth rate of GDP per capita over 1995-2007. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The excluded outliers in the regression in columns (2) and (4) are Liberia, Rwanda, Moldova, Ukraine, Tajikistan, Kyrgyz Republic, and Sierra Leona. Significance levels: *** 10-percent, ** 5-percent, * 1-percent. 33 34 113 Observations 2 0.403 113 No 0.0062* (0.0036) 0.0255*** (0.0097) 0.0416*** (0.0087) -0.0029*** (0.0009) 0.0379 (0.0508) 0.0153*** (0.0046) 0.0110*** (0.0039) -0.0231*** (0.0059) 0.0143* (0.0082) 0.0693** (0.0325) (2) 0.362 113 No 0.0037 (0.0033) 0.0160* (0.0090) 0.0389*** (0.0096) -0.0028*** (0.0009) 0.0056 (0.0506) 0.0171*** (0.0050) 0.0043 (0.0031) -0.0177*** (0.0056) 0.0155* (0.0084) 0.0714** (0.0333) (3) 0.355 113 No 0.0038 (0.0033) 0.0113 (0.0081) 0.0390*** (0.0093) -0.0027*** (0.0009) -0.0201 (0.0513) 0.0013 (0.0022) 0.0164*** (0.0049) -0.0159*** (0.0055) 0.0167* (0.0087) 0.0725** (0.0342) (4) 0.374 113 No 0.0070* (0.0038) 0.0219** (0.0099) 0.0416*** (0.0088) -0.0027*** (0.0010) 0.0392 (0.0550) 0.0068*** (0.0026) 0.0119*** (0.0040) -0.0220*** (0.0063) 0.0130 (0.0085) 0.0671** (0.0326) (5) 0.408 113 No 0.0387*** (0.0102) 0.0066* (0.0037) 0.0259*** (0.0097) 0.0446*** (0.0080) -0.0029*** (0.0009) 0.0470 (0.0539) 0.0101*** (0.0038) -0.0233*** (0.0063) 0.0126 (0.0086) 0.0676** (0.0332) (6) 0.397 106 Yes 0.0064* (0.0038) 0.0278*** (0.0097) 0.0439*** (0.0085) -0.0029*** (0.0008) 0.0562 (0.0471) 0.0171*** (0.0048) 0.0112*** (0.0040) -0.0222*** (0.0059) 0.0111 (0.0077) 0.0948** (0.0386) (7) 0.580 113 No 0.0028 (0.0028) 0.0445*** (0.0093) 0.0356*** (0.0079) -0.0018** (0.0008) -0.0164 (0.0473) 0.0116*** (0.0039) 0.0086*** (0.0031) 0.0107 (0.0073) 0.0691** (0.0291) 0.2471*** (0.0648) -0.0170*** (0.0051) (8) Notes: Results from estimating equation (12) in columns 1-7 and equation (13) in columns 8-9 using 2SLS. The dependent variable is the average growth rate of GDP per capita 1995-2007. The variables log (iEXP Y ), P RI, and hhrEXP Y residual are instrumented using the country specific P RODY variables log (csp iEXP Y ), csp P RI, and csp hhrEXP Y residual (see the body text and the Appendix for details and first-stage regressions). Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The excluded outliers in the regressions in columns (7) and (9) are Liberia, Rwanda, Moldova, Ukraine, Tajikistan, Kyrgyz Republic, and Sierra Leona. Significance levels: *** 10-percent, ** 5-percent, * 1-percent. R 0.356 No Excluding dummies Constant log area Population Oil share (mean) 0.0036 (0.0034) 0.0130 (0.0082) 0.0384*** (0.0099) -0.0027*** (0.0009) -0.0142 (0.0499) 0.0165*** (0.0049) -0.0165*** (0.0055) 0.0024 (0.0025) 0.0168* (0.0087) 0.0740** (0.0340) log Capital Intensity log Human Capital (PWT) log Human Capital (secondary sch) log Human Capital (years sch) Control of Corruption Government Effectiveness Regulatory Quality Rule of law log initial GDPpc hhr EXPY residual Pure Relocation Impact index log initial EXPY (1) Dependent variable : Growth rate of GDP per capita Table 7: Impact of pure relocation on cross-country growth. IV estimates 0.618 106 Yes 0.0022 (0.0028) 0.0481*** (0.0087) 0.0375*** (0.0075) -0.0017** (0.0007) -0.0074 (0.0377) 0.0122*** (0.0040) 0.0088*** (0.0030) 0.0075 (0.0063) 0.0951*** (0.0319) 0.2685*** (0.0632) -0.0147*** (0.0046) (9) Figure 1: Growth rates of the P RODY s, international trade, and World GDP Figure 2: Intensity of the International Relocation of Production using data at di↵erent disaggregation levels Note: The intensity of international relocation is measured by the mean absolute deviation (MAD) of the product relocation indices R0,T k . The 1-digit line is obtained using data for 18 sectors as explained in Subsection 2.2., whereas the 2-digit and the 6-digit lines correspond to data for the 96 industries and 4,873 products, respectively, in the HS-92 classification. 35 Figure 3: Initial 1995 P RODY and the pure relocation P R index for the 19952007 period (18 broad sectors) 36 Figure 4: Initial 1995 P RODY and the pure relocation index P R for the 19952007 period (6-digit products) Note: The coefficients in the box are the result of estimating the expression: P R0,T = 0 + 1 log(P RODYk0 ) + u k 37 Figure 5: Country relocation impact indices RI 0,T and pure relocation impact j 0,T indices P RI j . 38 Figure 6: Initial per capita GDP and the impact of international relocation as measured by the RI index. Figure 7: Initial per capita GDP and the pure international relocation impact as measured by the P RI index. 39 Figure 8: Countries’ Initial Export Sophistication (iEXP Y ) and per capita GDP growth Figure 9: International relocation impact (as measured by the RI 0,T index) and j per capita GDP growth 40 Figure 10: International pure relocation impact (as measured by the P RI 0,T j index) and per capita GDP growth 41 Figure 11: hhrEXP Y residual0,T index and per capita GDP growth j .35 ALB .3 LAOBIH BLR ESTTTO LTU DOM ROM LVA LKA UKR ARM BTN MKD IRL POL BGR MDA ZMB MNG FJI TUN TUR SVNFIN SGP JOR HRV NPL CHL MAR SVK HND PHL MUS CHN GEO HUN CZE GRCSWE HKG SLV KAZ KGZ THA MYS TKM AUT PRT GIN UZB AZE IDN NZL KOR PAK ESP PAN GBR ERI NLD MEX CYP CRI IND FRA ITA MDG CAN BLX MLI USA DNK DEU AUS SLE TCDSEN NIC GTMPERZAF RUS BFA ISRJPN BRA TGO BEN LBN KHM KEN VNM URY CHE TZA BHR TJK DZA MWI GMB CIV CAF MRT COL ETH GUY NOR MOZ NER UGA BOL EGY RWA BDI GHA ECU VEN ZAR KWT ARE SAU PRY GNB CMR PNG IRN YEM NGAAGO COG BGD .15 hhrEXPY residual .2 .25 LBR .1 GAB 4 6 8 log initial GDPpc 10 12 Figure 12: hhrEXP Y residual0,T index and initial per capita GDP j Appendix A.1 Construction of the instrumental variables and first stage regressions As explained in the body text, to break the potential circularity of high P RODY exports explaining the high income of a country, and the high income of a country leading to the high P RODY of its exports, we calculate specific P RODY s for each country that are constructed excluding all the data relative to the country (i.e., its exports and GDP per capita). Then, we use these country specific P RODY s to construct instruments for the country’s EXP Y and relocation impact indices. In this appendix we provide the specific formulas used in the 42 calculations. The country j’s specific P RODY s for good k are defined as: cs P RODYk,t j = X i6=j cs nsP RODYk,0,Tj = X i6=j where RCAtki j P P RCAtki j T i6=j RCAki RCATki j T i6=j RCAki GDP pcti , j GDP pc0i , j is the country i’s revealed comparative advantage in good k calculated by excluding country j’s exports from world trade. Thus, these indices reflect the level of development of the countries other than j exporting product k. The formulas for the EXP Y s and relocation impact indices constructed using the cs P RODYk,t j and cs nsP RODYk,t j (which are denoted as csp for country specific P RODY s) are the following: csp hhrEXP Yj0 = X 0 cs P RODYkT j !kj , k csp iEXP Yj0 = X 0 cs P RODYk0 j !kj , k csp hhrEXP Yj0 , csp iEXP Yj0 P 0 cs nsP RODYk0,T !kj = log k , csp iEXP Yj0 csp RIj0,T = log csp P RIj0,T csp hhrEXP Y residual0,T = log P j csp hhrEXP Yj0 0,T 0 k cs nsP RODYk !kj . The following table reports the first stage regressions of the key 2SLS estimations. 43 Table 8: First-stage regressions Dependent variable : (1) Relocation Impact (PRIj) (2) 0.9235*** (0.0262) -0.1174 (0.1954) 0.0336** (0.0143) 0.9832*** (0.0886) log initial EXPY log csp initial EXPY csp Relocation Index csp Pure Relocation Index (3) Pure Relocation Impact (PRIj) (4) 0.9243*** (0.0324) 0.0234* (0.0141) 0.0095 (0.0064) 0.9331*** (0.0603) 0.0476 (0.1500) -0.0410*** (0.0098) -0.0013 (0.0084) 0.0089 (0.0073) 0.0058 (0.0074) -0.0122 (0.0239) -0.0584** (0.0235) 0.0009 (0.0019) 0.0442 (0.1098) 0.0359 (0.0273) 1.0448*** (0.0679) -0.0156*** (0.0045) 0.0058 (0.0038) 0.0056* (0.0033) 0.0059* (0.0033) 0.0240** (0.0108) 0.0073 (0.0106) -0.0017* (0.0009) -0.0138 (0.0497) log initial EXPY hhr EXPYresidual (5) 0.1112*** (0.0201) -0.0155 (0.0250) -0.0176 (0.0161) 0.0090 (0.0146) 0.0656** (0.0265) 0.1315*** (0.0332) -0.0056 (0.0034) -0.0301 (0.2396) -0.0580*** (0.0129) 0.0057 (0.0101) 0.0156* (0.0088) 0.0120 (0.0086) 0.0025 (0.0217) -0.0491*** (0.0160) -0.0012 (0.0024) 0.0569 (0.1052) -0.1020 (0.1387) -0.2364 (0.3449) 0.1097*** (0.0226) -0.0143 (0.0192) -0.0164 (0.0168) 0.0093 (0.0169) 0.0556 (0.0550) 0.1336** (0.0540) -0.0060 (0.0044) -0.0012 (0.2525) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes F-statistic Observations 826.4 106 55.58 106 515.2 106 34.77 106 66.16 106 R2 0.982 0.835 0.982 0.785 0.874 csp hhrEXPY residual log initial GDPpc log Human Capital (years sch) log Capital Intensity Regulatory Quality Oil share (mean) Population log area Constant Excluding dummies Note. The specification of the regressions for log initial EXP Y (iEXP Y ) and RI in the first two columns correspond to our preferred 2SLS estimation of equation (11), which is in column 9 of Table 5. The specification of the regressions for logiEXP Y , P RI, and hhrEXP Y residual in columns (3)-(5) correspond to our preferred 2SLS estimation of equation (13), which is in column 9 of Table 7. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. Significance levels: *** 10-percent, ** 5-percent, * 1-percent. 44 Table 9: List of countries considered in the regression analysis ISO3 ALB ARM AUS AUT BDI BEN BGD BGR BHR BLX BOL BRA CAF CAN CHE CHL CHN CIV CMR COG COL CRI CYP CZE DEU DNK DOM ECU EGY ESP EST FIN FJI FRA GAB GBR GHA GMB Country name Albania Armenia Australia Austria Burundi Benin Bangladesh Bulgaria Bahrain Benelux Bolivia Brazil Central African Republic Canada Switzerland Chile China Cote d'Ivoire Cameroon Congo, Rep. Colombia Costa Rica Cyprus Czech Republic Germany Denmark Dominican Republic Ecuador Egypt, Arab Rep. Spain Estonia Finland Fiji France Gabon United Kingdom Ghana Gambia, The ISO3 GRC GTM HKG HND HRV HUN IDN IND IRL IRN ISR ITA JOR JPN KAZ KEN KGZ KHM KOR KWT LAO LBR LKA LTU LVA MAR MDA MEX MLI MNG MOZ MRT MUS MWI MYS NER NLD NOR Country name Greece Guatemala Hong Kong SAR, China Honduras Croatia Hungary Indonesia India Ireland Iran, Islamic Rep. Israel Italy Jordan Japan Kazakhstan Kenya Kyrgyz Republic Cambodia Korea, Rep. Kuwait Lao PDR Liberia Sri Lanka Lithuania Latvia Morocco Moldova Mexico Mali Mongolia Mozambique Mauritania Mauritius Malawi Malaysia Niger Netherlands Norway 45 ISO3 NPL NZL PAK PAN PER PHL POL PRT PRY ROM RUS RWA SAU SEN SGP SLE SLV SVK SVN SWE TGO THA TJK TTO TUN TUR TZA UGA UKR URY USA VEN VNM YEM ZAF ZAR ZMB Country name Nepal New Zealand Pakistan Panama Peru Philippines Poland Portugal Paraguay Romania Russian Federation Rwanda Saudi Arabia Senegal Singapore Sierra Leone El Salvador Slovak Republic Slovenia Sweden Togo Thailand Tajikistan Trinidad and Tobago Tunisia Turkey Tanzania Uganda Ukraine Uruguay United States Venezuela, RB Vietnam Yemen, Rep. South Africa Congo, Dem. Rep. Zambia