Covering America - Fighting For Our Health
Transcription
Covering America - Fighting For Our Health
Covering America R E A L R EM E D I ES FOR THE UNINSURED Jack A. Meyer Project Director Elliot K. Wicks Editor and Project Manager Advisory Panel David M. Carlisle Director, California Office of Statewide Health Planning and Development Lynn M. Etheredge Independent Consultant Judith Feder Professor and Dean of Policy Studies Georgetown University Christine C. Ferguson Director, Rhode Island Department of Human Services Jacob S. Hacker Junior Fellow Harvard University Society of Fellows Robert B. Helms Resident Scholar American Enterprise Institute Larry Levitt Vice President The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation Len M. Nichols Principal Research Associate The Urban Institute Mark V. Pauly Chair, Department of Health Care Systems The Wharton School University of Pennsylvania Alice M. Rivlin Senior Fellow and Johnson Chair The Brookings Institution Cathy Schoen Vice President, Research and Evaluation The Commonwealth Fund Gail R.Wilensky The John M. Olin Senior Fellow Project Hope Chair, Medicare Payment Advisory Commission Covering America R E A L R E M E D I E S F O R TH E U N I N S U R E D Jack A. Meyer Project Director Elliot K. Wicks Editor and Project Manager June 2001 Project Director Economic and Social Research Institute (ESRI) Jack A. Meyer Editor and Project Manager, ESRI Elliot K. Wicks ESRI Project Staff Sharon Silow-Carroll Emily Waldman Patricia Gepert-Guajardo Stephanie Anthony Todd Kutyla Mark Legnini Tarneice Hinton-Davis Copyright by the Economic and Social Research Institute, Washington, D.C. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be used or reproduced in any manner without permission in writing from the Economic and Social Research Institute, except in the case of brief quotations embodied in news articles, critical articles, or reviews. Economic and Social Research Institute th Street, N.W., Suite Washington, D.C. () - Website: www.esresearch.org Copy Editor Jean Bernard Economic and Social Research Institute Board of Directors Cover and Book Design Beth Schlenoff Mickey Levy Chief Economist, Bank of America Corporation This project was made possible by a grant from The Robert Wood Johnson Foundation, Princeton, New Jersey. Single volumes of this document can be ordered at no cost by logging on to our website: www.esresearch.org. The document is also available in PDF format from our website. William Lilley III President and CEO, Policy Communications Inc. Kenneth McLennan Retired President and Senior Consultant, Manufacturers’ Alliance for Productivity and Innovation Jack A. Meyer President, Economic and Social Research Institute Beth Shulman Consultant and former Vice President, United Food and Commercial Workers Union Sheila Zedlewski Program Director, The Urban Institute 3 Table of Contents 4 Acknowledgements 119 Kronick and Rice Proposal: Key Elements 5 Preface 121 6 A State-Based Proposal for Achieving Universal Coverage Overview 13 A Comparison of Reform Plan Features 21 Butler Proposal: Key Elements 23 Reforming the Tax Treatment of Health Care to Achieve Universal Coverage 43 45 by Richard Kronick and Thomas Rice 135 Pauly Proposal: Key Elements 137 An Adaptive Credit Plan for Covering the Uninsured by Mark V. Pauly by Stuart M. Butler 153 Singer, Garber, and Enthoven Proposal: Key Elements Feder, Levitt, O’Brien, and Rowland Approach: Key Elements 155 Near-Universal Coverage Through Health Plan Competition Assessing the Combination of Public Programs and Tax Credits by Sara J. Singer, Alan M. Garber, and Alain C. Enthoven by Judith Feder, Larry Levitt, Ellen O’Brien, and Diane Rowland 173 Weil Proposal: Key Elements 175 A Private/Public Partnership for National Health Insurance The Medical Security System: A Proposal to Ensure Health Insurance Coverage for All Americans by Jonathan Gruber by Alan R. Weil 57 Gruber Proposal: Key Elements 59 73 Hacker Proposal: Key Elements 193 75 Medicare Plus: Increasing Health Coverage by Expanding Medicare Wicks, Meyer, and Silow-Carroll Proposal: Key Elements 195 A Plan for Achieving Universal Health Coverage by Jacob S. Hacker 101 103 Holahan, Nichols, and Blumberg Proposal: Key Elements Expanding Health Insurance Coverage / by John F. Holahan, Len M. Nichols, and Linda J. Blumberg by Elliot K. Wicks, Jack A. Meyer, and Sharon Silow-Carroll 4 Acknowledgements The Economic and Social Research Institute thanks the following people and groups for their valuable contributions to this project: our Advisory Panel for guidance in the design of the project and its many elements,as well as the critiques of the authors’ proposals; The Robert Wood Johnson Foundation, a national philanthropy devoted exclusively to health and health care, and especially Karen Davenport, David Colby, and Linda Bilheimer for their oversight and valuable advice; our authors for their thoughtful analyses and their cooperation and timeliness in supplying numerous drafts and responding to requests for various kinds of inform a ti on ; Burness Communications for help in publicizing the work of the project; Jean Bernard for editing assistance; Beth Schlenoff for cover and book design; and ESRI staff—Sharon Silow-Carroll, Emily Waldman, Patricia Gepert-Guajardo, Stephanie Anthony, Todd Kutyla, Ta rn ei ce Hinton-Davis, Laurie Rosenberg, and Mark Legnini—for reviewing drafts, offering ideas,and providing support and encouragement. About the Economic and Social Research Institute The Economic and Social Research Institute (ESRI) is a nonprofit organization that conducts research and policy analysis in health care and in the reform of social services. ESRI specializes in studies aimed at improving the way health care services are organized and delivered,making quality health care accessible and affordable, and enhancing the effectiveness of social programs. 5 Preface The Economic and Social Research Institute has established a process to develop and evaluate a continuing series of major reform proposals to extend health care coverage to most, if not all, Americans. Supported by The Robert Wood Johnson Foundation, the project is designed to generate the kind of serious thinking and debate that will raise the visibility of the problem of inadequate coverage and lead to serious consideration of far-reaching soluti on s . We hope to inform,facilitate,and help re-invigorate debate over how best to provide health care coverage for the uninsured in the United States. In the past few years, bold, sweeping proposals have been moribund; in their place have come a stream of incremental changes and marginal thinking that leave the basic flaws of our current system largely untouched while tinkering around the edges. It is necessary to create some intellectual ferment around the need for serious reforms. While many ingredients are necessary to jumpstart the public discussion about health care reform, including both national leadership and public support, we believe that an essential ingredient is a forum where new and creative ideas can be developed, dissected, debated,and reconfigured. We have put in place a structure designed to draw the best, most knowledgeable, and most creative policy thinkers and analysts who are concerned with fundamental reform and achieving the ultimate goal of universal coverage. We envision this forum to be a place where innovative thinkers can gather to subject their plans to objective critique and continuous refinement and where policy makers, the media, interested stakeholders, and, ultimately, the public look for a variety of stimulating, practical proposals for health reform. A major activity of this effort has been the production of a series of commissioned proposals for extending health care coverage to people who are now uninsured. The hope is that policy makers will be able to draw upon the proposals generated through this process to formulate a set of reforms that moves the country toward universal coverage. But there is another objective: We hope that the process of producing, assessing, and revising these proposals will generate interest in broad-based reform and thereby help to raise the visibility of the issue and create awareness of the need for comprehensive reform. This kind of systematic consideration of reform alternatives is justified at this time for several reasons: first,the problem of the uninsured grew worse during the s despite a strong economy; second, the political climate seems to have warmed somewhat toward considera ti on of solutions to health care access probl em s ;a n d ,t h i rd , we can better afford the cost of a solution now than in recent history. As the proposals put forth in this volume show, the barriers to solving the problem of the uninsured do not include a lack of viable solutions. There are a number of reform strategies that would solve the problem, but deciding on a particular one is difficult because all viable solutions require making difficult trade-offs. There are no easy solutions—no “magic bullets”—that will solve the problem without requiring changes that some people would prefer not to make. However, the fact that there are no easy or non-controversial solutions to the problem of the uninsured should not deter us from making a commitment to find a lasting solution. We hope that the proposals presented here will help to take us one step closer to achieving that end. — Jack A. Meyer, Ph.D. President, Economic and Social Research Institute 6 Overview by Elliot K. Wicks The Reform Proposal Production Process This volume is the culmination of a year-long process designed to develop major, comprehensive proposals to extend health coverage to most Americans. Our objective in carrying out this project was to produce thoughtful, contrasting approaches to moving the country toward universal covera ge . We wanted the papers to represent the best, most innovative thinking on this important policy issue. In issuing invitations to potential authors—all expert health analysts and researchers—we stressed that we were interested in proposals that represent a rethinking of our present approaches to providing health insurance. We explained that the major question the paper should address is “How should the nation’s health care financing and delivery system be reformed to ensure coverage for nearly all Americans?” We indicated that we were looking for new, fresh ideas to move substantially toward universal covera ge . Although political feasibility is obviously important, we wanted authors to consider approaches that involve fundamental reform and perhaps even a complete overhaul of many current structures. We did not want polemics, advoc ac y pieces, or attacks on past or present injustices or inefficiencies. The proposals were to be practical, with some attention paid to addressing how we get from where we are now to where the authors would have us go. That is, they should acknowl ed ge the political difficulties and consider what has to be overcome, but they should not assume that current views cannot be changed. Writers were told not to assume the present political climate. Our process was de s i gn ed to select authors to ensure that final papers represent the spectrum of possible approaches and philosophical perspectives. The purpose of this project is to engender interest and debate, not to result in advocacy for any particular strategy or approach. Thus, an essential objective was to produce proposals that draw on the thinking of people representing the full range of ideas. We invited about people to submit letters indicating the approach they would take in tackling this assignment. About responded with interest in writing a paper; from this group, we chose (some of whom are a team of two or more people). We then commissioned these authors to prepare draft papers. Once the authors had completed a draft, they presented their reform proposals in person to a distinguished and diverse advisory panel of health policy analysts and researchers. These people were chosen for their broad experience, acknowledged expertise, and differing philosophical perspectives. The advisory panel provided feedback, comments, and critiques for each paper. Their task was to help authors clarify and strengthen their proposals; no endorsement was asked for or given, nor should it be inferred. The authors then prepared a new draft, taking into account the advisory panel’s review, as well as comments from the staff of the Economic and Social Research Institute. The results of the process are contained in this volume. These papers are just one step in an iterative process. These proposals lack cost estimates. A research firm will be commissioned to model these proposals for the purpose of providing estimates of their cost and impact on the uninsured. As part of this process, authors will have the opportunity to revise their proposals, particularly those el em en t s that have a crucial impact on the cost. So, in one sense, the proposals that appear here are provisional; authors are not wedded to every particular parame- 7 ter in their proposals, and all reserve the right to amend them if they think it is prudent to do so. The cost estimates,along with the revised versions of the proposals, will be disseminated at a later date. FIGURE 1 Proportion of the Uninsured Under Age 65 in Various Income Categories Measured as Percent of Federal Poverty Level, 1999 The Dimensions of the Problem Approximately million Americans—or . percent of the non-elderly population—are without any kind of health covera ge , either public or priva te .1 This figure is evidence of a major social problem that needs to be resolved. It has serious negative consequences that include lack of access to needed care, declining health, and, for some people, the assumption of crushing financial burdens. Unfortunately, despite the recent long period of sustained prosperity and economic growth, the number of people without health insu ra n ce protection has increased appreciably in the last decade. To craft sensible solutions to the problem of the uninsured requires understanding the dimensions of the problem. On the one hand, the million figure disguises the complications regarding the scope of the problem. The number who are without health coverage at some time during the year is higher than million, probably about percent higher. On the other hand, perhaps only half of the million lack coverage during the entire year. Both of these figures reflect the fact that at any time many people are moving in and out of insurance, which clearly complicates the task of engineering policies to cover them. Nevert h el e s s ,s ome people lack coverage for long periods, and they are probably most vulnerable to incurring high medical costs or going without needed care. The characteristics of the uninsured are well documented. They are predominantly lowerincome people, which suggests that a high proportion of the uninsured lack coverage because it is not afford a bl e . About percent of the non-elderly uninsured are people with incomes that put them below the federal poverty level, despite the availability of major public programs, primarily Medicaid Unless otherwise noted, the data in this section are taken from Sherry A. Glied. Challenges and Options for Increasing the Number of Americans with Health Insurance. The Task Force on the Future of Health Insurance, The Commonwealth Fund, January 2001. 1 Source: Glied, 2001, Table 1. and the State Children’s Health Insurance Program (S-CHIP), to cover low-income people. Another percent have incomes between the poverty level and percent of the poverty level. In total, people with incomes below percent of the poverty level account for percent of the uninsured (see figure ). The median family income of all uninsured families is only , (see figure ). The uninsured are predominantly members of families in which someone is employed. Only percent do not have a worker in the family. But many of those who work ( percent) are not offered health insurance. This leaves them with the option of buying coverage in the individual market, which is even more expensive than employer-sponsored coverage. Although the uninsured are disproporti on a tely employed in low-wage firms (thus, their low average incomes), they are distributed across firms of all sizes: in , percent were employed in firms with fewer than employees; percent were self-employed; but the remaining percent were employed in firms with or more employees. In fact, percent were in firms that employed or more employees. Uninsured adults come from all (non-elderly) 8 FIGURE 2 Income Characteristics of the Uninsured, Non-Elderly Population, 1999 Family Income as Percent of Federal Poverty Level Percent in Income Group Who Are Uninsured Median Family Income Under % %–% %–% %–% More than % All Uninsured % % % % % % , , , , , , Source: Glied, 2001. age groups: about a quarter of all uninsured adults are age to ; another quarter are between and years old; the remaining half are between ages and . Children make up about percent of the total uninsured.2 Many of the uninsured are eligible for some kind of coverage. About percent decline coverage available from their employers. Many others—about one-quarter of uninsured adults and two-thirds of uninsured children—are el i gi ble for public programs but fail to enroll for one reason or another. These statistics demonstrate that making coverage available is not enough. The uninsured have to know about the available coverage, have to be able to afford the portion that is not subsidized,and have to be willing to go through the process of establishing eligibility and enrolling. The uninsured represent a diverse, constantly moving target. Unidimensional strategies will not solve the problem. The proposals presented in this volume recognize that fact. Categories for the Papers All the proposals that follow differ from one another in important ways. Some build on the current Bureau of Labor Statistics. Current Population Survey. March 2000 Supplement. 2 system in one way or another, while others would jettison major parts of it; still others fall somewhere in between. Some would move quickly to virtually universal covera ge ; others would progress more gradually toward that goal. But as different as they are, the proposals share certain notable features. They all see affordability as the most important barrier to broader coverage,and they all make substantial financial subsidies available to a major portion of the population (typically to those with income levels up to the median or up to percent of the federal poverty level). Except in those instances where coverage is a matter of “right,” so that there is no test of eligibility for subsidies, they all use income alone as the only determinant of eligibility; that is, none would confine coverage to families, to children, to people whose assets fall below a defined level, to those who do not already have coverage, or to any other group. They all seek to improve horizontal equity by making the level of subsidies less dependent on the state where one lives. They all look to revenues from the federal government as the major source of financing, though they differ with respect to how the revenue would be collected (for example,a payroll tax versus general revenues). On the other hand, they all give some flexibility to states,allowing them to influence some elements of the new system (though there is wide difference in the level of state influence). Only one of the proposals would eliminate employers as a source of coverage and a means of risk pooling, although one other might produce this result over time. Finally, the proposed reforms (with the possible exception of one) would not dramatically change the role of health insurers and health plans; they would still continue to perform essentially the functions that they do today. Several other features are common to a significant proportion, but not all, of the proposals.Five of the reform proposals would rely heavily on some kind of purchasing pool or insurance exchange. These entities would offer coverage from a variety of insurers and health plans, with some standardization of products, and would generally be open both to employers and individuals. Usually, individual enrollees would be able to choose any plan partici- 9 pating in the exchange. In a number of instances, subsidies would be available only if people bought coverage through the exchanges. A feature common to six of the proposals is the use of tax credits (or vouchers) to subsidize the cost of care. Typically, proposals that espouse this approach also propose to alter the tax tre a tm ent of employer-paid insurance premiums: They would eliminate or reduce the right of employees to exclude this form of compensation from their calculation of taxable income. Although any attempt to categorize the proposals runs the risk of trying to force a proposal into a category that does not quite fit, it is still useful to think of them as falling into three general categories, based on their approach to subsidizing coverage. . The tax credit/voucher approach. Proposals that adopt this approach provide subsidies in the form of tax credits or publicly funded vouchers that can be applied against the cost of buying health coverage. Reform proposals that take this approach tend to encourage consumers to buy coverage in the private insurance market. That is, they may do away with Medicaid and S-CHIP (except for continuing with Medicaid coverage for special-needs populations and long-term care) and, instead, have people formerly covered by these programs buy coverage in private markets, just as the rest of the population currently does. . The Medicaid/S-CHIP expansion, premiumreduction approa ch . Approaches that fo ll ow this model generally build on these existing public programs by raising the income limits to include many more needy people, doing away with all tests of eligibility except income, and including provisions to move toward uniform eligibility standards across states. Another way to think of these approaches is that they are subsidizing the purchase of coverage by reducing the premium; for the lowest-income group, the premium is zero, and people above this level may pay something toward the premium but still less than the full price. Understandably, these approaches tend to give states substantial responsibility for designing, implementing, and operating the subsidy programs. Although they build on the foundation of existing public plans, these proposals sometimes give subsidized people the option to pur- chase a non-governmental plan. . The social insurance/health care as a “ri gh t” approach. The essence of this approach is to guarantee everyone—regardless of income or any other characteristic—access to a standardized benefit package at no direct cost to the covered person. Health coverage is “free” in the same sense that public education is free; that is, it is publicly financed through taxes. There are no tests of eligibility (except, perhaps, legal residency status). This approach can be thought of as applying the social insurance aspects of the Medicare model to the whole population. However, the approach is compatible with having people covered through their employers as long as a no-cost plan is available. In fact, several of the proposals combine this approach with payroll-tax financing and a “play or pay” requirement for employers. We now turn to a brief description of each proposal, identified by author. The Proposals in Brief Stuart Butler. This approach provides refundable tax credits to virtually all households. Credit amounts would be based on need as determined by family income and the amount of health costs (including premiums and out-of-pocket costs). One option for lower-income families would be a fixed credit of up to ,. The sliding-scale credit, available to all, is structured to limit health costs as a percent of income: the credit covers a higher proportion of health costs as these costs account for a higher share of income. Availability of tax credits would enable the gradual repeal of the current tax subsidy for working people, so that employees could no longer exclude from their taxable income the amount that employers contribute on their behalf to health insurance premiums. Workers whose employers offer coverage would have to use their credit to get coverage at the workplace, but other employees and individuals could use their tax credit to buy coverage from a range of other organizations, including other employers, churches, unions, associations plans, and other affinity groups. To receive new federal grants to supplement the tax credits, states 10 would have to agree to take certain steps to make coverage more affordable for low-income workers. Mark Pauly. This tax-credit/voucher approach emphasizes the advantage of beginning reform with a relatively simple,financially feasible,easily modifiable intervention. The author stresses that there is much uncertainty about the response of insurers and consumers to major changes,so it is desirable to adopt an approach that can be readily changed as experi en ce shows what works and what does not. The principal targeted group is lower-middleincome households with incomes above the poverty line but below the median income (regardless of the age, sex, or relationship of family members). They would be eligible for a voucher or credit that is large enough to cover perhaps one-half to two-thirds of the premium for moderately comprehensive covera ge . The credits, in the form of coupons worth , for individual coverage and , for family coverage, could be used for any qualified insurance that costs at least as much as the coupons. Very-lowincome households would be eligible for publicly provided or contracted comprehensive insurance, with no premium share required. People with incomes above the median (with a few exceptions for high risks and possibly those with incomes near the threshold) will not be eligible for the new program initially, but would retain the tax exclusion for group coverage. This approach encourages people to acquire coverage through private markets with the expectation that the market will adapt and improve under the impetus of the influx of new buyers. Sara Singer, Alan Garber, and Alain Enthoven. This tax-credit approach to reform is built around purchasing pools,called insurance exchanges, which would be established in all geographic regions and would provide coverage on a guaranteed-issue and community-rated basis. There are three incentives to form exchanges: tax credit subsidies could be used only for coverage purchased through exchanges; exchanges and participating plans are not su bj ect to state coverage mandates; and exchanges and participating plans are protected against adverse selection through premium risk adjustment. If no exchange arises vo lu n t a ri ly, a national exchange,similar in function to the Federal Employees Health Benefits Program, would be available to firms with fewer than employees. Medicaid and S-CHIP would still be an option for low-income individuals, but they and families with annual income up to , would be eligible for a refundable tax credit equal to percent of the median-cost exchange plan. Low-income people who do not use the tax credit to en ro ll in a plan would be automatically enrolled in a default plan, and states would be el i gi ble for federal grants to cover part of the costs of these otherwise uninsured people. The tax credit would continue on a phasedout basis for families with incomes up to ,; these people would have to choose between the tax credit and the tax exclusion for employer-paid premiums. Families with even higher incomes could continue to enjoy the tax exclusion subsidy, but it would be capped. Jonathan Gruber. This proposal is a premiumreduction approach, but it is also built around voluntary purchasing pools in each state. Most if not all insurers would be expected to participate in these pools because subsidies are available only if coverage is purchased through the pool. For people below percent of the poverty level, enrollment in a pool-based plan is automatic and free of charge. For those between percent and percent of poverty, the premium would be priced to limit the cost of coverage to percent of income. Others receive no subsidy. Employers have incentives to use the pool as their coverage source, since their employees are eligible for subsidies only if they purchase coverage through the pool. Financing comes from general revenues, a cap on the amount of employer-paid premiums that can be excluded from employees’ taxable income, and the phase-out of S-CHIP and Medicaid. Payments to health plans are paid on a risk-adjusted basis to encourage fair competition, discourage risk selection, and reward efficiency. John Holahan, Len Nichols, and Linda Blumberg. This proposal is a premium-reducti on ,s t a te - b a s ed approach that extends S-CHIP-type coverage to a larger portion of the population and encourages purchasing pools by making subsidies available only if coverage is purchased through pools. States have 11 incentives to participate because the federal share of the per capita cost is percent higher than Medicaid matching rates.States also have considerable flexibility in designing and operating the subsidy program. But the program would create an entitlement, so enrollment could not be limited by the state, and the federal government would specify a minimum benefits package. The standards for eligibility, based on income alone, would be the same across all states. People below percent of the poverty level would get full subsidies, while those between percent and percent of poverty would get partial subsidies. The new purchasing pools would be composed of Medicaid and S-CHIP recipients,state employees, and anyone else who chooses to join. Anyone, regardless of risk, could buy a standard benefits package through the pool at a cost that would never exceed a computed statewide community rate. Employers may, but are not required to, buy coverage through the pools, but they must offer employees pool coverage as an option, because subsidies are available only to those purchasing through the pool. After five years,states could mandate that all individuals purchase coverage. Judith Feder, Larry Levitt, E ll en O’ B ri en , and Diane Rowland. This approach considers how an extension of S-CHIP might be combined with an employer tax credit. Given the authors’ assumption that comprehensive reform is highly unlikely in the foreseeable future, their emphasis is on not disrupting but expanding a system that works quite well for low-income people, who are the main focus of the authors’ concern. They also want to use new dollars most efficiently, that is, to avoid having public coverage, whether credits or S-CHIP extensions, substitute for employer-based coverage. They would make comprehensive benefits available at no cost to all individuals with incomes below percent of the federal poverty level. Such coverage would also be available to people between percent and percent of poverty, but they would pay some premiums and cost sharing, up to a maximum of percent of income. The authors would prefer that eligibility be an entitlement, as with Medicaid, rather than being dependent on annual state appropriation decisions, as with S-CHIP. The proposal looks favorably on using tax credits to help fund coverage for those with incomes above percent of poverty. The authors suggest that it is difficult to design a modest individual tax credit that is simultaneously effective and well-targeted, while at the same time avoiding “crowd-out” of existing publicly sponsored and employer-sponsored insurance. A better approach, they indicate ,m ay be tax credits provided to employers to encourage greater offering of insurance. E ll i ot Wicks, Jack Meyer, and Sharon SilowCarroll. This is a tax credit approach that guarantees universal coverage by mandating that everyone buy coverage and by having Medicare provide fallback coverage for anyone who still remains temporarily uninsured. The new program replaces S-CHIP and Medicaid (except for long-term care and special populations). Everyone is eligible for tax credits, but the tax exclusion for employer-paid premiums is eliminated. People at or below the poverty level get credits adequate to purchase coverage comparable to that provided by Medicaid. People above the median income level get a tax credit roughly equal to the average value of the current tax exclusion. Those in the middle, between the poverty level and the median income, get credits that decline in value as income rises, starting with a credit sufficient to buy Medicaid coverage and ending with a credit equal to the credit that will be available to people with incomes above the median. People who do not have proof of private coverage automatically default to Medicare; so all providers know that Medicare will pay for those without other covera ge . To discourage permanent use of the Medicare default, at tax time, people who cannot show proof of other coverage have to pay a premium plus a penalty (to which the tax credit can be applied) for every month they were covered by Medicare. Administration of all claims, coordination of benefits, etc., goes through a centralized administrative entity to improve efficiency and reduce administrative burdens for providers, patients, and health plans. Jacob Hacker. This proposal is a modified “play or pay”approach that creates incentives for individuals and employers to participate in Medicare (with augmented benefits). Employers would be required either to provide and pay for private coverage and 12 automatically enroll their employees in an employer-chosen plan or pay a modest payroll tax ( percent) and enroll their employees in Medicare. For many employers, especially those with low-wage employees or higher-risk populations, the modest payroll contribution would be less costly and thus more attractive than offering their own plan. Workers would also pay a premium toward Medicare covera ge , based on income and family size. States would have federally financed incentives to enroll in Medicare those people who do not enroll through employment. S-CHIP and Medicaid would be replaced.States would also provide “wraparound” coverage to ensure that those who would have been in Medicaid still receive similarly comprehensive benefits. Individuals could buy into Medicare, paying premiums based on income. The author estimates that percent to percent of the population could eventually en ro ll in Medicare Plus, which would give the program bargaining leverage and en su re broad pooling of risk. Eventually, a mandate to have coverage would apply to everyone. Alan Weil. This proposal combines three key elements: making access to standard free health coverage a “right,” requiring employers to “play or pay,” and allowing people not covered by employer plans to buy coverage through large purchasing pools called “ i n su ra n ce exchanges.” Unless an employer offers one of the federally defined standard benefits packages, automatically enrolls all employees, and pays for percent of the employer premium and percent of dependent covera ge , the employer and the firm’s employees pay a payroll tax equal to approximately what the average employer and employee premium is today. People not covered by employer plans get coverage through insurance exchanges that operate in all geographic regions and can be private or public entities licensed by the federal government. Exchanges seek bids from and contract with a number of health plans. Individuals can choose any health plan the exchange offers; they have a ch oi ce of both standard and non-standard benefit packages. All plans are offered on a commun i ty - ra ted basis. Using revenues from the payroll tax, exchanges provide at least one insurance option that can be obtained at no charge, but they also offer more expensive coverage options to those willing to pay more. One option would be a medical savings account. S-CHIP and the portion of Medicaid that serves low-income, non-disabled adults and children are eliminated, but states operate subsidy programs to cover the copayments, deductibles, and uncovered services that these families face. Richard Kronick and Tom Rice. This social insurance approach combines a number of key features: access to health coverage as a “ri gh t ,” maximum flexibility to states, payroll-based financing, and elimination of employers’ roles in providing health coverage. To be granted the federal funds that finance most of the cost of the new system, each state must establish a financing and delivery system that makes access to a zero-premium, relatively comprehensive, standard benefits plan available to all. To get coverage,a state’s citizens need only enroll with the state; there are no income or other eligibility tests. Individuals who do not enroll voluntarily are assigned to a no-cost plan. More comprehensive plans will generally also be available, but at an extra cost.States have great latitude in designing their systems; for example, both a single-payer system or an approach based on contracts with private health plans would be acceptable. To get federal funding, states would show that they will en ro ll at least percent of the population and meet other standards related to maintaining quality of care and ensuring good administra ti on . States would be expected to contribute to the funding of the new program in an amount equal to percent of their present Medicaid and S-CHIP spending (both of which would be eliminated), but the bulk of the funds would come from a federal payroll tax equal to percent of what is currently spent by employers and employees for health coverage. Low-wage employers and employees would pay less. The division of the tax between employers and employees would be based on current distribution of spending. The federal government would monitor and enforce quality standards and provide incentives for states to improve outcomes. n 13 A Comparison of Reform Plan Features The following table provides a side-by-side comparison of the features of the reform plans that are described in detail in the following chapters. The plans are identified by the names of the authors. A Comparison of Reform Plan Features Butler Feder / Levitt / O’Brien / Rowland Gruber Hacker Holahan / Nichols / Blumberg General Approach Would make refundable tax credits available to working households. States would get grants to expand health coverage to more residents and make insurance more affordable. Coverage obtained at work or from a range of other organizations such as churches or unions. Expand Medicaid and the State Children’s Health Insurance Program for lowincome people. Possible combination with tax credit to small, low-wage firms to expand employer offerings. Establishment of purchasing pools in every state through which households with incomes up to 300% of the federal poverty level would be eligible for no-cost or reduced-cost coverage on a sliding-scale basis; automatic plan enrollment for lowestincome households. A modified “play or pay” approach that creates incentives for workers and employers to buy into “Medicare Plus,” a national program based on Medicare. Extend the type of subsidized coverage that is currently available under S-CHIP to all lower-income people and subsidize insurance for the highest risk. Target Population Working uninsured individuals and families; the plan would achieve near-universal coverage for all working households of legal U.S. residents. People below 150% of poverty level covered at no cost; those between 150% and 200% of poverty would pay some premiums and cost sharing. Higher-income people could buy-in to public coverage and pay a sliding-scale premium. Employees of small, low-wage firms benefit from tax credit. Individuals and households under 300% of the federal poverty level would receive subsidies. Households with incomes below 150% of poverty level would be eligible for no-cost coverage. All Americans not covered by Medicare or employersponsored insurance. Individuals with incomes under 250% of the federal poverty level and those at high health risk. Subsidies available only to those who enroll through the state purchasing pool. Form of Public Programs Refundable tax credit, funded via repeal of federal income tax provision that makes employer contributions to employees’ health insurance non-taxable income; federal tax revenues would fund grants to states to help lowincome families buy coverage. S-CHIP expansion, federally subsidized, with some state match, for those with limited incomes, and a federal tax credit subsidy for small employers to help cover workers. Household income determines eligibility for no-premium plans (for households under 150% of poverty level) or reduced-premium plans (for households under 300% of the federal poverty level on a sliding-scale basis but premium not more than 10% of income). Premiums for those buying into Medicare Plus would be scaled to income, with lowerincome citizens paying only a small percent of income. Employers would be eligible for transitional subsidies and for reductions in their contribution rate based on firm income. Increased federal-funding match to participating states; full subsidies to people below 150% of poverty; cost-sharing up to 7% of income for people between 150% and 200% of poverty and to 12% for people between 200% and 250% of poverty. Higher-risk individuals, regardless of income, pay no more than a statewide community rate. Mandates for Coverage None, but to receive tax credit, individual or family would have to buy a health plan that included a minimum set of benefits. High-level of voluntary compliance expected among most workers since employees required to tell employers which health plan they wished to join. None. None. None initially but individual mandate would apply eventually if a nontrivial share of Americans remained uninsured. After five years, states could mandate that everyone be covered. Sources of Funding Savings from elimination of existing tax exclusion, and federal general tax revenues. Federal general revenues, with state matching payments. Federal general revenues, savings from replacement of Medicaid and S-CHIP health programs, and limits on tax exclusion for employer-provided insurance. Payroll contributions and premiums, general revenues, and other smaller sources. Federal general revenues, and cuts in existing programs since the need would be reduced as health reform is implemented. 15 Kronick / Rice Pauly Singer / Garber / Enthoven Weil Wicks / Meyer / Silow-Carroll All non-elderly legal residents would be guaranteed comprehensive health insurance as a “right” (at no direct cost) through a public insurance approach designed by each state and monitored by the federal government. A refundable tax credit/voucher system would make some level of coverage affordable to lower-middleincome people who currently have no health insurance. Very-low-income households would initially be eligible for publicly financed zero-premium comprehensive insurance. Combines refundable tax credits and insurance exchanges to promote lowercost, higher-value health coverage while allowing employers and individuals to continue current arrangements if they desire. A new Medical Security System would be created to provide universal coverage, making coverage a “right.” Tax credits for all households, varying by income. Universal coverage achieved by mandating that everyone have or buy health coverage and having Medicare automatically cover anyone temporarily uninsured. Builds on present system of private health plans and employer-based coverage. All non-elderly legal residents. Principal target group is lower-middle income families and individuals with incomes above the federal poverty line, or about half of the uninsured. Very low-income families covered publicly, at least initially. Low and moderate-income people who are not eligible for Medicare. All legal U.S. residents under age 65. All of the uninsured. Federal subsidies to states to finance availability of nocost coverage to all legal residents. A voucher or tax credit large enough to cover one-half to two-thirds of the premium for moderately comprehensive coverage. The credits would be in the form of coupons worth $1,500 for individual coverage and $3,500 for family coverage. No-cost publicly financed coverage for very low income households. Continuation of Medicaid/ S-CHIP for eligible individuals and families who choose to stay in these programs; refundable tax credits equal to 70% of median-cost health plan; federal payments to states equal to 50% of the tax credit to cover the costs of running “default plans” for people who do not enroll. Payroll tax, Medicaid, and S-CHIP funds. Refundable tax credits for all households but varying according to income—minimum credit approximately $700 a year for an individual and $1,200 a year for a family. People below 100% of poverty would get credit sufficient to buy coverage comparable to Medicaid. Those above that level up to median income would get gradually reduced subsidies. All legal residents under age 65 automatically covered by comprehensive benefits. Everyone would have at least one health insurance option that would not require payment of premiums. There would be a mandatory payroll tax. None. None. All employers and employees would pay a new payroll tax. All people would have to enroll or be enrolled by default. Every individual and family would have to have health coverage at least as comprehensive as Medicare’s, plus prescription drugs and wellchild care. Those who fail to show proof of purchase would pay a premium plus a penalty for Medicare backup coverage for every month without other coverage. Primary revenue source would be a payroll tax levied on employers and employees, supplemented by federal general revenues, state revenues, and, in some states, premium payments from individuals. Federal budget revenues; those who buy more expensive coverage would pay outof-pocket. Full coverage for those with incomes below 125% of the federal poverty level would be financed through a combination of state and federal revenues. Phased-in cap on current federal tax exclusion; general revenues; and savings over time from changing consumer behavior and increasing health plan competition. Payroll tax, premiums, and federal subsidies. Federal general revenues, but partially offsetting savings would be realized from the elimination of Medicaid and S-CHIP and from making employer-paid health premiums taxable income for employees. Butler Feder / Levitt / O’Brien / Rowland Gruber Hacker Holahan / Nichols / Blumberg Major Tax Changes Repeal of the federal income tax provision that makes employer contributions to employees’ health insurance a non-taxable form of income. Explores tax credits to individuals or employers, the latter to subsidize the offering of coverage to uninsured workers with modest incomes. Limits the tax exclusion for employer-provided insurance equal to no more than the cost of the median-cost plan in each purchasing pool. Cap on tax exclusion of employer-provided health insurance at level of twice the average premium of Medicare Plus coverage. Federal taxes would be increased if surplus not available. Level of Benefits To qualify for the tax credit, families would have to enroll in a health plan that included at least the minimum insurance package, which would be primarily catastrophic coverage. Comprehensive but not specifically delineated. Physician services, inpatient and outpatient hospital, prescription drugs, nominal payments for well-child care, prenatal care, and immunizations. A defined benefit package similar to Medicare plus outpatient prescription drugs, preventive services, mental health benefits, and maternal and child health care. States determine a new standard benefit package—within federal guidelines—for everyone under 250% of poverty and those at high health risk. Role of Federal Government Would establish a default system of health insurance regulation to encourage availability of affordable insurance; would establish a benchmark health plan with basic features and catastrophic protection. Would monitor state compliance and work with states on a plan to eliminate uninsurance. Would make federal funds available at enhanced Medicaid matching rates to states willing to cover targeted uninsured. Funds subsidies, sets minimal rules, provides oversight of purchasing pool administration. The Health Care Financing Administration would have primary responsibility for administering Medicare Plus. In addition to offering standard fee-for-service coverage, Medicare Plus would also allow beneficiaries to enroll in private health plans that contracted with the program. Financial support, monitor state compliance of minimum rules, oversee state spending and enforcement. Role of State Government Would develop a mechanism to supplement federal tax credit for eligible workers and help cover those who did not purchase minimum insurance. Would have to use additional federal funds to expand existing or develop new programs to achieve target levels of coverage. Would work with health insurers on insurance reform that keeps benefits affordable. Would provide coverage to low-income uninsured residents, consistent with federal rules affecting eligibility, benefits, administration, and other program aspects. Not addressed, except for continued responsibility for remaining parts of Medicaid. Would transform from provider of insurance to a portal for coverage under the new Medicare Plus system. States would continue to finance care for the eligible aged, blind and disabled. In addition, they would have to reach out to and enroll nonworkers, provide wraparound coverage for those who would have been in Medicaid, and subsidize premiums for unemployed people. Increases role of states significantly while granting more flexibility. Kronick / Rice Pauly Singer / Garber / Enthoven Weil Wicks / Meyer / Silow-Carroll Payroll tax substitutes for employer and employee premiums, which has implications for tax exclusion provision of employer premium contributions. No major tax code changes, but tax credits in the form of coupons would help people purchase qualified health insurance. The new vouchers would be viewed and treated as tax reductions for those who use them. Phased-in cap on current federal tax exclusion for employer-paid premiums. New payroll tax would be established for employers and employees. The tax exclusion for employer-paid health premiums would be eliminated. A federally-defined standard benefit package. Benefits would include prescription drug coverage; dental and long-term care would not be required. To qualify for the credit, the plan would have to cover effective medical and surgical services, prescription drugs, and medical devices based on a standard definition. Patient cost sharing would be permitted, as would managed care. Generally determined by the market, with minimum standards set by the Insurance Exchange Commission, including goods and services known to be medically effective and provided at reasonable cost. Guarantee is for basic coverage, but individual may supplement with own funds to buy more comprehensive. A package of benefits comparable to Medicare’s plus a prescription drug benefit and well-child care coverage. Would impose payroll taxes on employers and employees, calculate money needed and provide funds to each state health care system, monitor state implementation of expansions, measure quality and health outcomes, determine and update standard benefit package, monitor and regulate quality of care in states. Would make information about insurance purchasing and plans available, including price and quality and could subsidize the production and distribution of such information. It also would be (or contract with) an insurer of last resort. Establish the Insurance Exchange Commission to oversee insurance exchanges, distribute tax credits and make default plan payments. Establishes U.S. Insurance Exchange as backup in markets without private exchanges. Would set up and regulate insurance exchanges, forward tax revenues, and determine size of payroll tax. Would fund all tax credits. Would establish general guidelines for states setting up the aggregate purchasing arrangements (APA). Would continue to operate Medicare, for the elderly and as a temporary back-up plan for people who do not have proof of private coverage. States would have much flexibility in designing a system— how to pay health care providers (e.g., single payer vs. competing health plans), be responsible for raising revenue to supplement federal financing, meet federal requirements, and enroll residents in health plans. Would provide information on enrollment options and procedures, negotiate with health plans and providers, regulate health plans, and collect data to evaluate the system. Would have primary role of selecting or managing the public plan for poor people not currently covered by Medicaid. Could continue to regulate individual insurance and regulate risk-rating. In addition, states could choose to provide payments for people with high medical expenses, possibly allowing smaller deductibles or less-constraining upper limits in low-cost plans. Continue to provide Medicaid and S-CHIP; use new federal funds to pay for care under default plans by reimbursing safety-net providers. States would continue to pay some Medicaid costs to keep coverage at current levels; would subsidize copayments under basic plan for lowincome residents. Each state would be required to establish an aggregate purchasing arrangement through which small employers and individuals would purchase coverage. In exchange for no longer financing the acute portion of Medicaid or S-CHIP, states would assume greater responsibility for long-term care services under Medicaid. 17 Butler Feder / Levitt / O’Brien / Rowland Gruber Hacker Holahan / Nichols / Blumberg Effects on Existing Public Programs Medicaid and S-CHIP would continue as now. Medicaid and S-CHIP would continue and be expanded. Gradual phase out of Medicaid and S-CHIP (and accompanying federal subsidies) for those families who qualify on income alone. Medicaid remains in place for the elderly and disabled. Would eventually replace existing public programs for the uninsured with a single national program based on Medicare. Medicaid and S-CHIP would be phased out with eligibles automatically enrolled in the new Medicare program or employer-sponsored plans. Participating states would receive enhanced federal S-CHIP matching rate for all current Medicaid and S-CHIP beneficiaries under 250% of poverty; all states must continue smaller, residual Medicaid program for children and adults with special needs as well as all long term care services; would eliminate federal payments to states covering individuals with incomes above 250% of poverty. No change in non-participating states. Role of Insurers/ Health Plans Would continue to be a major source of coverage. Would have to bring premium rates into line with federal or state underwriting and benefit requirements, but would benefit from administrative savings associated with the automatic enrollment system. Would stay the same as today, although some market reforms might be necessary. Could participate in stateestablished purchasing pool or continue to operate outside of such arrangements. Would stay the same as today; would compete for business from Medicare Plus system. Health plans participating in the new state plan would be required to accept all applicants, with premiums set at a statewide community rate. Payments to plans would be risk adjusted. Insurers would not be subject to any new federal market regulations outside the state purchasing pool. Role of Employers Similar to present but would have to inform employees about the tax credit program and deliver the tax credit. Would serve as a clearinghouse, creating automatic enrollment mechanisms for insurance, setting up payroll deduction and payment systems for employees and providing proof of insurance for each worker. Similar to present. If tax credit were pursued, small lowwage employers would be encouraged to offer insurance to their employees; employers would receive the tax credit if they provided insurance. Would continue to offer health coverage to workers, but could do so within the purchasing pool or outside of it. Employers would enroll workers at workplace. They could choose to sponsor coverage at least as generous as the new program’s or pay a modest payroll-based contribution to fund public coverage. Would continue to have choice to offer health coverage to their workers. If they offer, they must make state plans available, but they can also offer plans outside the state pool. Risk Share/ Purchasing Pools/ Insurance Regulation Insurance industry and states would have to work together to develop a means for adjusting risk among plans. Possible reforms in the individual insurance market unless tax credits could be applied to a publicly managed insurance product. Purchasing pools are foundation of proposal: subsidies are available only for coverage purchased through the pools. To avoid adverse selection, measures are imposed to make it more difficult for employers to shift between public and private coverage. 50% to 70% of the population might eventually enroll in Medicare Plus, providing strong bargaining leverage and broad pooling of risk. No new regulations are imposed on private insurance, and there are no insurance pools. State-established purchasing pools are foundation of proposal. Medicaid (except the disabled and elderly) and S-CHIP enrollees and state employees would be included in the pool. The pool would be open to individuals and employers, and insurers could offer standard benefit package at a statewide community rate, plus add-on products priced separately. Kronick / Rice Pauly Singer / Garber / Enthoven Weil Wicks / Meyer / Silow-Carroll Would vary by state, but new state program could replace S-CHIP and portions of Medicaid. Medicaid and S-CHIP would continue, and more lowincome people would be subsidized to enroll in these programs or some other public program. Medicare remains intact; people enrolled in Medicaid and S-CHIP may stay in these programs or opt instead for tax credits to be used in the private market. S-CHIP would be subsumed; Medicaid would be mostly subsumed. S-CHIP and Medicaid largely replaced, except for disabled and elderly. In some states, plans would compete for business from states and would have to include services specified in a federally-defined benefits package. Some states might choose to pay providers directly and eliminate the role of insurers/health plans. Would continue to be major source of coverage. Would be required to guarantee renewability in the individual market and to set premiums on modified community-rating basis in the small-group market. Insurers would redeem vouchers or certificates. Would compete to provide low-cost, high-quality care; collect and report quality of care and health outcomes data. Plans would contract with health insurance exchanges to offer range of plans, including a “no-cost” plan (that is, no enrollee contribution); would market plans and monitor quality of care. Would continue to be major source of coverage but would be required to offer a policy that covers the services comparable to Medicare plus prescription drugs and wellchild care, to participate in purchasing pools, and to community rate in individual and small-group markets. Employers would no longer provide or buy health coverage for their workers. Although employer role would be eliminated, both employers and employees would have to contribute to financing coverage. Similar to current role. May become their own insurance exchange; continue to offer benefits to employees; or purchase coverage from exchanges. Employers would collect payroll tax but could opt out by offering own generous plans to employees. Employers would be required to offer (but not necessarily pay for) coverage for employees and dependents. Benefits must be at least comparable to Medicare plus a prescription drug benefit and wellchild care. Employers with 10 or fewer employees would have to offer coverage through the purchasing pool. Since coverage in no-cost plan is automatic, everyone is pooled together, though states would have latitude to decide specifics. Few restrictions would be placed on qualifying coverage. But all policies must have a guaranteed renewability clause, and low-cost policies must be sold under modified community rating. Plans with more generous coverage could charge higher premiums to high-risk people. Insurers could impose modest waiting periods for people who did not enroll during open season. The Federal Insurance Exchange Commission would develop risk- adjustment strategies. Payments would be risk-adjusted both between health plans within an exchange and across exchanges. Insurers selling through insurance exchanges would be required to offer guaranteed-issue, community rated standard benefit packages. All health plans would have to accept all individual and small-group applicants and provide immediate and full coverage for all covered benefits with no waiting periods or exclusions for prior conditions. Insurers selling individual and small-group coverage would have to price premiums on a communityrated basis. Purchasing pools (APAs) open to all individuals and groups. 19 21 Butler Proposal Key Elements Stuart M. Butler has outlined a new proposal to achieve near universal coverage for health insurance that is built on the following key elements: available to working households would replace the current tax exclusion accorded to employees. Employees could no longer exclude from their taxable income the amount employers contribute on their behalf to health insurance premiums. sponsor coverage would have to use the credit to get coverage at work. Other employees and individuals could use their tax credit to buy coverage from a range of additional sources. These would include plans offered by employers, association plans, and plans offered by affinity groups such as churches, unions, and so on. , regardless of whether they sponsored coverage, would have to undertake a “clearinghouse” function, which could include adjusting employee tax withholdings to reflect their credit, creating an automatic enrollment mechanism for insurance, and setting up a payroll deduction and payment system for employees to pay their chosen plan. to supplement the tax credits, states would have to develop a plan acceptable to the federal government to make coverage more affordable for low-income workers. 22 About the Author . , .., is Vice President, Domestic and Economic Policy Studies, at The Heritage Foundation. Born and educated in Great Britain, where he earned a Ph.D. in American economic history from St. Andrews University in Scotland, Butler is considered one of Washington’s most innovative thinkers. He was named one of Washington’s “dozen key players” on health care reform by the National Journal, and played a key role in the intellectual and policy revolution that produced the welfare reform legislation. His books include, Enterprise Zones: Greenlining the Inner Cities; Privatizing Federal Spending; Out of the Poverty Trap (with Anna Kondratas); and A National Health System for America (with Edmund Haislmaier), which in presented a blueprint for reform based on consumer choice and competition. 23 Reforming the Tax Treatment of Health Care to Achieve Universal Coverage by Stuart M. Butler Overview The aim of this proposal is near-universal health insurance for working households, including the self-employed, using a tax-based subsidy and insurance reform to make such insu ra n ce affordable. Virtually all legal residents would be included in the proposed system (other than those enrolled in government programs), including those who currently have employer-sponsored health insurance. The place of employment would con ti nue to be the point at which subsidies typically are delivered and choices made for most working people, but employers would no longer have to sponsor plans for employees to receive a tax subsidy. The proposal envisions a range of other organizations, from churches to unions, that would supplement traditional employer-sponsored health insurance by sponsoring health plans in tandem with an insurer that carries the insurance risk. Self-employed individuals or those temporarily out of the workforce, and employees of firms that do not sponsor insurance, could use the tax benefit to en ro ll in plans offered by such organizations or by health insurers. In the proposed system the tax exclusion for employer-provided health insu ra n ce and other health care tax benefits currently available would be replaced with a new refundable tax credit based on income and household health costs (both insurance premiums and out-of-pocket costs). The design of the tax credit would provide greater assistance to lower-income families and less assistance to higherincome families than today’s system of tax relief. It would also give much more assistance to those households that face unusually high medical costs, regardless of their income. The proposal would achieve horizontal equity: Households with the same income and medical expenses would receive the same tax benefit, whether they obtained coverage through their employer or another organization, or they purchased their own insurance and care. Low-income households could choose between two forms of tax benefit: a refundable sliding-scale tax credit based on total health expenditures as a proportion of family income, or a flat credit that,if desired, could be assigned to a chosen health plan in return for a reduced premium. Households above a specific income threshold could use only the sliding-scale credit. The federal credits could be supplemented with state subsidies, and the federal government would encourage state subsidies through a new federal grant to states. Money for the new system of tax credits would come from two sources: elimination of the existing tax exclusion and other health tax breaks and general tax revenues. Americans generally are resistant to sweeping change, so the proposal envisions a gradual transformation of the tax treatment of health care costs, beginning with the introduction of limited refundable tax credits for those without employer-sponsored coverage or who are unable to afford it. Thereafter, the tax exclusion would be reduced gradually, in line with the general availability of a more comprehensive system of tax credits (available for out - of - pocket medical costs, health savings accounts, and insurance). Employers would be required to modify their federal tax withholding procedures to reflect each employee’s estimate of the health credit available to him or her. Employers would also be required to set up an escrow account to make payments, deducted from employee compensation, to any plan chosen 24 by the employee that met the minimum government requirement. Working families would have to en ro ll in at least a minimum, catastrophic health insurance plan to be el i gi ble for the tax credit for any health costs. They could choose any approved plan in the area, unless their employer sponsored a plan, in which case they would have to join it to obtain tax relief. If an employee did not choose a plan,he or she would be enrolled in a default plan or program determined by the state. The federal government would establish a “default” system of health insurance regulation to encourage the availability of affordable insu ra n ce that could be purchased with the credit. The default system would include modified community rating for all plans with federally approved minimum benefits,and a change in federal law to create new forms of group insurance plans.States could choose either to adopt the federal default or to agree with the federal government on a functionally similar statedesigned rate regulation system. In addition, each state and the federal government would have to agree on a plan to eliminate uninsurance. The proposal envisions a market in which families obtain insurance from organizations with which they are affiliated, such as unions, churches, and similar groups; from their employer if that employer decides to sponsor coverage; from large insurers or managed care plans; or from health plans sponsored by large employers and offered to non-employees. Coverage and Eligibility Today’s tax code provides a number of tax benefits for health care intended to help working families to 1 For a discussion of the tax treatment of health care, see Grace-Marie Arnett (ed.). Empowering Health Care Consumers through Tax Reform. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan, 1999. John Sheils and Paul Hogan. “Cost of Tax-Exempt Health Benefits in 1998.” Health Affairs 18 (2): 178. 2 Sheils and Hogan estimate the average value of all federal health tax benefits for 1998 at $296 for families with incomes of $15,000 to $19,999 and $2,357 for families with incomes of $100,000 or more (Sheils and Hogan, p. 180). Although these averages exaggerate the differential between lower- and upper-income families with employersponsored insurance (since a higher proportion of lower-income families receive no tax benefits), the combination of lower-cost plans and a lower tax bracket means a large inequity for insured families. Workers without employer-sponsored insurance typically receive no tax benefits 3 obtain health care coverage. But the current system places severe limits on who can obtain tax help.1 By far the largest form of assistance is the exclusion from an employee’s income of employer-paid health insurance benefits. The value of all health care tax benefits (including reductions in payroll and income taxes) has been estimated for at . billion at the federal level and . billion at the state level.2 The design of the exclusion has been widely criticized as a highly inefficient and inequitable method of helping working families to afford health care.3 Since the exclusion is for insurance only, it also leaves lower-income employees vulnerable to high out-of-pocket expenses without any tax relief.4 And because the exclusion is only for employer-sponsored coverage, employees of firms without a health plan cannot claim the tax benefit if they pay for their own plan.5 The proposal would fundamentally change this tax treatment,using the tax code to direct assistance in a far more equitable and progressive way. It would create a tax subsidy system available to all working households of legal U.S. residents (other than Medicaid and Medicare enrollees, and those normally enrolled in state-sponsored programs). The tax exclusion available to employees for employer contributions to their health care plan or expenses would be repealed, as would other health care tax deductions available to taxpayers, and replaced with a fully refundable tax credit available to all individuals for health insurance and out-of pocket medical expenses.6 The credit could be used to help pay the employee cost of employer-sponsored benefits. Employers would continue to deduct health payments as a cost of labor. All individuals unless they are self-employed. Many employers do offer tax-free Section 125 accounts that reduce this problem. But Section 125 requires employees to agree to a payroll deduction to fund the accounts, and unused balances in the accounts revert to the employer at year’s end. This discourages most employees from using the accounts to shield from taxation all but the most predictable out-of-pocket expenses. 4 Taxpayers can claim a tax deduction for unreimbursed health expenses, but the taxpayer must itemize deductions and can deduct only amounts that exceed 7.5 percent of income. 5 In the proposal, fully refundable means the individual or family would be eligible for a subsidy from the federal government if the computed credit exceeded the family’s federal income and payroll tax liability. 6 25 currently receiving tax relief for employer-sponsored plans would be eligible for the credit,as would those working families without access to employersponsored coverage. Thus there would be no eligibility distinction among those receiving tax relief for health care. As noted in the discussion below regarding administration of the program, there would be mechanisms to deliver the credit to those who are moving between jobs or are unemployed. To receive the tax credit,the individual or family would have to purchase a health insurance plan that included at least certain minimum benefits. With the refundable tax subsidy available to all those not currently in a government program, along with a grant program for states to supplement the federal credit and a federal-state compact to make affordable group insurance more available (discussed below), the proposal would achieve near universal coverage. Structure of the New Subsidy Lower-income households would have a ch oi ce between two forms of tax credit—a fixed credit and a sliding-scale credit. Other households would be able to claim a sliding-scale credit. Fixed Credit Low-income families could claim a fixed credit for health care expenses, provided the family obtained at least the minimum insurance coverage. Eligible expenses would include insurance, direct spending on services, the employee cost of employer-sponsored plans,and contributions to accounts intended to cover health costs, such as medical savings accounts and employment-based flexible spending accounts. The credit would be , per adult and per child, up to a maximum of , per family. This fixed-credit option would be available to families with inc omes of up to ,, and to singles with incomes up to ,. There would be no phase-out for this credit. The fixed-credit option offers simple and predictable assistance for lower-income working families,although in most cases the family would receive more assistance by choosing the sliding-scale credit. It would be available only for families below certain income thresholds. The reason for this is that a fixed credit for all households would exceed the value of the sliding-scale credit and the value of tod ay ’s exclusion for most upper-income families, while the purpose of this approach is to concentrate health tax benefits on those families facing the greatest difficulty in affording health care. An individual or family eligible for the fixed tax credit could choose to assign it to a chosen health plan in return for a commensurate premium reduction. In this case the insurance company would adjust its own tax payments to the federal government to reflect the fixed-credit amount, while for tax purposes the enrollee would be deemed to have received the credit. This could be arranged through the workplace, as noted below, or directly with the health plan for self-employed or temporarily unemployed individuals. Of course, many families would not be certain whether their income would be below the thresholds for the fixed credit, but this is less of a practical concern than it might at first appear. As explained below, the place of employment normally would be the means through which plan choices, payments, and tax benefits would be channeled. The employer would inform the employee whether the basic wages or salary of the employee would make his or her family eligible for a fixed credit. If the employee discovered during the year that his or her income exceeds the threshold and so becomes ineligible for the fixed credit (because of a salary increase or overtime pay, for example), the employee would not actually have to cancel the assigned credit with his or her health plan, but simply factor the amount into his or her adjusted withholdings or end-of-year tax retu rn . In a few cases, some particular workers with rising incomes might receive slightly too much money under the fixed credit. But requiring individuals who just exceed the eligible threshold to calculate a sliding scale and return the difference would not be worthwhile. It is not necessary for advance payments made through the tax code to be reconciled perfectly at the end of the tax year, only that they be reasonably close (as a comparison, the standard deduction is a loose reconciliation that may 26 shortchange the taxpayer or the IRS occasionally, but has the advantage of simplicity).7 The Sliding-Scale Credit Both high- and low-income households would have the option to claim a fully refundable sliding-scale credit based on health expenses as a proportion of total income.8 Different families would qualify for a different credit amount for a year’s health costs, depending on their incomes, much like the child care credit in the tax code. Expenses eligible for the credit would be the same as in the fixed-credit opti on . As in that opti on , health expenses would include premium costs and out-of-pocket expenses. It would be calculated as follows, subject to a maximum credit of , per year for families and , for individuals: 9 Structure of the Sliding-Scale Credit Option Health costs up to % of adjusted gross income (AGI) % credit Health costs between % and % of AGI % credit Health costs above % of AGI % credit An income-related sliding-scale option would be more complicated than the fixed-credit option (although many families use such a sliding-scale credit for the cost of child care), but it typically would mean a larger subsidy, especially for those whose high costs accounted for a large proportion of their income. It can also be designed to avoid major tax changes for middle-income Americans who would lose their current tax exclusion. In addition, 7 For a brief discussion of the tax reconciliation issue, see Linda J. Blumberg. “Expanding Insurance Coverage: Are Tax Credits the Right Tack to Take?” Unpublished paper, The Urban Institute, Washington, DC, August 12, 1999, p. 18. The design of the proposed credit follows consideration and evaluation of a number of tax credit proposals, including various fixed-credit and percentage-credit as well as earlier sliding-scale credit proposals by the author and his colleagues at The Heritage Foundation (one of which formed the basis of legislation, S 1743, HR 3698, introduced in 1993 by Sen. Don Nickles [R-OK] and Sen. Cliff Stearns [R-FL]). See Stuart Butler. “A Tax Reform Strategy to Deal with the Uninsured.” Journal of the 8 the sliding-scale credit provides some age and geographic adjustment, because families in areas with relatively high insurance and medical service costs— or other workers facing higher costs—would be able to claim a larger federal credit. The dollar value of the credit also would rise over time in proportion to medical costs. Moreover, for many families, the credit could be estimated very accurately, because heavy medical expenses are not necessarily unpredictable. For instance, a family with chronic medical problems may pay the full stop-loss amount routinely each year and be able to project its out-of-pocket costs. Families below the income thresholds for the fixed credit would have the option of claiming whichever credit provided them with the most money. Those above the thresholds could claim the sliding-scale credit only. The thresholds are calculated to be just below the “break even” point for the great majority of families, meaning that the value of the fixed credit at the thresholds typically would be only slightly less than the value of claiming the sliding-scale credit. In most instances this avoids a sharp “cliff effect,” in which a small rise in income means a large drop in the value of the credit. State Subsidies The tax credit proposal is designed to be as compatible as possible with existing state programs, such as Medicaid, the State Children’s Health In su ra n ce Program (S-CHIP), and high-risk pools. It is not designed to replace them. New Federal Grant Under this proposal, the federal government would provide $ bi ll i on annually to the states to assist them in su pp l em en ting the federal tax credit for health-related expenses. In addition, each state American Medical Association 265 (19) (May 15, 1991); Stuart Butler and Edmund Haislmaier. “The Consumer Choice Health Security Act.” Issue Bulletin 186, December 1993; Stuart Butler. Expanding Health Insurance through Tax Reform. Menlo Park, CA: The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation, Kaiser Project on Incremental Health Reform, October 1999. A combined fixed credit/sliding-scale credit similar to the current proposal was introduced in July 2000 (HR 4925) by Rep. John Cooksey (R-LA). A limit is placed on the credit on the assumption that families facing extremely high health costs are helped best by a combination of a federal credit and other means, rather than solely by a formula credit. 9 27 would receive a grant amounting to the estimated federal taxes raised in the state from individuals who do not enroll in a minimum health plan and thus cannot claim the federal credit. State supplements would be especially important for low-income workers, such as most of those currently leaving welfare,and, when combined with the federal credit, could enable the worker to afford a reasonable level of health insurance. States are required by the welfare reform legislation to provide Medicaid coverage to certain families even though they do not receive cash assistance, and many states also take advantage of the flexibility under the legislation to continue Medicaid coverage for other working families. But data indicated that about percent of women who had left welfare since were uninsured.10 The federal credit, especially if combined with state assistance, would provide significant assistance to these low-income families, increasing their potential to afford the out-of-pocket cost of employer-sponsored insu ra n ce ,i f offered, or to purchase other coverage and services. With the federal credit and grant available, states would have greater flexibility to design the best option to deal with various groups of working families, such as combining the federal credit with S-CHIP or other subsidies, and taking steps to make insurance less expensive for workers with the tax credit. exclusion for employer-provided insurance would have led to an increase in federal tax revenues in of . billion11 and a projected . billion in .12 Of this, approximately one-third would be extra payroll tax revenue (. billion in Social Security tax and . billion in Medicare Hospital Insurance tax in ). While the state grant in the proposal would be a discretionary spending item, the federal credit would be a tax entitlement and not subject to the budget limitations that apply to discretionary programs. In other words, Congress would not have to vote for a specific budget amount each year for the credit. The net cost of the tax reform and new grant is envisioned to be between billion and billion annually. Approximately one-third of the tax revenue from the increase in taxable compensation resulting from the reform would be in the form of Social Security and Medicare taxes, and would not be available to fund a new health care credit. On the other hand, because this earmarked money would go into the retirement trust funds, there would be a reduction in the future amount of general revenue support needed to fund future retirement benefits. Thus, the equivalent amount of future general revenue could be allocated to help fund the tax credit. Financing While a simu l a ti on of the proposal has not been undertaken, analyses of other similar proposals reveal its potential impact on government and household finances and on coverage. Effect on Government Finances According to estimates by the Lewin Group, eliminating various health care deductions and the tax 10 Bowen Garrett and John Holahan. “Health Insurance Coverage after Welfare.” Health Affairs 19, (January-February 2000): 177. John Sheils, Paul Hogan, and Randall Haught. Health Insurance and Taxes. Washington: The National Coalition on Health Care, 1999, p. 47. This figure assumes that employer contributions to employee retirement health plans remain tax-free. 11 State finances would be affected by the proposal in four ways .F i rs t , those states with an income tax mirroring the federal code initially would realize a windfall increase in tax revenues, assuming they did not change their tax rules. The proposal assumes this m on ey is retu rn ed to state taxpayers. Second, by reducing uninsurance, the new federal credit would substantially reduce the burden on states of subsidizing hospitals and physicians for uncompensated Letter from John Sheils, the Lewin Group, to Robert Moffit, The Heritage Foundation, dated July 6, 2000, assessing the impact of legislation (HR 4925) sponsored by Rep. John Cooksey. 12 28 The proposed tax credit structure is designed, on average, to leave most middle-income families with little change in their tax liability. care. Currently Medicare and Medicaid disproportionate share hospital (DSH) payments amount to approximately bi ll i on , so if the federal program were not reduced, the states would have a windfall gain. Third,each state would receive a grant based on the federal government’s estimated savings due to individuals in the state who do not obtain the minimum basic insurance and thus cannot claim the federal credit. And fourth, the federal government would provide states with a total of billion to supplement the federal credit and reduce uninsurance. The objective of the tax credit proposal is to make a reasonable level of health care insurance and services affordable to all working households without incurring strong opposition because of a large increase in the explicit tax liability of any other income group. Under the proposal, the net income of a family after taxes and health expenses would be affected by four factors. First, the family’s taxable compensation would rise according to the size (if any) of the employer contribution to the worker’s health plan. Second, the family’s tax bill initially would rise because of this increase in taxable compensation. Third, the family might increase or decrease its health care expenses, depending on its preferences and whether it could cash out the employer contributi on . And fourth, the family would qualify for one or both of the refundable tax credit options. The bottom line for the family would be the net effect of these four factors. The proposed tax credit structure is designed,on average, to leave most middle-income families with little change in their tax liability. Upper-income households with high medical expenses also would not see a major change in their taxes. And many of those households that would pay significantly higher taxes would do so because they took more of their compensation in cash rather than health benefits— receiving, in effect, a pay raise. Lower-income families would be as much as , better off in federal tax benefits even if they decided to opt for the simple flat credit. But lower-income families with above-average total medical expenses could receive a larger amount of tax assistance through the refundable sliding-scale credit. For example,a family of four with , in income and , in health spending in any one year would qualify for a federal credit of approximately ,. But this family also would qualify for supplementary assistance financed by the federal grant to states as w ell as any other assistance the state provided. Administration of the Program: A New Role for Employers The place of employment is a particularly convenient and efficient venue through which to make insurance payments and handle other transactions (such as collecting federal taxes). The proposal envisions employers as the key clearinghouse for plan choices, tax adjustments, and payments associated with health care. But, unlike today, it would not require employers to organize or sponsor a plan, or make any contribution to the cost of coverage, for the employee to obtain tax relief. As noted below, for those heads of household who do not work for an employer, such as the self-employed and those between jobs, other mechanisms would apply for receiving credits and paying premiums. Unless the employer sponsored a plan, employees would choose their own plans,and could change jobs without changing plans. Moreover, the tax benefits would no longer depend on insurance decisions made by the employer. All employers would be required to undertake two key functions—delivering the tax credit to workers and paying premiums through payroll deduction. 29 Delivering the Tax Credit to Workers Employers would be required to inform the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) and the state which health plan (or state-sponsored program) each employee had selected, and to adjust the employee’s tax withholding to reflect the estimated value of the credit. This employment-based selection and financing mechanism has been suggested by a number of analysts.13 Withholding adjustments is the simplest way for most workers to obtain a tax benefit prorated each pay period, so they would not have to wait until the end of the tax year to receive their subsidy. For employees who elect to have their credit assigned to a health plan in return for a reduced premium, the tax withholding would reflect receipt of the credit. Since assignment would necessitate informing the IRS (via the employer) of the employee’s choice,the agency could decide whether to audit an individual who did not file a tax return. The great majority of households that do not have to file a return would fall under the maximum incomes eligible for claiming the fixed credit. It should be noted that all employed Americans (other than those in public programs) would be in the tax/premium withholding system. Thus, there would be no obvious distinction between upperincome workers receiving a small credit, and lowerpaid workers receiving more assistance through a refundable credit. Only the withholding amount would vary, as it does for employees today. This system would mean no separate arrangements or stigma associated with the program. Paying Premiums through Payroll Deductions The second legal obligation on employers would be to institute an automatic payroll deduction system for health insurance premium payments,structured much like the flexible spending plans many employers now maintain vo lu n t a ri ly. Once the employee selects a health plan and indicates the employer’s 13 For example, see Lynn Etheredge. Tax Credits for Uninsured Workers. Paper prepared for the Health Insurance Reform Project of George Washington University, September 1999. 14 Employers would not be required to accept amounts for out-of-pocket premium cost, the employer would be required to deduct a specific amount each pay period and place that amount in an escrow account. The amount would have to be enough to pay the premium, but also could include additional amounts, as today, to pay predictable out-of-pocket costs.14 Since the eligible tax credit also would be made available at each pay period, the employee would have the necessary subsidy available for the payroll deduction. If the employee did not select a plan voluntarily, the employer would assign that employee to a default plan or government program selected by the state and make a default payroll deduction accordingly. Selecting a default plan or program,as noted below, would be part of an agreement between the state and the federal government to achieve maximum coverage. The employer would be responsible for providing new employees with information from the government explaining the tax credit and payroll deduction system. Employees would have to sign a document stating they understood the system and indicating the plan in which they wished to participate. If they did not do so, the default plan assignment and payroll deduction would go into effect until the employer received information that the worker was enrolled in a state health plan or in an insurance plan elsewhere (such as in a spouse’s plan). There is good reason to believe that this mechanism would be efficient administratively and would lead to a high level of employee enrollment. Lynn Etheredge has proposed automatic workplace enrollment for a tax credit system and estimates that the administrative cost of insurance using such a system could be . percent, compared with administrative costs several times that for individual and non-employment small groups.15 In addition, evidence from savings plans suggests that an automatic enrollment system for health insurance could have dramatic effects on sign-up rates. Brigitte Madrian and Dennis Shea have found that a workplace-based costs, though employers currently offering flexible spending accounts probably would do so. 15 Etheredge, 1999, p. 6. 30 automatic en ro ll m ent system for (k) plans— where, to be excluded, the employee must actively decline to be included—boosted participation rates from percent to percent for such voluntary pensions, with even sharper rises for young and lower-paid employees (for employees with incomes below ,, the rate increased from . percent to . percent).16 In the health system proposed here, of course, individuals not actively making a ch oi ce would be assigned a plan or en ro ll ed in a state health program. This payment system is also very similar to the way in which the Federal Employees Health Benefits Program (FEHBP) enables a federal worker who may work in a small office,such as that of a member of Congress, to choose from dozens of plans. In the FEHBP, the worker tells the employer which plan he or she has chosen, but the payment details are handled by the Office of Personnel Management (OPM), which for this purpose functions like a payroll processing firm for the individual’s immediate employer. OPM functions as a clearinghouse, deducting premiums from each federal employee, pooling the money, and making payments to each health plan based on the total number of its government enrollees. Estimating the Cash Value of Employer-Paid Health Benefits Employer contributions to the employee’s health plan would be considered taxable income in the first instance, but also would be considered employee expenditures on health for purposes of calculating the credit. This raises the question of how to calculate the per capita value of a group health plan for tax purposes. While this cannot be done perfectly— and, of course, the current system hides large tax benefit inequities—it can be accomplished accurately enough in one of two ways adopted in the Nickles-Stearns legislation. One option is for firms to negotiate the cash value with their employees. This probably would be the preferred option in 16 Brigitte Madrian and Dennis Shea. The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) Participation and Savings Behavior. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 7682, May 2000, p. 51. unionized firms with a benefits contract or where an employer makes a defined contribution to an employee’s health plan. If the firm and its employees did not choose this option, a fallback formula could be developed by the state or federal government. The best such formula might be a structure of relative values for various categories of household composition and risk (such as family structure, sex, age, etc.) that matches the categories used in underwriting restrictions placed on plan premiums by the federal government (for plans covered by the Employee Retirement Income Security Act, or ERISA) or state governments (for plans regulated by the state). In this way the assessed value for categories of workers would reflect the relative premium costs of coverage for these risk categories in the state. This same method of calculation would be use d when a firm and its employees chose to end a sponsored health plan in favor of turning that fringe benefit into cash income that employees could use to enroll in other plans. A temporary “maintenance of effort” requirement could be applied, so that in the first year after ending a plan the employer would be required by law to add the plan’s value to paychecks, making the full compensation amount explicit as the basis for future pay levels. If an employee had chosen to be enrolled in family coverage obtained by a spouse working for another firm, and thus did not receive an employer contribution and was not part of the employer’s insurance group, there would be no taxable employer contributi on . As today, it would be up to the employee (or his or her union) and the employer to decide if these employees received a taxable supplement to income in lieu of the contribution. If the firm and its employees chose to dismantle their existing plan to permit employees to choose other plans, the cash-out value for workers would be calculated the same way. Employer-Sponsored Plans This proposal envisions that those employers that wish to sponsor insu ra n ce themselves (arranging plans for their employees or self-insuring under ERISA) could continue to do so. If a firm decided to do that, its employees would have to use the plans 31 organized by the firm as their primary insurance under the rules specified by the employer if they wished to claim the federal tax credit. Thus, to maintain stability in the insurance pool, employees of such firms would not have the right to opt out of the employer’s plan. These employers would still be required to arrange for a payroll deduction and adjust withholdings, as most already do. Many smaller employers today wish to contribute to their employees’ health care, yet they face organizational burdens and high administrative costs in providing insurance themselves or they cannot provide affordable coverage. 17 Those that do contribute by sponsoring plans often do so only because of the design of the tax code. The tax features of the proposal would give many of these firms the attractive option of making a defined contribution to an employee-chosen plan not sponsored by the employer. To be sure, some firms now sponsoring insurance would decide—in most cases with the support of their employees—to end plan sponsorship and switch to a defined contribution. But that form of “crowding out” would be more efficient and beneficial to employees, since it would entail more choices. Less desirable instances of crowding out that might destabilize a company’s risk pool would be reduced in two ways. First, the proposal requires employees to enroll in a company-sponsored plan if it is provided to all employees. Second, employees have the right to use their credit to offset the out-ofpocket costs of coverage for themselves or their dependents, which would make employer-sponsored coverage more affordable for many lowerincome workers who decline it today. A New Opportunity for Large Corporate Plans This tax proposal would remove the current tax barrier to large corpora ti ons marketing their health plans widely to non-employees. It is common for 17 In a recent survey, for instance, 27 percent of small employers (with fewer than 50 employees) offering dependent coverage reported that their employees declined it because of the cost (EBRI Issue Brief, no. 226, October 2000). As part of its strategy to improve and coordinate care for its own workforce, Deere created its own HMO. To make the most efficient use of its new health facilities, the company then contracted with other 18 large firms to take products initially developed as an internal service to the firm and market them to external customers, thereby deriving revenues from what had previously been an overhead cost for the f i rm . For example, G en eral Motors formed the General Motors Acceptance Corporation (GMAC) out of its huge automobile loan service developed to help sell its cars. GMAC has now branched out into a broad range of financial services, including home mortgages, because the tax system does not deny the mortgage interest deduction to someone obtaining a mortgage from a car company. But only a few large companies have explored marketing their health plans to non-employees, most notably John Deere.18 The employees of firms contracting with the Deere plan are still in an employer-sponsored plan,so they qualify for the tax exclusion. But the tax code does not give tax relief to individuals or non-employment groups signing up for the plan, and this has discouraged Deere and other companies from offering such coverage. The proposed tax credit would remove this obstacle, opening up a potentially large new market for existing corporate plans and an opportunity for many working families to obtain coverage under these plans. Incentive for Employer Contributions Under this proposal, the employer would continue to be the link to health coverage, and the employee would be obligated to enroll in a plan, so the proposal would not mean a reduction in employer involvement. Moreover, with this new tax credit for non-employer-sponsored coverage, there would be an incentive for many firms that do not do so today to make a financial contribution to insurance, since they could do so without the burden of sponsoring insurance, while still enabling their employees to enjoy the same tax benefits that would apply to sponsored insu ra n ce . Thus, while the tax conse- firms to enroll their employees in the Deere plan. The Deere plan is now offered to federal employees in some areas under the FEHBP, as well, and to some Medicare and Medicaid beneficiaries. In fact, out of more than 400,000 individuals enrolled in the Deere plan, less than 20 percent are John Deere employees. See Stuart Butler. Transcending EmploymentBased Health Insurance. Council on the Economic Impact of Health System Change, 1999, conference paper available at http://sihp.brandeis.edu/council/pubs/Butlertx.pdf. 32 qu en ces of an individual obtaining insurance through an employer or any other source would cause some employers to close down their health plan and convert the benefit to cash income, those same consequ en ces could induce these and many other employers to make a contribution to an “outside” health plan selected by the employee. Self-Employment and Transitions The credit would be adaptable for working-age individuals who are self-employed and for individuals either tempora ri ly not working or leaving other health programs. For example, self-employed individuals would furnish the IRS with evidence of insurance and make appropriate adjustments to their estimated tax payments. If a worker chose to remain in his or her former employer’s sponsored plan under the Consolidated Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act (COBRA), the credit would apply to the cost of coverage,as it would to any normal medical cost. If such a worker were selfemployed, or worked for a firm that did not offer insurance, he would recover the credit for COBRA coverage through quarterly tax payments or withholding. An unemployed person with an assigned credit similarly would face a reduced premium. If the person did not qualify for or choose the assignment option,he or she could obtain the value of the credit as an ad ju s tm ent to his or her unemployment compensation. The tax credit for unemployed workers could be paid through the unemployment insurance system. This would require a funds transfer between the Treasury and the Department of Labor, with the money then distributed to state unemployment offices (similar to the supplemental benefit programs delivered in this way since ). The state unemployment offices also could take on responsibility for remitting premium payments to insurers. Early retirees would also be eligible for the credit, while the value of their health benefits paid by their previous employer would be taxable,unless converted into a cash contribution and shielded from taxation in some other way. Administering the Program: Working with States to Make Insurance More Available Reforming the federal tax subsidy system to channel more assistance to those who need help to afford coverage and care is only half the equ a ti on . The other half is ensuring that attractive and affordable health plans are available to individuals and families. In theory a credit can work in an insurance system that charges for its services according to a market assessment of a person’s medical servi ce s and insurance risk. But this would require huge and carefully designed subsidies to certain individuals, and would be impractical. A more practical approach has two elements. The first is to develop a subsidy system ,l i ke the one above, designed to deal with the great majority of individuals based on their income and medical needs. The second is for the federal government to work with states to make sure that new and affordable plans are available to families within a stable insurance market, and that plans are affordable for people who remain high-cost “outliers” despite the subsidy system. This proposal seeks to do this through a federalstate partnership aimed at making available new kinds of group health plans at reasonable prices. To achieve this, the federal government would have to do three things. First, it would amend laws to create opportunities for new kinds of group plans. Second, it would make available grants to states under certain conditions to enable the states to reduce uninsurance by supplementing the federal refundable tax credit. And,third,the federal government would negotiate with states, during which a state could accept “default” federal insurance regulation and federally sponsored insu ra n ce groups, or it could implement, with federal approval, an alternative insurance arrangement designed to achieve the federal goals of reasonably priced health plans at reasonable prices and a reduction in uninsurance. Potential New Insurance Groups One of employment-based coverage’s central claims is that it is an effective way of forming relatively sta- 33 ble groups for insu ra n ce purposes. This is true to some extent, especially for larger firms, in part because the heavy tax bias today in favor of employer-sponsored insurance makes a firm’s workforce in effect a “captive” group. But the benefits of employer-formed groups have been exaggerated ,p a rticularly for small employers, and they come at considerable cost in terms of reduced ch oi ce ,“ j ob lock,” and other side effects. 19 Indeed, the problems of small employer-based groups have forced many states and insurers to create new groupings to achieve greater insurance stability, spread risk, and provide affordable premiums regardless of health status. This proposal thus does not envision individual insurance as the principal alternative to tod ay ’s employment-based coverage. For one thing, forming people into groups for insurance purposes achieves administrative economies and is a means of spreading risk. But, in addition, an intermediary institution can negotiate with insurers or providers in the interests of group members. This intermediary function is necessary to achieve efficiency and satisfaction in a market where the consumer is not typically a sophisticated buyer. S ti ll , to achieve satisfaction and efficiency for the consumer, the goals of the intermediary must coincide with those of the consumer. For such reasons this proposal envisions the encouragement of other kinds of groups,particularly for individuals who do not have access to employer-sponsored insurance or for whom a group centered on the place of employment is not ideal. Four types of groups are particularly attractive alternatives to traditional employment-based covera ge : Affinity Groups. Several common institutions in American communities are well placed to serve this function for insu ra n ce . For example, unions as “f ri en dly societies” have had a long history of involvement in health care in the United States and elsewhere. Many unions are active in the organization of multi-employer health plans under the Taft- Ha rt l ey Act. Union plans also flourish in the FEHBP, in some cases offering associate membership to non-union members. Many religious denominations also have a long history of providing insurance services for their congregations.20 For lower-income African Americans and others, the church is a far more stable institution in the community than loc a l ,s m a ll employers, and one that has the long-term social welfare of families firmly in mind. In addition, the Catholic Church and other denominations sponsor networks of hospitals. Since churches, like unions and many other groups, routinely communicate with their members by mail, these intermediaries also present a lower-cost “piggyback” means of marketing health plans and reducing administrative costs. This proposal does not envision these alternative groups acting as insurers themselves, but instead as buying agents that reach agreements with insurance plans that actually shoulder the risk. These organizations would form the group of purchasers and receive a fee from the insurer for performing marketing and management functions. This is the arrangement used by such organizations operating in the FEHBP. Other affinity g roups, such as farm bureaus and professional associations, exist in part to negotiate insurance packages for their members, but such groups face significant limitations that restrict the role they can play. A major impediment is the tax law, which denies tax benefits to most people who obtain coverage through groups not closely associated with their employment. (Where that impediment does not apply, such as to union plans in the FEHBP, alternative groups play a major role.) In addition,state-level benefit mandates and insurance regulations discourage many affinity groups from offering health insurance. Associations. Various employment-related associations have arisen to group people together to obtain insurance without the employer directly 19 Uwe Reinhardt. “Employer-Based Health Insurance: A Balance Sheet.” Health Affairs 18 (6): 124–32. the 20th century, but were forced out of existence largely by tax-subsidized employer plans and, later, by Medicaid; see David Beito. From Mutual Aid to Welfare State. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina, 2000, chs. 9, 10. Fraternal organizations, many of them church-affiliated, were a major source of health insurance (and even capitated health plans) earlier in 20 34 sponsoring coverage. These include health purchasing cooperatives and coalitions (HPCs) and multiple-employer welfare arrangements (MEWAs), and they also face restrictions at the state level that affect their insurance arrangement and benefits. There have been proposals in recent years at the federal level intended to create new kinds of associations that would be free from many state restrictions, particularly state benefit mandates. The most important of these are HealthMarts and association health plans. While these proposals do raise concerns about their potentially disruptive impact on existing state efforts to devise affordable insurance groups because of possible risk selection,they could be vehicles for lower-cost group coverage.21 Federal Em pl oyees Health Benefits Program (FEHBP). While technically an employment-based system, the FEHBP actually serves the equivalent of a small country (with nearly million covered individuals) and offers a broad choice of plans. While a federal worker’s immediate employer does not sponsor plans, the place of employment is still the “entry point” for selecting plans, much like the process envisioned in this proposal. FEHBP plans are regulated at the federal level, through a combination of general statutory and administrative regulation supplemented by a process of nego ti a ti on between the Office of Personnel Management, on behalf of the federal government,and plans wishing to market through the FEHBP. Premiums are community rated, but costs and benefits vary widely.22 The FEHBP operates parallel to the systems for workers outside the federal government. There have been several proposals to open up the FEHBP to non-federal workers under various conditions, typically using a separate insurance pool.23 Large-Employer Plans. As noted earlier, the current tax laws discriminate against large corporations offering their health plan coverage to non-employees. Another major limitation on this opportunity is A Federal “Default” System of Insurance Regulation This proposal recognizes that stimulating the creation of new forms of group coverage not sponsored by employers involves two challenges. The first is to create an environment in which such alternatives are fostered, principally by removing any barriers to such plans. The second is to tackle the concern that such groups would be disrupted by the pressures of adverse selection. Under the proposal the federal government would enact legislation to help make new forms of group insurance more widely available and affordable in each state. Each state would have the choice of allowing this federal structure to supplement or replace its own system of regulation, or proposing its own package of changes to achieve the same objectives as the federal structure, perhaps incorporating some of the federal steps. The federal government then would negotiate with the state on the final regulatory arrangement, withholding the proposed grant and applying some or all of the federal set of changes if there was not complete agreement. The federal legislation would address four areas: . Premium regulation. ERISA and the Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act (HIPAA) would be amended to include limitations on underwriting and to establish a minimum set of benefits. Currently HIPAA establishes certain minimum protections for enrollees in federal- and stateregulated plans, including those under ERISA. It establishes a minimum,which states can exceed,and it allows states to propose alternatives for certain provisions that can be accepted as sufficient by the federal government. 21 For a discussion of the issues associated with such proposed new associations, see Elliot Wicks and Jack Meyer. Small Employer Health Insurance Purchasing Arrangements: Can They Expand Coverage? Washington: National Coalition on Health Care, 1999. 25–39; Stuart Butler and Robert Moffit. “The FEHBP as a Model for a New Medicare Program.” Health Affairs 14 (4); Craig Caplan and Lisa Foley. Structuring Health Care Benefits: A Comparison of Medicare and the FEHBP. Washington, DC, AARP Public Policy Institute, May 2000. For a description of the FEHBP, see Harry Cain. “Moving Medicare to the FEHBP, or How to Make an Elephant Fly.” Health Affairs 18 (4): 23 22 that the Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) does not protect such plans from state regulation unless they are made available to the employees of other ERISA-protected firms, or through federal programs such as the FEHBP. For instance, Senator Bill Bradley made such a proposal in his presidential campaign. 35 Federal law would be amended to encourage new types of group coverage. In particular, large affinity groups and associations would be permitted and protected from state regulation. The proposed federal legislation would amend ERISA and HIPAA to require a minimum set of benefits in all plans for which the new federal tax credit could be used. Unless states negotiated alternative arrangements, they could not prevent plans containing these minimum benefits from being marketed, provided the plans met other applicable state and federal requirements. In addition, ERISA and HIPAA would be amended to require that all plans, including plans in the individual market, limit underwriting so that premiums for any particular plan option could vary at most only by age, sex, geography, and family type, and not by such factors as health status. As noted, this would go into effect unless a state negotiated an alternative arrangement with the federal government. Plans could place more limits on premium variation either voluntarily or under state regulation. The narrower premium variations typical in ERISA plans—chiefly by family type—would meet that requirement. . New types of group plans. Federal law would be amended to encourage new types of group coverage. In particular, large affinity groups and associations would be permitted and protected from state regulation. Federal law governing the FEHBP would be amended to permit a separate insurance pool for non-federal employees. Plans currently available in the FEHBP would be allowed to market to the new pool, if they wished, and other plans could market exclusively to the new pool, provided they met the general requirements of the FEHBP. While the current FEHBP is community rated, the premiums of plans offered to non-federal workers in particular would have to comply with the federal underwriting requirements specified above or a rating system agreed to between state and federal government. In addition, the plans offered to non-employees by ERISA-regulated companies would be regulated under ERISA rather than under state law. . A new grant program for states. Congress would enact a new grant program, discussed earlier, for states to supplement the federal tax credit to achieve near-universal affordable health care coverage. The grant program would contain two sets of funds:One would be based on the estimated value of the federal tax benefits unclaimed by those who did not purchase minimum insurance, and the other would be a $ bi ll i on grant each year available to states on the basis of a federally approved state plan to reduce uninsurance according to agreed-on goals by making choices of affordable plans available in the state. . A federal-state compact. At least some of the federal reforms would go into effect unless a state proposed an agreeable alternative arrangement likely to achieve the same ultimate goal of affordable coverage for families eligible for the federal tax credit. A state might propose alternative premium rating requirements for non-ERISA plans and benefit requirements that made lower-cost plans widely available in the state. It could create a high-risk pool, and so reduce the need for underwriting restrictions. Furthermore, it could propose the use of state programs, including direct services through clinics and other facilities, to accomplish the equivalent of insurance coverage for some types of households. The state might also propose a modification of the federal law to permit the FEHBP and association plans to be made available in the state to integrate these new alternatives into its current insurance system. New group plans and premium restrictions would raise concerns about adverse selection. For this reason the proposal also envisions the federal government working with states to experiment with new ways to limit this problem. This might take the form of high-risk pools and/or a reinsurance market. In reinsurance the health plans themselves buy insurance against ending up with an unusual portfolio of risk. In ad d i ti on ,s t a tes and the federal government could experiment with retrospective risk-adjustment pools in which plans pay amounts into the pool based 36 on their enrollment and receive money from the pool based on the actual paid claims of their enrollees.24 An additional federally chartered national reinsurance pool or set of regional reinsurance pools could act as a final reinsurer between the cooperatives. A share of the $ billion federal grant would be available to states on reaching agreement with the federal government. The amount would be based on the costs of insurance and services still faced by lower-income households after they had received the federal credit. For these families, the grant could be used to reduce the cost of coverage, such as by subsidizing high-risk pools or by supplementing the federal credit. This proposal envisions states receiving a bonus if they achieve the objectives in the agreement, and losing some funds if they do not. This federal-state compact approach is similar to the approach taken in some provisions of HIPAA and the welfare reform legislation. In each case states could propose alternative means of achieving the federal objective,thereby avoiding certain provisions of the new federal law. In the welfare reform legislation, goals were set for reductions in welfare dependency, with bonuses available to those states that meet or exceed the agreed-on goal. An additional obligation of a state, as a condition of receiving the federal grant, would be to identify a fallback private health plan and/or government program for any employed individuals (and their dependents) who did not select a specific plan at their place of work. Employers would enroll automatically in the plan those employees who did not choose an alternative plan containing the minimum required coverage. Are Institutions Capable of Carrying Out their New Administrative Functions? The federal and state governments, as well as the private sector, would have a number of administrative obligations under the new program. For a review of the issues involved in blended approaches to risk adjustment, see Linda J. Blumberg and Len M. Nichols. “Health Insurance Market Reforms: What They Can and Cannot Do.” Urban Institute, 1998. See also Joseph Newhouse. “Risk Adjustment: Where Are We Now?” Inquiry (Summer 1998). 24 The Federal Government Administration of the proposed program would be shared by federal and state governments, but with key roles for employers and insurers. The Treasury, through the Internal Revenue Servi ce , would administer the federal tax credit. For the vast majority of individuals, the vehicle for distribution of the credit would be the normal withholding process by the employer, with the amounts reconciled in tax returns. Some small modification of the worksheets for withholding and tax returns would be needed. The Treasury would need to monitor individuals assigning their fixed credit to a health plan,especially those who did not file income tax returns, but this would not place significant additional requirements on the Treasury. There would need to be coordination between the Treasury and the Department of Labor to deliver the value of the credit to unemployed individuals through the state unemployment insurance system. If premium payments also were handled through unemployment offices, the Labor Department would have to remit credit and premium payments to an individual’s chosen plan. This would be a new obligation for the department, handled through local employment offices. In addition, the Labor Department would be the principal federal agency monitoring employer compliance with the requirements for establishing payroll reduction plans and remitting premiums. The Health Care Financing Administra ti on (HCFA) would be a logical choice to broker agreements with the states and to monitor these agreements, and to be responsible for changes in federal insurance rules. But it would be impossible for the agency to undertake these responsibilities with its current resources and bureaucratic culture—HCFA has been unable to carry out several responsibilities assigned by Congress properly because of a lack of resources. The experience of implementing and enforcing HIPAA indicates shortcomings at HCFA in data collection, oversight, and guidance of states. HCFA also has been unable to handle its obligations under Medicare. The ne w requirements in this proposal represent yet another reason to overhaul the agency. The Labor and 37 Treasury departments, responsible for some provisions of HIPAA, also have some weaknesses, though much less serious ones.25 A possible solution to HCFA’s inability to carry out many of the proposed new functions would be to combine these functions with structural reforms already proposed for Medicare. Such Medicare proposals include creation of a “Medicare Board,” separate from HCFA, to manage a system of competing health plans. The board would be modeled on the Office of Personnel Managem en t’s role in the FEHBP, leaving HCFA to focus on the traditional fee-for-service Medicare program. Establishing the board is seen as a way of creating an agency with a very different staff and culture from HCFA—one that would create and manage competitive markets. Given that the federal functions under the proposed tax credit system would be similar to those of a Medicare board—establishing conditions for affordable plans to exist in a competitive market—it might be possible to include them in a widened role for such a board. States New responsibilities for states would accompany the additional funding available through the new federal grant to states. After negotiating a plan and goals to reduce uninsurance, a state would have to develop a mechanism to supplement the federal tax credit for eligible workers and to deal with those who did not purchase minimum insurance and had a plan or program selected for them. States with an income tax might choose to use the employmentbased state tax withholding system to deliver such a supplement. Otherwise they would have to devise an alternative automatic system, such as payments to insurance companies, or enable households to claim assistance directly from the state. In cooperation with the federal government, states also would be responsible for administering the credit and premium payment functions for the unemployed. Supplemental benefit programs and temporary programs to provide supplemental cash benefits have Karen Pollitz, Nicole Tapay, Elizabeth Hadley, and Jalena Specht. “Early Experience with ‘New Federalism’ in Health Insurance Regulation.” Health Affairs 19 (4) (July/August 2000). 25 been delivered in this way since the s. A similar process could be created with the unemployment insurance system to pay health insurance premiums for unemployed Americans; with additional administrative funding to defray the costs,the same system could be used to provide con ti nu ed health insurance coverage. To meet their agreed-on goal of reducing uninsurance,states would have to use the additional federal funds to expand existing programs—or develop new ones—to achieve targeted levels of coverage. In addition, they would have to work with insurance companies to devise ways of introducing modified community rating along with a reinsurance and/or risk-adjustment system. This proposal envisions the states having the flexibility to accomplish these goals. In addition,each state would have to specify a default enrollment system for those employees of firms in the state who did not indicate a preferred plan to their employer (and were not covered under a spouse’s plan or a government program). Employers New obligations on employers would not be onerous. Employers would be required to inform their employees about the tax credit program and to make available the necessary federally produced en ro ll m ent forms. Employers already have to arrange tax withholding, so they merely would have to adjust that amount according to a worksheet to include the credit in their withholding calculations. Employers also would be required to provide the IRS with proof of insurance for each worker, which could easily be done by sending on an insurance statement received from the insurer. Fu rt h er, employers would have to set up accounts for payroll deductions to be placed for employees and make payments from these accounts to health plans. For large employers this would be similar to creating flexible accounts. For small employers it would be a new obligation, but a small one that could be carried out routinely by a payroll firm.26 26 See Butler, October 1999. 38 Insurers Insurers would face several new requirements that would add to their costs, but there would be significant administrative savings associated with the automatic enrollment system. Among the new costs would be the requirement to bring premium rates into line with federal or state underwriting and benefit requirements. In addition, the insurance industry and the states would have to work together to develop a mechanism to adjust risk among plans. That would be a major and costly undertaking, but in many states it would be a continuation of experiments already underway. Encouraging Households to Obtain Coverage Under the proposal a condition of employment for workers would be to tell their employers which health plan they wished to join, or to accept enrollment in the default plan or program chosen by the state. There are several reasons to assume that there would be a high level of voluntary compliance with this con d i ti on of employment, and that the selfemployed and those not regularly employed would choose to enroll in a minimum plan at least. Automatic Enrollment Indicating insurance coverage and adjusting withholdings for the credit would be a routine feature of employment, with individuals indicating their plan ch oi ce when they are hired or during an annual enrollment period. As noted earlier, evidence from pension plans suggests that even a voluntary automatic enrollment system can increase participation s h a rp ly, especially among younger and lowerincome workers. With a law requiring employers to enroll those employees who do not choose a specific plan in a default plan, there would be a strong incentive for employees to take the time to make an active choice. If unemployment offices made it simple for en ro ll m ent and tax subsides to con ti nu e between jobs, coverage also would likely be high among the short-term unemployed. Loss of Tax Benefits Any individual successfully avoiding enrollment in a minimum plan would lose significant tax benefits, not just for insurance, but for any health care product or service, from prescription charges to the cost of well-baby visits. In addition, particularly for selfemployed individuals who would not be assigned a default plan by an employer, the IRS could deny a personal exemption to those who do not include in their tax returns proof of year-round coverage. Individuals Who Could not Afford Insurance Of course, some individuals might feel unable to afford basic covera ge , despite the subsidy and the requirement to choose a plan or be enrolled in a default plan or program. For example, they might refuse to pay any costs associated with the default plan. Others with low incomes or who are selfemployed might fail to enroll in a plan despite the subsidies available. In these cases the state would have to decide how best to address the needs of these individuals. Since the state would receive a grant to supplement the federal tax credit, it would have funds to help families pay for insurance and sign up at the workplace or to deal with the family’s needs in other ways, such as enrolling the family in a state-based program. In addition, the state would receive a federal grant equal to the estimated value of federal tax credits left unclaimed by those who did not obtain coverage. A Basic Benefits Package To qualify for the tax credit, families would have to enroll in a health plan that includes at least a minimum insurance package, although the credit would be available for insurance and out-of-pocket costs that exceed the minimum. The federal government would establish a benchmark plan with basic features and catastrophic protection that would apply to federally regulated plans. As part of their compact with the federal government, states would have to incorporate this minimum into their insurance regulations or propose an actuarially equivalent minimum. This proposed federal minimum should not be 39 confused with proposals to establish a federal requirement for comprehensive coverage and specific benefits. The basic plan is intended to provide minimum, primarily catastrophic insurance protection,not comprehensive coverage. The vast majority of households would choose more extensive coverage, but requiring typical coverage as the required minimum would make insu ra n ce prohibitive to lower-income families, as the experi en ce of state mandates has demonstrated.27 In addition, the minimum would be in the form of broad areas of covera ge , such as hospitalization and major medical, similar to the requirements for plans in the FEHBP or the California Public Employees’ Retirement System (CalPERS), rather than a precisely defined set of specific benefits, such as Medicare fee-forservice. CalPERS operates much like the FEHBP, but for California state employees. For a minimum plan to meet the conditions for the credit, it would have to match the federal base plan’s broad features, and its benefits would have to be at least equivalent to the federal benchmark in actuarial terms. The Process of Reform The New Program and American Values The proposed new system of insurance has a radically different dynamic from today’s arrangement, yet its link with the place of employment fits in with the familiar aspects of today’s system that most Americans are loathe to abandon. Since enrollment and the financial transactions associated with insurance would continue to be at the place of work, it would look very much like today’s system. In several respects, however, the new system would be much more in line with the general American view of economic rel a ti onships and health care than is today’s employment-based sys- Melinda Schriver and Grace-Marie Arnett. “Uninsured Rates Rise Dramatically in States with Strictest Health Insurance Regulations.” Backgrounder 1211, Washington: The Heritage Foundation, August 14, 1998. 27 28 A recent poll conducted for the Democratic Leadership Council, for instance, found 72 percent support for a proposal to give employees the option of receiving a tax break if they chose to “purchase their health care through an outside organization such as the AARP, union, a church, or a community-based purchasing co-op instead of through their tem. For one thing, most workers would have far more choices than they have now. In addition, they would own their own policy as individuals or members of a group. This would give families far g reater consumer control over their insurer, and insurers generally would have the same incentive to satisfy enrollees (rather than their employer) as plans do in FEHBP. Workers who are not in employer-sponsored plans also could obtain their insurance through intermediaries they trust to protect their interests, rather than having to deal directly with insurers in the individual market. Americans have indicated, through their support for patients’ rights legislation and in responses to surveys, that they want the government or another intermediary to exert some control over health insurers. They also have indicated that churches, unions, and other such organizations are often more attractive intermediaries than employers. 28 The proposed system would remove many of the obstacles that make it difficult for families to obtain coverage through these groups. By delinking tax benefits and employer sponsorship of i n su ra n ce , the proposed system would achieve the true portability Americans want. Workers typically would be able to remain with their chosen health plan, even when they change jobs, merely by informing their new employer of their existing plan when they sign on for the required payroll deduction and tax withholding. Getting from Here to There Americans are nervous about radical change in their health care, including sudden changes in the tax treatment of their benefits, even if in all probability the change would be to their advantage. To address this,the proposal could be introduced in stages,over a long period, to make the transition as gradual and employer.” If given that option, half the respondents said they would choose it; see Mark J. Penn. “Health Care Is Back.” The New Democrat Blueprint (Spring 2000): 70, 71. Other surveys indicate similar support for non-employment groups as vehicles for insurance, and a recent poll of women conducted for the Center for Policy Alternatives indicated that 72 percent of women would like their health insurance to be independent of their employment (Women’s Voices 2000, Center for Policy Alternatives and Lifetime Television, Washington, DC, 2000). See also “Focus on Women.” The New York Times (September 27, 2000). 40 Because the proposed system would operate through the place of employment, it would have the major political advantage of not appearing to be a major departure from the existing familiar arrangement. politically feasible as possible. New refundable credits for households without access to employer-sponsored coverage already have been proposed in Congress and would be the logical first step. The second step would be to introduce the new state subsidy program, probably as an amendment to S-CHIP, to enable states to supplement the credits with federalstate funds. The second step also would require employers to administer the payroll deduction system. The third step would be for the federal government to modify HIPAA and ERISA, and to work with the state governments to introduce rating restrictions, basic benefits, and a risk-adjustment system. With plans available based on these regulatory changes, it would be more feasible to implement the core tax reform, which would replace the tax exclusion with a comprehensive tax credit system. Political Feasibility The purpose of this proposal is to achieve universal coverage in a way that relies on markets and choice rather than new government programs. To do so would change the way most health care for working households is subsidized through a major reform of the tax treatment of health care. But while the vision of change is comprehensive, one must acknowledge that Americans are reluctant to embrace radical change that disrupts familiar arrangements. Therefore, the actual introduction would have to take place in stages, each one explained clearly and extensively to build public support. Because the proposed system would operate through the place of employment,however, it would have the major political advantage of not appearing to be a major departure from the existing familiar arrangement. But the tax credit approach has other political advantages. For example, the basic idea already has broad bipartisan support. Major tax credit bills have been introduced regularly in Con- gress since , and several were introduced in the th Congress or put forward as proposals by groups of members of widely differing political persuasions. Both presidential candidates in also embraced tax credits as a part of the solution to uninsurance. While the proposal would place new requirements on states, it also would help to relieve the burden on states caused by uninsurance and uncompensated care. The federal credit itself would reduce the incidence of uninsurance, and states could combine it with their own subsidies to enable families to afford coverage, thanks to the new federal grant to state s .O f co u rs e ,m a ny states might not like federal preemption of insurance regulation and the obligation to meet targets for reductions in uninsurance, but they would have the flexibility to modify their own regulations to achieve the targets, and the new federal grant would be a clear inducement. The recent welfare reform experience indicates that the combination of agreed-on targets,flexibility, and financial awards to states can be a political winner, and a similar approach is incorporated into this proposal. There no doubt would be a range of reactions among insurers and health care providers, but the tax credit approach has already won strong support among such key groups as the American Medical Association and the National Association of Health Underwriters. This approach also has been gaining ground among associations representing managed care plans and insurers. Larger employers and unions traditionally have opposed changes in the tax code that would finance alternatives to the traditional employer-based system, fearing they would cause employer-sponsored insurance to unravel. But industry support is growing, in part because recent tax credit proposals have included protections for employer-sponsored coverage, and in part because of an increasing recogni- 41 tion of the limitations of employer-sponsored coverage, especially for employees of small firms. The U.S. Chamber of Commerce, for instance, now supports an income-related tax credit, as well as expanding ERISA to facilitate insurance pools based on associations and community-based organizations. The additional paperwork requirements in the proposed system would be only a minor change for most mid-size and larger employers, but would be seen as burdensome by many small firms. The requirement to assess the cash value of employersponsored benefits would be more problematic for employers, both because of the burden of making the calculation and because of concern about employee reaction to varying total compensation for employees with the same total income. So far, the major unions have continued to oppose tax-based initiatives, even though many of them actually operate plans that could prosper under a tax credit system. But emphasizing the protections for large employment-based plans negotiated by unions, and the opportunities for new unionsponsored plans in the service and small-business sector, could reduce this opposition. Conditioning tax relief on obtaining a minimum plan would make no practical difference to most families, since they either have or want good coverage. What would cause more consternation is taxing employer-paid benefits, even with a new tax credit. The idea of restricting or eliminating the tax exclusion to raise government revenues has been proposed several times and has encountered strong opposition. But this proposal contains clear advantages to employees contemplating new taxes on a previously tax-free fringe benefit. They would qualify for a credit that in most cases was approximately the same as their current exclusion or larger, thanks to the sliding-scale nature of the credit and the additional tax expenditure. Moreover, the tax change would allow families new tax relief for out-of-pocket costs, so there would be a visible benefit every time a person visited the doctor or paid for a prescription. And even though upper-income workers generally would face a net tax increase, in many cases this would be because of a conscious decision to take more of their compensation in cash income rather than fringe benefits. Thus the tax change would be an attractive swap for most workers. Other Issues Cost and Efficiency This proposal likely would increase pressures to use medical services efficiently and to control costs. For one thing, eliminating the exclusion and making employer subsidies explicit would spur employees to consider value for money much more carefully and to exchange unnecessary benefits for cash. The exclusion has long been recognized as encouraging wasteful overinsurance by middle- and upperincome families. For another, giving workers the opportunity to join large groups outside the place of work would sharpen plan competi ti on and allow workers in small firms, usually with costly and inefficient covera ge , to join more efficient plans. Making it more possible for families to join plans that reflect their preferences also would improve economic efficiency. Efficiency also would be improved by reducing the administrative costs currently associated with plans covering individuals or group plans serving the employees of small firms (including the high costs borne by small employers in arranging insurance). The proposal envisions many workers now in very small employer groups switching to much larger non-employment groups. Small employers currently providing insu ra n ce also would face lower costs in their new role. The potential reduction in administrative costs is difficult to estimate; it would depend on the types of plan that emerge. In estimating versions of the Heritage Foundation proposal, the Lewin Group assumed administrative costs of percent of benefit costs, based on plans covering large numbers of people in the individual market.29 The FEHBP market suggests that costs could be much lower. Others have estimated that, with automatic workplace enrollment and payments, the administrative costs of a tax credit system could be a low as . percent.30 29 Sheils et al., 1999, p. 45. 30 Etheredge, 1999, p. 6. 42 In any event, if large groups formed in the market, with enrollees coming from today’s individual and small-group market, the average administrative costs of insurance would tend to fall. Subsidies to low-income families for affordable insurance would encourage more Americans to leave welfare and unemployment permanently by removing a major obstacle to long-term private employment in the small-business sector. The system would have some marginal effects on work effort because of the credit design. But,although the sliding-scale credit does include a traditional phaseout mechanism, the cost/income ratio determining the marginal credit percentage leads to only a gradual reduction in the value of the credit for a given amount of health spending as income rises. The equivalent effective marginal tax rate for the credit phase-out drops at particular incomes, or bend points,as income rises. The rate also declines for any income level as expenses rise. For a family of four with , worth of expenses, for instance, the rate is . percent for incomes up to ,, declining to . percent for incomes of ,. Achieving Greater Equity Tax-based approaches of this kind sometimes are seen as less efficient because part of the tax expenditure goes to households that are insured already. Currently some three million workers and dependents purchase some level of health insurance, even though they are unable to claim tax relief. Moreover, if tax credits were available to offset out-of-pocket costs associated with employer-provided plans, many other insured families would be able to claim additional tax relief. Hence the cost per newly insured individual typically would be higher than approaches that restrict services or program eligibility only to those who are uninsured. A key objective of tax-based approaches to uninsurance, however, is to reduce the large inequities in the current tax treatment of health care costs. If a policy aim is to provide similar levels of assistance to families with the same income and health needs, similar subsidies must be provided to families currently with or without insurance. To do otherwise would discriminate against families that had taken steps to protect not only themselves but also their community by reducing the likelihood that they would incur medical expenses they could not pay. Moreover, the argument that a tax credit approach would mean subsidizing people who are already insured is not unique to this approach. Any program designed to assist individuals without insurance is bound to crowd out some existing insurance if the program is more generous. That is why Medicaid expansions and other efforts by states to cover uninsured families lead to at least some erosion of employer-sponsored insurance. If the equitable allocation of subsidies is an objective, this effect cannot be avoided. Quality of Care While the quality of care available to families under the proposal would depend on many factors, it is possible to make some observations about probable effects. One is that the wider coverage resulting from the reform would mean that many more Americans would receive their care through plans that monitor their health, rather than through emergency rooms and occasional visits to the doctor. Second,most families would have greater choice of plans than they do now, and thus could select plans that better meet their medical needs. Third, a more consumer-driven market would lead to more usable information that enables families to pick more appropriate plans, because plans would be under greater pressure to satisfy enrollees (rather than their employers). Increased choice and competi ti on in a market makes it more economical for third parties, such as consumer organizations, to obtain and distribute information to prospective enrollees—a phenomenon seen in the FEHBP. n 43 Feder, Levitt, O’Brien, and Rowland Approach Key Elements Judith Feder, Larry Levitt, Ellen O’Brien, and Diane Rowland outline an expansion of Medicaid and the State Children’s Health Insurance Program (S-CHIP) and explore its interaction with tax credits for individuals or employers. Specifically, they conclude that: - is best achieved by extending eligibility for public programs without cost sharing or premiums to all individuals with incomes below percent of the federal poverty level, and, as in S-CHIP, extending eligibility for public programs with modest premiums and cost sharing (up to a maximum of percent of income) to people with incomes between percent and percent of poverty. People with incomes above percent of poverty could also be allowed to “buy in” to public coverage by paying a sliding-scale premium based on income. to small, low-wage employers for providing coverage to their employees is a more effective and less disruptive complement to a public program than a tax credit directed at individuals to purchase non-group coverage. 44 About the Authors , .., is Professor and Dean of Policy Studies at Georgetown University. Over three decades, Feder has published extensively on financing for both health and long-term care.She has also served in policy leadership positions—specifically, as staff director of the Congressional Pepper Commission (chaired by Senator John D. Rockefeller IV) and, during the first Clinton Administration,as Principal Deputy Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation at the Department of Health and Human Services. Feder is currently Vice Chair of the Academy of Health Services Research and Health Policy; senior advisor to the Kaiser Commission on Medicaid and the Uninsured;and member of editorial boards for several health policy journals. A political scientist (B. A.from Brandeis,Ph.D. from Harvard),she is a member of the National Academy of Public Administration and of the National Academy of Social Insurance. As a senior scholar at Georgetown’s Institute for Health Care Research and Policy, Feder’s current research projects include co-directorship (with Sheila Burke) of a Kaiser Family Foundation project on incremental health reform and of a Robert Wood Johnson Foundation project on long-term care financing. , ...,is Vice President and Director of the Changing Health Care Marketplace Project and California Health Policy for the Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation. Before joining the Foundation, Mr. Levitt was a senior manager with The Lewin Group, where he advised public and private sector clients on health policy and financing issues. He previously served as a Senior Health Policy Advisor to the White House and Department of Health and Human Services, working on the development of President Clinton’s Health Security Act and other health policy initiatives. Prior to that,he served as the Special Assistant for Health Policy with California Insurance Commissioner John Garamendi— where he co-authored Commissioner Garamendi’s “California Health Care in the st Century” proposal—and as a medical economist with Kaiser Permanente. He also served in Massachusetts state government. He holds a bachelors degree in economics from the University of California at Berkeley, and a masters degree in public policy from Harvard University’s Kennedy School of Government. ’, .., is Assistant Research Professor at Georgetown University’s Institute for Health Care Research and Policy, where her current research focuses on trends in health insurance coverage and options for coverage expansion. In addition, she is examining issues related to employer decision-making about health benefits and the role of health insurance in labor markets. Dr. O’Brien is also a member of the teaching faculty in the Georgetown Public Policy Institute. Before coming to Georgetown in , she was a researcher at the Health Care Financing Administration where her work focused on long-term care in Medicare and Medicaid. Dr. O’Brien has an M.A. in Economics from the University of Iowa and a Ph.D in Economics from the University of Notre Dame. , .., is Executive Vice President of the Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation and the Executive Director of the Kaiser Commission on Medicaid and the Uninsured. She is an adjunct Associate Professor in the Department of Health Policy and Management at the School of Hygiene and Public Health of the Johns Hopkins University. Dr. Rowland serves on the Board of the Academy for Health Services Research and Health Policy, the Secretary’s Task Force on Infant Mortality, and the Commonwealth Fund Task Force on Health Insurance for Working Americans. She is a founding member of the National Academy for Social Insurance, Past President of the Association for Health Services Research, and a Brookdale Senior Fellow. Dr. Rowland specializes in issues related to health insurance coverage, access to care, and health care financing for low-income, elderly, and disabled populations. She has published widely on these subjects and is a noted authority on health policy, Medicare and Medicaid. 45 Assessing the Combination of Public Programs and Tax Credits by Judith Feder, Larry Levitt, Ellen O’Brien, and Diane Rowland Overview Intrinsic to any proposal to expand health insurance coverage is taking a position regarding the coverage that already exists.One set of proposals aims directly at replacing current coverage, creating new mechanisms that would apply to the already insured and to people who have no insurance. These proposals often place as much emphasis on equity—for example, ensuring that all low-income people receive equivalent government subsidies, regardless of how they are insured—as on decreasing the number of people who are uninsured. Another set of proposals aims more narrowly at the uninsured, but affects the already insured indirectly (and sometimes unintentionally) with the incentives and mechanisms newly put in place. Our approach resembles the second set of proposals in its focus on the uninsured. But, unlike either of the above sets, our objective is the retention, not disruption, of existing coverage—specifically, publicly provided and employer-sponsored health insurance. We adopt this strategy not because we think that these mechanisms have no flaws; we recognize that flaws exist. However, we are concerned that there is more to lose than to gain from disrupting them—particularly for low-income people whose coverage is our primary concern. Simply stated, our goal is to expand coverage for those without it and to “do no harm” to coverage mechanisms now in place. In the absence of comprehensive health reform aimed at universal coverage, we suggest that the following principles should guide the design of incremental efforts to decrease the number of uninsured Americans: • New dollars spent on health insurance should be targeted to significantly expand coverage. • Coverage should be expanded to the uninsured without disrupting coverage already available in the public and private sectors. • Expansion should begin with,and place priority on, coverage for those uninsured who are least able to pay. To satisfy these principles, we argue that, for the low-income uninsured, the most effective approach to expanding coverage is to extend the Medicaid and State Children’s Health Insurance Program (S-CHIP) eligibility now available to children and some parents to all low-income individuals. Because the lowestincome population is least able to purchase health insurance on its own, this public program should have the highest priority as a claim on federal dollars. Fo ll owing the Medicaid/S-CHIP approach would mean extending eligibility for comprehensive benefits at no cost (as in Medicaid) to all individuals with incomes below percent of the federal poverty level, and extending benefits with some premiums and cost sharing (as in S-CHIP) to individuals with incomes between and percent of the federal poverty level. People with incomes above percent of poverty could be allowed to “buy in” to public coverage by paying a sliding-scale premium based on income. Although public programs are the most appropriate way to extend coverage to the low-income population,they could be combined with tax credits to reach the uninsured who have modest incomes. In such a combination, careful attention is needed to en su re that any tax credits complement rather than su b s ti tute for existing public and private sources of coverage.A number of policy makers and 46 analysts have proposed tax credits that could be used by individuals to buy non-group insurance. Making such a tax credit non-refundable—thereby targeting it pri m a ri ly to those with incomes in excess of percent of the poverty level—would mitigate conflicts with public coverage. Even so, it is difficult to design a modest, non-refundable individual tax credit that is effective and well targeted, while at the same time avoiding disruption of existing employer-sponsored insu ra n ce . For example, allowing application of an individual tax credit to employer coverage would significantly reduce the risk of displacing that coverage, but it would also likely substantially increase the cost of the credits with payments to the already insured. Because it could be better targeted, a more effective approach to combining a public program expansion and a tax credit might be a health insurance tax credit provided to employers, rather than to individuals. It could be targeted to those small ,l ow wage businesses least likely to offer insurance today, maximizing the focus of public dollars on improving access to employer-sponsored covera ge . Although employer tax credits have the disadvantage of leaving people with modest incomes dependent on their employers’ willingness to expand covera ge , this downside may be more than balanced by the upsides of better targeting and less disruption. The following discussion begins by explaining the risks posed by disruption of either employersponsored or publicly sponsored covera ge , then examines the reasons,in the current policy environment, for reliance on more than one policy instrument to expand coverage. We then make the case for expanding public coverage and explore the issues raised by pairing that expansion with a tax-based approach. We conclude with a discussion of specific design issues raised by the public and private components of a combined strategy. Why Avoid Disruption? It is hard to disagree with a critique of the nation’s current mix of insurance mechanisms as insufficient, inefficient, and inequitable. However, to advocate replacing these mechanisms with something else pre- sumes the political wherewithal to achieve comprehensive reform and the political and administrative wherewithal to devise an improved system. Experience warrants skepticism on both counts. Over the last century, periodic efforts to achieve comprehensive reform have encountered significant political obstacles. The most recent effort, in –, was obviously no exception. There are various obstacles, but high on the list is the concern of those who already have insurance coverage that they will be worse, not better, off under reform. Proponents of the Clinton administration’s Health Security Act argued that the plan would secure health insurance for all Americans. But critics successfully countered that the plan would dramatically alter, indeed undermine, coverage of the already insured. The plan that claimed to benefit everyone came to be seen as likely to benefit the uninsured minority, while making the already-insured majority worse off. It is not clear that an alternative policy and political strategy—one that claims from the outset to benefit only the uninsured—will be more successful. After all, it will require explicit recognition of the need to redistribute resources from those who have insurance to those who do not. But given the political problems generated by the fear of disrupti on , it seems worth trying a more targeted approach. Moreover, when the aim of policy is incremental change—which is the most likely scenario in the near term—the need to minimize disruption becomes even more important, because the gains are not large enough to justify the risk of losses for those who are already insured. Minimizing displacement requires attention to the policy and political advantages of both existing employer-sponsored and publicly sponsored covera ge . Not only do most Americans gain coverage through employment, but polls also indicate that they value that approach, despite changes in the structure of employment and the dissatisfaction that has accompanied changes in employer-sponsored insurance over the last decade.1 From a policy 1 Kaiser Family Foundation and Harvard School of Public Health. PostElection Survey: The Public and the Health Care Agenda for the Next Administration and Congress. Menlo Park, CA: Kaiser Family Foundation, 2001. 47 perspective, the strongest advantages of employersponsored insurance are its administrative efficiencies (including practically automatic enrollment of employees) and its significant,if not total,spreading of risks across people of different incomes and health status. Employer coverage is particularly valuable to low- and modest-wage workers, because it provides for easily accessible enrollment and compensates for cash flow problems that would arise if workers had to shop on their own. Although the tax preference for employersponsored insurance is frequently criticized as “inequitable”—and its direct monetary benefits are, in fact, skewed to those who are better off— it also serves as an appropriate incentive to achieve efficient risk pooling. Despite rhetoric to the contrary, there is little or no evidence that newly created administrative structures can replicate the effectiveness of employers in effectively pooling risks.2 To disrupt employer coverage without confidence in a reasonable alternative ultimately puts the scope and adequacy of coverage in jeopardy. There is also a significant risk to disruption of public coverage—that is, coverage provided by the Medicaid and S-CHIP programs. Medicaid, in particular, has been criticized as being more discouraging than inviting of participation, whether by beneficiaries or providers. But barriers to participation likely have more to do with Medicaid’s meanstested eligibility and the implementation of that means test than with something peculiar to the Medicaid program. States’ dramatic expansion of Medicaid coverage at the end of the s, and their more recent implementation of S-CHIP, indicates that a public program’s attractiveness, or the ease or difficulty of participating in it, reflects policy ch oi ces that are an essential part of any program, new or old.3 The fact is that low-income people will always need more public support than the rest of the pop- ulation if they are to have affordable access to coverage and services. Medicaid’s -year history of providing health insurance to segments of the low-income population has established both administrative and legal structures that protect beneficiaries’ rights to benefits and care. Proposals to replace Medicaid may offer far less support than Medicaid currently provides—whether in benefits, administrative arrangements, or legal foundations (including enforcement of federal entitlements). And creation of new federally financed subsidy mechanisms for the uninsured—even if they ostensibly leave Medicaid untouched—may encourage political pressure to weaken existing protections. (As discussed below, enactment and implementation of S-CHIP raise precisely that possibility.) Just as it is appropriate to question whether new adm i n i s tra tive stru ctu res can ef fectively rep l ace employer-sponsored insurance, it is also appropria te to qu e s ti on wh et h er new ad m i n i s tra tive and subsidy structures can effectively replace Medicaid. Jack Meyer et al. Tax Reform to Expand Health Coverage: Administrative Issues and Challenges. Menlo Park, CA: Kaiser Family Foundation, 2000. The following discussion draws on: Judith Feder et al. “Covering the Low-Income Uninsured: The Case for Expanding Public Programs.” Health Affairs (January/February 2001); Diane Rowland, Rachel Garfield, Christina Chang, and Barbara Lyons. Building on Medicaid to Cover the Low-Income Uninsured. Washington: Kaiser Commission on Medicaid and the Uninsured, forthcoming. 2 Donna Cohen Ross and Laura Cox. Making It Simple: Medicaid for Children and CHIP Income Eligibility Guidelines and Enrollment Procedures. Kaiser Commission on Medicaid and the Uninsured, 2000. 3 Why Rely on More than One Policy Instrument? 4 The population without insurance is not a homogenous group. Differences in peoples’ circumstances or characteristics do not necessarily require the use of different policy strategies to reach them. But different policy strategies will be more or less effective in reaching different segments of the uninsured population (for example, those with lower versus higher incomes). Currently, tax policy has gained some political popularity as a strategy to expand coverage— targeted specifically to low- and modest-income people. President Bush campaigned in favor of such a policy, and various proposals for targeted credits have been put forward by both Democrats and 4 48 Republicans in Congress.5 The appeal of tax preferences to provide subsidies appears to be the potential to operate with minimal government involvement. In theory, people could apply by filing tax returns, rather than applying to a government office, and they could choose a plan on their own, rather than relying on plan options selected by a government agency. However, three factors make this strategy problematic for low-income people. The first factor is the tax system’s limitations in reaching the low-income uninsured. About half of people without health insurance do not file an income tax return or owe any income taxes.6 To reach them at all, an income tax credit would have to be refundable—that is, available without regard to tax liability. The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) is a refundable tax credit that has been enormously successful in enhancing income for the working poor. However, it is harder to support the purchase of health insurance than to b oost income. Tax credits, including the EITC, are typically refunds—money the taxpayer gets back at the end of the year. To buy health insurance, people with limited incomes need the cash in advance. Further, they need to know they can keep the money, even if their income changes. Advance payment and nonreconciliation of income and subsidies at year’s end would require significant departures from current tax practices—practices seen as ensuring the accuracy and efficiency of the tax system. The second factor is problems with the market or insurance products that such a credit could buy. About percent of the uninsured lack access to employer-sponsored insu ra n ce , whether through their own jobs or the jobs of family members. Credit recipients without access to employer coverage would be dependent on access to the non-group insurance market to obtain coverage. But that market is riddled with problems. To avoid adverse selection,insurers use practices to avoid enrolling people likely to use services. Except in a few states with comprehensive regulation, insurers can deny people access; exclude coverage for services, conditions, body parts, or body systems; and charge whatever premiums they deem appropriate. As a result, people pay more when they get sick and can lose access to coverage. Overall, benefits in the non-group market are quite limited (often excluding maternity benefits, prescription drugs, and mental health, and typically using significant deductibles or benefit caps). The fact that people insured in the non-group market are no less healthy than people with employer coverage demonstrates the effectiveness of insurer practices in controlling access to coverage by people in relatively poor health.7 The third factor is the questionable adequacy of the tax credit. The most prominent proposals involve tax credits that fall far short of the cost of health insurance (for example, a , credit for a family, when the cost of a typical family insurance policy typically exceeds ,). Clearly, the lower a person’s income, the less able that individual is to make up any difference between the credit and the cost of an insurance policy. For some or all of these reasons, even some proponents of tax credits recognize that a public program is better than using the tax system to reach the low-income uninsured. Building on existing public programs has two fundamental advantages. First and foremost is the extension of an adequate subsidy for an adequate product—that is, a subsidy for the full cost of comprehensive insurance to people with limited incomes. Second is the existence of an administrative apparatus in every state to determine eligibility for subsidies in advance and to facilitate enrollment in health insurance plans. Medicaid and S-CHIP programs—which now serve about million people—have contracts in place with providers and managed care plans (indeed, they are public managers of private markets) and have established mechanisms for collecting and matching funds from the federal government. Although recent Randall Weiss and Mark Garay. Recent Tax Proposals to Increase Health Insurance Coverage. Menlo Park, CA: The Kaiser Family Foundation, 2000. 7 John Holahan, Unpublished analysis of Medical Expenditure Panel Survey, 2000. 5 6 Jonathan Gruber and Larry Levitt. “Tax Subsidies for Health Insurance: Costs and Benefits.” Health Affairs (January/Feburary 2000). 49 The conclusion that a public program is the appropriate mechanism for reaching the low-income population means that if a tax strategy is to be pursued for those with higher incomes, it should complement, not substitute for, a public program. attention has focused on barriers to participation in public programs,a decade ago attention centered on the speed of Medicaid enrollment expansions in response to changes in federal law—from . million people in to . million in . And, although a year or two ago enrollment in S-CHIP seemed to be expanding slowly, all states have dramatically expanded income eligibility standards for children—above percent of poverty in states—in recent years.8 The conclusion that a public program is the appropriate mechanism for reaching the lowincome population means that if a tax strategy is to be pursued for those with higher incomes, it should complement, not substitute for, a public program. Issues at the Intersection of Public Programs and Tax Policies The likelihood and form of a combination of a tax credit and a public program will depend on the political process. But the effectiveness of such a combination—in expanding coverage with minimal disrupti on — wi ll rest on answers to some strategic design questions. Should the Two Instruments Be Parallel or Layered? Establishing a tax credit alongside existing or new public coverage might seem, on the surface, to offer individuals an attractive ch oi ce of how or where they wish to obtain covera ge . However, given the complexity of the health insurance market, and the difficulty of obtaining information for meaningful comparison-shopping within it, it is reasonable to doubt whether competing mechanisms constitute meaningful consumer choice. 8 Ross and Cox, 2000. This doubt is reinforced by the incentives states would face if tax and public programs existed side by side. Medicaid expenditures are always high on the list of state fiscal concerns, and Medicaid costs are once again rising faster than state revenues.9 A tax credit could enable states to justify a contraction of Medicaid and S-CHIP coverage on the grounds that alternative subsidies were available for use in the private market. And, from the state perspective, these subsidies would have the advantage of being financed at federal, not state, expense. Successful substitution of federal credits for state/federal public programs would mean both a shift from state to federal expenditures and a decline in the benefits and stability of health insurance provided to lowincome people. Given the incentives, establishing tax credits alongside public programs can be seen as establishing a choice for states,more than it does for individuals. The result may be to undermine rather than enhance protection for low-income people, especially if (as is likely) the tax credit option is significantly less comprehensive than public coverage. To secure and extend health coverage for low-income people, layering a tax credit on top of a public program—that is, targeting each policy instrument to a different income group within the uninsured population—is a more effective approach. How High up the Income Scale Should Eligibility for Public Coverage Extend? Public programs for the low-income population offer comprehensive benefits at little or no cost to beneficiaries, reflecting an emphasis on en su ri n g affordability of coverage and services for people with limited ability to pay. With the cost of private 9 National Association of State Budget Officers and National Governors Association. The Fiscal Survey of States: December 2000. 50 insurance at about , per adult and , per family, on average, the income level at which full or nearly full subsidies are arguably necessary to ensure affordability is relatively high. Expenses at this level are clearly beyond the means of people with incomes at the federal poverty level (, for an individual, , for a family of four). Indeed, even at incomes of t wi ce that level, a premium would absorb more than percent of family income. Hence, an argument can be made for extending public coverage to incomes up to and even above double the poverty level. However, as income rises, so does the proportion of people with employer-sponsored insurance. At incomes below percent of the federal poverty level, only percent of the population has employer-sponsored insu ra n ce . By contrast, at incomes between percent and percent of poverty, percent of the population has employer-sponsored coverage, and at incomes between percent and percent of poverty, percent has it.10 In a sense, these modest-income people who have coverage are actually paying for it, whether by forgoing income they would otherwise receive in wages or by paying actual out-of-pocket premiums. Whether people between one and two times poverty are perceived as able or unable to “afford” premiums and cost sharing, therefore, depends on whether the focus is on the percent who actually have coverage, or on the roughly percent not offered coverage (who would be expected to pay for coverage explicitly out-of-pocket instead).11 The scope of employer-sponsored insurance among people with incomes above the federal poverty level raises the additional question of how to balance affordability of coverage for low- and modest-income individuals with displacement of private coverage as public coverage is expanded. While the majority of employers offer health insurance to their workers, many also complain about its costs and administrative burdens. Some have talked a bo ut providing cash payments in the form of a 10 Paul Fronstin. Sources of Health Insurance and Characteristics of the Uninsured: Analysis of the March 1999 Current Population Survey. Washington: Employee Benefit Research Institute, 2000. “defined contribution” rather than sponsoring health insurance coverage. Despite a likely preference among employees for employer-sponsored over publicly sponsored coverage, availability of a public program at higher-income levels would create incentives for employees to choose free or nearly free public coverage over employer coverage that might require a substantial premium contribution. It also might create the opportunity for employers—particularly employers whose employees earn relatively low wages—to drop coverage entirely. Indeed, concern about crowd-out, as it is popularly described, led Congress to limit el i gi bi l i ty for SCHIP to children in families with incomes of up to percent of poverty who lacked employer coverage. In establishing eligibility levels for a program expansion, experience and analysis indicate the importance of careful attention to the potential disruption of employer coverage. How Big Should a Tax Credit Be, and to What Kind of Coverage Should It Apply? The concern about employers dropping coverage is clearly not limited to public program expansions. Departures from the provisions of current tax policy that favor the purchase of health insurance through the workplace instead of coverage purchased individually in the non-group market would perhaps be even more likely to induce employer dropping and employee switching than would public expansions. The likelihood that dropping would occur depends on the scope of a new tax policy. Making premium payments for non-group coverage tax deductible—widely advocated on equity grounds—would partially neutralize the current tax preference for employer coverage, though the benefits of pooling and lower administrative costs would remain. Extension of a tax credit for non-group insurance—more generous in many cases than a deduction—could actually create advantages to purchasing outside the workplace, especially for those employees who are young and healthy and, 11 Estimates from the 1996 Medical Expenditures Panel Survey, provided by Mark Merlis, Insitute for Health Policy Solutions. 51 thus,able to get favorable premiums. The more generous the tax credit, the more willing employees would likely be to seek coverage outside the workplace, and the more likely employers would be to drop sponsorship of health insurance. The potential for employers to drop coverage can be mitigated if new tax credits are applicable, not just to the purchase of non-group coverage, but also to worker payments toward employer-sponsored covera ge . The application of credits toward employer-sponsored coverage is also advocated on grounds of equity—treating individuals with similar incomes similarly, regardless of how they obtain their insurance coverage. However, allowing credits to be applied toward employer coverage will significantly increase the costs of an intervention, because in firms that already offer coverage,credits will go to the bulk ( percent) of workers who accept coverage,12 along with the minority who do not. Indeed, such an approach should not be seen as preventing substitution of public for private dollars; rather, it constitutes an explicit substitution of public for private dollars to achieve equity and to secure existing employer-sponsored coverage. A policy ch oi ce on this issue will clearly depend on the total dollars available and the willingness to spend on the already insured, as well as the newly insured. Can Subsidies for Public and Private Coverage Be Integrated Smoothly? A policy that layers a tax credit on top of a public program must pay particular attention to administrative and equity issues that arise at the intersection of the two policy instruments. For example,a policy that abru pt ly terminates eligibility for relatively comprehensive public coverage that is available at little or no cost at a specific income level creates a cliff: people with incomes below the specified level get a lot, while people with incomes just ab ove that level get nothing. That is, in fact, the way eligibility for both Medicaid and S-CHIP currently works. Clearly, extension of a tax credit mitigates this 12 Estimates from the 1996 Medical Expenditures Panel Survey, provided by Mark Merlis, Insitute for Health Policy Solutions. cliff, because it creates benefits above the eligibility level for public coverage. The more generous the tax credit, the less steep the cliff becomes. One way to think about establishing the size of the credit, then, is to set it so that the amount of out-of-pocket spending it requires recipients who are just above the limits of eligibility for public coverage to pay for private insurance is similar to the out-of-pocket spending toward public insurance expected of people whose incomes are just below the eligibility limit. The value of the credit, relative to the cost of premiums, could then decrease as income rises. The desire to smooth out cliffs in subsidies, however, must be balanced against the desire to avoid providing a tax credit—particularly one for non-group insurance only—that risks disrupting existing employer coverage. Smooth integra ti on also requires attention to the availability and characteristics of i n su ra n ce products. If no changes are made in the private insurance marketplace, some people who are eligible for a credit may be unable to find or afford coverage—given insurance practices that limit access to or set prices for insurance based on people’s age, health status, or other factors.13 One way to address this problem would be to regulate the insurance market by establishing rules affecting both access and price. Another would be to establish a new publicly managed market in which insurance products are made available to all potential purchasers (for example, a purchasing cooperative). A third would be to allow people above the eligibility level for public coverage to “buy in” to the public program—that is, pay a premium from their own resources to obtain publicly sponsored coverage (not really so different from a purchasing cooperative, because most Medicaid and S-CHIP programs now provide coverage to families though private health plans). Making the tax credit applicable toward—and, indeed, equal to—the premium for publicly sponsored coverage would further smooth any transition. Of course, when establishing a buy-in to a Deborah J. Chollet and Adele M. Kirk. Understanding Individual Health Insurance Markets: Structure, Practices, and Products in Ten States. Menlo Park, CA: Kaiser Family Foundation, 1998. 13 52 public program—or a purchasing cooperative, for that matter—one has to pay careful atten ti on to how it relates to the private insurance market to ensure that it does not turn into a dumping ground for high-cost individuals. The design choices actually made in each of these areas clearly have enormous implications for the cost, effectiveness, and administrative operations of any initiative that combines a public program and tax credits. And, as is often the case in policy making, design ch oi ces will require tradeoffs. Choices made to smooth integration, for example, may run counter to choices made to minimize substitution or disruption. Following is an array of possible choices. Establishing a Public Program The most effective way to reach the low-income people who are now uninsured would be to extend protections that are now available to some of them to all low-income people. Currently, Medicaid concentrates primarily, and S-CHIP almost solely, on lowincome children. Although Medicaid covers women while they are pregnant, and states have the option to include parents, in states uninsured working parents are ineligible for Medicaid if they work fulltime at the minimum wage.14 Further, low-income, childless adults, no matter how poor, are ineligible for coverage under federal law unless they qualify as disabled. To reach the entire low-income uninsured population,an initiative would make income, rather than family status,the sole criterion for eligibility. Such a public program extension must address a number of other policy issues, as outlined below. Eligibility The extension of eligibility for comprehensive benefits at virtually no cost to all individuals with incomes below percent of the federal poverty level would en su re affordable coverage with little threat to current employer coverage. Employers Jocelyn Guyer and Cindy Mann. Employed But Not Insured: A State-byState Analysis of the Number of Low-Income Working Parents Who Lack Health Insurance. Washington: Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, 1999. 14 now cover only about percent of the population with incomes below the federal poverty level and only percent of the population with incomes between percent and percent of the federal poverty level. Although the proportion with employer coverage rises at higher income levels (about half for people between and percent of poverty), to truly ensure access to affordable coverage, eligibility would have to go beyond this very poor group. One approach would be to build on public policy decisions that have already extended coverage to children in families with incomes up to percent of the federal poverty level and apply a similar policy to their parents and other adults. As in S-CHIP, it might be appropriate to apply some premiums and cost sharing in the income range between and percent of poverty (up to a maximum of percent of income). And (if resources allow) it would be desirable—on equity grounds—to avoid current S-CHIP rules in many states that deny coverage for a period of time to those who have had employer-sponsored coverage (consistent with current Medicaid policy). Finally, to ensure a smooth transition for people with higher incomes,it may be appropriate to allow individuals with incomes above percent of poverty to buy into the public program by paying a slidingscale premium based on income. Federal/State Roles Extension of public coverage requires consideration of the way federal and state governments share financing and authority. Medicaid (and S-CHIP) is a federal/state matching program, under which the federal government offers to match state expenditures to entice states to provide more coverage than they would on their own. The matching formula provides more federal money (raises the matching rate) for states with poorer populations. States accepting federal funds are required to abide by federal rules for eligibility, benefits, administration, and other aspects of program operations. Over the years, provision of federal matching funds has helped to expand coverage. But matching funds (without minimum federal eligibility standards) have not achieved uniform coverage across 53 Given the priority we place on covering the low-income uninsured, the most effective approach to expanding coverage is to extend the Medicaid and S-CHIP eligibility now available to children and some parents to all low-income individuals. states, nor have they miti ga ted states’ discomfort with applying rules that reflect federal priorities. In , Congress decided to achieve greater uniformity of coverage by phasing in a floor on eligibility levels for children—requiring states to cover children in families with incomes below percent of poverty as a condition for receiving any Medicaid funds. Above the floor, eligibility levels continue to vary. In , states had extended eligibility under Medicaid or S-CHIP to children with incomes above percent of the federal poverty level, while in eight states, eligibility standards were below percent of poverty. Variation is wider for parents, where no federal floor exists. Ei gh teen states extend eligibility for parents to incomes above percent of the poverty level, but states limit eligibility to parents with incomes below percent of the federal poverty level. Variation in eligibility across states reflects not only the reluctance of some states to spend, but also their reluctance to extend programs that are expected to comply with federal rules—as a condition for receipt of federal money. Rules affect benefits, provider payment,a host of administrative arrangements, and—as discussed below—beneficiaries’ “entitlement” to benefits. In recent years, states have successfully sought waivers from and elimination of rules that limit their ability to manage the federal dollars they receive according to state, rather than federal, priorities. To overcome state reluctance, SCHIP legislation explicitly increased federal matching rates and expanded state flexibility (on benefits and, as discussed below, establishment of an individual entitlement). Creation of a new public program aimed at covering adults would confront similar issues of limits on certain states’ willingness to spend and to operate under federal requirements. Simply making federal funds available at Medicaid matching rates to states willing to cover childless adults—who are ineligible under current federal law, regardless of income—might lead to coverage expansions by some states. But other states—particularly those that do not even take advantage of the existing option to cover parents of Medicaid children—are likely to respond only to an increase in federal matching rates or, perhaps, full federal funding. And a uniform response undoubtedly would require establishment of a federal floor (as former President Clinton proposed to apply to coverage for parents,if states failed to act). Without such action, any new coverage initiative would likely produce considerable variation in coverage across states. Entitlement vs. Block Grant Perhaps the most fundamental conflict over rules attached to federal matching funds has been whether the new coverage constitutes an individual entitlement (as with Medicaid) or a benefit provided at the discretion of the state (as with S-CHIP). Medicaid funds are available only as a federal entitlement—that is, everyone who satisfies eligibility requirements is guaranteed covera ge . Under Medicaid, federal financing follows the individual. Although states can establish eligibility levels, determine how easy or difficult it is for people to participate, and affect how generous or restricted benefits and access to care are, they cannot deny coverage to an eligible individual. By contrast,S-CHIP is a block grant that provides capped federal funds to states and allows them to choose whether to create an individual entitlement. States can choose to use the new federal funds to expand Medicaid, thereby creating Medicaid-like obligations to individuals (and assuring access to federal funds at the regular Medicaid matching rates if the cap is exceeded). But, if they prefer—as many have—states can create sepa ra te programs in which they can cap enrollment and receive a capped federal allotment to help pay for services. 54 This aspect of S-CHIP’s design was a critical element of the political compromise believed to be necessary both to enact the S-CHIP legislation and to ensure state participation. However, deterioration of economic circumstances, rising health care costs, and strained state budgets could lead states to limit en ro ll m ent by establishing waiting lists. To states concerned about existing, let alone new, coverage commitments, the option under S-CHIP that permits states to receive federal funds without an openended coverage guarantee is far more attractive than Medicaid’s open-ended entitlement. The existence of S-CHIP makes it likely that states would seek a similar option under any extension of public programs. It is ironic that the absence of a federal entitlement in a public program expansion would contrast sharply with the creation of a federal entitlement to any new tax credit. Under federal law, anyone who qualifies for a tax credit is entitled to receive it; obligations cannot be capped. A tax credit, like Medicaid, is a federal entitlement (albeit to a dollar amount, rather than to a defined set of benefits). If Congress is willing to establish tax credits as entitlements—as is the case for all other tax subsidies— consistency would suggest a similar approach to the expansion of public coverage. Establishing a Tax Credit along with a Public Program Expansion An individual tax credit aimed at people with incomes too high to qualify for public coverage— above, say, percent of poverty—could reach its target population without requiring any significant va ri a ti ons from standard tax practices. At this income level, tax liabilities are generally high enough to make refundability unnecessary, and individuals could simply apply for the credit retrospectively when they file their taxes. Cash flow problems are less severe than for lower-income populations, or they can be mitigated easily by making funds available through standard tax withholding mechanisms (which people in this income range are accustomed to using, for example, to account for mortgage interest). If the goal were to assure individuals with in- comes above percent of the poverty level that they would have to pay no more than percent of their income for coverage—the maximum level under S-CHIP—tax credits in the range of , for an individual and , for a family (phased out gradually as income rises) would be required. However, credits of this amount could prove disruptive to employer covera ge , and smaller amounts would provide a smoother transition from public coverage than exists today. Policy issues posed by establishing an individual tax credit include the following: Ensuring Access to a Market or Product Given that the bulk of uninsured individuals with modest as well as low incomes lack access to employer coverage,most of the beneficiaries of a tax credit will be dependent on the non-group or individual insurance market. Expanding that market may mitigate, but will not eliminate, the risk selection and instabilities it creates. These probl em s could be addressed by regulating access to and premiums in the non-group market. However, efforts to enact such regulations have run into enormous barriers—both political and technical—at the state and federal levels.A frequently proposed alternative to regulation is to make tax credits applicable to premiums paid to a publicly managed insurance market, in which access, benefits, and premiums are regulated. Medicaid could legitimately be considered such a market, given many state programs’ reliance on private insurance plans. Allowing credits to be used in Medicaid would assure individuals eligible for a credit that a product was indeed available to buy. However, allowing a buy-in to Medicaid in the absence of broader regulation—or creating a new insurance arrangement to accomplish the same thing—would likely increase the costs of a public program. The program is most likely to attract higher-risk and more costly individuals who are likely to find public protection a better buy, given the underwriting practices of insurers. An extra subsidy toward the premium for public coverage would be necessary to ensure affordability for this population; indeed, it could be thought of as a mechanism for spreading risk with a broad source of financing 55 Balancing Access and Disruption Deciding who gets how much of a tax credit would determine the degree to which a credit would disrupt existing coverage. With respect to public covera ge , a decision to make the tax credit non-refundable—in other words, to layer a tax credit on top of a public program by design—avoids the problem of encouraging states to substitute tax credits for public programs. Hence, disruption of public coverage would not be a major probl em . With respect to employer covera ge , the qu e s ti on is whether a tax credit at the levels described is high enough to promote participation, but not so high that it promotes substantial employer dropping and worker switching. The answer is uncertain. One way to prevent the credit from leading employers to drop or workers to switch coverage is to allow it to be applicable to a worker’s share of employer-sponsored covera ge , as well as to nongroup coverage. As noted above, such an approach would actually substitute public for private dollars as a means to secure employer coverage but also to promote equity. Security and equity, however, come at considerable public cost. Although a new credit would induce some employees to take up coverage for the first time,the bulk of credit recipients under these rules would likely be individuals who already have coverage, rather than the uninsured. Providing the credit to employers rather than to individuals might offer a more targeted means to prevent the credit from inducing employers to drop coverage—especially if eligibility for credits can be limited to a subset of employers (like small, lowwage employers) that are currently unlikely to provide covera ge . A refundable tax credit could be provided to employers in the subset that do provide covera ge , of fs et ting corporate income taxes.15 For example, each eligible employer could receive a flat dollar amount—possibly varying for single or family coverage—for each eligible employee who is covered by health insurance. Previous efforts to induce employer offering of coverage through subsidies at the state level or through local pilot projects have not been successful, but this may be because these subsidies were either too small or perceived as temporary by employers.16 In fact, recent economic analysis indicates that small employers are at least as responsive as individuals to changes in the price of insurance.17 Based on that analysis, subsidy levels and coverage expectations might be similar under the two approaches. To induce offerings, an employer credit would have to be at least as generous in relation to premium costs as an individual subsidy, and it would likely need to be refundable. Though an employer credit would not help individuals without a connection to an employer or uninsured workers whose employers do not offer coverage, many of these uninsured would be eligible for or could buy into public covera ge . Furthermore, the employer credit could also be extended to those self-employed who may be uninsured despite higher incomes. Though the primary goal of an employer tax credit would be to encourage more employers to offer health coverage, equity and ease of administration would require that it be made available to eligible employers who already provide insurance. These employers would likely use at least some of the proceeds of the credit to lower employee premium contributions and, therefore, increase take-up among currently uninsured workers. But because the vast majority of workers who have access to employer coverage already take it up, these resources would likely go primarily to those already insured (for example, in the form of higher wages). Targeting an employer tax credit to those 15 Jack A. Meyer and Elliot K. Wicks. A Federal Tax Credit to Encourage Employers to Offer Health Coverage. New York: The Commonwealth Fund, 2000. Subsidizing Employment-Based Health Insurance: Results From a Pilot Study.” Journal of the American Medical Association 267 (7) (1992): 945-48. Sharon Silow-Carroll. “Employer Tax Credits to Expand Health Coverage: Lessons Learned.” Unpublished paper, The Commonwealth Fund, 2000; K. E. Thorpe et al. “Reducing the Number of Uninsured by 17 (that is, general tax revenues). Unless resources are available to support that subsidy, however, adverse selection is likely to make the buy-in unworkable. 16 Jonathan Gruber and Michael K. Lettau. “How Elastic is the Firm’s Demand for Health Insurance?” NBER Working Paper W8021. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2000. 56 employers least likely to offer insurance today would maximize the focus of public dollars on improving access to employer-sponsored coverage. The credit could be limited, for example, to small, low-wage employers,the majority of which do not offer coverage. Among firms with between three and workers that have percent or more of their workers earning less than , per year, just percent offer health insurance (compared to percent of all firms with fewer than employees).18 Smaller, low-wage firms are even less likely to offer coverage. Unfortunately, limiting subsidies to firms in this category is not a perfect solution to the problem of substituti on . Large firms can spin off low-wage workers to create new small, low-wage “firms,” thereby qualifying for subsidies they would not get otherwise. In addition, a subsidy targeted at small, low-wage firms may be perceived as inequitable, since it is not available to larger low-wage employers. Nevertheless, directing subsidies to small, lowwage employers offers a reasonable approach for targeting a tax credit to the uninsured, rather than the already insured. Because most economic evidence suggests that individuals rather than employers actually bear the cost of insurance (even if the employer ostensibly pays), a subsidy provided to employers may be virtually identical in its effect to a subsidy provided to individuals for the purchase of employer coverage. But, in practice, focusing on employers may facilitate the targeting of credits based on employer characteristics (like small size and low wages) that are associated with an absence of coverage offerings. As a result, the primary beneficiaries would be uninsured workers, rather than workers who already have insurance. Focusing on the employer would also ease the cash flow problems posed by individual subsidies, because by its nature, employer insurance would guarantee coverage prospectively. A tax credit for employer coverage rather than for individual insurance has clear advantages in terms of targeting and avoiding disruption of 18 Kaiser Family Foundation and Health Research and Educational Trust. Employer Health Benefits 2000. Menlo Park, CA: The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation, 2000. employer coverage. But these advantages can be perceived as disadvantages by advocates of individual choice, because the availability of subsidies to individuals would depend on the action of their employers. Undoubtedly, many individuals would not become beneficiaries of the new policy. Only if there is a buy-in to public coverage—as discussed above— would these individuals have access to guaranteed support in a combined public program/tax credit initiative of this kind. Summary: A Viable Merger? Given the priority we place on covering the lowincome uninsured, the most effective approach to expanding coverage is to extend the Medicaid and SCHIP eligibility now available to children and some parents to all low-income individuals. Although health insurance tax credits of various kinds could be combined with this public program expansion, careful attention should be paid to ensure that any tax credits complement rather than su b s ti tute for existing public and private sources of coverage. It is difficult to design a modest individual tax credit that is simultaneously effective and well targeted, while at the same time avoiding disruption of existing publicly sponsored and employer-sponsored insurance.A better approach may be tax credits provided to employers, rather than to individuals, to encourage greater offering of insurance. What is probably most important to the current policy process is attention to the questions we have raised about the way various policy instruments and their application affect who will benefit from and who will be hurt by adoption of any new policy initiative. Given how difficult it has been to obtain the public resources that are essential to expand coverage, it is crucial that any resources that do become available to expand coverage be used to achieve that goal, especially for those least able to protect themselves. Acknowledgements This paper was prepared in con ju n ction with the Kaiser Family Foundation’s Project on Incremental Health Reform. n 57 Gruber Proposal Key Elements Jonathan Gruber has outlined a proposal to substantially reduce the nation’s uninsured rate and allow nearly all households to obtain affordable health coverage under a voluntary initiative relying heavily on the private insurance market. The program includes the following elements: - that would offer a menu of health plan choices to all individuals and employers. on a sliding-scale basis to individuals with incomes up to percent of the federal poverty level buying insurance in the pool; most families with higher incomes could obtain coverage for percent or less of their income. by limiting the tax exclusion for employer-provided health insurance to the cost of a median-cost health plan and by phasing out the Medicaid program—and accompanying federal subsidies—for those families that qualify on the basis of income alone (while the program remains in place for the elderly and disabled). on both a prospective and retrospective, risk-adjusted basis that would spread health risk across entire purchasing pools so that higher-risk individuals could obtain affordable coverage. 58 About the Author , .., is Professor of Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology and the Director of the Program on Children at the National Bureau of Economic Research, where he is a Research Associate. He is a co-editor of the Journal of Health Economics, and an Associate Editor of the Journal of Public Economics. Dr. Gruber received his B.S.in Economics from MIT, and his Ph.D. in Economics from Harvard. He has received an Alfred P. Sloan Foundation Research Fellowship, a FIRST award from the National Institute on Aging, and the Kenneth Arrow Award for the Best Paper in Health Economics in . He was one of scientists nationwide to receive the Presidential Faculty Fellow Award from the National Science Foundation in . During the – academic year, Dr. Gruber was on leave as Deputy Assistant Secretary for Economic Policy at the Treasury Department.Dr. Gruber’s recent areas of particular research interest include the economics of employer provided health insurance,the efficiency of the delivery of health care to the indigent,the effect of the Social Security program on retirement behavior, and the economics of smoking. 59 A Private / Public Partnership for National Health Insurance by Jonathan Gruber Overview The private/public partnership approach to health reform proposed in this paper builds on the popularity of a voluntary, private insurance system, while rationalizing public “wrap-around” support for this s ys tem. The plan’s central features are discussed below. Purchasing Pools. The central element of the proposal is a set of voluntary purchasing pools established throughout the United States, one in each state and the District of Columbia. The federal government establishes each pool and documents its catchment area. Then it establishes a set of ground rules for any health insurance plan that wishes to be part of the local pool. Any insurance plan that meets those ground rules is eligible to be included in the pool,and plans in the pool offer insurance to potential enrollees at a community-rated price (by family type). Individuals and Employers. Individuals or employers are eligible to purchase insurance from any plan in their local pool. This purchase is subsidized for lower-income families. All persons in families with incomes below percent of the federal poverty line are enrolled automatically and free of charge in a plan near the pool’s median-cost plan. All persons in families with incomes between percent and percent of the poverty line (roughly , to , for a family of four) receive a subsidy to help pay to purchase insurance from this pool. The subsidy caps the proportion of income that must be spent to purchase insurance from the median-cost plan in the pool;this cap rises from at percent of poverty-level income to percent of income at percent of poverty. These subsidies can apply to direct individual or employer purchase of insurance from the pool. Persons above percent of federal poverty-level income receive no subsidy, but their insurance may cost them less because they can purchase it through this pool. Employers are allowed to purchase insurance from the pool; they receive no direct subsidy if insurance is purchased through the pool, but lowincome families can use their subsidies to help pay for employer-provided insurance from the pool. Employers and their employees are eligible for these subsidies only if they restrict the employees’ insurance ch oi ces to plans offered through the pool. Continuation of coverage mandates (through the Consolidated Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act [COBRA] and state regulation) also are removed for employers buying all their insurance through the pool, providing even greater incentive for employers to join the pool. Plan Reimbursement. A key considera ti on with any pooling approach is adverse selecti on . Plans compete to attract the lowest-risk enrollees, which can raise prices significantly at the more generous plans that some truly sick enrollees may demand. Adverse selection in these pools is minimized through risk-adjusted redistribution across the plans in the pool. This risk adjustment is a mix of prospective (for example,based on demographic characteristics and long-term comorbidities) and retrospective (for example, actual cost outliers) factors. Financing. This approach involves a significant federal expenditure, primarily through subsidies for the low-income insured. These costs are partly financed from two sources. The first is a cap on the exclusion from taxation of employer-provided health insurance premiums. Any currently tax-preferred spending by employers and employees on 60 insurance above the cost of the median plan in that state becomes taxable income to the employee. After a transition period, the second financing source is the phase-out of current public programs that provide insurance to low-income families solely on the basis of income. Medicaid ultimately becomes a program only for the elderly and disabled, and the remaining Medicaid and State Children’s Health In su ra n ce Program (S-CHIP) populations move into this new subsidy program. The federal government then saves its share of spending on these programs and recaptures from states their spending on these programs. Implications. This private/public partnership results in a very different situation for individuals, insurers, and employers. In su ra n ce coverage rises significantly, as affordability, information, and stigma barriers to insurance for the lowest-income families are removed. Coverage is not universal, but almost all families in the United States should be able to buy insurance coverage for percent of their income or less. Insurers offer their products in a competitive environment that provides strong incentives for cost control. Individuals pay the full costs for choosing more expensive insurance products, because the tax subsidy to purchase insurance is capped. This leads consumers to choose costeffective plans, allowing for increased medical-sector cost control without public spending caps or other awkward interventions. Background The proposal developed in this report is designed to meet two key political constraints and to address the two key failings of our current system. The political constraints are that the U.S. Congress is unwilling to expand public insurance programs massively, or to legislate widespread new individual or employer mandates. The first failing is that employer-provided insurance results in incomplete access to pooling mechanisms for such groups as the unemployed,selfemployed, and those in small businesses. The second failing is that public safety net programs cannot provide health care to everyone who is uninsured. These failings are discussed in more detail below. Private Health Insurance Several features of the current insurance environment call for the private/public partnership approach. The first is that the primary source of health insurance is employers. More than percent of the privately insured, representing percent of the total non-elderly population, are covered by employer-provided insurance. Employer provision has much to recommend it. Workplaces of sufficient size represent pooling mechanisms that are largely independent of underlying health status, providing the kind of predictable distribution of costs potential insurers want. They also provide a means of spreading the fixed costs of an insurance plan across a number of insured persons. In addition, human resource departments provide professionals generally dedicated to effective provision of benefits, leading to both high satisfaction and innovation in health insurance options. On the other hand, employer-provided insurance as the primary mechanism of i n su ra n ce has some failings.First, small employers provide neither the economies of scale nor the needed predictable distribution of expenditures that make them attractive sources of insurance. As a result, while insurance offering is nearly universal among medium-size and large employers, it is much less common among the smallest employers; even in our booming economy, only two-thirds of employers with fewer than employees offer health insurance. Second,the fact that insurance is linked to work, and is not available at all jobs,can lead to insuranceinduced immobility across jobs, or “job lock.” Workers who value insurance coverage may not leave their current positions for poten ti a lly more productive ones, for fear of losing their insurance coverage.Estimates suggest that job lock may reduce mobility by as much as percent among those with employer-provided insurance. Job lock is mitigated by the availability of continuation coverage under state and federal mandates that allow individuals to continue to purchase insurance from their employer after leaving their jobs,at percent of the employer’s full cost of insurance. While research has shown these continuation mandates to be an effective means of increasing insurance coverage among job 61 changers, they are unpopular with employers because of their administrative costs and the (below average) health of employees who choose to continue their coverage (so that employers lose money, even though workers pay average insurance costs). Finally, the residual nature of the non-group market has made it an inhospitable environment for those who leave the employer pool. The non-group market features high prices, typically at least percent higher than group insurance costs for healthy employees, and much more for older and less healthy persons. Those with expensive medical conditions may be unable to obtain any coverage, and the coverage available in the non-group market generally is much worse than group coverage, with high deductibles and limited benefits. A final issue related to employer-provided insurance is that its popularity can be traced, at least in part, to exclusion of employer-provided insurance payments (and roughly half of employee payments for such insurance, as well) from taxation. This tax subsidy has been criticized as regressive: Because it is equivalent to a tax deduction, those who pay the highest income taxes benefit the most. It is also cited as a source of medical cost inflation, because it subsidizes the price of health insurance and can lead individuals to purchase excessively generous insurance plans. Finally, this is a major expenditure for the government, more than billion per year. Public Health Insurance In principle, public health insurance in the United States is designed to insure those unable to get coverage from the private insurance market. For the elderly, who are covered by Medicare, this is largely true (with some notable exceptions, such as the lack of coverage for pre s c ri ption drugs). But some of the n on - el derly still have difficulty getting covera ge , which results in our high and rising level of uninsurance. In , . percent of non-elderly Americans had no health insurance. Over the next decade, the non-elderly population without insurance coverage grew by nearly a quarter, to . percent, so that in million Americans were uninsured. This number declined to . million in . Particularly troubling is the significant increase in the number of children in the United States who are uninsured; despite dramatic expansion of public health insurance since the mid-s,the share of children without health insurance has grown by more than percent since . Medicaid is the primary source of public insurance. Most Medicaid spending is for insurance for the elderly and disabled, but most of the individuals covered are women and children. Traditionally, only those on cash welfare were eligible for public insurance, but this coverage has now been extended dramatically for two groups: pregnant women (for pregnancy-related expenses only) and children. Currently, pregnant women are automatically covered up to percent of poverty-level income by federal mandate, and most states have extended this coverage to percent of the poverty level or above. Children under age are covered up to percent of poverty level, as well, and most states cover all children to the poverty level or higher under their Medicaid programs. Moreover, the S-CHIP extended child coverage further by providing block grants to states, which many states have used to extend child coverage to percent of the poverty level or even higher. Despite these recent expansions, however, enormous holes in the public safety net remain. First, and most obvious, there is no source of public insurance (other than selected small state programs) for adults, aside from pregnant wom en . Second, even among eligible populations, the number of people taking advantage of this public insurance entitlement is low. Recent estimates suggest that as many as million uninsured children may be eligible for Medicaid or S-CHIP, but are not taking advantage of this eligibility. This is likely due in part to the fact that entire families are not eligible, limiting the incentives for participation, and among middle-class families there is some stigma attached to using public programs. Despite the fact that Medicaid remains an entitlement for low-income families leaving welfare, recent declines in public coverage resulting from welfare reform highlight the difficulties facing the safety net. 62 Details of Implementation An enormous number of details must be addressed when implementing a plan such as a private/public partnership. Important questions about such a plan and at least partial answers to them follow. Eligibility and Subsidy Structure Based on the income reporting described below, individuals are eligible f or one of two kinds of subsidies. If income is below percent of the federal poverty line for that person’s family size (“poor” families), then the individual and his or her family members are automatically enrolled free of charge in an insurance plan. The plan is selected randomly from among the plans near the median-priced plan in the pool. The use of a default plan is critical to the success of this approach, because it will increase take-up of insurance by this low-income group significantly. But placing the whole group in one plan that happens to be at the median is potentially inequitable and problematic if the particular plan cannot handle this many enrollees. Therefore, this low-income group is assigned randomly to a small number of plans near the median;the exact number of plans depends on the size of the pool and the range of prices around that median.Of course,these individuals are free to choose a different plan from among those close to the median, and to switch among these plans once they are assigned. The pool administrator notifies plans of any enrollees in this group, and the plan bills the government directly, rather than the individuals, for the premiums. A second subsidy for individuals in this income range is a cap on the copayments and deductibles for which they are responsible. Individuals enrolled in these plans are subject to maximum copayments of for any visit or drug purchase. In addition, these copayments, and any deductible,are capped at percent of income. Providers notify the plan, wh i ch , in tu rn , notifies the pool administrator, whenever a copayment is charged to someone in the poor group (who is identified by having a separate insurance card). When persons reach the percent of income limit, they are sent a new card indicating that they are no longer to be charged copayments. Individuals in this income range are also free to choose plans that cost more or less than the median. If they choose plans at above-median cost, they are bi ll ed by the plan for the difference between that plan’s premiums and the premiums of the median plan. If they choose lower-cost plans, they do not receive the difference. If these cost savings were available,there would be significant opportunity for fraud; low-cost plans might be set up that do not actually provide insurance, but that just allow lowincome individuals to turn their subsidies into cash. Because copayments and deductibles are capped for the low-income population, establishing such “cash cows” would be very easy. The second subsidy group, those families between percent and percent of the poverty line (the “near poor”), receives a subsidy that is structured so that, if they sign up for the mediancost plan, they will never pay more than percent of their family income on insurance premiums. The subsidy is phased in, so that there are no large reductions in subsidy as income grows (that is, to avoid large “implicit taxes” on income generation for families in this income range). In particular, at percent of the poverty line, the cap is zero, with full subsidies; at percent of the poverty line, the cap is . percent of income; at percent of poverty, the cap is . percent of income; and by percent of poverty, the cap is a full percent of income. For example, suppose that a family has four m em bers and an income of , ( ro u gh ly percent of the poverty line), and that family coverage in the median-cost plan costs ,. That family receives a subsidy for ,, the difference between the cost of the median plan and . percent of the family’s income. Individuals are then free to enroll in higher- or lower-cost plans as they wish, but the subsidy amount remains at ,, regardless of the plan chosen. For this near-poor group, if individuals do enroll in a plan that costs less than the subsidy amount,the government will pay them percent of the difference between the subsidy level (which is tied to the median plan) and the premiums in the plan they choose. This provides some incentive to choose lowcost plans, while potentially offsetting some costs of 63 Those families between 150 percent and 300 percent of the poverty line (the “near poor”) receive a subsidy that is structured so that, if they sign up for the median-cost plan, they will never pay more than 10 percent of their family income on insurance premiums. this subsidy program to the government. For this near-poor population (and for any poor individuals who choose above-median-cost plans), the pool administrator would notify the plan of the enrollees’ information and how much of a subsidy they are entitled to receive. The plan is then responsible for collecting the difference from the individual, and the subsidy is paid directly by the government to the plan. So, using the example above, the insurance plan bills the individual , per year, and the government, ,. If the individual chooses a cheaper plan—with a premium of , per year, for example—then the plan bills the individual only per year and continues to bill the government ,. If the individual enrolls in a plan with premiums of , per year, then the plan bills the government ,, and the government pays the individual a subsidy of .. Income for these purposes is a modified version of adjusted gross income (AGI) that includes all income elements, but does not exclude from income deductions from AGI that are included in the current tax code (for example, the ability to deduct contributions to retirement savings accounts). So this corresponds to a gross income concept. - A technical, but absolutely critical, issue of subsidy design is how eligibility is determined. There are two models to choose from. The first is a refundable tax credit/voucher system, with reconciliation. Under this system, individuals apply for subsidies before the plan year, using either their previous year’s income or a projection of their income for the coming year. They then receive those subsidies for that year. The following spring, there is a reconciliation process between the income they actually received during that year and the income they anticipated months earlier for subsidy determination. As a refundable tax credit, this approach faces the additional problem of advancing money to individuals months earlier so they can purchase the insurance. As a voucher scheme, however, the payments are advanceable by definition. The second approach is more like welfare. Individuals apply for subsidies more frequently, and report their income when they apply. If they qualify, they become eligible for that period. There is no reconciliation, although some mechanism must be in place to catch significant dishonesty in reporting income. The fundamental difference between these approaches is the reconciliation process. Reconciliation does provide a more natural means of correcting over- or underpayments than a backstop fraud mechanism does, but it may significantly deter participation by potential enrollees. For example, taxpayers can take advance payment of their Earned Income Tax Credit amounts, but only about percent of potential recipients do so, partly out of fear that they will underestimate income and owe taxes the next April . As a result, a refundable credit/ voucher approach could deter take-up significantly, for fear of reconciliation costs down the road. For this reason, the private/public partnership approach adopts a more welfare-like approach. Every six months, at open enrollment in November and May, individuals are asked to verify their income. Supporting documents are required, such as pay stubs or W forms. If individuals qualify for one of the two subsidy programs, they are guaranteed those subsidies, subject to penalties for fraud, but no reconciliation. A significant enforcement program will be in place to ensure that individuals do not abuse this presumptive eligibility by systematically understating their incomes. But prospective en ro ll ees can rest assured that honest mistakes and/or changes in income will not result in penalties. 64 Subsidies are also available on a shorter- ru n basis for those experiencing income fluctuations within a six-month period. If individuals can offer proof of income loss (such as unemployment),they can enter the subsidy pool at any point, and from then on, are on the regular six-month schedule. the additional costs (of course, those costs may be passed on to employees, either directly, through premium sharing, or indirectly). For the near-poor ( percent to percent of poverty), the employer is billed for the cost (minus the subsidy) of the plan chosen by the employee. All employers are also allowed, but not required, to purchase their insurance through the local pool. Employers may provide their employees a menu of insurance options that includes some plans from the local pool, and some from outside the pool. There are two significant incentives for employers to limit their employees’ choices to plans in the pool, however. First, only those employers that restrict employees’ ch oi ces to plans available through the pool can access subsidies for their low-income employees. Second, employers that purchase all of their insurance through the pool are no longer required to provide continuation coverage, because individuals can now purchase insurance through the pool on their own. These incentives for employers to en ro ll all their employees in the pool are designed to minimize adverse selection into the pools (discussed further below). Employers purchasing insurance through the pool effectively act as intermediaries for individual purchase. That is, employees enroll through their employers, perhaps using additional materials provided by employers to help them choose.Employers then withhold the premiums for the chosen plan from the worker’s paycheck and remit that amount directly to the pool, which, in turn, reimburses the plans. Using the pool as a middleman between insurers and employers makes it easier for employers to take advantage of the pool, providing another incentive for employers to use it as their source of insurance. Low-income employees who obtain their insurance through the workplace apply for subsidies through their employer. For the poor (incomes below percent of the poverty line),the employer pays no premiums if the employee enrolls in the median-cost plan. If the employee en ro lls in an above-median-cost plan, the employer has to pay Financing: The Employer Tax Subsidy and the Role of Public Insurance This plan is financed from three sources. The first is general revenue financing, one hopes,from the projected federal budget su rp lu s . But this program’s cost to the general budget ultimately will be offset by the following two sources of savings. Part of the financing for this plan will come from the limitation of the tax exclusion for employerprovided health insurance payments. This limitation will take two forms.First, for those low-income employees receiving subsidies, net employer payments for health insurance will be lower. Both economic theory and evidence suggest that the lower net employer payments will be passed on to workers in the form of higher wages, and, therefore, higher taxes. Thus, in essence, we will end the tax subsidy for employer-provided insurance payments to poor employees, and limit this subsidy for the near-poor. Second, the government will limit the tax exclusion for employer-provided health insurance payments explicitly to the cost of the median-cost plan in the local pool. All employers will track the total payments they make and any pre-tax payments made by their employees for health insurance. The government tells each employer before the beginning of each year the cost of the local pool’s mediancost plan. The employer is then responsible for reporting as part of an employee’s wages and salaries the difference between the total pre-tax employer/employee expenditure on health insurance and the premiums for the median-cost plan. This difference becomes taxable income for the purposes of both the income tax and payroll tax system. This is true regardless of whether the employer purchases insurance through the pool. 65 - This program obviates the need for much of the existing Medicaid program by providing insurance for low-income populations, so the program can be reorganized. The portion of Medicaid that provides health insurance coverage for non-disabled and non-elderly families—acute-care Medicaid—can be abolished, because those families can be automatically enrolled in their local pool, or offered a significant subsidy toward enrollment. The remainder of Medicaid that provides health insurance coverage for the disabled and the elderly (the bulk of Medicaid costs) remains unchanged. The S-CHIP program also can end under this proposal, because insurance for low-income families is available through the subsidy mechanism described above. This reorganization ultimately will result in considerable cost savings that can help to finance the new program. In addition to the federal government’s savings from reducing its Medicaid and SCHIP obligation, states can save considerable m on ey by no longer paying the Medicaid and SCHIP costs for their acute-care population, while the insurance coverage for this low-income population actually increases. To compensate for the loss of these payments, the federal government receives a transfer from each state equal to the amount the state was paying for the Medicaid and S-CHIP programs for the acute-care population in the year before the program was enacted. This payment rises over time with the cost of the median plan in each state. Once again, the majority of the program that applies to the disabled or elderly does not change, and no recapture applies to those funds. There are two important concerns with removing the public insurance entitlement,however. First, the net insurance entitlement of some families could fall, since children now receive free coverage under Medicaid up to or above percent of poverty in many states. But this should be more than of fs et by the subsidized or free coverage of adults in most families. Second, and more important, there could be major disruption of insurance during the transition from the current public system to this new private s ys tem. Low-income individuals who are taking advantage of the public system may be confused or otherwise unable or unwilling to use this new private approach. An unfortunate byproduct of this attempt to increase insurance coverage might lead to displacement of the neediest who are currently publicly insured. Therefore, a transition period will be necessary during which both the existing Medicaid/S-CHIP programs and the subsidies for the public/private partnership are available. The length of this transition period can be based on evidence of understanding and willingness among lowest-income families to move to the new system. The phase-out of public programs will occur in a “topdown” fashion, with eligibility for the highestincome groups currently in the program phased out first (starting with S-CHIP). A concerted outreach and public relations effort to establish an effective understanding of the new subsidy system will help this transition. This effort includes working through existing Medicaid offices, schools, day care centers, and other access points to reach low-income populations. Administration and Regulation—Benefits and Risk Adjustment Of key importance is how these pools that form the core of the private/public participation approach are established, administered, and regulated. In addition, a central feature of this proposal is risk adjustment among plans in the pool. This section addresses implementation issues in pool administration and regulation. The federal government notifies all potential insurers of the option to offer insurance through the pool one year before the local pool is open for enrollment. The government bears the full cost of this initial solicitation, screening potential insurers in line with the conditions outlined above, and initially assigning applicants to plans within the pool. Continuing administrative costs of the pool are financed by the small fee assessed on premiums earned by plans in the pool. The government administers the program out of 66 There is a key trade-off in setting minimum standards for plans participating in local pools. On the one hand, the federal government is obligated to make sure that these are real insurance products. On the other, the government should encourage individuals to choose efficient and low-cost health insurance plans. a new agency, the Private/Public Partnership Health Insurance Agency (PPPHIA), that is responsible for establishing pools and overseeing existing pool administration, coordinating subsidy payments, and coordinating income reconciliation. There is a key trade-off in setting minimum standards for plans participating in local pools. On the one hand, the federal government is obligated to make sure that these are real insurance products. On the other, the government should encourage individuals to choose, or at least should offer the option to choose, efficient and low-cost health insurance plans. These joint imperatives dictate a fairly minimal set of regulations that should guarantee that all the insurance products offered are real insurance, but then allows free ch oi ce . In particular, regulations should require only that each plan feature: • guaranteed issue and guaranteed renewability; • coverage of physician services, inpatient and outpatient hospital services (including emergency rooms), and prescription drugs; and • no or nominal copayments for one well child visit per year, prenatal care, and immunizations. These minimum standards should generate rough comparability across the benefit packages offered to plan enrollees. But variation in benefits, or in the value of insurance plans, will remain along four dimensions. The first is copayments and deductibles;there is no minimum standard for these patient charges, although, as noted above, they are subsidized for the poor. The second is variation in benefits around these minimum standards. For example, plans may or may not use a formulary to dispense pre s c ri ption dru gs ; may vary and limit their outpatient and inpatient mental health coverage; may or may not cover home health care services, etc. These are not trivial differences, but, once again, it is critical to reflect diversity of consumer preferences across plans. The third is va ri a ti on in provider networks offered among managed care plans, and the fourth is va ri a ti on in the degree of management of managed care plans,in terms of utilization review and physician financial incentives, among others. As noted below, information about all of these variations is readily available to families during open enrollment periods. In addition, the government must develop financial soundness criteria to ensure that the plans can provide their promised services. Subject to these c ri teria, any plan that wishes to offer its servi ce s through the pool may do so. Each plan charges community-rated premiums for each of four distinct populations: single; single with children; married without children; and married with children. The use of com mu n i ty - ra ted premiums immediately raises concerns about adverse selection, which are addressed below. To miti ga te adverse selecti on , individuals are allowed to choose a plan at only one time during the year. Open enrollment takes place during November for the next year, allowing pool administrators the month of December to process enrollment applications and assign enrollees to plans. Every family in each plan’s local catchment area receives a mailing on November detailing that family’s insurance ch oi ces for the coming year. The mailing has two components. The first documents each plan’s costs, reported after subsidy by income level, copayments and deductibles, and services covered. The second component provides more detail on the plans themselves. It includes information on provision of preventive care services and consumer satisfaction. In addition, it gives some details on provider financial incentives. There are also links to a web site where 67 individuals can learn more about each insuring entity and the plans themselves. Assessing what inf ormation should be disclosed in the mailing, on the web site, or not at all is the su bj ect of much debate, particularly surrounding financial incentives to providers. While detailed disclosure of provider incentives can improve the information available to very educated consumers significantly, these details may be more than most consumers need or want to know. Moreover, there are competitive concerns in mandating too much detail on such provider compen s a ti on arrangements, because part of how plans compete is over their provider incentive structures. As part of establishing these local pools, therefore, a commission of experts should meet to decide on the appropriate amount of disclosure. Plan switching is allowed during the year. Individuals may switch during open enrollment peri od , but if they do not return their forms expressing their desire to change,they are automatically en ro ll ed in the same plan for the fo ll owing year. Individuals who join the pool during the year can choose their plan at that point. But to minimize churning, any individual who leaves the pool at any point during the year cannot reenter the pool until the next open enrollment period. The pool administrator co ll ects the open enrollment forms and informs each plan of the pool of enrollees for the coming year. Plans are responsible for billing enrollees and are entitled to terminate coverage of any en ro ll ee who does not pay after three months (for example,if a bill is sent at the end of January, and is not paid by the end of April, the family can be disenrolled). Disenrolled families are barred from reentering the pool for three months. Plans also are entitled to charge interest on all premium payments not remitted within one month, at a rate set by the government to represent the borrowing costs of insurers. After forms are co ll ected, the administrator is responsible for notifying the government of all subsidy payments. The administrator also maintains a database of information on all enrollees,plan choic- es, and reported incomes, which is also shared with the government. - As noted earlier, risk adjustment is redistributed across the plans in the pool to minimize adverse selection. This risk adjustment represents a mix of prospective (for example, based on demographic characteristics and long-term comorbidities) and retrospective (for example, actual cost outliers) factors. More specifically, when individuals enroll each November, they provide information about their a ge , sex, and incidence of a set of chronic or past major illnesses (for example,diabetes, hypertension, heart disease or stroke, etc.). This information is not given to plans, but is maintained by the government. Even if individuals enroll through their employer, they send this information directly to the government to maintain confidentiality. In addition, at the end of each year, each plan reports the costs for each enrollee to the government. Based on these two sets of data, the government applies a formula to determine a set of cross-subsidy payments that flows across plans. This formula uses demographic and comorbidity information to form a predicted average health expenditure. It then takes a weighted average of that predicted health expenditure and the actual health expenditure per capita (the “cost index”). For each plan, the government tabulates its cost index and redistributes funds from the low-cost- to high-cost-index plans. Plans that leave the pool are still eligible to receive payments and are responsible for making payments for services incurred the previous year. The magnitude of the redistribution is determined by technical government analysis. This technical analysis trades off two considerations: more redistribution means less adverse selection, but also lower incentives for cost control. The optimal redistribution scheme does not compensate plans fully for differences in expenditure patterns, but does compensate them enough to limit incentives for adverse selection. For example, the optimal plan could state that any expenditures that are more than one standard deviation from the mean for an age/gender category will be reimbursed through this 68 redistribution system. This sort of approach still offers incentives to keep costs down when close to the mean, while “insuring” firms that en ro ll cases with very high costs. This risk adjustment does not address a different type of adverse selection risk: adverse selection into the pools themselves (“inside/outside adverse selection”). Since insurance is community rated, and plans that are less comprehensive are taxed by the risk-adjustment mechanism (higher premiums), there is a strong incentive for healthy individuals to remain outside this pool and in groups of healthy persons with very low insurance premiums. By the same logic, there is strong incentive for the sickest individuals to get into the pool, where insurance is subsidized for them more than it would be in the experience-rated and non-risk-adjusted private market. Enough adverse selection of this type could destroy this pooling mechanism; if only the sickest persons in society end up in the pools,the insurance in these pools will be so expensive that they will be unattractive to all but the most highly subsidized poor. This approach is designed to minimize this type of inside/outside selection, however, because the nature of subsidies (and discontinuation of the coverage mandate) provides a strong incentive to be in the pool. In the long run, all of the poor and most of the near-poor should be in the pool. Moreover, any employer that has a sizable share of its workforce in the income range to which subsidies apply (which should be most employers) will forgo a significant financial subsidy to its employees by not joining the pool. Remember, employers have to be entirely in the pool for their workers to receive subsidies, so they cannot “dump” their sickest workers into the pool while keeping healthy workers outside it. Low-income employees ultimately should choose to leave employers that are unwilling to join the pool, thereby putting pressure on firms to enroll. And the removal of the deeply unpopular COBRA mandate provides an additional incentive to pool. It is difficult to assess whether this impetus is powerful enough to get a critical mass of healthy persons into these pools. But it seems quite likely that it is, given the sheer size of the population to which subsidies apply. In short, the goal here is to use these subsidies to boost pool size to the minimum level necessary to lower costs and miti ga te inside/outside selection significantly. The transition to the private/public partnership is fairly straightforward, since the pools are voluntary. For example, suppose implementing legislation is passed in October that establishes the PPHIA, which immediately begins drawing up local boundaries for the pools and gathering data from plans that want to participate for calendar year . Then, in November the first enrollment period can open. Beginning January , , the government begins to phase out Medicaid coverage for the nondisabled and non-elderly. Also on that date, employers begin to include the “excess” (above-areamedian) costs of their spending on health insurance as part of taxable wages. Advertising to individuals about this new insurance system begins immediately with passage of the legislation in late . Medicaid administrators are responsible for ensuring that all non-elderly/nondisabled enrollees are aware that their Medicaid entitlement is terminating, and for introducing this new alternative. Implications of the Private/Public Partnership Approach This approach represents a fairly radical departure from the current private and public systems of providing health insu ra n ce . While the impact of this new system on the scope and shape of the health care delivery system is difficult to predict, this section discusses some likely implications of this type of reform. Politics The primary implication is the political dynamic surrounding the type of major reform envisioned by this approach. Obviously, any intervention of this magnitude faces a daunting legislative process. 69 There are likely to be concerns from at least five stakeholders about this approach. First, firms and unions will be upset about the reduction in the tax subsidy to employer-provided health insurance. There will be a “camel’s nose under the tent” concern about capping this deduction, even if the cap is relatively modest at first. Second, fiscal conservatives will object to the net price tag of this interventi on , particularly given the tenuous nature of current surplus projections. Conservatives may also be upset about the attendant increase in government bureaucracy. Third, insurers that focus on the non-group market, but do not feel that they can compete effectively in this new pooled group market, will protest their loss of market share. Fourth, advocates of the traditional Medicaid program, rather than private market solutions to the uninsured, will raise concerns about the loss of Medicaid entitlement. Finally, tax administrators may oppose the expanded use of the tax system under this plan and, in particular, the introduction of area-specific adjustments to the tax subsidy to health insurance (which is capped at the median-cost plan in the area). But important stakeholders will support this plan. Foremost will be reformers who see this as a means of reducing the number of uninsured significantly. In addition, this approach will be validated by market-minded advocates of competition as the best source of health care cost control. And advocates for the poor will recognize the important income redistribution of this approach. While upset about the limitation of the tax subsidy as a means of financing, employers (particularly small employers) ultimately may approve of this approach, because it allows them to shed their insurance provision obligations or b uy into a more effective mechanism for purchasing insurance,and to discontinue an obligation they consider a significant burden. Group insurers should also approve of a system that expands the reach of their products, both locally and nationwide. More relevant is that this approach has more po l i ti c a lly attractive fe a tu res than many other alternatives. The significant expansion in public spending programs necessary to cover an enormous share of the existing uninsured is not feasible in today’s pro-private solution climate. And alternative private-sector solutions, such as expanded tax credits, face very high costs because of the limitations of the non-group market in which they would be spent. Implications for Health Care Costs The lull in health care cost inflation in the United States over the past few years has dictated a focus on uninsurance and a backlash against the stringency of managed care. But significant increases in health care costs over the past year once again have raised concerns about cost containment. At the same time, there is little taste among the public or policy makers for a public cost-containment strategy for the privately insured. A key advantage of the public/private partnership is that it uses a competitive mechanism to assist in cost containment, while balancing the selection incentives inherent in competition through a mixed prospective/retrospective risk-selection adjustment. Unlike today’s insurance marketplace, individuals will face the full marginal cost of moving from less to more generous insurance plans. This makes these individuals more cost-conscious shoppers, which,in turn,puts pressure on insurance plans to lower their costs to attract new enrollees. Concern about competition as a source of cost control in the health care sector is twofold. First, there is some fear that competition will lead to inappropriate reductions in the quality of care. The best safeguard against this is providing complete information on plan characteristics, financial incentives, and con su m er satisfacti on , which will be done through the open enrollment mailing. Second,plans may compete,not to provide the most efficient care, but to select the best risks. This concern will be miti ga ted through the risk-adjustment mechanism described above. The net impact of improved competi ti on on health care cost growth is unknown. But competition, with full information, risk adjustment, and a level playing field across plans and consumers, remains the best politically feasible option for controlling costs. 70 Equity This approach has significant implications for both “vertical” equity (redistribution) and “horizontal” equity (fairness). In terms of vertical equity, as described above, this program involves significant redistribution from average-income taxpayers to those below median income (and primarily below percent of the poverty line). In terms of horizontal equity, this program removes many of the inequities that now haunt our private insurance system.Large employers,small employers,and individuals will be able to purchase insurance on the same basis, removing the existing enormous differences across these groups because of administrative loads and adverse selection premiums. Likewise, healthy and sick individuals have equal opportunities to purchase insurance from the same pool of providers. Sicker individuals may end up buying the more expensive plans in the pool, but this is by their own choice, not by the active selection efforts of insurers. Implications for Income Generation A concern with any program that includes incomerelated subsidies is the distortions toward income generation. The proposed system includes two such distortions. First, there is an additional implicit tax on income earned above the poverty line as the full subsidy available to those below poverty is phased out. The magnitude of this implicit tax is modest, however, amounting to only a . percent additional tax on income generation. For example, consider a family of four with an income at percent of the poverty line (roughly ,) that faces group premiums of ,. That family’s subsidy is the full group premium, or ,. If the family’s income rose by percent of the poverty line, to ,, their subsidy would fall by ., or . percent of the income rise. This is a very modest additional tax and is likely to cause little distortion to income generation. The second distortion is where the subsidy ends, at percent of the poverty line. If, at this point, any families have premiums that exceed percent of their income, then raising incomes above percent of the poverty line could lower net resources significantly. If, for example, group premiums for the family of four were ,, then at percent of poverty (,), they would pay only , for their coverage, and receive a subsidy of . But, when the family earns the next dollar of income, that en ti re subsidy disappears, which could present a significant disincentive to moving out of the subsidized range. This concern raises a t rade-off between limiting the subsidies and extending them further up the income range, which would mitigate this distortion but also would raise costs. I propose erring on the side of saving costs and limiting the subsidies for two reasons.First,at higher income levels,income is more dynamic (and less easily tracked, since higher shares are from non-wage sources),so that administering these subsidies is more difficult. Second, the magnitude of this distortion is likely to be relatively small. But the implementing legislation for this policy should include a mandate to study this issue and, in particular, keep track of the rise of health care costs relative to incomes and how this affects the magnitude of the “notch” at percent of poverty. Regional Variation Another concern about income subsidies is that the federal poverty line is not tied to regional variations in cost of living. It seems highly unlikely that there would ever be regionally rated subsidies, given the enormous difficulties of assessing the correct regional adjuster. But the structure of the subsidies in this proposal provides implicit ad ju s tm ent for regional cost variation, because the amount of the subsidy is tied to the cost of the median-cost plan, which reflects regional variations in the cost of living. That is, a much larger share of the population will be subsidized in Mississippi than in Massachusetts, but the subsidies for which they are eligible will be much smaller. Conclusions Radical change of the U.S. health care system involves a set of difficult trade-offs from both an economic and political perspective. The private/ public partnership approach laid out in this propos- 71 al is designed to respect the demand for voluntary, private solutions to the problem of the uninsured in the United States in a way that could provide insurance to the vast majority of needy uninsured in this country. But it is important to recognize that this proposal will not lead to universal health insurance coverage in the United States. Even with significant subsidies to the poor and near-poor, some still will choose to remain uninsured. In addition, a not inconsequential number of well-off people who can afford health insurance will continue to choose not to buy it. This raises a critical question of how far we are willing to go with health policy in the United States. This proposal guarantees that coverage is universally affordable, but not universally adopted. Is the role of the government to go beyond this to ensure universal coverage, or is universal access sufficient? The reform has a number of additional virtues. It involves significant income redistribution and a leveling of the playing field on which individuals purchase insurance. And it uses the powers of competition effectively to address rising health care premiums. There are additional complications, as well, and these need to be addressed if the program is implemented. But the key political economy advantages of a voluntary system suggest that this type of approach has promise as a means of addressing the failings of the current health care system. Acknowledgements I am grateful to The Robert Wood Johnson Foundation for support, to Barrett Kirwan for research assistance, and to Larry Levitt, Jack Meyer, E ll i o t Wicks, seminar participants at the National Bureau of Economic Research, and members of the advisory panel for their helpful comments. n 73 Hacker Proposal Key Elements Jacob S. Hacker has proposed a plan to achieve universal coverage by building on the Medicare program. The proposal includes the following elements: either to offer and automatically enroll employees in a plan at least as generous as that available under an enhanced Medicare benefits package or to pay a modest payroll-based contribution to help fund enrollment of their employees in Medicare Plus. the contribution instead of providing their own plan would be enrolled automatically in Medicare Plus at their workplace, although they could use their employers’ contributions (minus a penalty) to purchase other coverage that met the same standards as the workplace plans. to use outreach efforts to enroll non-workers in Medicare Plus, which would effectively replace Medicaid and the State Children’s Health Insurance Program (S-CHIP). who are not enrolled by their state would have an individual buy-in option available, with the premium based on income. 74 About the Author . , .., is a Junior Fellow of the Harvard University Society of Fellows. Before coming to Harvard, he was a Fellow at the New America Foundation and, prior to that, a Guest Scholar and Research Fellow at the Brookings Institution. A political scientist who studies social policy, he is the author of The Road to Nowhere: The Genesis of President Clinton’s Plan for Health Security (Princeton University Press), which co-won the Louis Brownlow Book Award of the National Academy of Public Administration. His articles and opinion pieces have appeared in the British Journal of Political Science; Studies in American Political Development; the Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law; the New Republic; the Nation; the Los Angeles Times; the Boston Globe; and the Washington Post. His second book, The Divided Welfare State: Government, Business, and Social Policy in the United States, will be published in . 75 Medicare Plus: Increasing Health Coverage by Expanding Medicare by Jacob S. Hacker Overview Motive and Rationale Universal health insurance has been the great unfulfilled hope of American health care reformers, a siren call luring countless victims to the shoals of political defeat. One reason for this has been the inherent difficulty of outlining a compelling series of self-reinforcing policy changes that would simultaneously move the nation toward universal coverage and build political support and administrative capacity for further steps in that direction. Instead, the political constraints that American reformers inevitably confront have repeatedly pushed advocates to embrace highly categorical and complex programs that have proved du ra bly resistant to expansion beyond their target populations. To suggest a way out of this persistent trap, this proposal outlines a sequential approach to universal coverage—or near-universal coverage, depending on how many of the steps are taken. It takes an established program, Medicare, and shows how it might be expanded through a series of measures designed to minimize short-term disruptions to existing coverage while creating strong incentives for the formation of an inclusive social insurance program. Although constructed on familiar foundations,this proposal combines el em ents usually viewed as distinct: a “single-payer” plan that pools risks broadly, an “individual mandate” on Americans to obtain coverage,and a modified “play-or-pay” requirement waiving a modest levy on employers if they provide coverage. Together, these elements would encourage, rather than compel, working Americans to obtain their insurance through a common framework—a strategy that might foster a gradual movement away from employment-based insurance. Asked to design an ideal, or even broadly acceptable, health financing structu re , few would pick the patchwork of private coverage and public residual programs that exists in the United States today. Unlike citizens of other affluent democracies, most Americans rely for their health security on voluntary employer plans, with public programs only partially filling the gaps left behind. Although the tax code encourages firms to offer insurance,a substantial share of smaller and lower-wage firms do not. Even when employers sponsor health benefits, an increasing number of workers decline coverage because the expense is too great. Equally important, economists generally agree that Americans who are covered pay for workplace insurance in the form of lower wages, and this forgone income represents a growing hardship. Over the past two decades, real premiums have nearly tripled, even as most workers’ real wages have risen only modestly. These voluntary arrangements leave more than million Americans without insurance, almost percent of them in families headed by workers. These arrangements leave to million more Americans insufficiently protected against medical costs and a third of Americans without insurance at some point during a two-year peri od .1 These arrangements saddle Americans with persistent uncertainty about how they will obtain protection if they change jobs or if their employer reduces cover- Stuart H. Altman, Uwe E. Reinhardt, and Alexandra E. Shields. The Future U.S. Healthcare System: Who Will Care for the Poor and Uninsured? Chicago: Health Administration Press, 1998; The Kaiser Commission on Medicaid and the Uninsured, Uninsured in America: A Chart Book, Menlo Park: Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation, 2000. 1 76 FIGURE 1 Share of Employees* with Health Insurance from Their Own Employers, by Wage Quintile, 1979-1998 l l 6 6 F F s l l 6 l F 6 s s l 6 F F n n F Fourth quintile Third quintile s Second quintile s s n Highest quintile 6 n Lowest quintile n n Source: James L. Medoff, Michael Calabrese, and Howard Shapiro. “Impact of Labor Market Trends on Health Care Coverage and Inequality.” Washington: Center for National Policy, October 4, 2000, table H23. *Private, nonagricultural wage and salary workers age 21– 64. a ge . These arrangements channel the largest tax breaks to affluent workers with generous insurance while placing the greatest burdens on lower-income workers and people in poor health. And during a period of notable prosperity, these arrangements are eroding. Ten million more Americans were without insurance in than in , with the most precipitous decline occurring among low-wage workers (see figure ). Over the past two decades, Americans have been required to pay more for their coverage and to join plans that restrict their ch oi ce of provider or limit their benefits. The insurance market continues to fragment while the financial “slack” that underwrites America’s tattered medical safety net grows tighter. If no action is taken, the situation will only grow worse. America’s public insurance programs, valuable as they are for many, do not represent an effective response to the weaknesses of workplace coverage. Although Medicare reaches virtually all elderly and disabled Americans through an inclusive national program, public programs for people under the age of are scattered,incomplete,and often stigmatizing. Aimed at the indigent and the especially vulnerable, these state-based programs offer meager assistance to working-poor parents and childless adults, and virtually none to workers who have coverage but risk losing it or who can barely afford the cost. Eligibility requirements and the availability of care differ dramatically across states,and millions of uninsured Americans who are el i gi ble for public help do not obtain it, including hundreds of thousands of lower-income families who have lost insurance in the transition from welfare to work. Despite the push to enroll children in Medicaid and programs set up under the State Children’s Health Insurance Program (S-CHIP), public coverage of children has actually dropped. Indeed, as late as September , almost half of the federal money allotted for S-CHIP had gone unspent.2 For all the shortcomings of the American approach to the uninsured, however, the political barriers to reform are a direct outgrowth of the incomplete financing system that has arisen in the United States. As the Clinton administration learned to its misfortu n e ,a ny plan that can be portrayed as a direct threat to the private protections that many Americans enjoy faces a steep uphill journey. At the same time, the existing melange of public programs 2 Robert Pear. “40 States Forfeit Health Care Funds for Poor Children.” New York Times (September 24, 2000), A1. 77 also vastly complicates the challenge of reform. Because programs for the non-elderly are meant to fill gaps in private coverage, there is constant reluctance to streamline enrollment or extend public insurance up the income ladder, lest public programs displace private insurance. Moreover, because these programs often provide generous coverage to recipients (at least on paper), reformers legitimately worry that replacing them with a more extensive and uniform plan will deprive some current enrollees of the benefits they now receive. Little wonder then that the road to reform has proved so rocky and the proposals put forward so maddeningly complex. And yet most Americans believe that the current financing system fails to live up to the nation’s ideals.3 Most also deplore the significant financial burden and insecurity that this system imposes on lower-income families, the ill, and those without insurance. The proposal outlined in the following pages presents a long-term policy approach to these fundamental problems based on three principles: . Affordable, guaranteed coverage offering a defined package of benefits should be available to all Americans, regardless of wh et h er their employers sponsor it. . Such coverage should be designed to uphold social insurance precepts, spreading risks broadly through an inclusive plan that is available to all and within the financial reach of the less wealthy and the less healthy. . Basic insurance coverage should be expected of all Americans as long as all have access to an affordable plan. These principles are goals, not methods— guideposts, not pre s c ri ptions. They must be tempered by judgments about the political and administrative constraints that a successful proposal must overcome. Five such judgments guide this proposal: . Universal health insurance will most likely be achieved through a series of large-scale but nonetheless partial steps that will need to be calibrated over time to the responses of other actors and institutions with influence over the breadth and depth of health coverage. . Any proposal that is perceived as taking away or significantly raising the cost of existing private coverage, imposing huge new costs on employers or individuals, or significantly reducing the benefits of public programs, is unlikely to be enacted. . A successful plan must be seen as beneficial and potentially available to all Americans, not as a form of organized charity through which the many aid the few. . Targeting coverage narrowly on the uninsured will likely be self-defeating, reinforcing the current confused welter of programs and leaving unprotected many Americans who are uninsured, insufficiently insured, at risk of becoming uninsured, or under serious financial pressure because of the cost of coverage. . Any plan should be simple to understand and to enroll in, based on popularly understood and time-tested institutions, relatively stra i gh tforward to finance and administer, and subject to democratic control. These principles and judgments underlie the proposal that fo ll ows. It envisions the sequential replacement of most state-federal public insurance programs with a nationwide program modeled after Medicare that all Americans without private coverage could enter by paying an income-related premium. The first part of the exposition lays out the fundamental features of the proposal as they would operate once fully implemented. The second part usefully complicates this neat picture by considering how the proposal might be phased in over time, and how it might attract the necessary political support to become robust legislation. To be sure, Americans’ views are complex and multi-faceted. Nonetheless, a wealth of opinion research indicates that while quite satisfied with the quality (if not the cost) of personal health care, the public is quite dissatisfied with the overall structure of American health financing. See, in particular, Rosita M. Thomas. Health Care in America: An Analysis of Public Opinion. CRS Report for Congress 92-769 GOV, Washington: Congressional Research Service, 1992; Lawrence R. Jacobs and Robert Y. Shapiro. Politicians Don’t Pander: Political Manipulation and the Loss of Democratic Responsiveness. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2000, 232–60; “A Survey of American Attitudes on Health Care Reform,” conducted by the Program on Public Opinion and Health Care and Marttila & Kiley, Inc., for The Robert Wood Johnson Foundation; Altman, Reinhardt, and Shields, 1998, 27–28; Robert J. Blendon et al. “Who Has the Best Health Care System? A Second Look.” Health Affairs 14 (4): 220–30; Robert J. Blendon et al. “Satisfaction with Health Systems in Ten Nations.” Health Affairs 9 (2): 185–92; and Karen R. Donelan et al. “All Payer, Single Payer, Managed Care, No Payer: Patients’ Perspectives in Three Nations” Health Affairs 15 (2): 254–65. 3 78 The Proposal in Brief In broadest outline, the proposal has three central components: . All Americans not covered by Medicare or employer-sponsored insu ra n ce would buy into an expanded Medicare program, called “Medicare Plus,” by paying an income-related premium. Most would be en ro ll ed automatically, either at their place of work or by state outreach efforts. Existing public insurance programs for the non-elderly poor and near-poor would be phased out. . Employers could choose to sponsor coverage at least as generous as that available under Medicare Plus or pay a modest payroll-based contribution to help fund public coverage. Workers whose employers paid the contribution would be enrolled in Medicare Plus automatically, although they could use their employers’ contributions (minus a penalty) to purchase private coverage that met the same standards as workplace plans. With the exception of extremely lavish plans, employer-sponsored insurance would retain its favored tax status. . All Americans would eventually be asked to show proof of coverage. This could be largely done at existing decision points rather than through a s ep a ra te process—when employers demonstrated that they covered their workers, when citizens were automatically enrolled in Medicare Plus, or when those automatically enrolled in Medicare Plus asked to opt out. Before reviewing these three core el em ents in more depth, it is worth noting some features that the plan does not contain. The proposal does not mandate that employers provide comprehensive coverage. It imposes no massive payroll tax on employers that do not sponsor insu ra n ce . It does not require any employer to enroll its workers in a public plan or compel any individual to take public coverage. It does not place vast new requirements on employer-sponsored plans and,indeed, would mean higher costs for few employers that currently offer covera ge . It does not eliminate the favorable tax treatment of health benefits. It does not impose major new regulations on private insurance. It has no new insurance pools, no complicated new tax subsidies, no complex new system of contracting or risk adjustment. It does not restrict the growth of private health spending. Indeed, it forswears essentially all new direct interven ti ons in the private insurance sector. This is not to deny that this proposal would bring a sea change in U.S.health financing—and for the better. All Americans currently eligible for public coverage would join an inclusive insurance pool that would allow them to obtain services from nearly all providers in their region (or to enroll in a qualified private health plan that contracted with Medicare Plus, much as private plans contract with Medicare today). Most smaller and lower-wage employers would likely decide that they would rather pay a modest payroll assessment than sponsor coverage,allowing their workers to receive subsidized coverage through Medicare Plus. Employers that still provided coverage would have to meet minimum standards, and any American without workplace coverage, even those turned down by private insurers, could buy into Medicare Plus. The plan’s simple structure would make it easy to understand, efficient to administer, and a visible target for en ro ll m ent efforts. As a very large payer using Medicare’s basic instruments, Medicare Plus would also have the capacity to ensure that expenditures were contro ll ed and that enrollees always had the option of maintaining free choice of provider. In short, the nation’s fragmented strategy for plugging holes in coverage would be replaced with a simple, inclusive,and familiar public plan through which all Americans without workplace insurance could buy coverage at affordable rates. Of course, this brief sketch leaves out many thorny details that must be tackled by any reform plan. Accordingly, the following sections take up a series of critical topics: benefits, coverage, contributions and premiums, employer and state duties, administration, financing, and horizontal equity. After examining these crucial features of the proposal, I then suggest how they might be put into place through a process of “large-scale incrementalism” that reinforces, rather than retards, political support for further steps toward full implementation. Finally, I consider the reasons why—and the 79 conditions under which—this long-awaited journey to universal insurance coverage could become a possibility. Benefits The Medicare Plus benefits package would be simi lar to the current Medicare package. It would, however, be expected to include several benefits now fully or partially excluded from Medicare coverage — most critically, outpatient prescription drugs, preventive services, mental health services, and maternal and child health. In addition, Medicare Plus would not emulate Medicare in two respects. It would su b s ti tute a single deductible and coinsurance rate for Medicare’s extremely high cost-sharing requirements for inpatient hospital care, and it would include a maximum cap on out - of - pocket spending. Finally, wraparound programs (either state or federal) would continue coverage for additional services now provided by state Medicaid programs to low-income families and children and to the working disabled. The proposal would not disturb current Medicaid arrangements for the nonworking disabled and the elderly. Taken as a whole,therefore, Medicare Plus’s benefits would be relatively modest compared with large employers’ health plans, mainly because of h i gh er cost sharing. Yet, unlike most private plans today, Medicare Plus would provide free choice of provider and place no limit on maximum benefits. And it would still be considerably more expansive than the current Medicare program. Although it would be desirable if these “extra” benefits were also gradually incorporated into Medicare, this proposal does not call for any specific changes in the Medicare benefit package. It seems likely, however, that the most important of these extra benefits—prescription drug coverage—will be incorporated into Medicare in some form within the next decade. Over time, moreover, political pressure from Medicare beneficiaries would likely push toward convergence of benefit levels across Medicare and Medicare Plus,creating the opportunity for an eventual merger. The proposal would also create a new Medicare Benefits Advisory Committee (MedBAC), an expert advisory body that would assist in designing the initial Medicare Plus benefit package, and would review the Medicare Plus and Medicare packages annually thereafter. Harmonizing the two benefit packages would be one of MedBAC’s goals. Whatever the exact benefit package chosen, it must balance competing objectives. Because Medicare Plus would be expected to enroll a large— and, most likely, growing—share of the population, the benefits that it provides need to be generous enough that enrolled Americans would enjoy adequate coverage for the services they need. If the benefits package were too minimal, moreover, all but the poorest and sickest Americans would be reluctant to en ro ll in the program, turning it into a poten ti a lly stigmatizing insurer of last resort. Weighing in the other directi on , however, is the need to minimize both the new revenues necessary to establish the plan and the new burdens on employers that sponsor insurance. Since firms that wished to sponsor tax-favored insu ra n ce would need to provide benefits at least as good as Medicare Plus’s, the benefits package should not be so generous as to require a major upgrade of most employers’ health plans. Coverage All legal U.S. residents without qualified private coverage would be automatically entitled to Medicare Plus.4 Enrollment would occur through three principal channels: . Workplace enrollment. The bulk of Medicare Plus beneficiaries would be enrolled automatically at their place of work when employers elected to make the payroll-based contribution instead of sponsoring tax-favored covera ge . Similarly, selfemployed workers would be required to show proof 4 Arguably, undocumented workers should be treated in the same fashion as other workers, with their employers either providing coverage directly or contributing to Medicare Plus. Yet, it is difficult to conceive of a way in which to levy payroll contributions without relying on Social Security numbers, and this would seem to preclude allowing undocumented workers into Medicare Plus. Nonetheless, undocumented residents would continue to be able to use emergency and other services provided for under current law, and a portion of disproportionate share hospital payments would be preserved to compensate medical institutions that serve large numbers of undocumented patients. 80 All workers and their families would be enrolled automatically in either Medicare Plus or employer-sponsored plans, so the individual mandate would have true significance only for those without ties to the workforce. of coverage or make the payroll-based contribution themselves. . State enrollment. State outreach and enrollment efforts to sign up non-workers (particularly those el i gi ble for Medicaid and other state programs) would be the second major way in which Americans joined Medicare Plus. . Individual buy-in. For those Americans outside the workforce who were not signed up by the states, an individual buy-in option would be available, with premiums scaled to income (but not to health risk). Because all Americans would be el i gi ble for Medicare Plus, the availability (in contrast to the cost) of coverage would not hinge on income or assets. Premiums would be based on income reported for tax purposes and con du cted by Medicare Plus’s enrollment division in coordination with the Internal Revenue Service (IRS). Thus, states would no longer have a reason to impose cumbersome and stigmatizing means tests on potential enrollees. Coverage of an individual under Medicare Plus would be con ti nuous unless one of two events occurred: the individual was hired by a firm that sponsored qualified covera ge , or the individual chose to opt out of Medicare Plus to purchase private coverage individually. In the latter case, the individual would be asked to present an annual insurance contract that met the same minimum standards as those required of workplace coverage. Opting out would be allowed only at the time of initial enrollment in Medicare Plus and during an annual enrollment period, and exemptions would have to be renewed. If the individual worked, the mandatory employer contributions made on his or her behalf, minus percent to compensate for the cost of healthy people disproportionately opting o ut , would be forwarded directly to the qualified plan. The individual would be expected to pay the difference with after-tax do ll a rs . In the unlikely event that the employer payments exceeded the private premium, private plans would be allowed to rebate the difference. All Americans would eventually be required to show proof of public or private covera ge , which could be done by attaching to a federal tax return a standard form supplied by Medicare Plus and qualified private plans. All workers and their families would be enrolled automatically in either Medicare Plus or employer-sponsored plans, so the individual mandate would have true significance only for those without ties to the workforce. To reach the many in this population who do not file tax returns, states would be given powerful incentives to enroll nonworkers in Medicare Plus. States would also be encouraged to subsidize Medicare Plus coverage for the tempora ri ly unemployed, and to establish mechanisms for en ro lling the uninsured in Medicare Plus when they sought care. Contributions and Premiums Most enrollees in Medicare Plus would be workers whose employers elected to make the payroll-based contribution rather than provide qualified coverage. This contribution would equal a percentage of wages, tips, and salaries up to the Social Sec u ri ty wage base (roughly , in ). The level of the contribution would be dictated by three considerations.First, the payroll-based contribution should be low enough that it does not impose an undue burden on low-wage firms, which are least likely to sponsor coverage. Second, the level of the contribution should ensure that Medicare Plus has substantial enrollment, with the majority of en ro ll ees not previously enrolled in public programs. Medicare Plus would not be a public assistance program, but rather the primary source of coverage for working 81 Americans who now struggle to obtain or afford insurance. Finally, the employer contribution rate should be not be so high that it would impose a large new cost (in the form of lower cash wages) on poorer citizens who previously enjoyed public protections or on wealthier citizens who previously enjoyed heavily tax-subsidized coverage. These considera ti ons all point to a contribution rate that is substantially below the average amount that employers now spend for health benefits. The payroll-based contribution suggested here — for esthetic as well policy reasons—is percent. This would be the maximum share of taxable payroll that any firm would be required to pay for health insurance. As described more fully in the section on employers, firms insuring their workers for the first time,and with very low average wages, would be eligible for steep reductions in their initial contribution rate. For those who wish to recall the bitter debates of the early s, percent will seem an extremely modest levy, well below the percent to percent that was common in proposals then. It should be noted that these earlier rates were usually divided between employer and worker, meaning that the portion paid directly by employers was lower. Moreover, the share of wages and salaries that employers spend on health benefits has actually fallen by about a percentage point since the early s. Still, a percent contribution rate is significantly lower than the average share of payroll that employers now pay for health benefits.5 This is intentional: A play-or-pay requirement with a modest contribution rate is an en ti rely different policy approach from the same requirement with a higher rate.A low contribution rate would protect against many of the risks and problems correctly identified with the play-or-pay design (though, of course, it does raise other concerns), and it would create powerful selfreinforcing effects that would serve to bolster the 5 According to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, the average private employer’s health spending represents between 7 percent and 8 percent of wages and salaries. Among firms with more than 500 employees, virtually all of which sponsor coverage, the cost is closer to 9 percent of payroll. U.S. Census Bureau. Statistical Abstract of the United States. Washington: U.S. GPO, 1999, 331. position of Medicare Plus. Nonetheless, the contribution rate should be thought of as a variable rather than an exact value. What is crucial is that the rate chosen is consistent with the goals of the proposal and with the considerations just discussed. In addition to the percent employer contribution,many workers enrolled in Medicare Plus would also be assessed a premium that would vary with income and family size. With regard to all but the poorest Americans,the level of this premium would be set so as to keep the nominal division of employer and worker responsibilities relatively similar to what it is today within firms that sponsor coverage. Economists are surely correct that, in general and over the long term, workers will end up paying much of the “employer share” through lower cash wages. Yet this impeccable economic logic runs up against the reality that most workers today do not recognize the extent to which they pay for health insurance through forgone wages, and most also seem to treat the distinction between employer and employee contributions as meaningful. If preserving the largely fictitious notion of employer contributions is the price that must be paid for significantly expanded covera ge , it seems a small price indeed. Medicare Plus would offer four types of coverage: single (individual), couple (individual and spouse), single-parent family (individual and children), and family (individual, spouse, and children). The amount of the premium for each type of coverage would vary with income and mechanism of enrollment and would be deducted directly from a worker’s paycheck. Although there are several possible premium structu re s ,t a ble describes a simple framework that meshes closely with the proposal’s goals. These premiums are higher than the average monthly amount that insured workers pay today for single coverage (, down from in ). But they are close to the average employee payment for family coverage and to the . monthly premium that Medicare enrollees pay for Part B coverage. And many, if not most, workers enrolled in Medicare Plus would be eligible for subsidies and thus not pay the full premium. For individuals en ro ll ed in Medicare Plus 82 TABLE 1 A Possible Framework for Monthly Premiums, by Income and Coverage Type* Income Relative to FPL** Single Couple Single-Parent Family Family Less than % No premium; cost sharing limited Less than % No premium; cost-sharing subsidies gradually phased out Less than % No premium Less than % – – – – % or more *As with employee payments to private health plans, Medicare Plus premiums would generally not receive favorable tax treatment.The main exceptions would be cases in which premiums plus other health expenses exceeded 7.5 percent of adjusted gross income (under the incometax deduction for extraordinary medical expenses) or in which premiums were paid with funds from a qualified "flexible spending account" set up by an employer. ** In 2000, the federal poverty level (FPL) was roughly $8,500 for an individual and $17,000 for a family of four. through the workplace, determining premium levels would be relatively simple, because payroll-based contributions would be based on wages and thus could be used as a proxy for income. This would also be true, of course, of single-parent families en ro ll ed through the workplace. The situation would be somewhat more complicated for cou pl e and family coverage. If both members of the couple were enrolled in Medicare Plus through the workplace, determining eligibility would be straightforward. A married individual en ro ll ed in Medicare Plus would simply indicate that his or her spouse was also covered, and the program would bill them as a unit for the couple or family premium, basing subsidies on combined income.6 If, by contrast, one member of the couple worked for an employer with private insurance while the other was en ro ll ed in Medicare Plus, estimates of joint income would be based on a combination of the employer’s wage and tax filings and on self-reported income, with a reconciliation process at the time of annual tax filing. Families in this situation could elect to receive fami- 6 It should be noted that the net cost would be the same if, instead of obtaining couple coverage, the couple paid for two single policies. And it would also be the same if, instead of purchasing family coverage as a unit, one member of the couple signed up for single-parent family coverage, and the other paid for single coverage. ly coverage through the private employer, in which case the payroll-based contributions made would be rebated directly to the employer. Or they could elect to buy into Medicare Plus, in which case the firm with private coverage would contribute percent of payroll to defray the cost of coverage under Medicare Plus. In all cases,there would be an annual reconciliation process based on tax information to ensure that Medicare Plus en ro ll ees had paid the appropriate premium in the previous year. Workers who overpaid would be refunded the difference, while workers who had underpaid would be charged the additional amount, which could be taken directly out of a tax refund, if applicable. In the case of major underpayments, a penalty would apply. Premiums would be based solely on income, so there would be no requirement to demonstrate limited assets to justify subsidized premiums or cost sharing. For those without ties to the workforce, both the method for determining income and the level of premiums would necessarily differ. All non-workers, including the unemployed and recipients of public assistance, would receive subsidized coverage if their income fell below percent of the federal poverty level (FPL). As with working Americans, limits on out-of-pocket spending would apply to 83 TABLE 2 Employer Contributions, Monthly Premiums, and Rebates in Four Examples Enrollee(s) Income (relative to FPL) Payroll-Based Contribution* Monthly Premium Rebate for Private Coverage Cost Sharing Limited? Single worker , (%) , (/yr) No Family of four , (%) , Yes Family of four , (%) , (,) , No Non-worker , (%) ** (,) No * If the employing firm paid the maximum 5 percent contribution. non-workers with incomes up to percent of the FPL, phasing out between percent and percent. For non-workers with incomes above percent of the FPL, premiums would rise on a sliding scale from zero for non-workers at percent of the FPL to the average actuarial cost of coverage at percent. As described later, states would be given incentives to establish assistance programs for the tempora ri ly unemployed. Non-workers could amend their self-reported income at any point during the year if their circumstances changed, and the same end-of-year reconciliation process would apply to non-workers as to workers. The four simple examples in table clarify these guidelines. The Role of Employers Although employers would be asked to take on new responsibilities, their obligations under this proposal would be inherently limited.7 Indeed,this proposal should actually reduce costs for many large and high-wage employers by obligating all firms to pay a share of the expense of covering working spouses and by reducing cost shifting from uninsured to insured patients. As for smaller and lower-wage I assume that public employers would be treated in the same way as private ones, but they could simply be required to sponsor coverage meeting minimum standards, since essentially all do now. 7 ** Assuming the average actuarial cost of single coverage was $2,200. employers, Medicare Plus would offer an inexpensive and simple option for insuring their workers, guaranteeing that no firm would have to pay more than percent of covered payroll for insurance. Many firms,however, would pay much less. This is because lower-wage firms and firms that had not previously offered insurance would be eligible for significant reductions in their contribution rate. For lower-wage firms, the payroll-based contribution would be just . percent if average annual wages were below ,, percent if average wages were between , and ,, . percent if average wages were between , and ,, and the full percent if average wages were , or more. Firms that had not offered insurance before would also be eligible for additional rate reductions during the transition period. These transitional reductions would equal . percentage points and would be on top of the discounts for low-wage firms. Thus a lowwage firm that had not offered insurance in the past could pay as little as percent of payroll for Medicare Plus coverage. To be eligible for this transitional reduction, firms would have to be in existence at the time the legislation was passed and not have sponsored insurance in any of the prior five years. This reduction would phase out over years, falling from . percent in year one to . percent in year two and so on. Besides the level of the payroll-based contributions, the potential burdens on business depend 84 upon three key aspects of the proposal: () the nature of the minimum requirements on coverage; () the complexity of administration and compliance; and () the rules for coverage of p a rt - ti m e workers, employees’ dependents, and departing workers. In each area, this proposal offers the maximum possible flexibility consistent with the goal of en su ring that all workers and their dependents receive health insurance. Minimum Requirements on Coverage The relatively modest Medicare Plus benefits package would become the benchmark against which employer-provided health plans were judged. Firms that did not offer coverage that was at least equivalent to Medicare Plus’s protections would be required to make payroll-based contributions to Medicare Plus. Such coverage would not receive special tax treatment. “At least equivalent” does not mean “identical.” Indeed, most employer-sponsored health plans are already more generous than Medicare Plus would be and are likely to remain so. Rather, employer-sponsored plans would have to meet criteria similar to those that currently apply to private health plans contracting with Medicare: Private plans would be required to include all Medicare Plus covered services, but could include additional benefits. Compliance would be assessed by the Department of Labor and the IRS, using congressionally approved guidelines. These enforcement procedures would build to a certain extent on current law. Federal regulations already require that plans furnish a description of benefits to the Secretary of Labor, and that plans with more than participants file a detailed annual return with the IRS (Form ). Administrative and Compliance Requirements To the fullest extent possible, this proposal would rely on existing administrative and enforcement mechanisms rather than new ones. In particular, the choice of payroll-based contributions as a major financing mechanism builds on the well-developed system for collecting Federal Insurance Contributions Act (FICA) taxes for old-age and survivors’ insurance, disability insurance, and Medicare. On top of the . percent FICA tax that employers already pay, firms that did not sponsor private coverage would contribute an additional percent to percent of covered wages. Somewhat more complicated, they would also have to deduct the Medicare Plus premium from paychecks and report these withheld contributions on tax statements. Because premiums would be based on income, formulas for estimating premiums based on current wages and self-reported income would be straightforward to develop. For instance, a new line could be added to worksheets for calculating workers’ automatic tax withholding (W- forms) to determine if workers had additional income that might change their premium. Existing mechanisms would also be expanded to assess whether employers were exempt from the payroll-based contributions. The IRS is already charged with determining whether employer-provided health benefits qualify for favorable tax treatment. Under this proposal, the IRS’s role would expand in three main directions. First, the IRS would assess whether employers actually sponsored insurance for their workers and dependents. Second, the IRS (in concert with the Department of Labor) would judge whether this coverage met the minimum standards necessary to allow the employer to be exempt from payroll-based contributions for the fo ll owing tax year. Third, the IRS would become the con du i t between enrolled workers and Medicare Plus, collecting payroll-based contributions and premiums while recording plan exit and entry. Accordingly, firms would be required to notify the IRS when workers entered or left their employ. All these duties would be compatible with existing IRS procedures and could be carried out using the normal tax calendar and reporting mechanisms. The favorable tax treatment of health insurance would be largely preserved under this proposal, with two important exceptions.First, supplemental plans provided by employers whose workers enrolled in Medicare Plus would not be tax-exempt. This not only would protect against large revenue losses, but also would discourage employers from economizing by dropping insurance and providing wraparound benefits to bring coverage back up to previous levels. Second, the tax exclusion for health benefits 85 would be capped at a level twice that of the imputed Medicare Plus premium. (A more complicated alternative, which would account for regional premium variations, would be to cap the level at twice the average amount paid by Medicare Plus to contracting private plans in a given geographic area. Given how high the cap is, this seems unnecessarily complex.) All other benefits currently receiving favorable tax treatment—or slated to receive it, as with the deductibility of premiums for the selfemployed—would continue to do so. Coverage Rules Employers that did not make payroll-based contributions to Medicare Plus would be required to offer comparable insurance coverage to all of their employees as well as their employees’ spouses and non-working children under the age of . They would also be required to automatically enroll all of their workers in one or more qualified health plans, a ll owing individuals to opt out only if they had alternative coverage. In practice, this would mean that employers could only exclude from coverage a worker who had a family policy through Medicare Plus (in which case the firm would contribute percent of the worker’s payroll to Medicare Plus) or through another employer (in which case the worker would show proof of private coverage under another employer’s plan, and the two firms would be free to arrange transfer payments, if they desired). Again, if an employer covered a spouse working for a firm that did not sponsor private insurance,the non-sponsoring firm’s percent contribution would be transferred to the other employer. Similar rules would apply to workers with more 8 These rules are less complex than they may appear at first. Recall that a worker whose employer did not offer coverage would be automatically enrolled in Medicare Plus. If that worker had coverage from another employer, he or she would simply notify Medicare Plus and show proof of coverage, and Medicare Plus would transfer the payroll contribution made by the first employer to the second. The same is true in the case of spousal coverage. A worker enrolled in Medicare Plus who had alternative coverage through a spouse would ask to decline Medicare Plus coverage and show proof of private coverage, and Medicare Plus would transfer the worker ’s contribution to the sponsor of the spouse’s plan. To be sure, this approach carries the risk that some workers will not report alternative coverage and simply remain in Medicare Plus (or take coverage from both sources). At least among those who are paying a premium to Medicare Plus, however, this would than one job. For example, if one employer of a worker with two jobs provided private coverage and the other did not, the latter employer would contribute percent of covered payroll to pay for the private policy.8 The minimum share of private premiums that employers would be required to contribute would vary with the type of coverage and the number of hours an employee worked.9 For employees who worked more than half-time, the minimum share would be three-quarters of the premium for single coverage and two-thirds for family coverage.10 (If an employer offered multiple qualified plans, the contribution floor would apply to the lowest-cost plan.) For employees who worked between one and hours a week, the minimum share would be lower, though exactly how much lower is hard to say, because the requirement would need to be sensitive to estimated effects on employer and worker spending. One possible approach would be to have the share fall by a percentage point for each hour fewer than worked per week. An employee who worked hours a week, for example, could be asked to pay as much as percent of the premium for single coverage and percent for family coverage. This would lower the expense of part-time workers without creating incentives for firms to increase reliance on such workers to evade coverage requirements. A weakness of many past plans that relied on an employer mandate or play-or-pay requirement is that they would have drastically reduced the cost of insuring parttime workers, en co u ra ging firms to hire part-time workers or limit existing workers’ hours. This proposal would maintain the Consolidated Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act (COBRA) con- seem a relatively unattractive option. Independent contractors would be treated as self-employed workers, while temporary and contract workers would have to be insured by the firm judged to be their primary employer—either the firm to which they provided services or the firm that arranged their employment. 9 10 Across all employers sponsoring plans in 2000, the average share of the premium paid was 86 percent for single coverage and 73 percent for family coverage, although the average shares have been as low as 79 percent and 68 percent, respectively, over the past decade. Jon Gabel et al. “Job-Based Health Insurance in 2000: Premiums Rise Sharply While Coverage Grows.” Health Affairs 19 (5): 147–48. Under the Federal Employees Health Benefits Program, government premium contributions average just over 70 percent. 86 TABLE 3 Costs and Benefits of Employers’ New Role New Costs Firms that Do Not Sponsor Insurance Firms that Sponsor Insurance At least percent of covered payroll for health benefits New requirements governing level and breadth of coverage Reporting and compliance expenses Cap on tax exclusion Reporting and compliance expenses New Benefits Access to low-cost coverage for workers through Medicare Plus New payments to cover working spouses Ten-year transitional reductions in Medicare Plus contribution rate Opportunity to limit cost of health benefits by paying into Medicare Plus Reduced cost of COBRA requirement makes coverage more affordable Reduced cost of COBRA requirement makes coverage more affordable Reduction in unpaid medical bills makes coverage more affordable Reduction in unpaid medical bills makes coverage more affordable ti nu a ti on requirement, but would slash its costs. Although displaced workers could obtain COBRA covera ge , most undoubtedly would choose subsidized insurance under Medicare Plus, especially if state unemployment insurance programs helped with the premiums. For this reason, employers would have markedly greater reason to inform departing workers of their statutory rights than they do now, because many employees who might have taken up COBRA coverage in the past would choose Medicare Plus instead. As under COBRA, employers would be required to provide standard information describing departing workers’ options. The new costs and benefits for employers are summed up in table . On the cost side, employers that do not sponsor health insurance now will have to pay at least percent of covered payroll for health benefits. Employers that do sponsor health insurance will have to bear new costs if their coverage fails to meet the minimum standards and they choose to upgrade it, or in the rarer event that they provide health coverage so expensive that it runs afoul of the new cap on the tax exclusion. All firms will have to comply with the proposal’s modest new administrative and compliance requirements. On the benefit side, firms that do not now provide coverage will be able to purchase low-cost coverage for their workers through Medicare Plus and will be eligible for transitional reductions in the Medicare Plus payroll contribution. Many firms that provide coverage for working dependents of their employees will receive a new transfer payment to of fs et the cost. Some firms that now provide coverage may also benefit from the option of enrolling their workers in Medicare Plus, which would effectively cap their direct obligations. The cost of COBRA continuation coverage will also be dramatically reduced, and all firms will benefit from the reduction in unpaid medical bills incurred by the uninsured. The Role of the States This proposal would end Medicaid and S-CHIP as we know them. Those now eligible for Medicaid and S-CHIP with ties to the workforce would be covered by Medicare Plus or employer-sponsored plans. For 87 eligible non-workers, the role of the states would largely be transformed from a provider of insurance into a portal for coverage under Medicare Plus. Nonetheless, states would still retain a substantial role. This role would, in important respects, be financial.States would be required to make “maintenance-of-effort” payments to Medicare Plus equal to their existing and projected spending on Medicaid and S-CHIP benefits for children, n on elderly adults, and the working disabled. Yet states would also serve vital administrative and enrollment functions. Not only would they be expected to continue to finance long-term care for eligible populations, they also would be responsible for () enrollment of non-workers, () provision of wraparound coverage, and () subsidization of Medicare Plus premiums for the unemployed. Enrollment of Non-Workers Although many Americans eligible for Medicaid and S-CHIP would be automatically en ro ll ed in Medicare Plus through their place of work, states would be given strong incentives to enroll the remaining uninsured in the program. These incentives would come in the form of reductions in the state’s maintenance-of-effort requirement. For each uninsured person previously eligible for Medicaid or S-CHIP that a state enrolled in Medicare Plu s ,t h e state’s maintenance-of-effort payments would be reduced by an amount proportional to previous state per capita spending. This credit, in effect, would give states that had expanded coverage in earlier years comparatively greater scope to reduce their financial responsibilities. In addition, of course, states would directly reduce their spending on Medicaid or S-CHIP by shifting beneficiaries into Medicare Plus. For non-workers not previously eligible for Medicaid or S-CHIP, a smaller credit would be awarded. A portion of prior Medicaid spending would also be earmarked for ongoing outreach efforts, with costs shared between the federal government and the states,as under current law. Provision of Wraparound Coverage An important principle of this proposal is that cur rent recipients of public coverage should not receive less generous benefits than they do now—although, of course, some would be paying a portion of the cost of coverage that they currently receive free or virtually free. It is important, therefore, that wraparound coverage be available to provide those eligible for Medicaid with benefits that are not included in Medicare Plus or are not commonly covered by employer-sponsored health plans. This wraparound coverage would be provided to former recipients who continued to meet their state’s income eligibility criteria. It would also be provided to all those automatically eligible for Medicaid coverage under federal law.11 Employers of workers likely to fall into either category would be informed that no-cost supplemental policies were available. In providing wraparound coverage, the states would have two options. They could con ti nue to operate state programs to provide these benefits, with the state share of spending credited against maintenance-of-effort payments. Alternatively, they could agree to have these populations enrolled in a set of standardized federal supplements to Medicare Plus. States would be encouraged to choose the second option by generous terms: For each en ro ll ee , the state’s contribution would be equal to the (regionally adjusted) average cost of the supplemental package multiplied by percent of the state’s previous matching share of Medicaid spending. Thus,if a state previously paid percent of expenditures, it would pay percent of the cost of the supplemental package.12 Both the state’s contribution and the percent savings would be credited against maintenance-of-effort payments. Subsidization of Coverage for the Unemployed The tempora ri ly unemployed represent a distinct population that states could do much to help. Although workers between jobs may be eligible for COBRA coverage, they must finance the entire cost at a time when they are often under financial strain. Moreover, such workers may end up having non11 Over the long term, it would be desirable if the eligibility requirements for wraparound coverage were standardized and federalized to ensure equal treatment of citizens across states. This formula is similar to the enhanced federal matching rate under SCHIP. 12 88 trivial incomes for the year and thus be reluctant to participate in Medicare Plus out of fear that they will be asked to repay subsidies or incur a penalty. (This concern would be largely unfounded because workers could amend their expected income during the year.) Those who are between jobs and uninsured are, in short, precisely the sort of group for which a social insurance system requiring small sums to be put aside for future contingencies would be well suited. Currently, however, no such system exists. As a response to this problem, states would be encouraged to develop a framework of subsidies for the tempora ri ly unemployed. This system could operate in conjunction with unemployment insurance and be financed by a small surcharge on state unemployment taxes. Alternatively, states could operate federally backed low-interest loan programs paying the Medicare Plus premiums of the unemployed, with full or partial forgiveness offered to workers whose income after regaining employment fell below a specified level. At a minimum, states would be required to provide enrollment information to all recipients of jobless benefits. States that operated such programs, which would be largely self-financing, would receive a reduction in their contribution requirement proportional to the number of unemployed residents assisted. The replacement of state insurance programs with alternative arrangements poses unavoidable challenges. This is as true of many tax credit proposals as it is of the Medicare expansion outlined here. Replacing Medicaid and S-CHIP with a refundable tax credit, for example, could easily cause some former beneficiaries to lose benefits, face higher costs, or fail to obtain coverage. By comparison, the transition process envisioned under this proposal contains only minor risks. All current Medicaid and S-CHIP beneficiaries with ties to the workforce would be automatically guaranteed coverage, and most would be el i gi ble for generous subsidies. Virtually all of the remaining beneficiaries would be members of populations that states are required by federal law to cover—most notably, individuals who meet eligibility criteria for the former Aid to Families with Dependent Children program, preg- nant wom en , and very poor children. At the same time, states would have overwhelming financial incentives to move these recipients into Medicare Plus. Finally, all former Medicaid beneficiaries would be guaranteed supplemental benefits through state or federal wraparound programs. Administration A crucial virtue of this proposal—or crucial vice, for those who harbor deep-seated animus toward the Health Care Financing Administration (HCFA)— is that it builds on well-established and time-tested institutions of administra ti on and finance. This choice is not incidental: Medicare is a familiar and overwhelmingly popular program, Americans’ famed distrust of government notwithstanding.13 Judged across many dimensions, moreover, it succeeds admirably in covering a high-needs population that private insurers shunned almost entirely before its implementation. It has a well-developed, if not well-funded, administrative infrastructure; an established system of private administrative intermediaries; a sophisticated hospital and physician payment schedule;an improving procedure for contracting with private health plans; and,above all, an accepted and longstanding place in American medical finance. Any health policy analyst could no doubt dream up health financing systems that work far better than Medicare does. But existing and necessarily imperfect institutions — wh et h er public programs or private benefits—should first be judged,not against rosy visions of ideal reforms, but against concrete alternatives. Expanding Medicare is the best route to inclusive and nationally comparable coverage that reaches all Americans not insured through employment. That said, the new responsibilities inherent in this proposal will require improvements in MediNinety-five percent of Americans believe it is “important” or “very important” that Medicare be preserved, putting it alongside Social Security as the cherished core of American social insurance. And among Americans within 15 years of entering the program, Medicare is more trusted as a provider of high-quality and easily accessible care than either employer-sponsored insurance or privately purchased individual coverage. Cathy Schoen et al. Counting on Medicare: Perspectives and Concerns of Americans Age 50 to 70. New York: The Commonwealth Fund, 1999. 13 89 Expanding Medicare is the best route to inclusive and nationally comparable coverage that reaches all Americans not insured through employment. care’s occasionally creaky administrative machinery, if only because this proposal envisions a major expansion of the program. Because Medicare’s administrative costs are already quite low (less than percent of total program expenditures), administrative spending could be boosted without bri n gi n g expenditures anywhere close to the administrative costs of private health plans. Under this proposal,HCFA would have primary responsibility for Medicare Plus, as it does now for Medicare. The Social Security Administration and Treasury and Labor departments would see the expansion of their historical roles as managers of the FICA tax system and regulators of the operation and tax treatment of private health plans. As already discussed, states would also have important administrative duties related to the en ro ll m ent of n on workers in Medicare Plus and, if they so chose, the provision of wraparound coverage. With few exceptions, then, Medicare Plus would expand existing administrative institutions rather than create new ones. Like Medicare, Medicare Plus would consist of a default fee-for-service program coupled with a system of contracts with private health plans. Medicare Plus would use existing Medicare rates, ad ju s ted when necessary for the lower costs of the non-elderly. In service areas where Medicare coverage does not now extend, new rate schedules would be developed based on existing methodologies. Medicare Plus would contract with private health plans using procedures similar to those now used or under development by HCFA. Because enrollees in Medicare Plus are more likely to be familiar with health maintenance organizations and other private plans, and less likely to have chronic conditions, they will probably be more interested in private plans than are elderly Medicare beneficiaries. On the other hand, because Medicare Plus will cover a more comprehensive range of benefits than Medicare, Medicare Plus en ro ll ees may have less incentive than Medicare beneficiaries to join private plans offering benefits not covered under the feefor-service program. Financing Neither the payroll-based contributions nor the premiums are designed to cover the full cost of providing Medicare Plus benefits. The chief reasons for this are fivefold: • The opposition of businesses that do not provide insurance would likely be overwhelming if the payroll-based contributions were raised to a level closer to full funding. Under this proposal, all employers would make some contribution to the cost of i n su ra n ce , but none is forced to assume a large new burden. • A higher tax, even when proportional to income, also places a significant burden on lowwage workers, who are not only least capable of paying any new levy, but also most likely to have earnings at or near the minimum wage. For these workers, new labor costs cannot be fully of fs et by wage cuts and may increase unemployment. • The premiums and payroll-based contributions are set so that virtually all working and nonworking participants in Medicare Plus would purchase coverage at highly subsidized rates, with lower-income participants receiving a large subsidy. This cannot be done without tapping into other funding sources. • Relying on multiple sources of financing guards against the disruptions that might occur if any one source failed to produce the expected revenue. • Most important from a political standpoint, multiple-source financing is essential if legislators are to minimize the visible new costs that Americans 90 will face. Current financing arrangements fundamentally obscure the real costs to Americans of health insurance. Any transition away from this system will require careful policy choices designed to avoid imposing large, visible, and immediate losses, and this entails sacrificing some degree of clarity in the interest of political feasibility. The magnitude of the funding shortfall depends on three principal factors: () the generosity of Medicare Plus coverage, () the number of workers whose employers choose to make payroll-based contributions rather than to sponsor qualified coverage, and () the income and health characteristics of those who en ro ll in the program, which would influence both revenues and costs. Since the benefit package has already been discussed, the brief analysis that fo ll ows examines the second and third of these three crucial factors. How Many Americans Will Be Enrolled in Medicare Plus? This proposal requires firms to provide basic health coverage, but allows them to limit their financial obligations by enrolling workers in Medicare Plus. It thus incorporates the core element of the (now much-maligned) play-or-pay plans of the early s, which were subject to a number of separate estimations.14 Although this proposal differs markedly from these earlier plans, the various analyses conducted nonetheless provide some guidance as to its likely effects. The key va ri a ble in estimating the number of working Americans who will be covered under a play-or-pay proposal is the “pay” requirement— that is, the share of payroll that employers are required to contribute to the public plan if they choose not to insure their workers. A lower contribution requirement will result in more workers For example, The Pepper Commission. A Call for Action. Washington: U.S. GPO, 1990; Jack A. Meyer and Sharon Silow-Carroll (eds.,). Building Blocks for Change: How Health Care Reform Affects Our Future. Reston, VA: ESRI, 1993; John Holahan, Marilyn Moon, W. Pete Welch, and Stephen Zuckerman. Balancing Access, Costs, and Politics: The American Context for Health System Reform. Washington: Urban Institute, 1991; Sheila R. Zedlewski, Gregory P. Acs, and Colin W. Winterbottom. “PlayOr-Pay Employer Mandates: Potential Effects.” Health Affairs 11 (1)(2000): 61–83. 14 en ro lling in the public plan.15 Typically, analysts have assumed that employers (and, by implication, workers) do not care whether coverage is public or private, and will choose the option that minimizes costs. This assumption seems persuasive with regard to firms that do not sponsor insurance but somewhat more questionable with regard to firms that do. After all, these latter firms sponsor insurance in the absence of any coverage requirement, presumably because of labor competition and tax policy. If workers in this firm’s labor pool continued to desire private coverage, and if tax policy remained essentially the same, these employers might continue to sponsor private insurance despite being able to obtain public protections for a lower cost. Because of the significant uncertainty surrounding employer responses, forecasts based on the assumption that employers minimize costs should be considered upper-bound estimates of public plan enrollment. Previous estimates suggest that at a percent to percent contribution rate, between percent and percent of the non-elderly population would be covered by public insurance, compared with approximately percent today. It is important to recognize, however, that most of this increase is due to the movement of Americans who are uninsured or have non-group insurance into public coverage, not the transfer of workers out of employmentbased health plans. Indeed,earlier estimates suggest that even at contribution rates as low as percent, the share of Americans en ro ll ed in employmentbased plans would most likely increase as the uninsured and non-group insured moved into both public coverage and workplace plans. This would certainly not be the case if the payroll contribution rate were percent or lower. Still, the shift from private group coverage to Medicare Plus might not be as large as earlier estimates suggest. In 15 Many of these earlier estimates further assume that employers minimize their direct contributions under each option (rather than total premiums, including the share paid by workers). Yet it is not clear why the respective shares of the premium paid by employers and workers should make a difference for firm decisions (as long, of course, as both receive favorable tax treatment). Rather, employers would be expected to compare the total cost required to provide coverage via private insurance to the total cost of providing insurance under public auspices. 91 the first place ,s i n ce the early s, employers have kept health costs in check during a period of impressive wage growth. As already noted, employer health spending is lower as a share of wages now than it was a decade ago. Moreover, the recent upswing in the incidence of employment-based coverage masks a long-term decline in rates of plan sponsorship and coverage among low-wage employers .G iven that the employers most likely to take advantage of the “pay” option increasingly do not provide health benefits, the expected shift from public to private coverage may well be less significant today than it was a decade ago. Finally, percent represents only the mandatory employer contribution, not the total cost of Medicare Plus covera ge . Workers with incomes above percent of the federal poverty line would have to pay additional premiums, so the effective contribution could exceed percent for workers obtaining single coverage and percent for workers obtaining family coverage.16 Although reliable forecasts will require microsimulation modeling, a very rough high-end estimate based on earlier studies and current data is that approximately percent to percent of the n on - el derly population would be enrolled in Medicare Plus when the program was fully implemented.17 Put more simply, the plan would be very large—certainly larger than was contemplated (at least openly) by any of the sponsors of play-or-pay proposals in the past, when critics loudly charged that a public plan with a third of the non-elderly population was an abandonment of the American way.18 These critics will resurface whatever the size of the public plan. But this is an area where an intuitive and widely held notion—that displacement of employment-based coverage should be avoided at all costs—is fundamentally at odds with good public policy. A large public plan should be embraced, not avoided. It is,in fact, key to fulfilling the goals of this proposal. The virtues of a large public plan are multiple and compelling. First,a large plan enrolling a signif icant share of the population ensures that a diverse cross-section of Americans will be within a common insurance pool, which is essential both for the political strength of the program and to guard against the prospect that the public plan will be saddled with the highest-risk groups. Second, a large public plan facilitates cost control by simultaneously increasing the bargaining power of the public plan and the share of health costs paid by it. Third, and perhaps most often overlooked, a large public plan ensures that subsidies for coverage are available, not just to the very poor and the previously uninsured, but to near-poor and lower-middle-class workers, who are burdened the most by high premiums and at the greatest risk of losing covera ge . Because the premiums of employment-based plans essentially constitute a regressive head tax, a low contribution rate and large public plan inevitably produce a more progressive distribution of the costs of health coverage than a higher contribution rate and smaller public plan. Although anathema to the philosophy of some on the left, the notion that the public sector should cover lower- and middle-income Americans while leaving the more affluent in private arrangements is not really so exotic or threatening. Social Security’s benefit formula, after all, provides income replacement rates that are far lower for high-income workers than for low-income workers, and few are surprised or dismayed that, as a result, most upper- 16 The highest effective rate would be paid by a worker at exactly 300 percent of the federal poverty level—roughly, $25,500 for an individual and $51,000 for a family of four. With the full Medicare Plus premium set at $600 per year for an individual and $1,680 for a family, the effective rates would go up by 2.3 percentage points (600 divided by 25,500) and 3.3 percentage points (1,680 divided by 51,000), respectively. who are currently covered by employment-based coverage (22 percent to 39 percent of the non-elderly population). These expected enrollment rates use the high-end estimates of Zedlewski, Acs, and Winterbottom, 2000, as the low end of the range of possible effects. Data on the current distribution of coverage among the non-elderly come from the Current Population Survey tabulations of John Holahan and Johnny Kim. “Why Does the Number of Uninsured Americans Continue to Grow?” Health Affairs 19 (4): 189. 17 This would include all or virtually all former recipients of Medicaid and other public insurance programs (approximately 9 percent to 10 percent of the non-elderly population); nearly all of the previously uninsured (15 percent to 18 percent of the non-elderly population); 80 percent to 100 percent of Americans with non-group insurance (4 percent to 5 percent of the non-elderly population); and a third to three-fifths of Americans 18 Confusingly, a chorus of criticism also raised the concern that the public plan would be too small—an unpopular, stigmatizing, residual plan enrolling only those on the periphery of the economy or dependent upon public assistance. 92 income workers obtain private supplements. In the Netherlands, about a third of citizens are allowed to remain outside the statutory health program, with no dire effects. Similar rules apply in Germany. In contrast, the traditional American approach has been to target new coverage at the bottom third of the income scale while trying not to disturb coverage among the top two-thirds. But the better approach, on both political and distributive grounds, is quite the opposite: Provide good, affordable coverage to the bottom two-thirds of Americans, and let the top one-third essentially do what they please. Of course, critics will decry this approach as an unstoppable expansion of government’s purview. But they will also argue for a minimal tax on struggling small and low-wage firms,and a lower tax will mean a larger public program. Moreover, the initial enrollment in the public plan will not be etched in stone. If the private sector keeps insurance costs down,then an increasing number of workers will be shifted back into employment-based plans. Nothing in this plan prevents employers from providing qualified coverage on their own. In contending that the scope of the public plan will inexorably grow, opponents must essentially concede that employers cannot be counted on to provide insurance or restrain the growth of private premiums. What Will Be the Characteristics of Medicare Plus Enrollees? In addition to the virtues just enumerated, a large public plan also addresses the second major criticism of past play-or-pay proposals: that the public plan will be su bj ect to a devastating influx of the unhealthy. Such adverse selection is always a potential problem, but much less so when half or more of Americans under age are enrolled in the public plan. To begin with, those most likely to be moved into public coverage are probably not much more costly than average.19 Although some of the uninsured are in poor health (in part because they lack insurance), many are young and inexpensive to insure. The same is true of lower-wage workers. Past estimates suggest that the overall costs of uninsured Americans should be about equal to the rest of the population once they are covered. If Medicare Plus simply enrolled all citizens up to a given wage level — say, three times the poverty level—there would be little reason to expect significant adverse selection. But, of course, that is not what Medicare Plus would do. Employers that can obtain lower rates in the private market are free to opt out of the program, and individuals and families can elect to get back percent of employer payroll contributions to purchase coverage on their own. As a result, employers with high-risk workforces would have a stronger financial incentive to pay the fixed payroll contribution than similarly situated employers with low-risk workforces, and high-risk individuals and families would be less likely to opt out of Medicare Plus than lowrisk individuals and families. These responses would raise the average risk of enrollees in Medicare Plus. For several reasons, the probable effect appears manageable. With regard to employers’ behavior, the overriding determinant of the ch oi ce between public and private coverage would be average wages rather than the health characteristics of workers, because the cost of coverage is so heavily subsidized at lower wage levels. In addition, nearly all smaller firms would probably enroll their workers in Medicare Plus to avoid the large administrative and loading costs of private insu ra n ce in the smallgroup market. Thus, most firms that opted out would be larger groups, which would be expected to have more heterogeneous risk profiles. Moreover, to the extent that there was moderate adverse selection against Medicare Plus because high-risk groups opted in,this could be defended as the equivalent of a federal high-risk pool, protecting the private group market from the destabilizing effects of an extremely skewed distribution of risks. 19 The only possible exception is the 12 million Americans with nongroup insurance, who do appear to be above-average risks. Mark Pauly and Bradley Herring, Pooling Health Insurance Risks, Washington: AEI, 1999, ch. 6; Alice M. Rivlin, David M. Cutler, and Len M. Nichols. “Cost Estimates: Authors Respond.” Health Affairs Supplement (Spring 1994): 55; P. Anthony Hammond. “Actuarial Memorandum: Premiums in Regional Health Alliances under the Clinton Administration’s Proposed Health Security Act.” Health Insurance Market Reform, Hearing before the Committee on Finance, United States Senate, 103rd Congress, 2nd Session, February 1, 1994, Washington: U.S. GPO, 1994, pp. 102–4. 93 If adverse selection were more severe, several possible remedies could be adopted. An obvious solution would be to impose community rating and other reforms on the private insurance sector. But this would inspire considerable political opposition and interfere with the practices of self-insured health plans. Instead, an attractive halfway measure would be to make it more difficult for employers to shift between public and private covera ge . For example, exemptions from the payroll-based contributions could be renewed on a five- or -year basis rather than annually, forcing employers to stay in or out of Medicare Plus for a long, continuous period. Employers could also be penalized for opting into the plan in proportion to the number of years they had stayed outside it, discouraging opportunistic switching as workforces age. Similar remedies could be used to reduce adverse selection caused by the individual opt-out provision, but fewer problems should arise here for at least four reasons. F i rs t , those who opt out of Medicare Plus receive back only the amount that their employer contributed to the program,minus a percent penalty designed to reduce adverse selecti on . In other words, no income-related subsidies are available for the purchase of non-group coverage. Second, private non-group coverage is, in most cases, not eligible for special tax treatment.20 For all but very-high-income buyers,this means that a fairly substantial portion of private premiums will have to be paid with after-tax dollars. Third, opting out of Medicare Plus will require an affirmative decision and a potentially costly search. Evidence on private benefit plans suggests that, even with minimal switching costs, levels of participant inertia are very high.21 Fourth, and finally, non-group premiums are comparatively expensive and, absent insurance reform, undoubtedly will remain so. For political reasons, it seems prudent to allow 20 The exceptions are when it is purchased by the self-employed, or when premiums plus health costs exceed 7.5 percent of income, under the deduction for extraordinary medical expenses. If the opt-out provision were destabilizing Medicare Plus, however, the extraordinary expense deduction could be amended to exclude private non-group insurance premiums. Brigitte C. Madrian and Dennis F. Shea. “The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) Participation and Savings Behavior.” National Bureau of 21 people to leave Medicare Plus if they have qualified private coverage. Some affluent Americans will surely seize this expensive exit option,as do affluent citizens in other social insurance systems that allow it. But in practice very few Americans will find the rebate attractive. Additional Financing Despite the advantages of a lower contribution rate, it does have the disadvantage that it brings in less revenue per enrollee, even as it increases the size of the public plan. The amount of revenue forgone at lower contribution rates, however, is not proportional to the reduction in the rate. This is because a significant proportion of enrollees in Medicare Plus — public assistance recipients, non-workers, very-low-wage workers—would pay little or nothing toward the cost of coverage at any tax rate. Furthermore, as the tax rate goes up, fewer employers contribute to the plan, and they contribute less on avera ge . Finally, as already discussed, adverse selection is likely to be a greater problem at higher contribution rates than at lower ones. The contribution rate and premiums envisioned in this proposal clearly imply a significant net government cost.22 How significant a cost is the big question. It bears noting that several features of the proposal help to keep net expenditures in check. F i rs t , all workers enrolled in Medicare Plus have a share of their wages automatically devoted to health insurance. Although this proportion is relatively modest and will cover only a small fraction of the cost of coverage at the lowest wage levels, s om e workers who previously received public coverage for free will now make a contribution, while some with h i gh er earnings will pay all or most of the cost of their coverage. This differentiates this proposal from plans relying on refundable tax credits or expansions of low-income programs, because these plans typi- Economic Research Working Paper No. W7682, Cambridge: NBER, May 2000. 22 This is to be distinguished from a net cost to the economy as a whole. In the short term, new spending on the uninsured would raise economy-wide costs, but if Medicare Plus effectively slowed the rate of increase in health expenditures, these costs would be outweighed by savings quickly. 94 TABLE 4 Other Potential Sources of Revenue, with CBO Estimates Source Revenue, - Rationale Expand Medicare to include uncovered public employees . billion Most excluded workers qualify for coverage on the basis of another job or their spouse’s employment. One to percent “health tax” on private insurance payments or provider revenues from private sources No CBO estimates available Would compensate for adverse selection against Medicare Plus and ensure that high-income workers made some contribution to the program. Would also reduce externality costs of rising private health costs Increase the cigarette tax up to cents/pack Up to billion Increasing excise taxes would reduce the health costs of smoking. Increase the federal alcohol tax up to per proof gallon Up to billion Increasing excise taxes would reduce the health costs of alcohol consumption. Three percent excise tax on non-retirement fringe benefits – billion Would reduce the subsidy for benefits without requiring the valuation of each employee’s benefits. Sources: Congressional Budget Office. Budget Options. Washington: Author, March 2000; Sherry Glied. Chronic Condition: Why Health Reform Fails. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1997, ch. 8.; Sheldon D. Pollack. “It’s Alive.” American Prospect 11 (17) (July 31, 2000). cally raise little or nothing directly from recipients. Second, this proposal limits new subsidies for coverage to those insured by Medicare Plus. Although the rationale for this feature is discussed in the next section, the important point to note is that it further reduces the budgetary costs of the plan. Third, the proposal eliminates federal spending for S-CHIP and for some portions of the Medicaid program, while recapturing a large share of previous state spending for these purposes (as well as unspent S-CHIP funds). By vastly reducing the strain on providers that serve low-income communities, it would also allow for a significant reduction in federal and state spending on disproportionate share hospital payments. Fourth, the proposal will naturally create three positive revenue effects: a reduction in tax subsidies for workers who shift from tax-favored private cov- erage into Medicare Plus, a reduction in tax subsidies now realized by people who purchase very expensive health coverage, and a long-term increase in payroll and income tax receipts caused by the substitution of wages for health benefits among firms that pay less for insurance than they would have without reform. Nonetheless, additional financing will be needed. A significant share could c ome from the -year budget surplus, roughly trillion of which is due to the recent slowdown in the growth of Medicare and Medicaid.23 Table lists a handful of ad d i ti on a l sources of revenue that could potentially be tapped. (The list is illustrative, not exhaustive.) All receipts Karen Davis, Cathy Schoen, and Stephen C. Schoenbaum. “A 2020 Vision for American Health Care.” Annals of Internal Medicine 160 (22) (2000). 23 95 would be transferred directly into a dedicated Medicare Plus trust fund that would have access to permanent budget authority, a ll owing budget resources to be spent without new legislation.24 Fiscal Sustainability Programs need to do more than get up and running; they must also be fiscally sustainable over time. Given that medical cost escalation has fairly consistently outpaced wage growth, is there any reason to expect that a public program covering a defined set of benefits would be able to con ti nue into the future, absent huge tax increases? And what assurances are there that the surplus that now makes general revenues look attractive won’t evaporate in the future, forcing a Darwinian struggle among a rash of underfunded programs? The second question has an easy answer: There is no assurance that any program, even one financed solely by earmarked contributions and possessing entitlement status, will not confront future fiscal pressures. The suggestion that general revenues should finance a portion of Medicare Plus reflects twin policy judgments: first, that the surplus is due in substantial part to reductions in Medicare and Medicaid spending; and, second,that the program should not be financed solely by payroll levies, which would impose excessive costs on lower-wage workers and the firms that employ them. It also reflects a political ju d gm en t that Medicare Plus will be large and popular enough to weather potential fiscal storms. The broader concern about fiscal sustainability is more serious. Here too, however, important features of Medicare Plus promise to keep its costs manageable over time. In the first place, affected businesses will put heavy political pressure on Congress to minimize the payroll-based contributions. Although these contributions are not the only financing source, keeping them at modest levels will act as an effective restraint on program growth. It 24 Some may find it strange to create a trust fund when full funding for Medicare Plus would not come from earmarked payroll taxes. But this is quite consistent with the financing of many existing trust funds, including Medicare’s Part B trust fund, which is financed principally by general revenues. See Eric M. Patashnik. Putting Trust in the U.S. Budget: Federal Trust Funds and the Politics of Commitment. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2000. will also ensure that Medicare Plus enrolls a significant share of the workforce, maximizing the program’s ability to use its concentrated purchasing power to keep medical expenditures in check. Indeed, if sustainability is a concern, it applies equally well to private-sector spending. Medical costs that rise consistently faster than the economy as a whole translate into a growing share of national income devoted to health care, whether those costs are financed by public or private sources. There is no compelling reason to expect that Medicare Plus would be more profligate than the private sector. To the contrary, if Medicare’s experience since the early s is any guide, Medicare Plus should be at least as capable of controlling costs as private health plans — indeed, based on the past few years of essentially zero growth, significantly more capable. But if employers did hold down costs more effectively, then private insurance would become increasingly attractive compared with Medicare Plus. And if, by contrast, private health premiums were not kept in line,an increasing share of employers would enroll their workers in Medicare Plus. In short, the structure of the proposal ensures that the sector most capable of controlling costs gains a larger share of the population. It does so, moreover, in a context in which minimum standards for coverage and strong protections for lower-wage workers would ensure that cost containment did not simply equal cost shifting. Horizontal Equity The financial architecture of this proposal raises the important issue of “horizontal equity,” the notion that similarly situated Americans should be treated similarly. Under this proposal, Americans with incomes below percent of the poverty level would receive highly subsidized coverage if their employer elected to make payroll-based contributions to Medicare Plus, but only existing federal tax subsidies if they did not. Thus, a low-income worker whose employer sponsors coverage would receive significantly less in federal subsidies than a similarly situated worker enrolled in Medicare Plus. This problem could be rectified by providing 96 In practice, nearly all smaller and lower-wage employers would likely choose to contribute to Medicare Plus rather than provide coverage on their own. additional subsidies for health coverage to lowincome workers who receive coverage from their employer—or, if desired, who purchase coverage on their own. But providing income-related subsidies to all workers would be complicated (would subsidy amounts vary by regi on , for example, or with the health characteristics of workers?),and it could raise costs dramatically. It would also, of course, discourage employers with low-wage workers from enrolling in Medicare Plus by reducing the expense of providing employment-based coverage. This, in turn, would reduce the ability of Medicare Plus to pool risk and provide common protection to lowwage workers. In addition, there would be no guarantee that subsidies would cover a reasonable portion of the costs of coverage, as there would be under Medicare Plus. Thus, if the problem were judged sufficiently pressing, a better solution might be to further lower the contribution rate for employers insuring their workers for the first time and perhaps also for employers with very small groups or very-low-wage workforces. In practice, nearly all smaller and lower-wage employers would likely choose to contribute to Medicare Plus rather than provide coverage on their own. For firms that had low average wages or faced very high private premiums, the potential savings offered by Medicare Plus’s fixed contribution rate would be overwhelming. Low-wage workers who obtained private coverage from their employers would therefore be principally concentrated in high-wage sectors in which the payrollbased contributions were larger and employers saw advantages in providing insurance. Available evidence suggests that low-wage workers in such industries are already treated comparatively well; their rates of coverage are higher and their avera ge con tri buti ons lower than other low - w a ge employees.25 It also should be noted that those covered by pri- vate employment-based plans would con ti nue to receive federal tax subsidies. These subsidies are worth little to workers who face low marginal tax rates, but they are quite valuable for the higherincome workers who are most likely to remain in private workplace plans under this proposal. The break-even point at which existing federal tax subsidies would be greater than federal subsidies for Medicare Plus coverage is probably around , to , in annual income for a single worker and , to , for a family of four. (By way of comparison, the median household income in the United States is about ,.) In effect, then, this proposal would replace the regressive tax subsidy in current law with a subsidy structure whose benefits were distributed more equally across the income ladder, even without creating a complex new system of tax credits. Implementation Because this proposal builds on existing institutions, it could be implemented swiftly. Certainly the task would be no more daunting than the original establishment of Medicare, which, in the pre-digital era, went from passage to the payment of benefits in a single year. It is more realistic to expect, however, that implementation would be extended over several years and broken down into a series of discrete steps. In that context, the key issue would be whether each step increases the chance of future progress toward full implementation or, to the contrary, blunts political interest in further movement or even allows opponents to scuttle progress altogether.26 Jon Gabel et al. “Class and Benefits at the Workplace.” Health Affairs 18 (3) (1999): 144–50. 25 26 Alan Weil. “Increments Toward What?” Health Affairs 20 (1) (2001): 68–82. 97 The typical American approach is to extend coverage by population group: first, the elderly; then, poor children; then, the near-elderly; then, the parents of poor children; and so on. The advantage of this approach is that it fixes political attention and public sympathy on specific vulnerable groups that, as a rule,are not expected to be able to obtain coverage on their own. But the advantages of this approach are counterbalanced by a principal disadvantage: The divide-and-cover strategy does not lend itself to ready movement beyond the target population. When public assistance for a residual group is defended as a special exception, everyone else is presumed to be well served by the status quo. At the same time, addressing the plight of the most sympathetic groups further reduces interest in a general solution. Thus, while Medicare Plus could well begin by covering a specific population, such as children, there would be no assurance that this initial step would be fo ll owed by others, and, in fact, some reason to think it would not. A more promising route would be to phase in the components of the proposal on an extended timetable. This could be done by, for example, softening the initial requirements for employers, subsidizing firms being asked to provide coverage for the first time, exempting certain employers at the outset, or gradually moving non-workers and low-wage workers from state programs into Medicare Plus. Two features of the proposal, in particular, could be delayed or softened substantially without sacrificing its fundamental goals. The first is the limit on taxfree employer-sponsored health benefits, which would affect few existing plans but could be made even less threatening without crippling the proposal. The second is the individual mandate. Because all workers would be enrolled in private plans or Medicare Plus, while many non-workers would be former recipients of state programs who would be automatically enrolled as well, the remaining pool of the uninsured would consist principally of people who are between jobs and higher-income citizens who have chosen to forgo insurance. Covering Americans who continue to go without insurance even after being informed of the highly subsidized protections available under Medicare Plus would naturally be a lower priority than guaranteeing basic health security for low-wage workers who now lack it. The approach I have just outlined is best termed “large-scale incrementalism,” and it is similar to the strategy pursued by Medicare’s original architects, who saw public coverage for the elderly as merely the first step toward universal health insurance.27 Without adopting the highly categorical route that Medicare’s architects took, it is possible to outline a comparable step-by-step agenda for full realization of this proposal that would play out over five or or even years following initial legislative enactment. Step : Laying the Foundation. In the initial year after enactment, employers and individuals would be allowed to buy into Medicare Plus, with employers that enrolled their workers in the program making payroll-based contributions. Transitional rate reductions for employers newly insuring their workers would be made available and widely publicized. Because their value would phase out over years, there would be strong incentives for employers to take advantage of these reductions immediately. States would begin the process of moving Medicaid and S-CHIP beneficiaries into Medicare Plus. Step : Requiring Em pl oyer Sponsorship. In the second phase of implementation, employers that did not enroll their workers in Medicare Plus would be required to offer, but not contribute to the cost of, at least one private health plan for their workers that would have to meet very minimal standards to receive favorable tax treatment. Step : Requiring Employer Contributions. In the third phase, employers that did not contribute at least half of the cost of private coverage for full-time workers would be required to do so. Over a period of years, the contribution requirement would be raised to the full cost. Simultaneously, the minimum standards for private coverage would be upgraded gradually to ensure that private plans were at least as generous as Medicare Plus. Step : Closing Gaps. If a nontrivial proportion For a fuller explanation of the strategy behind Medicare and its only partial success, see Theodore R. Marmor. The Politics of Medicare, 2d ed. Hawthorne, NY: Aldine de Gruyter, 2000. 27 98 of Americans remained uninsured, the individual mandate would go into effect. The final two pieces of the proposal, the cap on tax-free health benefits and the tax on supplementary coverage, would also be put in place; yet these elements could be postponed indefinitely if circumstances required it. This step-by-step approach is not, of course, without risks. Perhaps the most threatening is that opponents of the proposal, beaten in the initial legislative round, will nonetheless rise anew to scuttle Medicare Plus later. This possibility, made vivid by the repeal of the Medicare Catastrophic Coverage Act, would be far less likely if initial en ro ll m ent in Medicare Plus were substantial and broad-based. Not only would significant initial enrollment create a large pool of beneficiaries ready to mobilize against backtracking; it would also create a new business constituency in favor of continued progress. Just as large employers have typically been more favorable toward employer mandates, employers who enrolled their workers in Medicare Plus would likely become more supportive of measures requiring their competitors to assume similar burdens. In comparison, other risks seem more tractable. It is true, for instance, that adverse selection is likely to be significant with a voluntary buy-in option. Yet, if implementation proceeded as envisioned, this would be a temporary phenomenon. Initial unfavorable selection could be treated as a transition cost and financed through short-term transfers from general revenues. More troublesome perhaps is the possibility that some employers will drop coverage and encourage their workers to purchase Medicare Plus on their own. Some monitoring would probably be necessary to prevent flagrant abuses of this option,and some “crowd-out” is to be expected. But unless employers were already planning to eliminate coverage (in which case Medicare Plus would be cushioning an inevitable blow), it seems unlikely that they would wish to suddenly confront their workers with the fairly large direct costs of buying into Medicare Plus individually, especially because these firms would be forfeiting the goodwill that employer-sponsored coverage buys. Political Robustness This proposal runs against the grain of current political debate in a number of key respects. It presents an integrated approach to universal coverage in an era in which incremental steps have become the modus operandi of U.S. health policy. It shifts the primary locus of public insurance protections from the states to the federal government after more than two decades in which new coverage has been achieved under state auspices. Perhaps most politically challenging, it suggests a dramatic expansion of an established federal program at a time when America’s political class firmly believes that the only route to broadened coverage is via modest expansions of state-based programs or a bevy of new tax subsidies for private health insurance. Surely this proposal defies all reasonable standards of political feasibility. In the near term, this is undoubtedly true: The prospect that the current President and Congress will follow the map outlined here is nil, and,in fact, there is little prospect that either will take substantial steps toward universal coverage by any means. Some believe that a tax credit approach will attract widespread support, but the magnitude of credits required to reduce significantly the number of uninsured is unlikely to materialize anytime soon. Far more likely is a modest new package of credits and deductions that throws more money into the private insurance sector but achieves limited tangible results. In the long term, however, the tides of American politics are more difficult to foretell. Just a decade ago, it is worth recalling, leading corporations, trade associations, and professional organizations were widely convinced that major reforms would be enacted, and many entered the debate favoring an approach bearing some similarity to the one de s c ri bed here. Historically, health reform has become a major issue about every years, after a period of dormancy during which politicians and private leaders celebrated private market solutions. If the past is prelude to the future, the next big tide of health policy ferment is set to roll into Washington sometime near the end of this decade. 99 At the moment,this tide may seem unthinkable. Yet the same was thought in the early s, when,as now, tax-based reform was the rage, and employers seemed sold on the “new” inventions of utilization review and managed care. It is instructive to recall what happened next. Faced with a significant recession, many large firms became alarmed about the cost of providing health insurance, and a significant number stridently argued that smaller firms (whose workers were often insured by large firms through family policies) should be required to provide coverage.State governments, too, faced hard times,feeling the pinch of an expanded Medicaid program at a time of fiscal distress. And as employers tried to control costs, Americans grew alarmed about the uncertainty and increasingly visible costs of health benefits that many had once taken for granted.28 Today’s preferred policy options—inacti on , symbolic gestures, or, at most, modest tax credits or small program expansions—are a reflection not just of the long shadow of the Clinton health plan’s failure, but also of good economic times and the historically low rate of increase in private premiums that has come with them. If the economy continues to weaken, if the cost of private health insurance returns to the high growth rates of the past (as it has over the past few years), and if the states begin to face new fiscal pressures (as they already have started to), the interest of employers and the states in strict cost containment may revive once again. Yet it will do so after a decade during which both players have used nearly all the managerial and administrative tools at their disposal, in the process prompting a public backlash against some of the most restrictive of their practices. The alternatives left will be much less attractive: for the states,cutting Medicaid benefits for the very poor to retain or expand coverage for the near-poor; for employers, switching to so-called defined contribution arrangements in which workers are given a fixed amount for medical costs that is pegged to inflation or company revenues rather than health costs. Judged against these options, Medicare Plus may become not simply a viable alternative, but an attractive solution for many key stakeholders—not least the American public. If it does, this proposal will have at least three important political advantages. First, it builds on positive aspects of broadly popular and widely understood institutions—namely, Medicare and employment-based health insurance. Group health plans work well for better-off workers in large firms. This proposal allows them to con ti nue to do so, while at the same time using the workplace as a conduit for public coverage for the rest of the working population. Medicare Plus also immediately gains the legitimacy and familiarity of a well-liked program. No great leaps of faith are required to anticipate how it will opera te . Nor are tales of sinister bureaucracies quite so fearsome when the bureaucracy in question already takes care of grandparents, parents, neighbors, and friends.29 Second, this proposal is designed to impose minimal new costs on employers that do not now provide insurance and to reduce costs for most employers that do sponsor covera ge . At the same time, it provides new subsidies for lower-wage workers without imposing large, visible new costs on other Americans. Third, this proposal promises to retain a substantial role for private health insu ra n ce and to spare insurers that choose not to contract with the program from extensive regulation of their business. Implicitly, it strikes a bargain: Insurers that can thrive in a market dominated by large employers and a public contracting regime will be free to operate as they have before. Those whose competitive advantage rests on cherry-picking healthy small groups will face harder times. To be sure,the political challenges will be formi- Jacob S. Hacker. The Road to Nowhere: The Genesis of President Clinton’s Plan for Health Security. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1997, ch. 1. demand that her elected representatives “keep government’s hands off my Medicare.” Commentators quickly go on to conclude that Medicare is in woeful shape: Even its beneficiaries don’t know that the federal government runs it. Yet, if anything, this seems another strong political count in the program’s favor—and a strong reason to base an expanded public program on it. 28 It is often noted that some do not recognize that Medicare is a government program. A frequently repeated story, for example, describes an elderly woman leaping up at a congressional town hall meeting to 29 100 dable. Yet this proposal holds a final advantage over other likely contenders—what might be termed “political robustness.” Political robustness refers to the ability of a proposal to function successfully despite alternative specifications and to sustain itself politically over time. This proposal is politically robust in both senses. First, a number of its features could be altered (or new features could be added) without fundamentally compromising its effectiveness. For example, this proposal would be compatible with a system of refundable tax credits targeted at lower-wage workers, as long as the credits could be applied to Medicare Plus as well as to private insurance premiums, and the default option for workers without employer-sponsored insurance was Medicare Plus. Indeed, one possible first step in implementing this proposal would be to provide a refundable tax credit of a relatively low value (say, , per person), but make it fully convertible into coverage under Medicare Plus. (The same could be done, of course, if a refundable tax credit were already in place.) This would allow Americans to apply the credit to employer-sponsored or non-group insurance if they chose, but also would ensure that they could buy into a comprehensive program by paying a modest, income-related premium. By com p a ri s on , refundable tax credit schemes are not so robust: It is difficult to guarantee, for instance, that a tax credit will purchase adequate benefits over time, and because take-up of private insurance is highly sensitive to the level of the subsidy, the effects of a tax credit program on coverage are dramatically different at alternative levels. Second, and more important, the proposal creates several powerful self-reinforcing processes that are likely to facilitate its expansion over time. Of these, one that has already been mentioned is the level of the payroll-based contribution. There will be strong political pressure to keep the contribution rate low. Yet, paradoxically, a low contribution rate will bolster the size and bargaining power of Medicare Plus. Similarly, if private health premiums rise more quickly than the payroll-based contribution, then the share of the population enrolled in Medicare Plus will also rise over time. Another source of political robustness is the structure of the premiums. As enrollment reaches up the income ladder, Medicare Plus will naturally bring in more revenue per enrollee. As the income of new enrollees reaches the break-even point, the subsidies required for new enrollees will be offset almost entirely by the savings in federal tax subsidies for private health coverage. Moreover, controlling Medicare Plus’s spending will also automatically reduce the tab for existing tax subsidies by lowering the level of the tax cap on private workplace coverage. A final source of political robustness is the character and source of the subsidies. By targeting new subsidies on workers enrolled in Medicare Plus, the proposal ensures that the bulk of new spending goes to the most vulnerable, and that these subsidies are spent on a defined-benefit package that spreads risk broadly across a large population. Not only does this mean substantial savings over more scattershot subsidy arrangements; it also means clear lines of political accountability that would generally be lacking in proposals that simply offered new tax credits for private health plans. And because these subsidies are financed almost en ti rely at the federal level, there would be no concern that states would be under competitive pressure to keep spending low, or that responsibility for the program would be lost in the interstices of state and federal duties. In sum, this proposal offers medium-term promise of political success. More important, it holds out the hope that the next big step in American health politics will lead not to another political dead end but to the beginning of the difficult yet necessary journey toward universal health insurance in the United States. Acknowledgements For valuable advice, I thank all the participants in this project. Special thanks go to Judith Feder, who offered useful suggestions at the pre-writing stage, and to Elliot Wicks, who reviewed an early draft. Gina Kramer provided able research assistance, financed by the William Milton Fund of the Harvard Medical School. These individuals and institutions are, of course,absolved of responsibility for the argument and analysis contained herein. n 101 Holahan, Nichols, and Blumberg Proposal Key Elements John F. Holahan, Len M. Nichols, and Linda J. Blumberg have outlined a new proposal to cover the uninsured that would extend the subsidized coverage that is available under the State Children’s Health Insurance Program (S-CHIP) to all lower-income people. The proposal is built on the following key elements: financial incentives to states to expand health coverage subsidies to all families and individuals with incomes below percent of the federal poverty level and those facing higher-than-average health expenses, regardless of income. Subsidized coverage could be purchased only through purchasing pools, which states would have broad discretion to design. of a match amounting to percent more than the current Medicaid match, provided to states in exchange for meeting minimum federal standards. States choosing to participate would have to provide coverage to those meeting the eligibility rules, but could specify a minimum benefits package consistent with federal guidelines, as in the S-CHIP program. Non-participating states would continue their Medicaid and S-CHIP programs. Medicaid and S-CHIP. People below percent of poverty would get full subsidies, while those between and percent of poverty would get partial subsidies, and the high-risk (regardless of income) would be subsidized as well. A set of uniform federal rules would apply nationally. , with high health costs, could buy insurance through a state-designed purchasing pool at a premium no higher than a statewide community rate for a standard benefit package. Employers must offer employees the state pool coverage as an option, but they could choose whether to buy coverage exclusively through the pool. would combine existing Medicaid, S-CHIP, state employees’ purchasing programs, and willing participants from the private sector to create administrative efficiencies, pool insurance risks, and improve bargaining clout for those within the pool. 102 About the Authors . , .., is Director of the Health Policy Research Center at The Urban Institute. He has authored numerous publications on the impact of public policy and market forces on the health sector, with a particular focus on effects on low-income populations. These include analyses of the recent growth in Medicaid expenditures, variations across states in Medicaid expenditures, and the implications of block grants and expenditure cap proposals on states. He has also published research on the effects of expanding Medicaid on the number of uninsured and the cost to federal and state governments. He directs the health policy component of the Assessing the New Federalism project which has produced several reports on health policy for low income populations. Other research interests include health system reform, changes in health insurance coverage, and managed care payment arrangements. Dr. Holahan has a Ph.D. in economics from Georgetown University. . , .., is an economist and Principal Research Associate at the Urban Institute who studies private health insurance markets and how they work in response to decisions by employers, individuals, regulators, and public insurance programs. He has written extensively on these and other issues under the general rubric of health reform at both the national and state levels. He has also been a consultant on health policy for the World Bank and the Pan American Health Organization. Dr. Nichols is currently a member of the Competitive Pricing Advisory Commission (CPAC) for the Medicare program as well the Technical Review Panel for the Medicare Trustees Reports. He was the Senior Advisor for Health Policy at the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) during the development of and debate over the Clinton health reform proposals of –. Prior to OMB, Dr. Nichols was a visiting Public Health Service Fellow at the Agency for Health Care Policy and Research, and prior to that he was an Associate Professor and Economics Department Chair at Wellesley College. He received his Ph.D. in economics from the University of Illinois in . . , .., is Senior Research Associate at the Urban Institute. She is currently working on a variety of projects related to private health insurance and health care financing: estimating the coverage and risk pool impacts of tax credit proposals, estimating employer price elasticities of offering health insurance, the effects of insurance market reforms on the risk pool of the privately insured, and a series of analyses of the working uninsured. While at the Urban Institute, she has also done research on insurance market reforms, the effects of the Medicaid expansions for children on private health insurance, tax credits as tools for expanding health insurance coverage, provision of health insurance coverage by small employers, the Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act of , the District of Columbia’s Medicaid program, reform of the Medicare AAPCC, and health insurance purchasing cooperatives. From August through October Dr. Blumberg served as health policy advisor to the Clinton Administration during its initial health care reform effort. She received her Ph.D. in economics from the University of Michigan. 103 Expanding Health Insurance Coverage A New Federal / State Approach by John F. Holahan, Len M. Nichols, and Linda J. Blumberg Overview We propose a new consolidated federal-state health insurance program based on five principles: . Substantial new federal subsidies to finance expansion of coverage with state discretion to participate and to modify rules. . Equity among individuals with similar incomes and among states in a new program that would also end the complexity in current public programs. . Spread excess health risks broadly across the general population. . Organize the purchasing of subsidized health insurance. . Choice—all privately insured can keep their current arrangement if they prefer. These principles would be implemented in the following ways. Substantial new federal subsidies to finance expansion of coverage with state discretion. In those states that choose to participate,full subsidies are provided for those with incomes below percent of the federal poverty level (FPL), and partial subsidies are made available for those with incomes between percent and percent of FPL. Within minimal federal standards—for example, minimum benefit packages—states are given broad leeway to design and or ga n i ze purchasing arrangements that work best for their local conditions. Our federalism model is the current State Children’s Health Insurance Program (S-CHIP), with high federal contributions and considerable state flexibility. The federal share of the total subsidy in our plan is percent higher than today’s Medicaid matching rates. Our model would differ from S-CHIP in that there would be no fixed budget allocations and states could not limit enroll- ment arbitra ri ly. State participation is voluntary, a n d ,a f ter five ye a rs ,s t a tes are free to impose an individual mandate if they choose. Participating states also receive the higher match on their residual Medicaid progra m ,i n cluding long-term care benefits to the elderly, and wraparound benefits for the nonelderly. As discussed below, participating states can keep their disabled residents in the residual Medicaid program or bring them into the new program (under special arrangements). Non-participating states would continue to receive their current Medicaid and S-CHIP matching rates. The higher federal share of expenditures in the proposed program is designed to ensure that the net incremental cost to states is relatively low and, thus, is intended to give strong incentives for state participation. Equity. All people at the same income levels in each participating state are eligible for equal subsidies, whether they are currently en ro ll ed in Medicaid, S-CHIP, or private plans, or they are uninsured. This simplifies complex and conflicting eligibility rules that discourage coverage expansion. The primary condition for receiving subsidies is to purchase insurance through a state-organized purchasing pool. States receive the same federal matching funds for all of their enrollees,unlike the current system, which provides higher federal shares for h i gh er-income S-CHIP children than for lowerincome Medicaid children. Finally, individuals with incomes below percent of FPL are treated equally in every participating state,and those b etween percent and percent are treated similarly across the states as well. The federal government imposes a floor on the subsidy levels between percent and percent of FPL. Spread excess health risks broadly. No one, 104 regardless of his or her personal health risk, is charged more for insurance than the hypothetical (and computed) statewide community rate,and this guarantee is financed with public (federal plus state) do ll a rs . The statewide community rate is the rate that would be charged by a competitive insurer for a person of average risk for the standard benefits package. This is a key new concept, and we devote considerable attention to it. This explicit subsidy for h i gh er-risk individuals is available only to those who purchase through the new state-organized purchasing pool. At the same time, private insurers would be free to price products outside the pool as they see fit. The key design feature is that the financial consequences for higher-than-average risks are shared across all citizens, because those inside and outside the state pool pay taxes, the source of financing for our proposed subsidies. Organized purchasing of subsidized health insurance. The primary new institution is a purchasing pool composed of Medicaid and S-CHIP recipients and all others who choose to join. Federal law requires this pool to be open to all at community rates. Administrative efficiencies, risk pooling, bargaining power, and data collection for risk adjustment and community rate determinations are all enhanced through this kind of purchasing en ti ty and risk pool. States have broad discretion to design their purchasing pools within federal guidelines, and they can choose to en ro ll all state and local employees in the pool as well, or give them the ch oi ce of enrolling, as might any other employer. Certainly the uninsured, but those with private insurance who might prefer to purchase standardized benefits packages through this pool at a statewide community rate as well,are free to join, or they can maintain their existing arrangements. This choice—to join the state pool or make their own private arrangement—is a central el em ent in our plan and our fifth principle, explained below. The state-organized purchasing pool—which can be operated by a private vendor—is required to operate (or contract for) its own managed fee-for-service (FFS) health plan and may choose to manage competition among private plans as well. The purpose of requiring a state FFS plan is to ensure suffi- cient enrollment capacity and to provide the state with a basis of comparison for premium rates submitted by private insurers who wish to sell their plans through the pool. The state assumes the insurance risk for this FFS plan. Choice. All of the privately insured who want to can keep their current arrangements may do so. No new regulations are imposed on insurers outside the state’s risk pool, and states are free to repeal insurance market regulations not required for compliance with the Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act (HIPAA). Employers are free to offer coverage or not. If they do, they can offer their coverage exclusively through the state pool, or they can offer it both inside and outside the state pool. In either case,the employer selects its preferred contribution level. All workers must have access to the pool because subsidies will be available only to pool en ro ll ee s . In addition, anti-discrimination rules require that firms offering coverage inside and ou tside the pool must make equal contributions to both. Any individual in the state is always free to join the state pool during open enrollment. Rationale Our proposal is based on the premise that a purely federal expansion of coverage is politically impossible. In our view, broad expansions based on a federal-state partnership are much more likely to earn political support. The enthusiastic response to the S-CHIP program suggests that public support for coverage expansions should follow a joint federalstate model. This plan also recognizes that individual and small-group insurance markets have serious flaws that are difficult to overcome and plague all proposals that rely on the p rivate market to expand coverage. Simply put, insurers and managed care organizations have strong incentives to market to the healthy and avoid the sick. State efforts to reform small-group and individual insurance markets may have been somewhat successful at spreading risk, but they have not expanded coverage. Guaranteed issue improves access for high risks, but may increase premiums, thereby reducing the 105 attractiveness of coverage for low risks. Efforts to force community rating reduce premiums for the sick, but increase them for the healthy, leading to possible reductions in the overall numbers covered under a voluntary system.Our proposal spreads the costs of h i gh - risk individuals more broadly and uncouples that support from premiums paid by the relatively healthy. Our program is explicitly designed to recognize that the system of coverage for low-income Americans has become increasingly complex and highly inequitable. Medicaid eligibility rules are unfathomable to all but a handful of experts. Medicaid eligibility has become even more complex with the delinking of Medicaid and cash assistance fo ll owing welfare reform.Enactment of S-CHIP with different rules for income eligibility has added to the complexity that potential eligibles must navigate. The current subsidy system is highly inequitable because higher-income S-CHIP children receive greater federal support than do lower-income children and their families who receive Medicaid. These differentials have provided incentives for states to favor S-CHIP enrollees or try to maximize S-CHIP participation at the expense of Medicaid. Moreover, within S-CHIP, states that have adopted broad expansions (for example, Minnesota and Washington) could get a higher S-CHIP matching rate only if they extended coverage further. In effect, there is a financial penalty for having already enacted a broad expansion. Our proposal eliminates this feature and treats all states with similar income levels identically. Finally, while no doubt providing some fiscal benefits, current efforts in S-CHIP to prevent displacement of private coverage have led to significant inequities. By limiting eligibility to the uninsured,SCHIP denies subsidies to families paying considerable amounts for individual coverage or for the employee’s share of an employer’s plan,even though their incomes are low enough by the program’s standards to merit assistance. By providing subsidies based on income and regardless of current coverage, this proposal provides financial relief to those lowincome individuals who pay a lot for coverage in addition to those we hope to encourage to purchase health insurance for the first time. At the same time, we preserve incentives for employers to con ti nu e offering and helping to pay for coverage. We have consciously decided against using tax credits to expand coverage for four reasons.First, we believe that subsidies for expansions of coverage should be income-related. The administrative barriers to effectively providing income-related tax credits are tremendous when credits are provided at the same time that required payments to insurers and advance payments are reconciled with year-end taxable income. Credits would have to be provided at the beginning of the year to ensure that low-income persons had the liquidity necessary to purchase health insurance. Because the credit amount would be based on taxable income, advance payments would have to be based on current or expected income. If these estimates of actual full-year taxable income were incorrect,the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) would need to reconcile the amounts at the end of the year. This “recapture” of overpayments of credits would be costly, because low-income families tend to be inconsistent in filing income tax returns.1 In fact, the cost of reconciling the credits is likely to exceed the amount of m on ey actually recouped. In addition, the risk that the credits or a portion of them might have to be returned at yearend is a significant disincentive for low-income individuals to participate. Second,and related to the first issue, tax credits are particularly difficult to administer for low-income individuals and families. Such people are more likely to change jobs and have gaps in employment, and may not be consistent tax return filers. Thus, it is difficult to reach them with advanced payments of credits made through employers. Consequently, alternative administrative structures would be required to serve this purpose, but the need for such additional structures diminishes any efficiency to be gained by implementing such a subsidy through the tax system. Third, part of the subsidy we have designed is Experience with the earned income tax credit shows that individuals using the advanced payment feature of the credit have high rates of non-filing of tax returns and not reporting receipt of the advanced payment if they do file tax returns. If this experience is consistent with what would occur under a health insurance tax credit, the administrative costs of correcting such errors and attempting to recover even modest underpayments from low-income persons may be significant. 1 106 explicitly related to individual health risk. Determination of health care costs relative to the state average is outside the scope of Treasury Department activity and expertise. Appropriate premium contributions by individuals and appropriate payments to insurance plans are best determined by administrative entities at the state/local level, aided by specific insurer, provider, and enrollee data and information that our proposed state purchasing authority would collect. Fourth, most tax credit proposals allow people to use their tax subsidies only in unorganized insurance markets. Indeed, this lack of interference in markets is often viewed as a strength. We believe that some structuring of the market in which subsidies are used is necessary to ensure efficiency, equity, and access. Coverage and Subsidies In this program all participating states agree to provide full subsidies to all of those living below percent of poverty who enroll in the state purchasing pool. Further, participating states extend partial subsidies to those between percent and percent of FPL. For those in this income range, states can set the premium schedule, up to federal limits, on overall cost-sharing burdens—that is, premiums plus deductibles and coinsurance. These limits on cost sharing are no more than percent of family income for those between percent and percent of poverty, and no more than percent of income for those between percent and percent of poverty. (Limits on cost sharing for children’s only coverage are limited to percent of income, as in S-CHIP). States can use their own funds to subsidize individuals or families above percent of poverty if they choose. Participating states also permit anyone, regardless of income, to buy into the state pool at a premium that reflects a statewide community rate.2 No subsidies (beyond the current tax exemption for employer-sponsored insurance) are extended to anyone purchasing cov2 The specific meaning of the statewide community rate is explained in detail in the section on the state pool. erage outside of the pool. Participating states can choose to keep their disabled residents in the residual Medicaid program or bring them into the new program. As participating states, they receive the percent higher federal matching rate in either case. In the new program, states are required to provide access for the disabled to the state fee-for-service plan or to special managed care plans designed for the disabled. The state program has to provide for guaranteed issue—that is, anyone can sign up during open enrollment. Anyone who does not sign up can enroll retroactively by paying a full year’s premium plus a percent penalty. (Note that those below percent of FPL face no premiums and, thus, have no retroactive obligation, and those between percent and percent of FPL face reduced penalties). The intent here is to avoid the severe adverse selection problems that result when an an individual signs up after being diagnosed with a serious illness. Given our income-based subsidy scheme, this penalty is less serious than a -month pre-existing condition exclusion and, in most cases, is less burdensome than the medically needy provisions of Medicaid. Therefore, the medically needy path to eligibility is eliminated for participating states. - The crowding out of private insu ra n ce can be thought of in a number of ways: • employers dropping or not beginning to offer employer-sponsored coverage given the availability of public alternatives; • workers dropping employer-sponsored coverage to enroll in public alternatives; or • public spending on health care replacing current private spending. Obviously, all of these are interrelated; however, it is helpful to keep each one in mind, because our program has different implications for each. While some employers may drop coverage as a result of our program, we do not expect that many will. The current tax exemption for employer-sponsored insurance coverage continues to apply only to those enrolling in insurance coverage through their 107 The administrative costs of plans offering coverage inside the pool will be significantly below the administrative costs of existing non-group policies, and such savings alone will likely be sufficient to induce the vast majority of those in the non-group market to enroll. employers, maintaining the incentive for workers to purchase their insurance through their existing group arrangements (if employers do drop coverage and wages are increased as a consequence, those increased wages become taxable income, while the contributions to health insurance were not). Competition for higher-wage workers who have strong demand for employment-based tax preferences for health insurance will keep most firms offering health insurance to be competitive in the labor market. Although subsidies are available only to those purchasing coverage through the state insurance pool, employers are permitted to buy coverage for their employees in that pool. The state pool premiums charged to employer groups are based on a statewide community rate; the level of the employer contribution to the premium is left up to the employer. Firms competing for workers have to maintain reasonably high employer shares to attract workers who are ineligible for subsidies. These provisions serve two purposes with regard to the crowd-out noted above.First,they ensure that there is no incentive for individuals to drop out of employer-sponsored insurance arrangements. Second,they limit the amount of private dollars displaced by public dollars, particularly in firms with workers who earn vastly different amounts. In firms with high-wage and low-wage workers, high-wage workers will continue to want employer-sponsored coverage to take advantage of the current system’s tax subsidy, in addition to the convenience and administrative economies of scale and risk-pooling advantages of employment-based insurance coverage. Their interests have to be taken into account by employers when the employers set their premium contribution levels for the employer-sponsored plans they offer (including plans in the state pool). We do not purport to have developed an ironclad approach to avoiding crowd-out; this was not our intent. We do believe, however, that our approach creates a reasonable balance between maintaining much of the existing employer-based system and generating much more equity by income class. — Below percent of poverty most individuals and families have an incentive to join the state pool. Most of those with incomes less than percent of FPL who currently have employer-sponsored coverage will receive subsidies. Because of the offer of at least partial subsidies, they will choose to obtain coverage inside the pool. For those workers whose firms drop coverage, presumably small firms with low-wage workers,many will also enroll in the plans offered by the pool. Those currently in Medicaid and S-CHIP are enrolled automatically. If the state chooses, state employees can be automatically en ro ll ed , as well. Among the low-income uninsured, incentives to join are strong. Lack of information and indifference to health insurance are the greatest barriers; there is plenty of evidence of non-participation by those eligible for current public programs. With all state residents eligible for enrollment, however, we expect the stigma witnessed under the Medicaid program to be reduced substantially. Those who currently have private non-group coverage are also likely to sign up because the pool will offer more comprehensive coverage at lower cost. The administrative costs of plans offering coverage inside the pool will be significantly below the administrative costs of existing non-group policies, and such savings alone will likely be sufficient to induce the vast majority of those in the non-group market to enroll. The income-related subsidies available to this population increase the incentives to join even more. Seasonal workers and those who 108 tend to change jobs frequently also may find the pool attractive, because participating in it means that changing jobs does not mean changing insurance plans. However, some non-group purchasers who are eligible for only partial subsidies, and who can obtain coverage at low rates due to excellent health and/or the desire for less generous benefit packages, may continue to purchase coverage outside the pool. — Those with incomes at or above percent of FPL, and who face high health insurance premiums either because of above-average administrative costs (in small groups or for individuals) or above-average health risks due to poor health status, will find the state plan to be attractive. This includes individuals in firms with employer policies that have high premiums for either reason. They are able to purchase some plans inside the state purchasing pool at a price no higher than the statewide community rate. Those benefiting from good experience rating or who are willing to purchase less generous benefits packages are less likely to enroll. Finally, while it is unclear how many of the non-income-subsidized uninsured will enroll, many of the uninsured are likely to find the plans in the state pool more attractive than what is available in the current non-group market, with its extensive underwriting and high costs of comparing benefits across insurers and plans After a period of five years, states are permitted to mandate that each individual obtain health insurance covera ge , either inside or outside the state pool, individually or through an employer. This delay is necessary to establish en ro ll m ent procedures, ensure efficient operation of the pools, refine procedures for determining the statewide community rate, etc. The federal government will support the mandate with the same schedule of subsidies outlined above. A mandate, or any serious expansion of coverage, permits the federal government to scale back its support of acute-care activities that are now per- formed outside the insurance-based system (for example, disproportionate share hospital payments [DSH]). We discuss this more fully in the section on financing. In addition,a mandate is not likely to cost substantially more than if a state adopted the voluntary version we have outlined. This is because, after some years of the voluntary program’s operation, most of those brought into coverage by the mandate will be in households with incomes of more than percent of poverty, and thus would not receive income subsidies. Those below percent who would come in only under a mandate are likely to be the healthiest members of this group, so their per capita cost should be lower than average, as well. Federal/State Relations States obviously have considerable responsibility under this program in exchange for a large amount of federal funding. States are required to meet federal standards for eligibility determination, outreach, and enrollment.States have to incorporate Medicaid and S-CHIP recipients into the purchasing pools (which are de s c ri bed in detail below), along with subsidized low-income individuals, employer groups,and others who choose to enroll.States may choose to incorporate state employees into these pools, as well, or they can maintain a separate system. As with any other employer, states must offer access to the pool and make the same contribution to coverage in the pool. In addition, their workers are eligible for low-income subsidies only inside the pool. We expect that states will find it most efficient to integrate current administrative structures for purchasing insurance for state employees with the new state purchasing entity. In some states,however, this integration will take time to achieve politically. To counter this,the federal government can provide financial incentives for states to integrate their employees early in the implementation of the program. States have to establish procedures for informing enrollees about their choices of plans and establishing standards of quality, provider payment,and risk adjustment. States also have to develop a standard benefits package that meets or exceeds federal bene- 109 fits package requirements. Federal standards will include local flexibility in the spirit of the S-CHIP program. For example, under S-CHIP, states must establish a benefits package equal in actuarial value to one of several benchmark plans, such as the standard Blue Cross and Blue Shield plan offered under the Federal Employees Health Benefits Plan (FEHBP),the health plan offered to state employees, or the benefit plan offered by the health maintenance organization (HMO) with the largest market share in the state. This flexible standard gives states a great deal of leeway. States are responsible for establishing fair and equitable subsidy schedules so that premiums do not exceed established maximum payments for individuals of particular income gro u p s .S t a tes are responsible for organizing purchasing pools, establishing reporting and dissemination requirements, and negotiating with plans over price or establishing competitive bidding mechanisms.States are required to operate (or contract for) a discounted fee-forservice plan to further ensure beneficiary choice and provide an outlet for those worried about managed care plans’ quality. States are not required to pay the full cost of the discounted fee-for-service plan for low-income enrollees if enough capacity and choice is available in managed care arrangements. Finally, states are responsible for operating a residual Medicaid program. This would continue to cover all groups (the elderly and,if the state chooses, the disabled) and benefits (for example, nursing home care) now required as part of Medicaid that are not incorporated into the new program. Optional groups and optional benefits can still be provided at state discretion at the new higher matching rate. The federal government monitors state compliance with program rules. This includes ensuring that states are meeting federal standards for eligibility determination, outreach and enrollment, and some provider payment levels. The federal government monitors state procedures for calculating the statewide community rate to ensure that it is fair to beneficiaries—that is,not too high—and fair to the federal government—that is, not too low (further detail about the statewide community rate is pro- vided in the next section). The federal government also monitors state efforts to organize markets and engender efficiency in their competitive bidding processes or nego ti a ti ons with health plans. This again is necessary to ensure that the federal government does not pay more than necessary to obtain the coverage it seeks, and to disseminate lessons learned by the federal government to inform other states and improve performance nationwide. The federal government monitors state spending, including supervision of subsidy calculations for low-income people and for those with aboveaverage risk. The federal government also strictly enforces provisions to avoid the financial manipulations that have occurred in Medicaid.3 For example, the federal government might have to establish rules on the maximum payments that can be made to particular classes of providers. It may also be necessary to monitor payments made by health plans to specific classes of providers. Both of these strategies are possible mechanisms for preventing states from encouraging providers to set their charges high, thereby allowing the state to leverage more federal matching funds. There is one natural limit to the ability of states to en ga ge in these arrangements: payments by plans to providers have to be covered by a plan’s capitation rate. If the capitation rate is too high,the plan has to charge premiums in excess of the amount subsidized by the state. Given the sensitivity of lower-middle-class individuals to premiums, plans should be reluctant to raise rates. Why Rely on States? There are several problems with a model that relies so heavily on states.First,states differ widely in their performance of current programs under current arrangements. Among the individual states represented in the National Survey of America’s Families (NSAF), uninsurance rates for low-income children vary from a low of percent in Massachusetts to a high of percent in Texas, and, for low-income These include disproportionate share hospital payments, supplemental payments made to public hospitals and nursing homes financed with intergovernment transfers, and other arrangements that have had the effect of obtaining federal funds with little or no state and local matching funds. 3 110 adults, from percent in Massachusetts to percent in Texas.4 According to the Current Population Survey, Medicaid coverage varies from percent of low-income adults in Nevada and percent in Idaho to percent in Tennessee and percent in Vermont. In , Medicaid spending per child enrollee va ri ed from , in New Hampshire to in Mississippi.5 Eligibility standards for children under S-CHIP ranges from a maximum of percent of poverty in South Dakota and North Dakota to percent of poverty in New Jersey.6 Reliance on states alone can result in Americans with com p a ra bl e incomes being treated quite differently. Second, as referenced above, a range of financial abuses, including disproportionate share hospital (DSH) payments and, more recently, supplemental payment programs, have allowed states,at their discretion, to increase their effective matching rates. These financing abuses have led to widespread skepticism about state discretion at the federal level, and have threatened the viability of federal-state financial relations. Third, there is extreme variation in administrative capacity at the state level. States such as New York, Massachusetts, Minnesota, and Washington have far more health policy expertise than do many of the smaller states in the south and west. Despite these problems, we believe that it is politically unrealistic to enact a broad expansion of coverage at the federal level at this point in time. Right or wrong, the mom en tum in the nation is toward greater reliance on state government. We also believe that S-CHIP offers a fundamentally different model from Medicaid.S-CHIP has combined higher federal matching payments with more state flexibility. The higher federal matching rates have made coverage expansions for children much more 4 Urban Institute tabulations of 1999 National Survey of America’s Families data. Details of all Urban Institute calculations are available on request. Urban Institute calculations based on Health Care Financing Administration (HCFA) 2082 data and the March Current Population Survey. Form 2082 financial and enrollment data are supplied by the state to HCFA. 5 F. Ullman, I. Hill, and R. Almeida. CHIP: A Look at Emerging State Programs, New Federalism Issue Brief Series A, no. A-35, Washington: Urban Institute, 1999. 6 financially attractive to states, and state governors have been able to receive credit for reducing the number of uninsured children. All states have adopted S-CHIP (and the majority have extended coverage to at least percent of poverty),and several have expressed interest in extending coverage to include parents. With a high level of federal matching funds it will be hard for states to walk away from the opportunity to expand coverage to low-income and high-health-risk individuals. For all these reasons, we believe that S-CHIP provides a good model of federalism to follow. One concern with state stewardship is inadequacy of funding. However, with about percent of a state’s population enrolled in the program, program beneficiaries should have sufficient political power to avoid chronic underfunding. While there is more state flexibility under S-CHIP than under Medicaid, a range of federal standards is essential. For example under S-CHIP, there are rules for minimum benefits packages. As described above, we believe the federal government will need to set rules for benefits packages,minimum provider payment standards, operation of the pools, and to avoid the financial abuses of Medicaid. A different concern is that states will not be able to control the growth of costs. However, because state expenditures will still be large compared with other state spending, states will have an incentive to control costs. Organization of the State Purchasing Pools and the General Insurance Market Development of State Health Insurance Purchasing Pools Under our reform proposal,each state is required to construct a single purchasing authority and risk pool through which insurance coverage is provided for those who are subsidized because of low incomes or above-average health risks and for those with higher incomes who want to take advantage of the choices and efficiencies inherent in large-group purchasing mechanisms. Those subsidized because of income include most of those currently eligible for or enrolled in Medicaid or S-CHIP and many who are not currently eligible for those programs. 111 To the extent that a state has existing state-only comprehensive insurance coverage programs (for example, Washington State’s Basic Health Plan), we expect that these states will integrate these programs into the state purchasing pool to secure the large federal share of subsidy dollars for this population. Our equity principle requires that all subsidized enrollees with equivalent incomes be treated in the same manner inside the pool—that is, the distinctions between Medicaid and S-CHIP and other types of enrollees are erased. In addition, individuals exceeding the income eligibility cutoffs for subsidies and private employer groups may purchase coverage through this pool. All purchasers/enrollees in a given geographic coverage area have access to the same health plans and enrollment options, regardless of whether they are subsidized (for some plans, additional payments will be required—see below). States have the option to contract with private insurers and managed care plans to provide coverage through the state pool. However, even if private insurers are used in this manner, each state is required to operate its own managed FFS plan. The state can either run this plan directly or contract with an insurer or a third-party administrator for this purpose. In addition to FFS being an increasingly popular option for Medicaid managed care programs, one important benefit of this managed plan is that it serves as a safety valve and as a check on proprietary health plans’ bidding and contracting strategies. For example, if plans all submit relatively high bids, the state may be able to operate a managed fee-for-service program, one that monitors use and nego ti a tes fee discounts from providers, at a lower cost. Our vision of this new health insurance program is sufficiently general that one could imagine a state qualifying for the subsidy payments with just this managed FFS plan—that is, without trying to manage competition among proprietary health plans. An FFS plan may also be essential in states or substate areas where sparse populations prevent managed competi ti on from developing. The state purchasing pools can build on existing structures for state employees’ plans, Medicaid, S-CHIP, or other state purchasing pro- grams, or entirely new entities may be created at the state’s discretion. As noted earlier, the new program provides two types of subsidies. The first provides premium subsidies to those below percent of poverty, with those in families below percent of poverty receiving subsidies sufficient to cover the full cost of a comprehensive plan. The second subsidizes individuals with above-average health risks so that the premium they face is equivalent to a community rate calculated over the entire insured population in the state. Both subsidies are available only to those en ro lling in coverage inside the state purchasing pool to minimize administrative complexity. General Features of State Pools Once the state determines the benefit package, subject to federal minimum requirements, private insurers may decide to sell supplemental benefits in the pool. But these benefits must be priced separately and treated as add-ons to, not replacements for, the standard package. Those enrollees who are entitled to additional benefits because of Medicaid eligibility under current law (for example, children with special needs and the disabled) continue to receive those benefits as wraparounds through a residual Medicaid program (which also continues to provide long-term care as under current law). The state purchasing pools operate under guaranteed issue and guaranteed renewal for all groups and individuals. Each year the state purchasing pool holds an open enrollment period at least one month long. Enrollment will be permitted at non-open enrollment times; however, late enrollees (regardless of the month they enroll) will be required to pay what they would have paid in premiums for one full year plus a percent penalty. As de s c ri bed above, for workers with employer offers, the income subsidy inside the pool can be applied only to the employee share. No additional insurance market reforms are required outside the state purchasing pool. We assume that HIPAA remains in place in non-participating states,and that participation in the program satisfies HIPAA’s requirements for an individual market mechanism. 112 Premium Payment Details We have four goals for our premium payment mechanics: () spread excess health risk broadly throughout the population; () provide subsidies for those with low incomes; () create incentives for efficiencies in care delivery and insurance administration; and () ensure that private insurers remain willing sellers—that is, that they co ll ect enough money for the risks they are bearing. This section and the more technical appendix explain the pricing mechanics through which we achieve these goals. One of our core principles is to set premium payments so as to spread excess (above-average) health risk across all taxpayers. No person enrolling in the state purchasing pool has to pay more than he or she would under a statewide community rate for the state-determined standard benefits package. Low-income persons are subsidized either completely or partially, depending on their income. To show how this works, we present two examples. The simplest case is represented by a state using only a managed FFS arrangement for its risk pool— that is, there are no competing private health plans. In this case, the state determines the premium it charges all enrollees, based on expected use of an average person in the entire state as well as negotiated price and utilization management incentives it has agreed to with participating providers. In this case, the FFS plan is the benchmark plan, by definition. Those with incomes below percent of FPL can enroll in this plan without cost. Those with incomes between percent and percent of FPL pay a share of the statewide community rate according to the schedule determined by the state. Individuals with incomes above percent of FPL are able to buy into this managed FFS plan by making a payment equal to the statewide community rate, which could entail some premium variation by age at the state’s discretion. Federal and state governments share in the costs of the low-income subsidy, according to the relevant matching ra te . The governments also jointly bear the difference between the statewide average cost and the expected cost of providing care to those enrolled in the state pool’s FFS plan. This includes the higher costs due to the pool’s attracting higher- than-average-risk enrollees. The managed competition regime, under which competing private health plans join the state-run FFS plan as an option for en ro ll ee s , is somewhat more complicated. Its details are laid out in the technical appendix. In this case, the state must perform four key functions to determine appropriate payment amounts. . Elicit “bids” from plans interested in participating in the pool. . Choose and implement a risk-adjustment mechanism from the choices approved by the federal government. . Set the benchmark within-pool rate. . Determine the statewide community rate. We describe these functions in the fo ll owing paragraphs. Elicit bids from plans. Insurers that want to compete for the substantial business inside the purchasing pool must submit premium bids for a standard risk enrollee—that is, a healthy young adult male. The healthy young adult male is chosen so that insurers do not base their bids on different expectations about the people who are likely to enroll in the state pool. There are two advantages to having plans bid this way. First,it is standard procedure for insurers to determine premiums for the standard risk. Second, it allows the state to have a uniform measure for comparing plan bids to non-pool rates, because plans typically file rates for standard risks with state insurance departments. While competitive bidding is one clear mechanism for eliciting such bids, the state does not have to use this approach. It can also set or negotiate standard rates with the plans. In addition, insurers include an administrative load in their standard risk bids. Choose and implement a risk-adjustment mechanism. The state must also establish a risk-adjustment system to compensate plans appropriately if they enroll above- or below-average-risk individuals. The federal government provides a list of acceptable risk-adjustment methods from which states select one. States can also request approval for their own risk-adjustment method. The approval process is intended to guarantee some consistency and quality control across the nation. States use the 113 risk-adjustment mechanism to compare average risks enrolled in each plan with average risks throughout the state. These relative risk rankings are necessary to determine premiums to be paid by enrollees and the state and federal governments,and to be received by plans. Set the ben ch m a rk within-pool ra te . We expect plans to submit or nego ti a te a range of bids. The government then determines or selects a benchmark bid. This can either be the median bid or it can be set at a pegged level—for example, percent of the lowest bid. The benchmark bid must be set high enough to engender sufficient plan capacity to en su re that those who are fully subsidized have some choice of plans, and low enough so that all plans have incentives to become efficient and bid low. The benchmark bid is used in setting the level of the full income-related subsidy, the excess risk subsidy, and the statewide community rate. Because the government cannot commit financially to providing low-income persons a complete subsidy for any plan that they might choose, the benchmark is used to define a reasonably efficient premium level. If any plan’s bid is above the benchmark, the individual choosing to enroll in that plan (regardless of income) is responsible for paying the excess. Determine the statewide community rate. The state must compute the expected average premium that is sufficient to cover health services plus administrative loading costs as if all those insured in the state were enrolled in the in-pool benchmark (efficient) plan. This premium is what we refer to as the statewide community rate. It is calculated by adjusting the benchmark bid for the standard-risk person to the level of average risk of all those insured throughout the state (not just in the pool). This requires insurers to report average risk scores both inside and outside the state pool. Because this is a difficult calculation and necessarily an approximation, it may be necessary for the states to supplement insurer reports with other information. Two representative data sources come readily to mind: the Medical Expenditure Panel Survey of employers collects state-specific premium data for most states, and actual provider revenue data collected to support the Commerce Department’s estimates of gross domestic product (GDP) are used in HCFA’s ongoing state and national health expenditure estimates. Both of these sources can be used to develop alternative ways to calculate the statewide community rate for adults and children. It may also be politically necessary to use panels of experts,including actuaries, plan representatives, beneficiary advocates, and representatives of federal and state government, to decide on the reasonableness of the statewide community rate estimate. Calculating the statewide community rate reasonably accurately is important. If it is estimated too high, potential beneficiaries will have to pay more to en ro ll in a state pool than we intend, and too few will want coverage inside the pool. If it is estimated too low, cost to the federal and state government will be higher than necessary with more enrollees coming into the pool for the subsidies, and the per capita excess risk subsidy being too large. Because calculating the statewide community rate is so politically charged, it is probably desirable to err on the high side in the beginning; this maximizes the chances that the system will be up and running without implacable insurer opposition. The extra cost this imposes will be low in the early years because only a few states are likely to implement the program initially. Once calculation of the statewide average cost is institutionalized, fluctuations and uncertainty in this estimate will be reduced, and lessons learned in the early years can be applied in the bulk of states that will implement the program at a more measured pace, and in all states over time. When these calculations are completed, we have several pieces of essential information. We have bids from each plan, risk adjustments reflecting the health status of enrollees of each plan in the pool, as well as in the en ti re state, and calculations of the statewide community rate. The state can then determine the required contributions from beneficiaries, payments to plans, and payments by government. What enrollees will pay. E n ro ll ees in the state pool are responsible for paying the statewide community rate,less any applicable income-related subsidies. Employer contributions count toward an enrollee’s obligation. In addition, if the beneficiary 114 chooses to en ro ll in a plan whose bid exceeds the benchmark bid, he or she will also have to pay the difference between the two bids. If the beneficiary chooses a plan whose premium falls below the benchmark, the plan may choose to rebate the difference to the enrollee as an incentive. The enrollee’s payment is never affected by the mix of risks in the plan he or she selects. What plans are paid. Plans receive a premium payment equivalent to their bid for the standard risk, adjusted for the relative risk of those individuals actually enrolling in their plan. If a plan’s bid is below the benchmark bid, the plan can offer a discount to the beneficiary. Thus, plans receive the full costs they expect to incur and that their competitive bids reflect. But, in general, it is important to note that plans get part of their payment from enrollees and part from the government in the form of income subsidies, excess risk subsidies, and riskadjusted premium payments. What the government pays. The government is responsible for paying two types of subsidies. These subsidy dollars flow directly to plans; they are not transferred through enrollees themselves. First, the government pays all of the applicable low-income subsidies attributable to enrollees in each plan. Second,the government pays the difference between the benchmark standard-risk bid, adjusted for the relative risk of those enrolling in a particular plan, and the statewide community rate. This second type of payment compensates plans for the difference in the health risk of their en ro ll ees compared to all insureds in the state. This payment does not subsidize a plan’s inefficiency, however, because the health risk subsidy is based on the cost of the plans’ enrollees as if they were enrolled in a plan priced at the benchmark. Pure inefficiency—higher bids than the benchmark bid for the standard risk—must be recouped from enrollees. State options. Each participating state has a number of choices that are sometimes limited by federal floor or minimums. Nevert h el e s s ,t h ere is considerable state discretion to affect the character of the purchasing pool. In addition to choosing whether to contract with private plans, some of these choices result from asking the following questions: • Will employers choose a plan on behalf of employees, or will employees have full ch oi ce of plans in the pool? • Will state and local government employees be incorporated fully into the pool, or will they maintain separate coverage with the option for workers to enroll in the pool? • Will the pool be publicly managed, or will it be run through a public-private partnership? • What will the premium structure be—single vs. family; single, couple, single-parent, two-parent (from a menu, or with federal approval)? Each state will be required to offer a child-only premium. • Will any age adjusters be used for setting the unsubsidized premiums within the pool? • What will be the pool’s approach to private insurer premium determination within the pool? Will the state rely on pure competitive bidding, negotiation, or some hybrid? (All pools will have the power to exclude plans deemed unacceptable by reason of quality and/or price.) • What will be the exact risk-adjustment method (from a menu or with federal approval)? • How large a geographic area will be served by each pool (statewide, substate, etc.)? Financing — Who Will Pay? This program is paid for through a combination of federal and state funds.The proposal is expensive, to be sure, as is any serious proposal to expand covera ge . There are currently million non-elderly adults and million children living below percent of poverty. Of these, million adults and million children currently have employer-sponsored coverage. Another . million adults and . million children have private, non-group coverage.7 Even though many of these individuals currently have covera ge , they can receive subsidies, if they choose to join the state plan. Another . million adults and . million children have Medicaid; under our proposal the federal government pays a h i gh er share of expenditures on this population. Urban Institute analysis based on data from the 1998 March Current Population Survey. 7 115 We are not substantially increasing the total number of dollars spent on health care services; rather, we are changing the financing source of those dollars to be more heavily weighted to federal, progressive income taxes. Finally, . million low-income adults and . million low-income children are uninsured and can begin receiving coverage. The large number of low-income adults and children who already have coverage but can nonetheless join the state pool means that the price of achieving equity—that is, treating individuals with similar incomes the same—is high. It is important to remember, however, that we are proposing to change the ways in which health insurance is paid for with regard to low-income people and people with above-average health risks. We are not substantially increasing the total number of dollars spent on health care services; rather, we are changing the financing source of those dollars to be more heavily weighted to federal, progressive income taxes. Our proposal involves considerable expenses attributable to health risk subsidies for those above percent of poverty. Because health expenditures are very unevenly distributed (that is, a large share of expenditures is attributable to a small percentage of the population), a relatively small proportion of the population benefits greatly from the risk-related subsidy, but this subsidy is likely to account for a large share of premium dollars. These costs are borne by both federal and state governments, but primarily the former. Compared to proposals that would be completely federal (for example, refundable tax credits that could achieve the same degree of coverage, if generous enough), the federal expenditures for our proposal are lower because of the state contribution. The federal share is paid for through federal general revenues—and by cuts in existing programs,the need for which would be reduced under such a reform. The increase in federal expenditures is also limited by the strong incentives for employers to con ti nue contributions to their employees’ coverage. These incentives include the tax advantage to higher-wage workers, market pressures to compete for workers who demand health insurance at most or all jobs, and anti-discrimination rules that make it difficult to exclude subsets of workers from health benefits that some workers value highly enough for the firm to offer. We fully expect that some time after full implementation of the program, the federal government and the participating states will be able to begin to reduce other direct payments made directly to providers (for example, DSH payments) to fund care for the uninsured and low-income populations. While the need for such extra sources of funding should be lower under the proposed program, we do not anticipate eliminating these payments completely. Even in states that do adopt an individual mandate, a residual number of uninsured are sure to persist,and some support for providers in particularly high-need areas, such as inner cities, may still be necessary. In those states not choosing to participate in the program, the costs associated with providers in high-need areas can be expected to continue to grow. Changes in federal programs will have to be sensitive to the different needs in participating and non-participating states. Under our proposal, states pay lower matching rates than they do under Medicaid, but they will pay on many more lives. At the same time,they get more federal dollars for those they currently cover under Medicaid. Moreover, they receive the higher federal match on residual Medicaid benefits. This is a large substitution of federal funds for existing state obligations. But federal contributions for those above percent of poverty under the current S-CHIP program are eliminated; therefore, those states that have extended S-CHIP coverage to higher-income levels lose some federal benefits. Still, remembering the savings states get from higher matching ra te s across the board in Medicaid, states are free to use some of their savings to maintain or increase subsi- 116 dies for those above percent of FPL with stateonly money, or to supplement the federal subsidies between percent and percent if they prefer. In addition,states that have existing high-risk insurance pools can eliminate them and send enrollees into the new state combined pool. There are several sources of potential savings to different groups that offset much of the necessary tax increase. Many individuals and businesses will pay lower premiums because of lower administrative costs that result from switching into the pool from the current small-group and non-group markets. In addition, many of those who remain in the private market will pay lower premiums because many above-average risks will enter the pool because of the community rate. To the extent that insurers currently price small-group and individual policies at inefficiently high levels because of fears of adverse selection that do not actually come to fruition,this means real system savings. The consolidated purchasing power of the new pool should engender new efficiencies among health plans and throughout the health care delivery system. Lower premium payments will also lead to higher wages and more tax revenue than would have been the case at the same income and payroll tax rates. Political Feasibility This proposal has a number of political strengths, and its share of weaknesses. From the perspective of federal executive and congressional policy makers, the plan offers a way to attack a major nati on a l probl em . Political leaders will receive credit for offering a solution to the problem without a major expansion of the federal bureaucracy. On the other hand,leaders at the federal level will have to bear the political burden of using surplus revenues or raising taxes to finance the program. Further, while federal political leaders will provide general oversight, most of the credit for the program’s success will go to state political leaders. At the state level, political leaders have the opportunity to receive the credit for solving a serious issue for their constituents with very little increase in state revenues. They have the luxury of building con- sensus and adopting a program only after that consensus exists. However, there will be some increased financing at the state level. Moreover, states will have a large number of new administrative challenges, and state leaders will bear the brunt of criticism for operational failures. Liberals are likely to applaud the coverage expansion that will result, but they will be dissatisfied that the proposal leaves us short of universal coverage and grants so much state discretion. There may be opposition to segmentation of low-income and less-healthy Americans into state purchasing pools, separate from plans serving higher-income and healthier Americans. There is also likely to be distrust and lack of confidence in states’ ability to administer such a complex program and concerns about chronic underfunding. Conservatives will oppose a large government initiative and the introduction of what is essentially an expanded entitlement program. They will view the large amount of spending on those who currently have coverage as inefficient. Conservatives are likely to find favor with the large state role,and they cannot argue that it is a “one size fits all” program. The fact that any individual or family can continue to choose a private plan should mollify some conservative critics. The business community should clearly benefit. No firm will be worse off, and many will have new, less expensive options. The administrative burdens on many smaller firms will be reduced,and the costs of coverage will fall because of the movement of above-average risks into the pool. Some of the savings, however, might be offset with wage increases over time. Insurers and providers are likely to find the plan a mixed blessing. While it will greatly increase the number of covered lives, insurers are likely to be concerned about so many lives being within the scope of the state-organized pool. They are likely to fear what organized purchasing and bargaining power can do to their traditional discretion to segment markets and earn very healthy profits. The fact that a voluntary market outside the state pool is not regulated beyond current law will be viewed as a positive, however. Similarly, providers will also see 117 the benefits of more covered lives, but they will be concerned about government bargaining power being used to lower capitation rates, which can affect their revenues. Health insu ra n ce consumers would either be better off or, at least, no worse off. They can retain existing arrangements, which may become cheaper, or seek a new offering in the state pool. People with low incomes, those in poor health, and those in small firms would clearly benefit. To the extent that increased competition holds down the cost of premiums, those working for employers that offer coverage will see higher wages in the long run. Of course, taxes will be higher than otherwise, offsetting these benefits to some extent. Transitions Our general principle is to leave the pace of the transition to the new subsidy and pooling structure to the individual states, with financial incentives to start early. We offer two-year planning grants to states that are willing to start the first year. These planning grants include enough money to fund development of standardized reporting formats for risk adjustment and statewide community rate cal- culation purposes. One advantage of our system is that it builds on existing institutions: state Medicaid agencies, S-CHIP, and state employee health insurance programs all perform many, if not all, of the functions we have in mind, except for calculating the statewide community rate. Several states—for example, Minnesota, Washington, and Massachusetts—have many of the features of the system we are proposing already in place. We anticipate that other states will choose to participate in the program at varying rates. An advantage of delayed state entry is the opportunity for those entering later to learn from the experi en ce of the pioneers. Our recomm en ded pace is two years of planning, combining Medicaid and S-CHIP in year two, and then adding free choice of the pool in year three. At least five years of state operation under the new system are required before the state could opt for an individual mandate. This waiting period serves two functions: first, it ensures that the state’s pool is operating effectively and efficiently; and,second, it permits federal and state governments to generate more accurate estimates of the cost of the mandate for budgeting purposes. Enforcement mechanisms are up to the states to devise, and they need to be approved by the federal government. Technical Appendix Premium Payment Details, Managed Competition Case This appendix explains how we determine beneficiaries’ obl i ga ti on s , government payments, and net payments to health plans,and achieve our objectives of equity and efficiency. Initial bids will be requested from all private plans participating in the state pool; bids would reflect the insurer’s price for a standard risk, including administrative load. “Standard risk” is used to define the premium cost for an individual of a specified age group and gender, usually a young adult male, the lowest-cost insured adult. It does not mean the average risk for the population insured in the pool. Expected health costs and administrative costs are embedded in this bid for the standard risk. A given plan’s bid is denoted as SRi. From the distribution of bids, the state purchasing authority will determine a benchmark bid, SR b. As noted in the text, states may decide to set premiums through a pure competitive bidding process, they may use a more interactive negotiation approach, or they may set the “bid” unilaterally and then accept only those plans willing to accept that rate, or some alternative method. This standard risk bid will be converted to a premium level by using a risk adjuster that takes into account the difference in expected health costs 118 between actual enrollees in an insurer’s plan within the pool and the expected cost of the standard risk. In general,the premium for the i-th plan is Pi = SRi * (1 + RAi), where Pi is the premium, SRi is the i-th plan’s bid for a standard risk enrollee, and RAi is the risk adjuster or risk score for all the enrollees in plan i, relative to the standard risk. RAi = 0 implies that the i-th health plan has drawn all standard risks,and RAi = .12 means that the plan’s enrollees are expected on average to be percent more costly than the standard risk. We do not have strong opinions about which risk-adjustment method states decide to use, though the federal government should approve the method chosen to guarantee some consistency and quality control across the nation. Any number of specific techniques will produce risk scores relative to the . standard risk that is bid,and it is these relative scores that make up RA.Each person, given his or her characteristics and recent medical history, has an RA score, and average RAs can be computed for any group of persons. Two other concepts are prerequisites to a full explanation of our payment mechanics. The first is the risk adjuster score that reflects the average risk in the state as a whole, RAst , and the other, which builds on this, is the statewide community rate, or CRst = SRb * (1 + RAst). That is, the statewide community rate is the product of the benchmark bid and the average risk statewide, incorporating those both inside and outside the pool. Now, to remain in business, each health plan must collect its expected costs, given the actual average health risk it happens to enroll, or Pi = SRi * (1 + RAi). Our equity principle says that no person should pay more than the statewide community rate CRst , except for an inefficient plan, one that bids above SRb. This CRst is also the amount of the full income-based subsidy, so that an en ro ll ee in a household living at less than percent of poverty can choose an efficient plan and pay nothing out-ofpocket. Partial income subsidies are fractions of percent, s, (s £ percent), times CRst. Thus, the community-rated premium for plan i would be CRi = SRi * (1 + RAst). This is the standard risk bid by plan i, adjusted for the risk of all insured individuals in the state. CRi is the premium facing an individual enrollee in plan i who is not eligible for an income-related subsidy. Those who are eligible for low-income subsidies would pay: CRi - sCRst = SRi * (1 + RAst) - s * SRb * (1 + RAst) = (SRi - s * SRb) * (1 + RAst). When s = 100 percent,and SRi = SRb, those with incomes below percent of poverty pay nothing. If a plan bids above the benchmark, or enrollees’ income exceeds percent of poverty so that s < 1.0, then they must pay something out-of-pocket for that plan. The government must pay the income subsidy and make sure the plan is adequately compensated for the risk profile it actually attracts. The simplest way to accomplish both these goals is to set the government amount as a residual, the difference between what the plan requires to stay in business and what the enrollee pays. The government then would pay: SRi * (1 + RAi) - (SRi - s * SRb) * (1 + RAst), which can be rearranged to yield: SRi * (RAi - RAst) + s * SRb * (1 + RAst). The first term in the government obligation is the combination risk-adjustment and risk subsidy payment that compensates plan i for its enrollees’ risk relative to that in the state as a whole. The second term is the income subsidy amount appropriate for an enrollee with a particular subsidy level, s. Obviously, aggregate government payments will be determined by the average risk and subsidy levels of in-pool enrollees, in addition to the efficiency of plans that compete in the pool. Thus, both governments and beneficiaries gain if most plans are efficient and, therefore, have strong incentives to foster a competitive climate and bidding mechanism that encourages health plan efficiency. Health plan efficiency is key to minimizing the cost of achieving our goals of coverage expansion and equitable access for the low-income and the high-risk. n 119 Kronick and Rice Proposal Key Elements Richard Kronick and Thomas Rice propose that the United States adopt a health care financing system that would: .. a “right” to comprehensive health insurance coverage. Health insurance would be a social insurance program, not a means-tested program. for designing and administering the health care financing system, allowing them the flexibility to create systems that meet the needs of their residents. To receive federal funding, states would need to assure that nearly all legal residents would be covered and have access to at least one zero-premium plan that includes a federally defined standardized benefits package. , which largely relies on employment-based health insurance, with one relying on a payroll tax levied on employers and employees. This tax would be supplemented by federal general revenues, state revenues, and, possibly, individual contributions for plans or benefits beyond those in the standardized benefits package. - long-term care. and make a substantial investment in measuring quality and outcomes, particularly for vulnerable groups. 120 About the Authors , .., is Associate Professor in the Department of Family and Preventive Medicine at the University of California at San Diego. His work focuses on understanding how and whether markets can be made to work well in health care,particularly for vulnerable populations. He recently co-authored, with Joy de Beyer, Medicare HMOs: Making Them Work for the Chronically Ill (Health Administration Press, ). He has developed and helped state Medicaid programs implement risk-adjusted payment systems. In – he was a Senior Health Policy Advisor in the Clinton Administration, where he contributed to the design of the Administration’s health care reform proposal. In the late s he coauthored, with Alain Enthoven,a proposal to achieve universal coverage in the U.S.,and contributed to the theory of ‘managed competition’. Prior to that he served as the Director of Policy and Reimbursement in the Massachusetts Medicaid program.Dr. Kronick received his Ph.D. in Political Science from the University of Rochester. , .., is Professor in the Department of Health Services at the School of Public Health, University of California at Los Angeles. He was Department Chair from to . Dr. Rice is a health economist, having received his doctorate in the Department of Economics at the University of California at Berkeley in . Before joining the faculty at UCLA in , he taught at the University of North Carolina School of Public Health. His areas of interest include health insurance, competition, physicians’ economic behavior, and Medicare. Dr. Rice has received the Young Investigator Award () and the Article of the Year Award () from the Association for Health Services Research. His book The Economics of Health Reconsidered was published in . He served as editor of the journal Medical Care Research and Review from to . 121 A State-Based Proposal for Achieving Universal Coverage by Richard Kronick and Thomas Rice Overview We propose that the United States adopt a health care financing system that provides comprehensive health insurance to all legal residents. The system will be administered by the states and overseen by the federal government.Employers will no longer be involved in providing health insurance covera ge , although both employers and employees will contribute. Other sources of financing include the federal and state governments and, in some instances, individuals and families. The proposed system will replace most of the major components of the U.S. health care financing system; the two exceptions are Medicare and Medicaid-financed long-term care. Each state will administer its own delivery and financing systems. The federal government will contribute to a state’s system as long as several requirements are met, including coverage by and access to at least one zero-premium plan that includes a standard benefits package for nearly all legal residents. Beyond that, states will have wide latitude in crafting their own particular systems. For example, a state can choose to establish a “Canadian-style” single-payer system, in which hospitals are paid based on a negotiated budget and physicians on a fee-forservice basis (presumably with an aggregate expenditure cap). Alternatively, and perhaps more likely, a state can contract with health plans that compete for enrollees through low premiums, high quality, and/or service, with individuals who choose more expensive plans paying for them with ad d i ti on a l premiums. All health insurance ch oi ces offered must include the services specified in a federally defined benefits package that states may choose to augment. Services to be included are inpatient and outpatient care, skilled nursing and home health care, mental health care, preventive services, prescription drugs, and durable medical equipment. To receive coverage, individuals and families will enroll with their states. They only need to provide evidence that they are legal residents of the state; no income verification is required. People living in states that choose to contract with private health plans also must choose a plan. Those failing to do so will be placed in a plan requiring no premium payment. The plan will be financed through a variety of sources. The primary revenue source, a payroll tax levied on both employers and employees, will be supplemented by general federal revenues,state revenues, and, potentially, by individual contributions for certain plans and/or benefits beyond those included in the standard benefits pack a ge . Employers with predominantly low-wage workers will pay a lower tax rate than other employers. The proposal provides a number of assurances that important con s ti tu ency groups, such as states, larger employers, small employers, and families, will pay no more, on avera ge , than they currently do for their health insurance coverage. The proposal will help en su re that the United States meets health care access, cost, and quality goals. All Americans under age who live in the country legally will be provided with health insurance that includes coverage for all major health care services except long-term care. Those eligible will have at least one health insurance option that does not require them to pay any premiums. Thus, neither financial considera ti ons nor burdensome application processes will present barriers to obtaining health insurance, thereby ensuring that the goal 122 of universal coverage is met. Costs are likely to be contained because nearly all participants in the health care marketplace will have an incentive to control them.States will receive an annual fixed-dollar contribution from the federal government; thus they are at risk for additional spending and will have a strong incentive to spend wisely. If they rely on competing health plans to provide insurance packages,these plans will vie with each other for enrollees, recognizing the strong role that premiums play in consumer health plan choice. The plans, in turn, will continue to pay providers in ways designed to reduce excessive and unnecessary use of services. A major ch a ll en ge will be ensuring that goodquality care is provided. Markets, by themselves, cannot ensure this, particularly in light of the difficulties consumers have in obtaining and evaluating the necessary information. The federal government will need to invest substantial resources in measuring health care quality and health outcomes across states, with a sp ecial emphasis on vulnerable populations. As part of the proposal, the federal government will closely monitor the quality of the care provided under each state system, and provide financial rewards to states that improve quality. A second challenge is that states will be taking over a number of responsibilities for administering health insurance that previously were carried out by employers. Depending on how a state chooses to organize, these responsibilities may include, for example, outreach, enrollment, nego ti a ti ons with health plans and providers, data compilation, and quality assu ra n ce . States will need technical and financial assistance to carry out their enhanced roles. Detailed Description of Proposal Federal Requirements To receive federal contributions, states must demonstrate that they have met and continue to meet specific criteria. There are two aspects to this: having their initial program approved,and continuing to meet coverage and quality requirements. This section addresses the initial requirements. Ongoing requirements are addressed later. To obtain approval for their initial plans, states must submit their proposal to a federal agency.1 The proposal will have to demonstrate the following:2 • Nearly all (at least percent) of the legal residential population3 in the state will be enrolled. • All localities will offer at least one plan that does not require any premiums, and that, like all plans, includes the federally mandated benefits package. • New state residents will be covered in a timely fashion. • A plan is in place to monitor and en su re the quality of services provided to all state residents. • There is also a plan in place for collecting and compiling the data necessary to evaluate the system; this is likely to include information on enrollment, utilization (perhaps through encounter data), costs, quality, and satisfaction. • The state has a reasonable plan for carrying out all of the necessary activities to implement its proposed system. States are not required to implement universal coverage; such approval is necessary only if the state wishes to obtain federal contributions. But given the fact that the vast majority of revenues will come from the federal government through the payroll tax and general revenues,it is anticipated that states will be anxious to obtain timely approval of t h ei r proposals. Nevertheless, a state may choose not to participate, in which case it forfeits the federal money that would have been available.4 We assume that this would be an executive branch agency, but we do not take a position on which one; it could be the Health Care Financing Administration, another agency in the Department of Health and Human Services, or a newly established agency. 1 2 This is not unlike the system established in Canada. Under the 1984 Canada Health Act, provinces must demonstrate that the following five provisions are met to receive federal health contributions: public administration, comprehensiveness, universality, portability, and accessibility. The residential population excludes prisoners, those residing in institutions, and the homeless. Although states are encouraged to enroll individuals in these populations, we recognize that this will be a difficult task. Some safety net system of care will still be necessary to care for some of these individuals, as well as those who do not reside legally in the United States. 3 A state that chooses not to participate could continue to receive federal matching money for the Medicaid and State Children’s Health Insurance Program (S-CHIP). 4 123 Eligibility All legal residents of a state are eligible for the state’s program.5 To sign up, they simply have to demonstrate that they live in the state and are residing legally in the United States. No intrusive inform a ti on , including income, will be solicited. One exception, discussed below, is if states chose to supplement federally mandated benefits with additional ones based on such criteria as low income. Each state will be responsible for en ro lling its residents in a particular health insurance plan. Under a system such as single-payer, there probably will be a single plan for which everyone in the state is eligible. Services could be received from any certified provider simply by showing one’s eligibility card. Under systems that contract with private plans, individuals will ne ed to enroll in a particular plan. This can be done when a person registers for coverage or, alternatively, within a designated period of time after registration. Benefits will be fully portable. A person who is visiting another state will be eligible to be reimbu rs ed for urgent and em er gency services during that visit, and those moving to another state will also be covered during the period in which their eligibility is being transferred from one state to another. Benefits There will be a federally determined standardized benefits package to which all states, and all plans within states, must conform. We propose that this include such elements as medically necessary acute inpatient care, outpatient care, acute nursing and home health care, mental health care (in parity with physical health care), preventive services, prescription dru gs , and du ra ble medical equipment. Specifically excluded are dental care and long-term 5 It would be desirable to grant eligibility to all state residents, legal or not, but we have not proposed this because of the political difficulties inherent in granting full benefits to those living in the country illegally. Nevertheless, there are several reasons to cover them: (a) they have health needs like everyone else; (b) their inclusion will lead to true universality, removing the need for a safety net system that could be quite expensive in areas with many such residents; and (c) their inclusion could improve social cohesiveness. As an alternative to covering these individuals, we suggest that the federal government make direct payments to states with significant concentrations of undocumented persons, with the stipulation that these monies be used by the states to support those providers that serve this population. care (both of which states may choose to provide to certain residents). In general, the benefits package should be similar to that currently provided by most large employers. In those states relying on competing health plans, determination of medical necessity will be carried out by the plans initially. As noted below, however, states will oversee the quality of care provided by plans.A second “check and balance” is that the federal government will monitor and, when necessary, regulate the quality of care provided in the state—including whether plans in the state are defining medical necessity too narrowly. As experimental therapies and technologies are developed, we foresee a multi-level decision-making process. In states that contract with competing health plans, decisions about whether and when to provide the new therapy will likely be made by the health plans initially, although certainly in consultation with the state. The state will have the option of being more prescriptive and requiring each plan to provide covera ge . In states that make direct payments to doctors and hospitals, the state certainly needs to be directly involved in deciding whether to pay for new therapies. The federal government will have the option of intervening and being more prescriptive if it does not like the choices made collectively by states and health plans. The exact set of benefits to be covered will be established by Congress. Of major importance will be how these are to be updated over time. We suggest that recommendations for updating the benefits package be made by the Medicare Payment Advisory Commission (or a new agency) for Congress,and by the Health Care Financing Administration (or a new agency) for the President. We anticipate that states may wish to provide more benefits than those included in the standardized package—for example, Title V services to children with special health care needs. As with the status quo, states could establish their own eligibility criteria for such additional services, with funding largely provided by the federal government. One key issue concerns patient cost-sharing requirements under the standardized benefits package. Some advocate substantial cost sharing to make 124 people think twice before using services, while others believe that this is inequitable and will reduce the use of necessary services. Our proposal follows the lead established by the great majority of developed countries: they have instituted low or no copayment requirements on basic services such as inpatient, outpatient, and preventive care. Low copayments also follow the precedent established in most employer-sponsored insurance. Cost-sharing requirements should be kept low for several reasons: • Cost sharing represents a larger share of income for those individuals with lower incomes,thus it is regressive. • Similarly, low-income people are, on average, in poorer health, so requiring them to pay a good deal for services is doubly inequitable. • There is evidence to indicate that the health of low-income families is adversely affected by cost sharing.6 • There is also evidence that cost sharing is indiscriminate in that it reduces the use of necessary and unnecessary services.7 • Low copayments will obviate demand for supplemental insurance that covers these copayments. Such policies may be viewed as undesirable by states because, by increasing utilization, program costs will rise, as well. • Although it is clear that an individual facing substantial copayments will use less health care than an individual for whom care is nearly free, it is far from clear that a health care system in which many people face copayments (but are fully insured for care beyond some catastrophic limit) will provide less care than a system in which copayments are low. In the absence of supply side constraints, if providers are paid mo re for delivering more servic- 6 R. H. Brook et al. “Does Free Care Improve Adults’ Health?” New England Journal of Medicine 309: 1426–34; M. F. Shapiro. “Effects of Cost Sharing on Seeking Care for Serious and Minor Symptoms.” Annals of Internal Medicine 104: 246–51; R. O. Valdez. The Effects of Cost Sharing on the Health of Children, Santa Monica, CA: RAND Corp., 1986. K. N. Lohr, “Effect of Cost Sharing on Use of Medically Effective and Less Effective Care.” Medical Care 24 (supplement): S31–S38. 7 Under the proposal, acute care services cur rently paid for by Medicaid will be folded into the standard benefits package. Average unit payment rates to providers are likely to be higher under the standard 8 es, then they are likely to respond to lower levels of consumer demand by adjusting standards of care. We propose that copayments under the standard benefits package be similar to those in policies currently offered by typical large employers. Even these relatively low copayments will disadvantage those who are currently covered by Medicaid and, therefore,now have no copayments.States may choose to provide supplemental coverage for low-income persons; this supplemental coverage might cover copayments as well as other services not included in the standard benefits package, such as dental care. Financing The system will be financed according to the following principles: , The federal government will estimate the cost of providing the standard benefits package to all legal residents in each state. First, it will estimate current health expenditures in each state using data from the Na ti onal Health Accounts, su pp l em en ted by survey data on employer health insurance costs and health maintenance organization (HMO) premiums. The estimate of current expenditures will be adjusted upward for expected utilization increases from insuring the uninsured (and underinsured).8 It will be adjusted downward for expected efficiencies that will result from universal coverage. ’ State governments will be expected to contribute percent of their current Medicaid and S-CHIP spending on services that are included in the standard benefits package for covered populations (that benefits package in many states than the rates currently paid by Medicaid; however, we do not suggest adjusting current expenditure levels upward to account for the difference. Rather, we suggest assuming that average payment rates for non-Medicaid services will decline slightly, resulting in overall average unit payment rates (combining Medicaid and non-Medicaid) that will be similar after universal coverage as they are under the status quo. To the extent that there is strong evidence that utilization rates of cur rent Medicaid recipients will change when they are covered by so-called mainstream plans, modelers might want to assume some utilization response; however, we are doubtful that such evidence exists. 125 All legal residents of a state are eligible for the state’s program. To sign up, they simply have to demonstrate that they live in the state and are residing legally in the United States. is, state Medicaid spending on dental services,longterm care, undocumented persons, and the elderly would not be included in this amount). ’ The federal government will pay to state governments that operate a qualified plan an amount equal to the estimated cost of providing the standard benefits package to all residents (estimated as discussed above) minus the state government financial responsibility amount. The state government financial responsibility is not a “maintenance of effort” requirement. If states can provide the standard benefits package to all legal residents at lower-thanexpected cost, the state contribution will be smaller than expected. Alternatively, if more money is needed, it is state governments’ responsibility to raise a portion of the necessary revenues. If we could be confident that the state-specific estimates of expected expenditures after universal coverage would closely approximate the expenditures needed to maintain the status quo in the health care system ,t h en we would be comfortable placing financial responsibility for the marginal health care dollar entirely in the hands of state governments. State governments will be making important decisions about health care financing, and they should be accountable for the outcomes of these decisions. However, uncertainties in the accuracy of the state health accounts data and the ad ju s tm en t s needed to move from the status quo to universal coverage create uncertainty about the precision of the estimates of state-level post-universal coverage expenditures. As a result, it is possible that expenditures in a given state will be substantially greater than expected expenditures, not because the state has chosen to be generous in its payments to providers, but rather because the expected expendi- tures were an underestimate of the expenditures needed to maintain the status quo in the state’s health care system. If a state’s expenditure for services included in the standard benefits package differs substantially from the expected state government financial responsibility amount, we suggest that the federal and state governments share in the su rp lus or deficit.A reasonable approach would be to make the state fully responsible for spending that is percent more or less than the expected state government responsibility; have the state and federal governments share the next percent surplus or deficit -, and have the federal government be responsible for percent of the su rp lus or deficit if state spending is more than percent of the expected amount, or less than percent of the expected amount. For example, if a state is expected to spend billion but actually spends . billion, the federal government would increase its contribution to the state by million—that is, percent of the difference between actual state spending and percent of expected spending. Inevitably, there will be disagreements between the federal and state governments about which state expenditures should be included in this calculation.9 In the long term, a system in which the federal contribution is fixed and states are financially responsible for their decisions is preferable to a system that encourages disputes about matching payments. However, in the short term some sharing of financial responsibility for deviations from projections is sensible. We suggest below that Congress appoint a commission to make recommendations on realigning federal contributions across states; the work of 9 Witness the disagreements in the Medicaid program about disproportionate share hospital payments, and, more recently, about payments to nursing homes and hospitals under the Upper Payment Limit regulations. 126 this commission would facilitate the transition to full state financial responsibility. The federal government will raise most of the money needed to finance its contribution to state programs through a payroll tax on employers and employees. The amount of money raised by the payroll tax will be equal to percent of the total amount currently spent by employers and employees for health insurance for covered benefits (that is, it would not include amounts spent for dental care or other services not included in the standard benefits package). This amount would include expenditures for non-group coverage and out-of-pocket payments for health care, to the extent that payments for these services are expected to be included in the standard benefits package. The tax rate will be uniform throughout the country. Following the model of the Medicare payroll tax, we suggest that the health care payroll tax be applied to all wages; however, if there is a desire to limit the progressivity of the financing system, the payroll tax could be imposed only on wages up to the Social Security wage base. In a full proposal,a payroll tax rate will be specified. Rather than providing our own back-of-theenvelope estimate of what this tax rate will be, we leave this to the modelers. For purposes of discussion below, we assume that the total payroll tax will be percent—that is, we assume that an percent tax will generate an amount equal to percent of what is currently spent by employers and employees (including non-group coverage and out-of-pocket payments that would be covered). The total payroll tax will be divided between employers and employees based on the current distribution of spending between employers and employees. If, for example, the modelers estimate that percent of current spending is done by employers, and if the total tax is percent, then employers would pay a percent tax,and employees would pay a percent tax. We propose that the employee portion of the payroll tax be treated as pre-tax income, as much of employee spending for health insurance is now. To increase the progressivity of the financing system and minimize negative effects on the level of employment, we propose a lower tax rate for employers with predominantly low-wage workers. For example, employers whose average employee makes less than per hour would pay percent of covered payroll rather than percent of covered payro ll . Self-employed persons will pay both the employer and employee portions. The difference between the amount of money the federal government is obligated to pay to the states and the amount raised by the payroll tax raised will be financed by general revenues. We expect that much of the general revenue obligation will be a transfer from federal Medicaid funds currently used to support Medicaid and S-CHIP. However, some of the general revenue obligation will require new federal funds, presumably drawn from the anticipated budget surplus. The federal payment to the states will grow at a rate to be specified annually by Congress, after receiving a recommendation from the President and the Medicare Payment Advisory Commission (MedPAC) or a new advisory agency to be established. In making its recommendation, the advisory agency will consider factors similar to those that MedPAC considers in recommending payment updates for Medicare. In addition, the agency must consider the effects of any changes in the standard benefits package. To provide some protection to state governors and health care providers, the five-year growth rate of per capita federal payments to the states will not be less than the five-year growth rate of per capita Medicare expenditures, unless compelling rationales are advanced that health care needs are increasing much more quickly in the over- population than in the under- population.10 10 The rationale is that if Congress has the political will to get tough with providers in the Medicare program, then it is reasonable to ask governors to be similarly hard-nosed; alternatively, if Congress decides that Medicare needs additional funds to provide high-quality care to seniors, it is not reasonable to ask governors to be significantly more frugal for their states’ under-65 population. 127 The proposed financing system is intended to leave the status quo largely intact for health care providers—revenues to the health care financing system in each state after universal coverage is implemented should be similar to current revenues (adjusted for the expected effects of universal coverage, as discussed above). In addition, state government payments are intended to be similar to the current system—with a percent savings in each state to encourage governors and state legislatures to support the proposal. As a result, there will be wide disparities across states in the amount of federal support; in states that have high per capita health care costs, federal support will be greater than in states with low per capita cost health care costs. This is likely to be seen as unfair by those people living in states that historically have spent relatively little on health care. We suggest that Congress appoint a commission to make recommendations on long-term realignment of federal contribution levels.11 - Federal government payments to the states will be contingent on the states satisfying basic requirements. To the extent these requirements are not satisfied, graduated financial penalties will be applied. For example,if a state does not provide the standard benefits package to percent of its legal residents, the federal contribution is reduced—certainly by the per capita contribution amount and, we propose, with an additional penalty. A state that fails to meet quality standards or to provide required information will also be subject to financial sanctions. 11 A number of factors should be considered in thinking about equity. Federal contributions might be compared to the amount of payroll tax revenue coming from the state; one might focus only on the federal per capita contribution from general revenue as the amount to be concerned with when considering fairness. Alternatively, if we think of current federal Medicaid spending as an entitlement to the states (or, at least, as part of the status quo), then the federal contribution to focus on might be simply the new general revenue payments (that is, treating the displaced Medicaid funds, like the payroll tax, as belonging to the states). One also might want to consider the size of the per capita state contribution in considering equity, as well as the contribution of the state to medical education, and, potentially, research. To avoid a large windfall to shareholders of companies with retiree health obligations, a tax on corpora ti ons that show Federal Accounting Standards Board Section obligations on their balance sheets will be enacted. The government would estimate the portion of a corporation’s Section liability that would be assumed by the states under reform. Employers would be assessed percent of this amount, and would pay a special “retiree health assessment tax.” The total retiree health assessment would be paid over years. Administration and Regulation Once the new syst em has b een implemented, it will be necessary to monitor its performance and make necessary corrections. There is a trade-off, of course, between accountability and state autonomy. On the one hand, consumer protection is especially critical in health care, where much is at stake and consumers face severe information problems. On the other hand, for a proposal like this to be successful, states need to tailor a system that best fits their particular circumstances. The main concern is quality—whether the average quality is sufficiently high and whether disadvantaged populations face particular quality barriers. Most parties will have strong incentives to control costs, which obviously raises issues about sacrificing quality. These concerns are discussed in the following section. As noted, the federal bureaucracy envisioned is minimal. The executive branch will be advised by the Health Care Financing Administration or a new agency, and Congress by the Medicare Payment Advisory Commission or a new agency. Once the system has been implemented, some of the ongoing duties of these two agencies will include making recommendations on: • updating the benefits package; • revising the formula for allotting contributions to each of the states; and • deciding how much federal contributions will increase over time. 128 Quality Assurance The major concern with the proposal is ensuring that high-quality services are provided. There are two somewhat independent aspects to this. First, plans—particularly in states that emphasize price competition—are likely to be under strong pressure to keep costs down, potentially threatening quality. Second, even if plans do attempt to provide goodquality care, they may lack the tools to do so. Regulatory oversight is necessary to address the first issue, because in markets where full consumer information is probl em a ti c , there is no assurance that the services provided will be of the quality sought by consumers. Fu rt h ermore, some states may not meet their responsibilities to ensure the provision of good-quality care. This is particularly a concern for services delivered to vulnerable groups such as racial and ethnic minorities and the poor. As a result, quality assurance is the only major area of the proposal in which strong federal regulation is called for. We propose that a quasi-independent, bipartisan federal quality commission be established to monitor the quality of health care delivered in each of the states, and to provide financial incentives to states to improve quality. (Quality will be defined as encompassing access and quality.) The commission needs to be given a sufficient budget for staffing adequately and collecting the data necessary to fulfill its mission, which will include assessment of: • whether nearly all individuals have health insurance; • whether the most vulnerable individuals face any unduly significant barriers to accessing necessary preventive and acute care services; • the technical quality of care provided to patients through assessments of appropriate processes and desirable health outcomes; • patient satisfaction; and • state-provided data to evaluate access, costs, and quality. As noted earlier, these data would likely include information on en ro ll m en t , utilization (perhaps through encounter data), costs, quality, and satisfaction. In addition to measuring quality, we propose that the quality commission be empowered to financially reward states that perform the best in improving quality of care. A portion of the federal payments to states would be deducted from the direct federal payments and provided to the quality commission to distribute as a “quality bonus” to states that improve their performance. The bonus pool might begin at . percent of federal support, and grow to percent after years. The proposed growth in the size of the pool reflects anticipated improvements in our ability to measure meaningful aspects of quality. The movement of funds to the quality improvement pool should lag the implementation of universal coverage—perhaps by three to four years, to give the quality commission time to implement measurement tools and establish baseline performance levels. Of course, some aspects of a health system (for example, adequately trained physicians and other personnel, well-staffed and equipped hospitals) are critical to the provision of quality care. These structural aspects, however, are left to the states to regulate. The second issue is that many states, health plans, providers, and consumers lack the necessary tools to ensure adequate quality of care. The “freerider effect” will result in too small an investment in the necessary data and research on quality. States will want to take advantage of investments made by other states, and health plans of investments made by other health plans. To illustrate, suppose that one health plan is considering investing in a system that evaluates the quality of primary physician care, feeding back information to providers so they can improve. In most cases, however, providers are enrolled in many managed care plans. If one plan invests in improving quality, the other plans in which the provider participates will gain without making a concomitant investment. As a result, all plans will underinvest in quality improvement. The best way to deal with this problem is to treat research on quality as a public good and have the federal government invest in it. This is done in clinical care through the National Institutes of Health and, to some extent, in health services research. But the amount of investment in the latter is much too low. In , the United States spent . trillion on 129 health care.12 In contrast, the budget of the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality (AHRQ), the federal agency mainly responsible for the accumulation and dissemination of this knowledge, was only about million—a mere . percent of health care dollars spent.13 We believe that this figure should be at least percent of total health spending, although this enhanced funding should be phased in. Some of the actions to be emphasized in this research and dissemination effort should include: • reducing medical errors; • ensuring that providers in all medical specialties use state-of-the art technologies; • enhanced measurement of health care processes and outcomes; • focusing on the health status of disadvantaged population groups; and • creating the necessary databases to accomplish these tasks. Integration with the Current Health Care Financing System The Medicaid program for long-term care services would remain. For aged or disabled persons who meet Medicaid financial eligibility standards, reimbursement for institutional and home and community-based long-term care would continue, with the current federal formula for matching payments. Two areas deserve special consideration—a va ri ety of services outside the standard benefits package that are currently provided under Medicaid to children, and non-long-term care payments currently made for those who are dually eligible for Medicaid and Medicare (for example, prescription d ru gs , copayments, deducti bl e s , Part B prem iu m payments.) For children, there are a va ri ety of services— dental care is a prominent example—currently provided by Medicaid that are not part of the standard benefits package. There are at least two options here: first, maintain Medicaid financing for dental www.cdc.gov /nchs /products /pubs /pubd/hus /00tables.htm# National Health Expenditures 12 13 www.ahrq.gov/about /profile.htm services under current Medicaid rules, or, second, provide funds under a block grant to the states, with the stipulation that the funds be used to support health care for low-income children. While maintaining the Medicaid entitlement and open-ended matching funds may sound attractive to advocates, we doubt that it is a good idea. First, some services—such as dental care—are currently optional for states under Medicaid. More important, in most states access to dental care is extremely problematic. Even under the current system, most states have done a very poor job in providing dental services to low-income children. There are other federal programs—such as Title V (providing funds for services for children with special health care needs), Section funds for community health centers, support for community mental health centers, and support for rural and migrant health centers—that should continue, even under universal covera ge . Eventually the need for these funds might be reassessed, but this is not included in the proposal. Similarly, although on a much larger scale, the Department of Veterans Affairs health care system might eventually change in response to an environment of universal coverage for the standard benefits package, but changes to the VA are not part of the proposal. Medicaid currently pays for prescription drugs, copayments, deductibles,and Part B p remiums for a variety of low-income Medicare recipients. Under this proposal, the federal government will administer this Medigap-like coverage directly, rather than relying on the states to fill gaps in a federally run program. Ninety percent of the financial burden lifted from the states by federal assumption of current Medicaid responsibilities would be added to states’ financial responsibility. The standard benefits package for persons under age will be richer and deeper than the benefits currently available under Medicare. This will add to the already existing pressure to improve the Medicare benefits package, but changes to Medicare are not included as part of this proposal. 130 We have chosen to rely on states to make major decisions about health care financing and delivery because we think they are the appropriate locus of financial and political decision making. Protecting safety net providers would be largely a state responsibility. As discussed above, a variety of Health Resources and Services Administra ti on (HRSA) programs in support of providers such as community health centers and rural and migrant health centers would be expected to continue. However, since the Medicaid acute care program would be folded into the universal coverage system, Medicaid disproporti on a te share hospital (DSH) payments would end. Consistent with the federal requirement to provide the standard benefits package to all state residents, state governments could choose to con ti nue direct payments to hospitals currently receiving DSH funds; however, these payments would compete directly with money that might be used to pay for health insurance premiums (in a system with competing health plans) or to support other providers (in a single-payer system). These are problems for the states to work out, although state plans submitted for approval to the federal government must demonstrate that the needs of traditional community providers have been taken into account in designing the state financing system. The Central Role for States As the title of this paper suggests, this is a “state-based proposal.” This section discusses some of the advantages and disadvantages of a state-based proposal, and indicates why we have chosen this direction. We have chosen to rely on states to make major decisions about health care financing and delivery because we think they are the appropriate locus of financial and political decision making. We see three major substantive problems with a system run solely by the federal government.First,it will be difficult for the federal government to do a good job of figuring out, in total, how much money should go into health care. Providers will always argue for more and complain that quality will suffer without more resources. Some providers will go out of business. Decision makers in Washington are so far away from local conditions that it will be difficult for them to determine whether the providers are correct and how much to be concerned that some providers may go out of business. Imagine, for example, that Medicare was expanded to cover the entire population. Suppose now that some hospitals or physicians in Boston or St. Louis have negative margins and face the prospect of c ut ting back services or, perhaps, closing their doors entirely. Alternatively, these hospitals might argue that they are unable to adopt quality-enhancing technology because of inadequate reimbursement. The providers will certainly appeal to the federal government for help. How are decision makers in Washington going to determine whether such help is needed? It is difficult to imagine that they will do a good job. We have concerns about the ability of state governments to make good decisions here, as well, but there is greater financial and political accountability with decisions made closer to the bedside (and closer to patients and providers and taxpayers!). Second, the federal government, under intense scrutiny and pressure, has a very difficult time experimenting with new forms of finance and delivery, while states are able to move somewhat more nimbly. For example, the federal government has tried unsuccessfully a number of times to implement a competitive bidding demonstra ti on for Medicare. In contrast, state governments, in purchasing benefits for both state employees and Medicaid beneficiaries, have been able to adopt innovative purchasing practices with much less political resistance. Federal government control is likely to lead to a system that is less innovative and flexible over time than a system in which state gov- 131 ernments have major responsibility for financing and delivery decisions. Related to this point, state diversity and experimentation will allow for the dissemination of best practices. Third, we continue, collectively, to disagree about whether “competitive” or “regulatory ”a pproaches to health care financing will produce the desired combination of quality and economy. These fights are unlikely to be resolved any time soon, and preferences are likely to differ across states. A state-based approach allows for diversity, while a federal approach would be likely to impose a uniform solution. (One could imagine a federal approach with substantial waiver authority to allow state diversity, but this is likely to be difficult to implement if state governments do not have financial responsibility, as well.) We have justified our choice of state rather than federal control of major health care financing decisions. In the concluding secti on , we present our ra ti onale for proposing increased public-sector involvement in health care financing and eliminating the role of employers as middlemen in our financing system. In this proposal, states will have substantially expanded roles and responsibilities, including: • choosing the financing and service delivery systems used (for example, single-payer, competing private health plans) to provide health insurance coverage to nearly all state residents; • providing information on enrollment options and procedures to all state residents; • carrying out the enrollment process, which will often entail having all residents choose a health plan; • negotiating with health plans and providers over services, payments, and quality; • ensuring that the necessary data are collected, both for estimating the cost of the system and for evaluating its performance; • ensuring that insurers and providers do their part to provide good-quality care; and • sharing with the federal government in the financial risk associated with financing health care services for the population. This reliance on states undoubtedly is contro- versial; it was not chosen as the basis of our proposal lightly. There are two major concerns about placing such key responsibilities with the states. First, until now they have not had the main responsibility for administering health insurance for their populations. This lack of experience will be costly if they are not able to carry out the many roles listed above. Second, it can be argued that some states have not been as “trustworthy” as others in implementing their primary health insurance program, Medicaid, and that some states have done a poor job of protecting disadvantaged groups such as racial minorities. In the case of Medicaid, some states have extremely stringent eligibility criteria and pay providers so poorly that few want to treat patients in the program. With respect to the first problem—lack of experience—there is no doubt that most states will need both technical and financial assistance to carry our their enhanced roles. Congress needs to allot sufficient funding for these activities. Nevertheless, one should not be too pessimistic about states’ abilities to carry out these roles because they are already have a great deal of experience in regulating private insurance and HMOs; enrolling state residents in programs such as Medicaid and S-CHIP; contracting with health plans and third-party administrators as part of Medicaid; and operating public health systems. The second problem is more worrisome: some states have done a poor job of providing health insurance coverage in the past, and these problems could be magnified under the proposal, which provides strong financial incentives to states for controlling costs. Aggressive cost control, in turn, could harm quality. Several aspects of the proposal address these potential problems. First, all non-Medicare-eligible state residents will be part of the system. State officials whose systems provide poor-quality or inefficient care will be under strong political pressure to improve them. Second, states will find it difficult to skimp on providing adequate access because this is a federal government requirement. Those states that do not enroll at least percent of their population will face severe financial penalties. Third, only those state plans that are initially approved by the federal 132 government will become operational. Fourth, there is a strong federal quality monitoring system built into the proposal (with sp ecial emphasis on quality and outcomes for vulnerable groups), coupled with financial incentives that will reward states that offer good-quality care and penalize those that do not. Transition The following steps need to be followed in implementing the proposal. We also provide a suggested timetable for the transition from our current hodgepodge to the reformed system. . Congress passes a law enacting the reforms on July , . . The federal agency responsibility for oversight of the new system, in consultation with governors and other interested parties, develops guidelines for the state plans.Guidelines are promulgated by July , . The federal government makes planning grants to the states. . States enact enabling legislation, and submit state plans to the federal government no later than December , . The federal government makes funds available to the states for transitional assistance and provides technical assistance and training. . On January , , the federal government starts co ll ecting new payroll taxes. States with approved state plans start receiving payments from the federal government and providing coverage to all under-, non-Medicare residents of the state. Employers presumably stop providing health benefits to employees for services included in the standard benefits package. If a state does not implement a plan, then employers and employees will be paying a substantial payroll tax, but not receiving federally subsidized health benefits. This is likely to create extremely strong pressure on state governments to design and implement acceptable plans. Impact of Proposal on Society’s Goals Access The proposal will help ensure that the United States attains the three major policy goals of universal access, cost control, and good quality of care. With regard to access,all Americans who live in the country legally will, as a right, be provided with health insurance that includes coverage for all major health care services except long-term care. Everyone will have at least one health insurance option that does not require payment of any premiums. Thus, financial considera ti ons will no longer be a barrier to obtaining health insurance, nor will stigma be an issue because everyone will receive coverage through the state. States will be given strong financial incentives from the federal government to en su re that they meet coverage requirements. Combined,these should ensure that the goal of universal coverage is met. This is not to imply that access issues will be solved. There are many barriers to access, and financial impediments are only one. In addition, to the extent that there are some copayments under the standardized benefits package, some individuals currently enrolled in Medicaid may find themselves worse off. Similarly, the benefits package excludes various services covered by state Medicaid programs, which could also impede access. States may wish, therefore, to consider providing additional coverage to poor and vulnerable individuals to compensate for this shortfall. Costs Costs are likely to be contained because nearly all participants in the health care marketplace will have an incentive to control them. Because states will receive an annual fixed-dollar contribution from the federal government, they are at risk for additional spending, so they have a strong incentive to spend wisely. If they rely on competing health plans to provide insurance packages,these plans will vie with each other for enrollees, recognizing the strong role that premiums play in consumer health plan choice. The plans, in turn, will continue to pay providers in ways designed to reduce excessive and unnecessary use of services. As in the case of access, cost control is hardly guaranteed, nor should it be. In fact, as medical therapies become more efficacious and the population ages, the United States may wish to spend more on health care. 133 Some elements of the proposal will almost certainly increase health care costs. These include universal coverage and comprehensive benefits (the latter will increase utilization for those who are currently underinsured). Quality The biggest ch a ll en ge will be en su ring that goodquality care is provided. We do not believe that markets, by themselves,can assure this,particularly with the difficulties consumers have in obtaining and evaluating the necessary inform a ti on . Nor can states—some of which may be under tight fiscal constraints—necessarily be depended on. If the federal government is going to turn over large amounts of revenue to the states, it will need to invest substantial resources in measuring health care quality and health outcomes across states, with special emphasis on vulnerable populations. The types of investments and oversight needed to accomplish this goal were discussed above. Political Feasibility We are aware that our proposal represents a substantial departure from the status quo and will face significant political opposition. Two main features of the proposal are likely to create opposition: first, transforming current voluntary employer and employee payments into a mandatory payroll tax, and, second, turning over the money and the responsibility to state governments. We address each of these concerns below. There are two reasons to propose a payroll tax. First and most important, we know of no way to get to universal coverage, or anywhere close to it, without required contributions. The main alternatives to the payroll tax for the required contributions are a value-added tax or an increase in the income tax (accompanied by an individual mandate). The payroll tax is closer to the way the United States currently finances health care and is arguably politically more palatable than either of these alternatives. Proposals for expanding subsidized coverage (for example, expanding S-CHIP to parents in families with incomes less than percent of federal pover- ty level) are not likely to do much to reduce the number of uninsured. The S-CHIP-like expansion proposals may be the best we can hope to accomplish, but we should be clear about how far they leave us from universal coverage. The second reason we propose public-sector decisions about health care financing is that we think employers have added relatively little value to health care purchasing. Employers are in business to make a product or provide a service,not to purchase health care. Since most actions that employers might take in an attempt to purchase better health care will only be effective if they are joined by many other employers, they face a significant co ll ective action problem. While a few employer groups, such as the Pacific Business Group on Health, have made some progress in overcoming the collective action probl em , progress has been limited, and effective purchasing coalitions are the exception,not the rule. Certainly the tribulations of Medicare and state Medicaid programs give us pause, as well, but these organizations have the potential, partially actualized, to be prudent intermediaries in health care finance. Some who support public financing and the elimination of the employer role in purchasing care will be upset that our proposal calls for state governments to set the rules of health care financing, rather than simply expanding the federal Medicare program to cover all Americans. Certainly Medicare is an extremely popular program and has the advantage of an existing and concrete framework. Our proposal envisions new state structures and suffers from uncertainty—what exactly will health care look like in my state after Congress passes universal coverage legislation? The answer must await state action. However, the difficulty of having a uniform set of federal rules to respond flexibly to the needs of the residents and providers in each state outweighs, in our judgment, the potential advantages of simply expanding Medicare. We are aware that our approach relies on substantially more public-sector involvement in health care financing and delivery than the country has been comfortable with in the past. There is likely to be concern about this proposal from a variety of 134 important constituencies—some employers with relatively young and highly paid employees might end up paying more in payroll tax than they now pay for health insurance, as would employers who currently do not offer health benefits at all. Some providers and insurers will be nervous about concentrated purchasing power in the hands of state government; some governors will be reluctant to absorb substantial new responsibilities and the political demands these responsibilities create; and some citizens will be concerned about giving state governments greater control over the financing and delivery of health care. However, the proposal will have appeal, as well: The left should find mandated universal coverage with no required premiums attractive, and the right should like the opportunity for states to tailor their own health care system, and the likelihood that many of these state systems will embrace market-based approaches over administered pricing approaches. As we approach million uninsured (the Current Population Survey results showing a decline in the number of uninsured are most likely a short-term blip in a longerterm trend), rising costs (again) for employers and employees, increasing dissatisfaction among physicians and hospitals, managed care backlash from patients, and a poor outlook for profit growth for health insurers reveal at least the potential that the country might be ready to experiment with approaches that are more revolutionary than evolutionary. Our proposal provides a sensible policy prescription that could be successfully implemented if the political window opens more widely than its customary narrow slit. Acknowledgements We would like to thank Harold Luft for helpful comments on a draft of this proposal. All opinions are solely those of the authors and do not reflect those of the reviewers, sponsor, funding agency, or our respective universities. n 135 Pauly Proposal Key Elements Mark V. Pauly has outlined a new proposal to reduce the number of uninsured that would: that could be easily modified in response to lessons learned from this new approach. - - with flexible, refundable tax credits or “coupons,” redeemable for insurance premiums or a reduction in taxes, for any licensed medical-surgical insurance policy with a premium at least as large as the credit. - eligible for publicly provided or contracted insurance, or for equivalent-cost private insurance, with no premium share required. to retain the tax exclusion for group coverage, until mandated to participate in the new program at some point in the future. are renewable. 136 About the Author . , .., is Bendheim Professor and Chair of the Department of Health Care Systems, Professor of Health Care Systems, Insurance and Risk Management and Public Policy and Management at the Wharton School,and Professor of Economics in the School of Arts and Sciences at the University of Pennsylvania.Dr. Pauly served as commissioner on the Physician Payment Review Commission,and he is an active member of the Institute of Medicine. One of the nation’s leading health economists,Dr. Pauly has made significant contributions to the fields of medical economics and health insurance. His classic study on the economics of moral hazard was the first to point out how health insurance coverage may affect patients’ use of medical services. He has explored the impact of conventional insurance coverage on preventive care, on outpatient care,and on prescription drug use in managed care, as well as studying the influences that determine whether insurance coverage is available and the effect of insurance use on health outcomes and cost.Dr. Pauly is co-editor-in-chief of the International Journal of Health Finance and Economics and an associate editor of the Journal of Risk and Uncertainty. 137 An Adaptive Credit Plan for Covering the Uninsured by Mark V. Pauly Introduction To deal with the problem of large numbers of persons without health insurance, this paper outlines a flexible and adaptive method of using refundable tax credits, supplemented by a full publicly subsidized program for very-low-income households. This flexibility and adaptability is necessary for two reasons: () The availability of credits will transform insurance markets in ways that eventually (but not initially) will change how credits might be used. Specifically, credits will cause some uninsured persons to seek coverage, and that influx of new customers may help to transform the markets they enter. () There is substantial and (currently) irreducible uncertainty about two key aspects of this system’s response to the availability of partial credits. How many will take up insurance for a given credit policy, and how the markets in which they will use their credits will be transformed,are subject to enormous uncertainty that cannot be addressed by better current data collection and/or analysis or simulation. The reason for this uncertainty is that there has been no experience with such a large-scale system of credits or subsidies offered to the target populations; we simply don’t know what will happen because we have never seen anything like it. Attempts to extrapolate from other situations we have observed (tax subsidies for the self-employed, behavior of Medicaid recipients) can offer some hints about direction and size of relative effects, but they cannot substitute for actual experience. Policy analysts typically deal with such behavioral uncertainty in federal programs in one of three ways. One way is to acknowl ed ge the uncertainty f ra n k ly, present ranges of values for possible out- comes, with no pretense that some value in the range is a “best” (or even “better”) guess than others, and then suggest a plan that deals with uncertainty and learns from its resoluti on . Such a plan ordinarily will not be best for any one particular scenario for the unknown variables, but it will be good on average for a wide range of possible scenarios. A second approach is to design an interven ti on that leaves it to the states to resolve some of the uncertainty, and counts on them to offer different approaches. The third approach is to pick one possible behavioral response, declare it to be virtually certain, and design a policy that fits it. This last approach in policy for the uninsured leads to stalemate, because, for any policy that inspires optimism in some, there will be others with worries and concerns who can block the proposal. Until now we have done virtually nothing about the bulk of the uninsured, because the outcomes are uncertain and undesirable results cannot be ruled out. The strategy here is to follow the first approach, and to proceed in two stages or phases. We begin with a relatively simple, financially feasible, easily reversible or modifiable intervention,targeted at the uninsured for whom it is most suitable. We embed a s ch eme to learn from that intervention to alter aspects of the program according to a fixed, transparent, and comfortable process. The first phase of the plan also is intended to be easy to administer and understand, and permissive and encouraging rather than restrictive and intimidating in determining el i gi ble persons and qualified insurance policies. The program initially targets one subset of the uninsured population for credits. As a result, this simple initial program is less than comprehensive and less than perfect. But it is a step forward, 138 and one that is better than the current situation. In the second phase, the observed outcomes from that intervention set the stage for generalizing the program, and inform a ti on from that interven ti on is used to determine the best way to generalize. In this process, change is an indication of learning, not mistakes, and we do not have to wait until every possible glitch is anticipated before moving ahead. In what follows, we primarily provide details on the Phase I proposal. The alterations to this structure that might take place during Phase II are described later. Overview In Phase I,the flexible credit plan divides the under U. S. population into three groups, each treated differently. Lower-middle-income households, which make up two-fifths of the uninsured, are the primary initial target group. All families with incomes above the poverty line but below the median (regardless of the age,sex, or relationship of family members) are made eligible for a voucher or credit of a given amount, varying only by whether it is used for individual or family coverage, that can be used to purchase insurance. For budgetary and political reasons,credits are likely to be less than the full premium for a comprehensive insurance policy for all eligible persons. So to maximize the use of the subsidy, few restrictions are placed on the type of insurance for which it can be used, or on the cost of that insurance, but a publicly provided or contracted fallback insurance plan will offer policies financed with the same subsidy on the same terms as private plans. The subsidies take the form of refundable credits or “coupons” redeemable against either all or part of the insu ra n ce premium, or redeemable as a tax reduction on presentation of proof of insurance purchase. A key assumption is that an influx of new buyers will improve the functioning of private insurance markets substantially, especially individual markets. In addition, in Phase I, very-low-income households will become eligible for publicly provided or contracted comprehensive insurance, with no premium share required. People with incomes above the median (with a few exceptions for high risks and, possibly, those with incomes near the threshold) will not be eligible for the new program initially, but may con ti nue to use the new individual insurance plans, and may retain the tax exclusion for group coverage. The most important behavior to monitor in planning adjustments for Phase II is that of the emerging private insurance markets, both individual and group other than employment. If these markets are functioning reasonably well, the contribution toward insurance for very-low-income households will be converted in Phase II into a voucher or credit that these households also can use for private insurance, with coverage similar to that of the Medicaidtype plan. If many of the uninsured with incomes above the median also use the new private market,it should be possible to implement a mandate requiring the remaining tiny minority to buy some coverage,and to cap the value of the exclusion,thus turning the exclusion into an adjustment of the income tax base for almost everyone. Finally, the coverage that can be obtained with the credit or coupon alone to buy a “low-priced” plan will be examined to determine if there are any substantial health benefits to lower-middle-income people from adding coverage (at added budget cost). If such benefits do exist, stricter minimum standards and financing to pay their additional cost would be added in Phase II. There are two novel features in this plan. First, using coupons as a vehicle for credits should improve the take-up rate greatly. Coupons are attractive, solve cash flow problems, and are easy to administer. Second, permission to use the credit for insurance plans with premiums no greater than the credit ensures that virtually everyone in the target group will end up with at least some coverage. There will be universal coverage for everyone, though not for all expenses; non-poor people should be allowed to use cost sharing. Public financial constraints and efficient cost containment mean that such coverage will not fully cover all medical services. There will, however, be some public subsidy for insurance for people who currently receive no subsidy toward any insurance. To deal with valuation in risk across households 139 These new credit vouchers or coupons should be thought of as tax reductions for the lower middle class and, thus, treated as tax reductions for all who use them. and over time, all policies will be guaranteed to be renewable (at premiums that are no higher than those charged to average risks). In addition, plans requiring no additional premiums must be rated on an adjusted community rating basis, but premiums for coverage beyond this level may be risk rated if insurers wish to do so. A high-risk pool is an option in Phase II if many high-risk individuals are still paying very high prem iu m s , but this outcome is unlikely (for reasons discussed below). The public alternative plan(s) will be regulated, rated, and subsidized on the same basis as private insurance.States may continue to regulate individual insurance, and may add additional subsidies to the credit (in various ways), but the states will be responsible if regulation results in fewer people being uninsured than expected. Objectives, Assumptions, and Rationale To design a system that adapts to different outcomes, we need to set priorities among these different outcomes. The two most important of these are fairness and efficiency. The problems associated with these are: everyone is for fairness but defines it differently, and there is only one definition of efficiency but not everyone is for it. An efficient outcome is one that matches consumers with the insurance policy they prefer (given the subsidy) and whose costs and premiums are minimized. With respect to the effect of the subsidies, the objectives and goals of the providers of those subsidies—taxpayers—are important. One would usually include as social objectives improved health status, control of infectious diseases, and l on ger life expectancy, but goals dealing with the dignity, privacy, convenience, and satisfaction with care and coverage may also matter. We assume that the key to efficiency is to offer neutral incentives to both low- and middle-income people for choosing among insurance plans, and to offer targeted subsidies for those poor enough to need help. A fair outcome is one in which people who are similar in income and health status are treated the same, but the amount lower-income families must spend on care and insurance should be limited. How limited, and how low is “low-income,” are political decisions. We do not enshrine or condemn particular ways of providing insurance or even particular types of insurance (as long as they do not lead to worse health outcomes). Specifically, there is no intrinsic merit to employment-based group insurance or insurance provided by the government, non-profit firms, or for-profit firms, and no intrinsic flaw in HMO coverage or in rationing care (which logically must occur) by one means over another. We want to outline a tax credit proposal for the uninsured that uses private market arrangements as much as possible. In other words, we give private markets the benefit of the doubt. The strongest benefit from private markets is their ability to satisfy consumers with varying desires. If everyone wants the same amount of some product or activity, government provision can work reasonably well; the “public good,” in which all must consume the same qu a n ti ty, provides the classic example. Health insurance is not a “public good” that all must share equally. Rather, people differ in how much insurance they want,how they want their insurer to perform,and how much they value different aspects of plan performance. These differences in preferences apply both to the level of financial protection and to the degree to which physicianpatient decisions are constrained by insurers. In addition, these preferences are not entirely dictated by a family’s income; people at given income levels will still choose different covera ge . One key unknown is how much variation there is in private demands. 140 The production efficiency benefits that competitive markets can furnish also matter. Even here we assume that the key issue is not so much current cost but rather the rate at which costs will grow over time, and that government provision or production can be as efficient as private-sector provision or production. For various reasons, not enough tax reduction can or will be made available to fully subsidize insurance that makes all care free at the point of service for everyone. There need to be limits, either on what fraction of the market price insurance covers or on the amount of services providers are permitted/encouraged to supply. We do not advocate such constraints, or the partial coverage they imply, but we do recognize reality. Related to these constraint and diversity issues, we posit that not all undesirable possible behaviors should be regulated. Put slightly differently, we assert that regulations forbidding things that almost no one ever does are not appropriate. One reason for not trying to prohibit everything undesirable that happens only occasionally is the cost of monitoring and administration and the desire for administrative simplicity; the other reason is that passing such regulations often opens new avenues for additional political influence, lobbying, and legal action. Coverage and Eligibility The proposed credit will be a fixed-dollar amount for persons with incomes at certain levels. (We tentatively suggest , for individuals and , for families.) The key design parameters that will need to be specified in a political process are the dollar amount of the credit, the definition of the income levels (and possibly other characteristics) that trigger eligibility, and what kinds of insurance are eligible for the credit. Some assumptions about plausible values for these parameters are made below, but the choice of their levels is ultimately a political one. One uncertainty, if we specify insurance coverage and eligibility, is how many of the eligible persons will apply for the credits, and, of those who obtain the credit, how many were formerly uninsured. Will many of the eligible uninsured pass up the credit? Will many of the insured claim the credit? Will there be some uninsured people who are not eligible for the credit? The other uncertainty is the performance of markets in which consumers use the credit. The individual and small-group markets will be most affected. We know that how markets behave is influenced by the demands, information, and tastes of buyers who use them, which implies that the influx of a large number of insurance buyers who are different in important ways from buyers already in these markets will virtually guarantee that the market will change. But how? Will insurers be more or less concerned about the risk level of new buyers? The Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act (HIPAA) now requires that individual and small-group insurers treat those already insured who become higher risk the same as all others they insure, so will the additional premium for this “guaranteed renewability” feature rise or fall? Will the Internet allow new produ ct s ,m ore choice, and lower premiums, or will it just add to the confusion? In the current private health insurance market, only relatively high-income people receive substantial tax subsidies. In current public insurance markets,especially Medicaid, the subsidy is so large that the net premium is zero or close to it. We have no experience with significant tax credits for lowermiddle-income families. This means that we cannot predict with any degree of accuracy how they will respond, and that no additional information is available to refine these estimates. With regard to insurance markets, most potential tax credit recipients are of approximately average risk and would have to use the individual or small-group markets to obtain covera ge , but we have no experience with the consequence for such markets of an influx of a large number of averagerisk buyers in those markets subsidized to pay moderately high premiums. In current markets potential customers are not willing to pay high premiums or, if they are,it is because they are unusually high-risk. Our approach here is to begin with the subset of the uninsured likely to be most in need of and responsive to the new credit. (If this policy is effective in prompting the previously uninsured to seek 141 TABLE 1 Segment Income as % Poverty Proportion of Uninsured % with Private or Employment-Based Insurance* Low Less than % % % Medium –% % % High Greater than % % % *Includes private individual insurance, private group insurance, and insurance furnished by state and federal governments to employees and dependents (including military). Source: Current Population Survey, March Supplement, available at bls.census.gov/cps/ads/adsmain.htm, 1999. coverage, we think that the presence of large numbers of new demanders will make it easier—and perhaps inevitable—to change the way in which insurance is produced and priced for everyone.) As shown in table , we divide (for a sample plan) the current population of uninsured Americans into three groups: low-income households with family incomes below percent of the poverty line (about percent of the uninsured); those with family incomes above percent of the poverty line (about percent),and those with family incomes between percent and percent of poverty (about percent of the uninsured). The last group will be the primary target of a creditbased intervention. We recommend that eligibility for fully subsidized, complete comprehensive coverage at a publicly chosen insurer (Medicaid, Children’s Health Insurance Program [CHIP], the insurance plan for state employees, or an insurance with the same coverage and policies as Medicare) be extended to all low-income households, regardless of whether they include children or able-bodied adults. All poor people would receive free comprehensive insurance. (These households will also be el i gi ble for the coupons described below, but we would expect few to use them.) Households with incomes between percent and percent of poverty (roughly median income) would receive a credit, but it would be large enough to cover only part of the premium for complete and comprehensive coverage. At the upper end of the distribution of el i gi bl e incomes, the voucher could be “phased down” (over a range from percent of poverty to percent of poverty) to equal the average value of the employment-based group insurance exclusion. For instance, for a typical family at percent of poverty with an employment-based policy with a premium of , and a percent marginal income tax rate combined with the payroll tax, the value of the exclusion would be ,; if the marginal income tax rate were percent,it would be ,. Therefore, phasing down the family voucher to a value of about , might be reasonable. The key group might be described as “lowermiddle income people” or “middle-income people below the median.” As we have defined the groups, this group contains the most uninsured people. However, about percent of people in this group are already insured, with private or employmentbased coverage; even at the low end of the range, most people obtain such insu ra n ce . That is, most people in this group are able to “afford” coverage, but some (for a variety of reasons) do not purchase it.1 More important, for reasons we describe below, this group’s characteristics suggest that it would be most affected by and would most benefit from a moderate but not complete insurance tax credit. 1 M. V. Pauly, and M. K. Bundorf. “Is Health Insurance Affordable for the Uninsured?” Working paper, Stanford University School of Medicine, November 2000. 142 Finally, while it is difficult (and awkward) to make distinctions here, one might argue that, relative to those with higher incom e s ,c redits will have a greater impact on the health of this population. This group is very heterogeneous with regard to almost all characteristics. Whether we look at the total lower-middle-income population or the subset of that population that is uninsured, there is substantial representation of all age groups under , all employment options, and all expense risk level s .O n e common characteristic that will be important is that more than percent of this population is in families with at least one worker; lower-middle-income families in America (whether insured or not) work for a living. But for other characteristics, there are variable (and offsetting) influences. For example,the uninsured are more likely, other things being equal (including age), to be in fair or poor health, but they are more likely than the insured to be young. The effect of lower average age offsets the effect of the greater likelihood of being in poor health, so, overall, their risk level is no higher than average. Most of the uninsured in this subpopulation (as in the overall set of uninsureds) have been privately insured before and have been uninsured for less than a year (although some are uninsured for a long time). Thus, this subpopulation has had access to and experi en ce with private insurance, and most would be expected to have access again.A potentially important implication of this typical orientation toward the private insurance market is that single publicly run insurance programs might not be best for (or strongly desired by) this group. If buyers will have to pay some part of the premium for a comprehensive policy (as they must), they may not want to be channeled into Medicaid, S-CHIP, or even a Medicare clone. Instead, we hypothesize that, other things being equal (including the depth of coverage and the premium the person must pay), most people in this subpopulation would opt for private insurance, and for a variety of plans, ranging from reasonably costly but permissive at one extreme, to high-deductible, low out-of-pocket limit, and down ri ght cheap at the other. This hypothesis, in tu rn , implies that more of these buyers would be more likely to be willing to be insured if the plan could be private (as well as public) than if it has to be public only. Some people in this population almost surely would prefer a public insurer offering a public plan: one chosen somehow in the political process and managed at some level by government employees. Others will prefer a private plan that they can stay with, even if their incomes rise or they get decent jobs. These considera ti ons direct us away from a strategy of extending Medicaid/CHIP-type plans up the income scale to the income range for this subpopulation of lower-middle-income persons, but push us toward making sure that one of the available plans is a public one. Thus, in our ideal arrangement a public plan of some type is an opti on , but not an obligation, and the “terms of trade” among all plans should be neutral and reflect only true cost and quality differences. This public insurer could offer a variety of plans, including the “low-cost” plan described below. Subsidies Credits toward purchasing qualified health insurance should be made available to all lower-middleincome, legal residents of the United States. In the ideal arrangement, one might prefer to vary the value of the credit with family income in a continuous fashion. However, in the interest of administrative simplicity and making the process of using the credit as easy as possible, we think it de s i ra ble to start with a single value for lower-middle-income families with a given number of dependents. As a rough rule o f thumb, we think the credit should be somewhere between half and two-thirds of the premium for a decent basic policy. Both the proportion of premium covered and the definition of a decent policy are subject to adjustment (although they are obviously related). Ro u gh ly speaking, one might assume that the average premium for a decent family coverage policy would be , to , per year; therefore, a credit averaging about , would fit the specifications; the analogous amount for a self-only policy would be about ,. Credits would be updated in proportion to the growth in actual premiums paid 143 in transactions. At the high end of the income range (say, between percent and percent of poverty), the credit might be phased down gradually to equal the average value of the exclusion. This phasedown could be accomplished by end-of-the-year adjustments in income taxes. However, the actual premiums that would be quoted in the individual market would vary with age. The self-only premium for people under age would be less than ,, for example, whereas that for someone age (even in reasonably good health) would be about ,. Should these effects of age be of fs et? There is no easy answer, nor are there hard data, for this question. A fixed-dollar (unadjusted) approach will pay for decent coverage for more people, but they will be young. A proportional approach, or some other method that increases the credit when the premium increases because of age, will provide better incentives for decent coverage for older people. However, evidence suggests that older people are willing to pay more for covera ge ; they have a clearer idea of their need for benefits, and they behave more responsibly. In contrast, younger people are most likely to be uninsured. The real issue here is precisely what is not known—how many people of which ages would buy coverage under different plans, and how many older people with difficulty in obtaining coverage would compensate us for covering a large number of young people? In the first phase,in the interest of simplicity, we propose a uniform credit, independent of age. We can then see what pattern of insurance purchasing emerges. If this program appears to be ineffective in affecting the coverage choices of middle-aged people,the credit could be age-adjusted to some extent. Doing so, however, would cause some potential conflicts with employment-based insurance, as we discuss below. Financing Financing for the tax reductions or credits for the lower-middle-income population ( percent to percent of poverty) will be accommodated by federal budget revenues. Those who purchase coverage more generous than the low-cost plan will use their own resources, either through direct payment of premiums or through indirect payment by employees as part of their total compensation in lieu of money wages. Financing for full coverage for those below percent of the poverty line will be provided by a combination of state and federal revenues, with existing levels of state payments for Medicaid and S-CHIP to be retained. These new credit vouchers or coupons should be thought of as tax reductions for the lower middle class and, thus, treated as tax reductions for all who use them. Since virtually all eligible persons should be expected to claim and use their credit coupons,it should be possible to estimate the gross value of the tax reduction fairly precisely. However, since use of the credit offsets the value of the tax exclusion, the net tax reduction will be somewhat more difficult to estimate, because it requires knowledge of the distribution of the value of the exclusion and, more important, because persons at the upper end of the income eligibility range who now benefit from the exclusions may or may not prefer to use the credit coupon rather than continuing to use the exclusion. Insurance and Risk The two most common ways in which private insurance is provided in the United States both have problems. The most dominant form, employmentbased group health insurance, suffers from lack of portability across jobs and lack of good matching between the types of plans employers or unions choose to offer and what each employee (or perhaps even most employees) really want. We know that workers are dissatisfied with employer-chosen managed care plans (and,to a much greater extent, when there is only one managed care offering), and we know that employers do not feel that they can take enough out of wages to pay for unrestricted indemnity insurance plans. The result is a compromise between offering restrictive inexpensive plans and more costly plans with “parachutes” in the form of point-of-service features or preferred provider organizations (PPOs) with very large provider networks.On the other hand,the non-group insurance market uses a much larger share of the prem iu m 144 dollar to cover administrative costs, and may make it difficult for some “non-average” risks to obtain coverage at premiums they find acceptable. Policy makers, therefore, tend to dislike both currently available vehicles for providing health insurance, and often imagine that there could be potential group-purchasing arrangements, rather than the job-based setting for individuals or small firms,that could offer a wide range of choices to voluntary participants and keep premiums low. At a minimum, many feel that the market in which credits may be used should be organized into some type of “quasigroup” setting and regulated to prevent risk rating. This hope may well not be realized, however, so we need to design a plan that does not depend on it. There are two reasons why individual plans are so expensive that reinforce each other. It is costly to offer a large variety of plans to one buyer at a time; the plan finally selected will be costly because it is custom-designed. But when the plan is costly for the benefits it provides, more effort has to be made to persuade people to buy it, so commissions are generous. There is a kind of catch- in that insurance is hard to sell because it is expensive, and then it becomes expensive because it is hard to sell. Currently about million people under age buy coverage in this customized and costly individual market. Ei gh teen million more people would receive credits and become potential customers in a reformed situation. If the credit is set on the generous side and a wide variety of policies at different costs are eligible, many of these buyers will be eager to obtain insurance. It is possible that the flow of large numbers of heavily subsidized demanders who are known to be average risks (or better) could help individual markets to function better. The subsidy itself should simplify one of the most difficult and costly tasks in the current individual market. Commissions (and some part of general administrative expense related to billing) are substantial, and they serve primarily to compensate agents and brokers for persuading people to buy insurance. (Since brokers typically offer plans from a variety of companies, they put little effort into selling one firm’s product rather than another’s). But with a significant subsidy, there should be much less need for an expensive sales effort. The credit or coupon only becomes valuable if it is used for insurance, so people will want to use it. There is evidence that when significant subsidies to purchase are offered, private administrative costs are reduced substantially. When Blue Cross of New Jersey was required to heavily subsidize individual coverage, administrative expenses were only percent of premiums. Private insurers in Chile sell to customers who receive credit for the payroll taxes they have already paid; even though the coverage has had upper limits until recently, the loading is still about percent.2 Not only might the creation of a mass of new demanders allow for lower administrative costs, it also might help provide direct help to avoid the other serious problem with individual insurance: difficulties in dealing with risk variation. If individual insurers do not charge higher premiums to higher-risk individuals, they will have to set (average) premiums so that insurance is too expensive for average-risk individuals compared with what it provides. A credit will greatly diminish this problem, for several reasons. As noted above, the lowermiddle-income uninsured are reasonably good risks, so the proportion of high risks in the pool of potential individual market buyers will greatly diminish. With fewer high risks to worry abo ut , firms would rationally put less effort into trying to identify high risks to charge them higher premiums. The benefit from identifying a high risk is the avoidance of high claims that only a small minority incurs. But if the proportion of such risks drops in half, say, the screening cost to identify one such risk doubles, which is bound to lead to less underwriting at the margin. Even though insurers know that the bulk of benefits will be paid to a few insured persons,if the proportion of such persons is few, it does not pay to incur underwriting expenses to discover who they are. Moreover, with a generous enough subsidy, many lower risks will still find insurance a good deal, and will stay in the pool rather than for2 C. Sapelli and A. Torche. “The Mandatory Health Insurance System in Chile: Explaining the Choice between Public and Private Insurance.” Submitted for publication, International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics (2000). 145 going coverage. The threshold level of new buyers that can alter insurer underwriting practices is not known. This vision of what the insurance market might look like obviously is not guaranteed to materialize. However, if we offer generous credits with only modest amounts of premium rating regulation, we will soon know whether enough good-risk buyers will enter the market to make it a reality. Of course, if we are right, even fairly strict premium regulation would not be constraining. If the behavior a regulation is designed to constrain is going to be rare anyway, why not play it safe and regulate it? The most obvious answer is that writing, monitoring, and reporting to comply with regulations have a cost of their own. So there are a number of regulatory options here, none of which is fully satisfactory. In Phase I we would propose a compromise strategy in which any low-cost plan must be sold under modified community rating, while plans with more generous coverage could charge higher premiums to those (given age, sex, and location) whom they identify as high risks. In all cases, insurers would be permitted to impose modest waiting periods for people who did not enroll during an initial “open season.” However, we think that this will be rare, because all persons would, at a minimum, be enrolled initially in a low-cost plan. An important reason why few high risks should need new coverage is that a kind of risk regulation already exists in federal law that helps to provide substantial protection to high risks. This is the requirement that all non-group insurance be sold with a guaranteed renewability provision (section . of HIPAA),in which the insurer must promise not to raise premiums selectively for those already insured who become high risk;in return,the initial premium to low risks is slightly higher than it would be otherwise. Over time, unless there is enormous turnover among insurance plans, this provision should result in almost all high risks paying average-risk premiums. Guaranteed renewability protects people against increases in premiums because of the onset of highrisk conditions. It does this by offering insurance that guarantees that a person’s premium will only increase at the same rate as the premiums of all who buy that insurance plan.Such a promise is financially feasible for insurers because they charge what is, in effect, a “two part” premium—one part to pay for current-period expenses and the other to cover any above-average premium for those who began as average or low risks but became high risk. Both common sense and economic theory 3 suggest that a risk-averse low risk should prefer to stay with such a plan rather than switch to one in which the insurer has a reputation for increasing the insurance premium of people who become sick. For such a guaranteed renewability arrangement to work, however, people have to be willing to buy insurance, even when they are not high risk. If they choose to buy insurance only after they get sick, such behavior will prevent any insurer, regulated or not, from being able to cover its benefits costs with moderate premiums. For any voluntary market to work,there needs to be a penalty on low risks who try to stay uninsured until they get sick. If a credit makes insurance affordable for lower risks,there is no longer any justification for such irresponsible behavior, and penalizing those who wait to buy insu ra n ce until they become high risks before seeking insurance makes sense. A guaranteed renewability requirement should require minimal enforcement and, indeed, almost all individual policies contained this feature even before HIPAA required it. Nothing is completely without cost; guaranteed renewability will lock h i gh er risks into particular insurance companies, but that prospect should make prospective buyers more careful in the first place. The key point is that, with guaranteed renewability, all persons who keep buying health insurance will be protected against high premiums, even if they become high risks. Finally, since almost everyone can buy at least a low-cost policy at modified community rates, there should be few high-risk customers who were formerly uninsured. To the extent that the low-cost insurance already covers catastrophic expenses, the 3 M. V. Pauly, H. Kunreuther, and R. Hirth. “Guaranteed Renewability in Insurance.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 10 (1995): 143–56. 146 If credits or coupons are widely offered, it is reasonable to assume that profit-seeking insurers will try to sell their insurance to people who are receiving substantial subsidies to pay for it. Thus, our strategy is to rely on insurers to market insurance to their customers, rather than use government agencies to enroll clients. impact of risk differences on the cost of incremental coverage should be smaller. There would still be a modest reward for buying more comprehensive coverage with guaranteed renewability, however, in the form of no waiting period and, possibly, no higher premiums. Indeed, theoretical research suggests that a good way to deal with adverse selection is to combine a subsidized community-rated base policy with risk rated add-ons. Administration and Regulation The Role of Employers The great majority of people with private insurance in the United States obtain it in part because they receive a portion of their compensation in the form of tax-shielded health insurance premiums. That is, the employment contracts for most American workers entail a compulsory diversion of compensation to health insurance; the wage-benefits package includes a partially paid health insurance premium available to all workers. A worker who declines to use this employer-enforced contribution may be able to save the other part of the premium, labeled “employee share,” but the “employer” portion generally is not returned to individual workers who decline coverage. Employees and employers both prefer to arrange compensation for employees in this fashion because it is the only simple way to obtain a substantial reduction in the amount of employee income subject to income and payroll taxes, and because it tends to lower insurer administrative cost (though limiting plan choice). We propose that any tax credit, in contrast, not be limited to workers who choose this form of group insurance. In s te ad , all people at the target income levels would be eligible for the credit if they obtain insurance at least as costly as the credit. The credit would go to the newly insured who were formerly uninsured, those who obtained their insurance by spending their wages on non-group covera ge , those who divert part of their wages to group covera ge , and those who formerly chose employment-based coverage and now have some other method of arranging insurance. The size of and eligibility for the credit would depend only on whether the person obtained insurance,not on how he or she obtained it. In contrast to the current situation in which employment-based group insurance is subsidized, but other ways of obtaining insurance are not, incentives would be neutral. Therefore, credits would be available to those with “employer paid” insurance; neutrality would be achieved if credits were set equal to the difference between the value of the exclusion and the value of the credit (or, in the alternative, workers using the credit could simply report total employer premiums as taxable income). For those firms able to offer attractive plans at lower premiums than their employees would pay in the non-group market, we expect that employer provision would continue. There would be some potential shifting of workers out of the group market into the individual market, compensated by increases in money wages, especially for very small and poorly run groups. These workers indeed might be better off with individual insurance if it were not much more expensive than their (small) g roup coverage and offered them a va ri ety of plans that better matched their needs and were portable across jobs. A defined contribution strategy is another good way to implement such a transition. This change would make many lower-wage workers better off than they are now, either because they would obtain coverage for the first time or because they are able to choose the coverage they prefer. 147 Some fear that allowing insurance to have the same tax tre a tm ent in both group and non-group s et ti n gs would som eh ow “break the pool” in employment-based group insurance and harm higher-risk working families. We think that this is extremely unlikely. Employers would not be required to let workers (individually or collectively) out of the pool, so there would be no way for individual low-risk workers to impose costs on fellow workers. Moreover, the empirical evidence strongly suggests that the current reduction in money wages to pay for group insurance is greater for older workers and women, other things being equal. Younger workers who seek a relatively inexpensive individual policy would not expect (if their company dropped its coverage) to get back very much in money wages, so that individual insurance would not be a very good deal. Finally, the proportion of people in employmentbased group insurance who are truly high risk is quite low. The reason is simple: to get such insurance, someone in the household must be able to work. Among workers themselves, very few people have high-cost chronic conditions. There are highcost dependents, however, but the availability of public programs for the disabled also draws off most of the high risks. In effect, people in employment-based pools have already been pre-screened, and their premiums (in virtually all regulatory regimes) depend on the risk le vels of insured workers and their dependents, not on the average risk level in the population or even the average risk level among all workers and their dependents. This pre-screening helps to keep down the possibility of adverse selection, so there is some merit to linking insurance to the employment relationship for at least some workers (though not necessarily all). There are some other reasons to maintain a connection. Employers have an interest in seeing that workers do not miss work because of illness and,thus,disrupt the production process; for workers who are key members of production teams, lost output can be substantial. Much of the long-term incidence of improved productivity through reduced absenteeism and greater “presenteeism” (higher productivity on the job) will be transformed into higher worker wages. The payroll mechanism may be a good vehicle for ensuring regular deductions from salary to pay premiums, and starting a new job may be a good time for people to think about adding insurance benefits. But the best way to decide whether these advantages of fs et the disadvantages of letting the employer select and manage the worker’s insurance is to let workers make neutral choices. Marketing Subsidized Insurance One of the ch a ll en ges to government-managed insurance plans such as Medicaid or S-CHIP is to get poor people who are eligible for subsidized coverage to enroll and accept their subsidies. Even now, nearly a third of those eligible for Medicaid fail to obtain it, and, after its recent “success,” S-CHIP picks up barely a third of the remaining uninsured children. This is unacceptable. Sometimes, one suspects, state governments with budget concerns might not be too worried about a low “take-up rate,” but even when efforts are made, the rate is often (though by no means always) low. It is the low takeup rate for such free insurance that causes some estimates of the impact of credits on coverage to be relatively low.4 If credits or coupons are widely offered, it is reasonable to assume that profit-seeking insurers will try to sell their insurance to people who are receiving substantial subsidies to pay for it. Thus,our strategy is to rely on insurers to market insurance to their customers, rather than use government agencies to enroll clients. The main problem that these agencies have faced is the difficulty of limiting enrollment to those eligible, while at the same time encouraging people to reveal the financial information needed to determine eligibility. To do so, they have felt it necessary to impose onerous burdens on potential eligibles, such as New York’s annual obligation to provide face-to-face evidence of income and family composition qualifications to a government official. Our strategy, even in this first phase, but more effectively in the next,is to achieve a high take-up rate by sepaJ. Gruber and L. Levitt. “Tax Subsidies for Health Insurance: Costs and Benefits.” Health Affairs 19 (1) (January-February 2000): 72–85. 4 148 rating the purchase of insurance from the process of establishing eligibility. To do this, we propose to provide potential clients with vouchers or certificates good for , or , off an insurance plan premium,and sending them (through the mail or some other device) to people with incomes close to what would make them eligible. The certificate could be transferred to the insurer who provides coverage,along with any initial premium,and then redeemed by the insurer for its face value after a period of con ti nuous covera ge . However, the certificate would be coded with the person’s Social Security or other taxpayer identification number, and anyone who used the certificate but was ineligible to do so (because family income was too high) would have to make up the difference (and pay a penalty) on his or her income tax return. This device also would provide a convenient way to subsidize people who are eligible for part of the year, and it would provide a way to obtain insurance that would not require the lower-middle-income buyer to advance the full premium before seeking reimbursement. Lower-income families (below percent of poverty), technically eligible for free publicly managed insurance, also would be permitted to use the certificates if they preferred private insurance to Medicaid or S-CHIP. For people with no “employer-paid” coverage, the credit coupon could simply be tu rn ed over to the insurer, which would then redeem it with the government. For those whose employers paid for premiums as part of compensation, eligible employees could attach the coupon to their tax returns,and calculate the net credit as the difference between the value of the credit and taxes on the employer payment. While precise details depend on parameter values, these ad ju s tm ents also would permit the value of the credit to equal the value of the exclusion for incomes near or slightly above the upper limit. Initial distribution of the coupon could be done in several ways. Coupons could simply be mailed to those indicating a low expected wage on their tax withholding (W-) form. These also could be available at post offices or other convenient sites. Insurers could furnish coupons,as well. The coupon would clearly state who is eligible to use it, and impose end-of-year tax penalties on those who are ineligible. If Publishers Clearinghouse can reach nearly everyone,there must be a program that could work for health insurance. Finally, those taxpayers with incomes in the range at which they are eligible for the credit, who nevertheless fail to redeem their credit, could be enrolled automatically in a low-cost insurance plan with a premium no greater than the credit. Such a process will require a monitoring mechanism. Benefits An important design issue concerns specifying the policy for which the credit may be used. Defining “minimum benefits” is always politically troublesome, because every supplier of medical services will lobby to have generous coverage of its services included. But requiring that everything be covered means that the premium will be very high—higher than any feasible credit, higher than many persons are willing to pay, and higher than taxpayers are willing to subsidize. A solution to this problem would be to have a fairly inclusive definition of covered services, but permit policies to hold down premiums through deductibles, coinsurance, and upper limits. That is, at least initially, any policy that would qualify for the credit would have to pay for all medical and surgical services and all prescription drugs and medical devices, based on some commonly accepted definition of what constitutes standard (non-experimental) care. However, cost sharing could be imposed, as could managed care rules and incentives for providers. The definition (for medical and surgical services) used for the traditional Medicare plan probably could be used here, but, even if some of the services not typically covered were included in the definition of covered services, the presence of cost sharing would limit the extent to which they would be used as well as their additional cost. Citizens could be free to choose, at additional cost, plans that cover these services with lower levels of patient cost sharing. In effect, we tell people that they may use their individual , credit to pay for any policy covering a set of medical and surgical 149 goods and services that has a premium of , or more. However, one can be certain that, unless the credit is as large as the premium for a generous insurance plan, some people will not be willing to make additional payments to buy some specific generous plans, but will choose either no insurance or a partial-coverage plan inste ad . Different analysts (and different citizens) have different views on how much coverage they think a family at some income level ought to have. There is a trade-off here. We could put stricter bounds on qualified covera ge , making such coverage more adequate. But the credit would not cover the full premium, and then some people would refuse the credit, preferring to remain uninsured rather than pay an additional premium. In line with our primary objective of covering the uninsured, we think that,at first,there should be virtually no rules about cost sharing. The only rule would be that the policy provide dollar benefits appropriate to its premium. Rather than attempt the surely difficult and probably impossible task of specifying the appropriate levels of cost sharing for every credit recipient, we propose to begin by letting the credit recipients themselves decide what kind of coverage they prefer. Once we know the pattern of coverage, and can check to see what effect it has on access to care and health levels, we can judge whether stricter regulation of the package is needed. We start in an unrestricted way (and try to stay with light restrictions) because we think that the highest-priority objective ought to be to get at least some health insurance coverage to every American who is not high-income, even if the level of coverage cannot be adjusted (or financed) to be what some regard as perfect in the initial round. We postulate that the law of diminishing returns holds here as everywhere else: the first infusion of coverage will do the most good, and the benefit of latter additions, though probably positive, will be smaller. The way to get almost everyone to buy coverage in response to a credit is to permit people to use the credit as they like, with as much or as little of their own contribution as they prefer. It would be irrational for someone to refuse to use his or her credit on a (private or public) insurance policy that costs no more than the credit and provides at least some protection against what otherwise would be out-ofpocket payments the person would be forced to make and/or a policy that improves access to some types of care. Finally, if insurance did take the form of full coverage above a deductible, the RAND health insurance experiment reassures us that cost sharing will not have substantial adverse effects on most measures of health status for the non-poor. In the experiment, the only adverse health outcome (beyond some minor effects on vision correction and oral health) was for people initially at high risk for hypertension. For the majority at normal risk and for other high-risk conditions, cost sharing does not appear to harm health, as long as there is catastrophic coverage.5 Fit with the Current System The Role of States States would have the primary role in administering the Medicaid-like coverage for poor adults. The bulk of the additional cost for this coverage would be provided by the federal government. States would be permitted to regulate the extent to which premiums for coverage in excess of the lowcost policy vary with risk, but would be penalized if this regulation caused people to remain uninsured or caused disproportionate numbers to choose minimal-coverage (low-cost) policies. Finally, states could provide payments for people with very high costs or chronic illness. Doing so would mean that the low-cost coverage in such states could have a smaller deductible or less-constraining upper limits. What Improved Private Insurance Markets Might Look Like (and How We Can Get There from Here) It seems eminently plausible that the influx of large numbers of lower-middle-income workers and their families into non-group insurance markets would 5 J. P. Newhouse. Free for All?: Lessons from the RAND Health Insurance Experiment. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1993. 150 change those markets. We have offered some optimistic views of how they might change, but the truth is that no one knows for sure what might happen. The usual response of policy designers or policy makers is to abhor uncertainty (as definitely worse than a vacuum) and, therefore, to design many rules and some incentives to configure the outcome. For reasons stated earlier, we are skeptical of such efforts, not only because there really are no experts who know what outcomes will be produced by what rules, but also more generally because we think it important to give the widest scope to possible innova ti on s . This said, we do think that some probable contours of a new market may be worthwhile to forecast and even to contemplate encouraging (or at least not deterring). The most common reaction to proposals that employees be armed with credits that they can use for different insurance from that which their employers provide (if the employers provide any at all) is to begin to imagine the design of a new and improved type of group insurance, with many choices (all good), well administered. We do not share this vision of a single tidy market for all. We remain skeptical that such quasi-groups generally can achieve anything like the administrative savings now obtained by large groups with compulsory participants. We think there ought to be a “HealthMart” option, but that we ought to think of (and permit or foster) other alternatives. The key to considering alternatives is to note that there must be trade-offs: a scheme can offer a limited set of choices priced in a transparent fashion, but that scheme surely will have a cost in terms of the scope of options (especially new options) offered and, probably, in terms of administrative cost. Another unrealistic view is to imagine that the Internet alone can cut administrative cost and expand choice without being bedeviled by adverse selection and mass confusion (not to mention an inability to generate revenues). Our proposal in this case is to impose a modest amount of voluntary standardization on plans and plan types, and then allow the market itself to sort out how they should be offered. The standardization would allow plans to be designated as meeting certain model types, to facilitate shopping and compar- ison, but a plan could be non-standard as long as buyers were clearly warned about its type. “Site” or program sponsors could offer assurances or guarantees about the plans they list, but they would then be responsible for the performance of the plans they list. Conversely, an eBay of health insurance could list all legitimate offers cheaply, but make no representation about their quality beyond what is embodied in state regulations. The public sector would have a role in making information about insurance purchasing and plans available to potential consumers. Information about quality and price is in the nature of a public good, and would not be supplied adequately or in an unbiased fashion in a private market (although development of helpful and accurate guides for federal employees suggests that the same thing could happen for million new insu ra n ce customers). Subsidizing the production and distribution of such information would be a good role for government; one vehicle would be to distribute publicly financed vouchers that could be redeemed toward purchasing the buyers’ guide of one’s choice. Monitoring, Adapting, and Phase II We recognize that the Phase I plan we have suggested will not achieve universal comprehensive covera ge , nor will it necessarily perfect how insurance markets function. That is why we envision a formal monitoring process and a plan to bring the other two groups in the population—people below percent of poverty and people above percent— into the system in a second phase. What would be the best way to monitor this system’s performance? Possibilities might include the fo ll owing: State insurance or health departments (which often regulate health insurance anyway) might be one expert entity. Or there might be a federal advisory commission, as there has been for Medicare. It would be desirable to offer incentives to any oversight body to make the process work. For example,states might be rewarded if the number of uninsured in their state in the target income category fell more than expected,and they might be penalized in some fashion if the number fell short, espe- 151 cially if the shortfall could be attributed to state regulation of rating or costly mandated coverage provisions in the individual or small-group markets. States also might be given the task of monitoring the effect of credit-subsidized insurance on health status. In addition, they should determine whether the partial coverage plans affordable with the credit amount alone adversely affect health status more than plans with more generous covera ge . State health departments already exist, and it is likely that effects vary by state. The key point here is that monitoring should focus on changes in use of services and, ideally, on changes in health outcomes. In the state-monitored scheme, for example, if a state were able to encour age the use of more services that are effective for health, we would not be especially concerned about the distribution of people who switch from being uninsured to insured. Because the availability of credit certificates increases the competitiveness of firms not offering group insurance in the labor market, those firms that did offer some coverage would be motivated to manage it more effectively to continue to be competitive, and these changes might help health outcomes substantially. Attention also might be given to other consumer goals, such as financial stability and relief of anxiety. The specific issues to be monitored most closely are the two major policy uncertainties: how many people of what type will take the credit,and how the group market based on groups other than employment will be transformed. If substantial numbers of large firms dropped group covera ge , or if small firms with high-risk workers did so, that would indicate that something is wrong. (Remember: the fallback insurer is always available for a person at any risk level, and the low-cost coverage has adjusted community-rated premiums.) Enhancement of a high-risk pool would be the p roper response to any evidence of increased risk segmentation. If credits were not claimed in adequate numbers, that would imply that the value of the credits was too small compared with the premium for a good policy. The supply, purchase, and form of any “zero-premium” partial-coverage policies should be monitored, as well. Quality: What Would a Good (but Imperfect) Low-Cost Plan Look Like? One of the most controversial aspects of our plan is its acceptance that people may use a moderate-size credit to buy a less than comprehensive policy whose premium is close to the credit. It is easy to argue that this is bad idea if one assumes that people will make poor choices in the plans they choose, or if one believes that nothing less than full coverage will do. (To achieve “first best” optimal covera ge , either a mandate or a lavish public budget would be necessary. While we favor a mandate in a politically unconstrained world,6 in this paper we assume that mandates are not feasible.) At one extreme, the previously uninsured person could buy a policy with full coverage above a substantial deductible. While, according to insurance theory, this makes perfect sense in an otherwise perfect world, in reality it is likely to be unattractive to some lower-middleincome people because they would expect much of the benefit to substitute for charity care they might have received for free if they contracted a serious illness (and were able to obtain care without insurance coverage). On the other hand, a first-dollar policy with a very low upper limit would not be especially attractive either (although it would be better than nothing and would appeal to those consumers, fervently believed by politicians to exist, who only want insurance if they can be assured of collecting some money from it). The best cost-sharing pattern might be one with a moderate but not trivial deductible (say, ), and as high an upper limit as the credit will buy. Our own analyses suggest that, for the average worker, the upper limit might be on the order of , to , per year.7 Illnesses costing more than , could be covered by public insurance for the chronically ill, if states chose to do so. The fallback insurer could assist people who do not understand which low-cost coverage is best. M. V. Pauly, P. Danzon, P. J. Feldstein, and J. Hoff. Responsible National Health Insurance. Washington: AEI Press, 1992. 6 7 M. V. Pauly and B. Herring. “Expanding Insurance Coverage through Tax Credits: Tradeoffs and Options.” Health Affairs 20 (1) (JanuaryFebruary 2001): 1–18. 152 The other strategy this insurance might follow is aggressive use of closed panels and managed care, but with the option of going “out of plan” with outof-pocket payments. Given the oversupply of physicians in the United States and the wide range of hospital costs, an effective discount network might be established to fit within or close to the total value of the credit. However, we strongly suspect that, once a person signs up for a frugal plan, the experience of high out-of-pocket payment or strict rationing will prompt that person to put a moderate amount of his or her own money on the line and buy the next step up in insurance policies in the future. There is no doubt, however, that the mar ket for low-cost plans would be stimulated. Phase II Administrative Changes Now suppose that a new and improved type of nongroup health insurance market does em er ge , and that credits substantially reduce the number of uninsured. The next step is to allow those with incomes below percent of poverty to use such private insurers. This would be relatively easy to do; we only need to permit poor people currently using the public fallback insurer to use the same money to buy private insurance that non-poor people do. That is, the comprehensive Medicaid-like coverage already being provided to the poor would be converted into a premium support system, with expenditures converted into vouchers usable for private alternatives. The other change is that it should be possible to abolish, or at least radically transform,the safety net system. This system is intended to help people who “fall through the cracks” through no fault of their own. If credits for full coverage are offered to people with low incomes,and if lower-middle-income people receive credits large enough to allow them to afford insurance,there should be very few who qualify for the safety net system (perhaps only non-regis- tered aliens and people who become ill in the midst of a transition from one plan to another). One might convert payment for the services provided by public hospitals and clinics into a pre-paid plan, and allow people to sign up for this type of insurance. What of the people with incomes above percent of poverty? If a properly functioning private insurance system em er ge s , we think it might be a good idea to mandate that they buy covera ge . The simplest way of doing this would be to levy a tax surcharge equal to the premium for the fallback coverage on people with incomes above the median who are not insured. This system could be put in place easily, and it would affect only a tiny minority of the population who could hardly claim to be financially strained to pay the tax. Mandating coverage for lower-middle-income people (as already noted) will prove to be a more serious problem, and we do not advocate it now. The tax exclusion could be extended at a capped level to all high-income people (that is, to the small minority who currently buy nongroup coverage, possibly as part of a tax law change capping the value of the exclusion for all). Conclusion This proposal suggests addressing the lower-middle-income uninsured first with a system of generous tax credits to purchase insurance of their choice in a lightly regulated competitive market. If the good outcome that is possible does emerge,then the poor, near-poor, and the well-off could be invited to join this system, with substantial subsidies for the poor and substantial good wishes for the well-off. If the plan does not work, we could hardly be worse off for trying. We will have settled the controversy over what kind of markets private insurers can expect to offer, and what kinds of roles private insurers should be expected to play in helping to deal with the uninsured. n 153 Singer, Garber, and Enthoven Proposal Key Elements Sara J. Singer, Alan M. Garber, and Alain C. Enthoven have designed a comprehensive, new approach for expanding access to health insurance. The proposal is built on the following key elements: near-universal coverage by making private plans more affordable and helping low- and middle-income people buy coverage. This would be accomplished though tax credits and by creating “insurance exchanges” that would provide health insurance choices and promote competition among health plans. by public or private entities or employers (for their own employees). Exchanges would offer individuals a choice of at least two health plans in every geographic region at community-rated premiums. The “U.S. Insurance Exchange” would be established to serve individuals and companies with fewer than employees in areas where private exchanges do not emerge. Coverage purchased through exchanges would be exempt from state small-group reform laws and insurance mandates. - - who purchase insurance through an exchange would receive refundable tax credits valued at percent of the median-cost plan. The credits would apply only for coverage purchased through the exchanges. Eligible low-income individuals who did not enroll in a health plan would be automatically enrolled in a federally funded default plan organized by the state. Other individuals would continue to exclude from taxable income their individual or employer-paid health insurance contributions, but a phased-in cap would limit this exclusion. “ ” would be created. It would be similar to the Securities and Exchange Commission—having authority to distribute tax credits and default payments, accredit insurance exchanges, risk-adjust premiums across insurance exchanges, and serve as an information clearinghouse for consumers. 154 About the Authors . , ..., is Executive Director of Stanford University’s Center for Health Policy and a Senior Research Scholar at Stanford’s Institute for International Studies. She is program director for the Center for Demography and Economics of Health and Aging, project director for the “Project on Global Healthcare Productivity,” “Developing Best Practices for Patient Safety,” and “Managed Care and Health Care Markets,” and she was lead investigator for “Decreasing Variation in Medical Necessity Decision-Making.” Ms. Singer is also a member of Stanford’s University Committee on Faculty and Staff Benefits. In , Ms. Singer served as staff director of the California Governor’s Managed Health Care Improvement Task Force. She developed legislative strategy for moderate Democrats on the Ways and Means Committee during the committee’s debate of the Health Security Act of . In , Ms. Singer was a health policy analyst in the Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget. She holds an A.B. degree from Princeton University and an M.B.A. degree with a Certificate in Public Management from Stanford University. . , .., .., is the Henry J. Kaiser, Jr. Professor and Professor of Medicine at Stanford University, where he is also Professor of Economics, Professor of Health Research and Policy, and Professor of Economics in the Graduate School of Business (courtesy). He is the founding director of both the university’s Center for Health Policy and the Center for Primary Care and Outcomes Research at the School of Medicine. He is a Staff Physician at the Veterans Affairs Palo Alto Health Care System and Director, Health Care Program, of the National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. (NBER). He serves as Chair of the Medical and Surgical Procedures Panel of the Medicare Coverage Advisory Committee and is a member of the national Blue Cross and Blue Shield Association’s Medical Advisory Panel, the American Society for Clinical Investigation, and the Institute of Medicine of the National Academy of Sciences. A summa cum laude graduate of Harvard College, he received his Ph.D. in economics from Harvard and an M.D. with research honors from Stanford. His research is directed toward methods for improving health care delivery and financing, particularly for the elderly, in settings of limited resources. . , .., is a Senior Fellow, Center for Health Policy, Institute for International Studies, and the Marriner S. Eccles Professor of Public and Private Management, Emeritus, in the Graduate School of Business at Stanford University. He holds degrees in Economics from Stanford, Oxford and MIT. He has been an Economist with the RAND Corporation, Assistant Secretary of Defense, and President of Litton Medical Products. In , he received the President’s Award for Distinguished Federal Civilian Service from John F. Kennedy. He is a member of the Institute of Medicine of the National Academy of Sciences and a fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences. He is a consultant to Kaiser Permanente, the former Chairman of the Health Benefits Advisory Council for CalPERS, and former Chairman of Stanford’s University Committee on Faculty and Staff Benefits. He has been a director of the Jackson Hole Group and PCS. He was the winner of the Baxter Prize for Health Services Research and the Board of Directors Award, Healthcare Financial Management Association. His latest book, published in , is In Pursuit of an Improving National Health Service. 155 Near-Universal Coverage Through Health Plan Competition An Insurance Exchange Approach by Sara J. Singer, Alan M. Garber, and Alain C. Enthoven Overview We propose to expand access to private health insurance among the non-elderly population ineligible for Medicare. Our plan will accomplish this goal by making private plans more affordable for low- and middle-income households and by promoting competition to increase the value of insurance offerings. The proposed approach will promote the collection and dissemination of information on the quality of health plans and their providers. The plan promotes higher-value health insurance coverage by exposing consumers to price differences and better information about plan quality. Although the plan can accom m od a te Medicare beneficiaries with little structural modification, we do not propose to replace Medicare during the plan’s initial implementation. Beneficiaries currently enrolled in Medicaid, State Children’s Health In su ra n ce Programs (S-CHIPs), or other government programs could remain in these programs, but could choose instead to enroll in private plans. The plan also provides new funding and incentives for states to improve access to basic health services for the uninsured,and to improve insurance coverage rates. The plan does not impose new mandates on employers to pay for coverage. The proposed plan has these key elements: • Insurance exchanges are public or private entities, including certified employers, that serve as the vehicle through which most individuals acquire health insurance. They offer individual choice of a minimum of two different health plans on a guaranteed-issue and community-rated basis, with incentives to choose high-value plans. At least one insurance exchange generally is available in each geographic region. Exchanges help make coverage affordable by being large enough to achieve economies of scale in brokering plans and in providing information to enable people to make choices among plans. The principal incentives to support establishment of insurance exchanges are () new tax credits for low- and middle-income households that could be used only for coverage purchased through a qualified insurance exchange, () preemption from state insurance mandates (that is, Employee Retirement Income Security Act of [ERISA] protection), and () protection from the effects of adverse selection for exchanges and participating health plans. • U.S. In su ra n ce Exchange (USIX), a national program parallel to the Federal Em pl oyees Health Benefits Program (FEHBP), will serve as an insurance exchange for individuals and firms with fewer than employees, in areas in which no private health insurance exchange has emerged. • Subsidies in the form of refundable tax credits for health insurance will be available for low- and middle-income Americans who purchase qualifying health insurance plans. In contrast to families in higher tax brackets, such households today have limited financial incentives to purchase private health insurance plans. • New financing for “default plans” and basic health care services will be provided for low-income individuals who are eligible for the refundable tax credit, but who do not choose to enroll in a health plan. Each state will receive new grants to provide a default plan in each geographic area within its jurisdiction; people who do not choose their own health 156 plan will be enrolled automatically in the default plan. Many states will provide new financing for public hospitals, clinics, and other providers that meet open-access standards, as part of their default plan.Each state would receive a payment equal to percent of the new tax credits for individuals who are eligible for such credits but who remain uninsured.States will receive incentive bonuses or reductions based on the extent to which they improve performance of a set of preventive care measu re s (for example, childhood vaccinations, firsttrimester pregnancy visits, hypertension control) and reduce the percentage of the population that remains uninsured. The goal is to ensure that every eligible individual is enrolled in a health plan. • There would be a phased-in cap on the currently unlimited health insurance exclusion from taxable income for health insurance benefits paid by employers or individuals. Individuals eligible for both the exclusion and the subsidy could choose which of the two tax benefits to use.The dollar value of the cap would be set high enough to represent a substantial subsidy, yet low enough to provide substantial new financing for expanding health insurance coverage and other uses. • A new, independent Insurance Exchange Commission (IEC) with narrow, specific powers would be created to accredit insurance exchanges, conduct risk adjustment across insurance exchanges, and serve as a clearinghouse for public information on the quality of health plans. This agency would have an appointment procedure and organizational structure similar to that of the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), and would have a similar function—to encourage smooth information flow and functioning of insurance exchange markets. No single component of this proposal is likely to achieve near-universal health insurance by itself. Effective cost containment is essential to the expansion of health insurance in the long term, which otherwise would require prohibitively costly subsidies. Moreover, tax credits will be ineffective if beneficiaries cannot use the credits to obtain coverage. Thus they need access to competitive ,h i gh - va lue health insurance plans with guaranteed issue (that is, the requirement to offer health insurance, regardless of the applicant’s medical history). For these reasons, we propose to implement a coordinated policy of targeted subsidies, consumer choice, and incentives to offer and choose high-value health care coverage. A summary o f the proposed subsidies and associated requirements follows (see next page). Coverage/Eligibility: Establishing Insurance Exchanges to Expand Plan Choice Central to the proposal is individual choice of subsidized plans through insurance exchanges. Ideally, almost everyone would be covered through insurance exchanges large enough to achieve economies of scale in brokering plans and capable of providing information about plans to individuals and businesses. Like the FEHBP, the California Public Employees Retirement System (CalPERS), and a number of recently formed private purchasing groups that serve employers, the insurance exchanges would offer a ch oi ce among multiple plans, with incentives for individuals to choose highvalue ones. Advantages of such insurance exchanges include: • The exchanges would provide reasonably priced coverage for the self-employed, n on - poor unemployed, people between jobs, and employees who currently lack access to affordable,high-quality health insurance. • Insurance exchanges would facilitate continuity of plan covera ge . Exchanges are likely to offer many of the health plans operating in an area, so that most people could keep their health plan membership when they change jobs. • The exchanges would serve as an entry point for low-income, uninsured individuals, who would become eligible for substantial new subsidies to purchase coverage. • The exchanges would miti ga te many of the market imperfections that plague the small-group market (for example,through risk pooling, community rating, guaranteed issue, and competi ti on ) , making it easier for small employers to offer a choice of plans. 157 S U M M A RY OF PROPOSED SUBSIDIES AND REQUIREMENTS Eligibility Category Proposed Subsidy Requirements Medicare beneficiaries Medicare No alternative proposed Medicaid and S-CHIP eligibles Medicaid and S-CHIP, respectively, or full refundable tax credit If refundable tax credit is chosen, forgo Medicaid and S-CHIP benefits and must purchase through an insurance exchange Low-income individuals up to , and families up to , Full refundable tax credit equal to percent of median-cost plan Must choose between the tax credit and the capped exclusion; if tax credit is chosen, must purchase through an insurance exchange Low-income individuals up to , and families up to , who do not enroll percent of the full refundable tax credit, paid to state Automatic enrollment in default plan Middle-income individuals up to , and families up to , Partial refundable tax credit, phased out to Must choose between the partial tax credit and the capped exclusion; if tax credit is chosen, must purchase through an insurance exchange Individuals not eligible for the refundable tax credit Capped exclusion NA Federal, s t a te , and private group-purchasing arrangements operate in many markets today, with varying success. Insurance exchanges will share some fe a tu res with these organizations, but will improve on existing arrangements in several important ways. The most important problems associated with existing group-purchasing arrangements include the inability to gain market share and achieve administrative savings; adverse selecti on , either as a natural feature of plan competition or as a result of regulatory and legal constraints; and resistance to or opposition from health plans and insurance brokers.1 From the individual’s perspective, the exchanges offer far more choice than typically would be available today. In contrast to the current system, when individuals enroll in an HMO through an exchange, Elliot Wicks, Mark Hall, and Jack Meyer. “Barriers to Small-Group Purchasing Cooperatives.” Washington: Economic and Social Research Institute, March 2000. 1 it would be because they chose to enroll voluntarily, rather than because they lacked an alternative insurance option. Furthermore, choices would be determined by value as perceived by the consumer, since the consumer who chooses a plan with a higher premium than the low-priced plan will pay for the added cost of the choice.Good information, such as our proposal would generate, is critical to the operation of the exchanges; people are more likely to be satisfied with their choices if they know what they are getting. A key challenge will be the formation and growth of the exchanges. Our proposal inclu de s substantial incentives to promote private insurance exchanges. • People are el i gi ble for the substantial new refundable tax credits for low-income individuals only if they purchase health insurance through certified insurance exchanges. • Health plans offered through an insurance exchange are exempt from state small-group market 158 reforms and laws mandating health plan benefits for enrollees (that is, ERISA preemptions). These preemptions are necessary to allow insurance exchanges to form and operate across state lines, to enable insurance exchanges to become a competitive option for employers who now self-insure, and to give employees of small firms and the selfemployed access to flexible insurance plans that are currently available to employees of many large firms. • Exchanges and health plans participating in insurance exchanges are protected from adverse selection (see “Insurance, Risk Selection, and Risk Adjustment” below). Insurance exchanges could be private or public, for-profit or non-profit organizations, electronic or traditional. Large and mid-size employers also could be designated as insurance exchanges serving employees of the firm. The IEC will certify that insurance exchanges meet minimum standards for eligibility for tax credits and ERISA preemption. Exchanges would be certified through annual filings with the IEC, which would be empowered to deny or withdraw certification for exchanges that failed to meet these requirements. Certified insurance exchanges will be required to meet the fo ll owing basic requirements: • Non-employer exchanges must accept all individuals not eligible for Medicare and groups in their service area (guaranteed issue) at a flat premium rate (community rating), with adjustments only for covering additional people, such as a spouse or dependents. Beyond these requirements, non-employer exchanges would have flexibility in formulating eligibility rules (that is, employer size maximum) and underwriting policies (for example, waiting periods and open en ro ll m ent practices for individuals). Employers can also qualify as exchanges if they accept all employees, except part-time workers, at a flat premium rate. • Exchanges must offer a “meaningful choice” of plans, defined as the offer of a minimum of two products from a minimum of two independent companies,2 though considerably more ch oi ce s would be desirable, including point-of-service (POS) or preferred provider organization (PPO) products as well as closed-panel health maintenance organizations (HMOs) and newer alternatives such as defined-contribution “care groups.” Such offers must include at least one product that provi de s some coverage for treatment by most providers in a region (for example, a POS-type plan), and a lowpriced alternative (perhaps with more restrictive choices or catastrophic coverage). • Exchanges must require participating plans to offer some standardized basic benefits to facilitate plan comparison and discourage plans from segm en ting markets by health risk. However, plans would be allowed to offer enhancements to the basic features. • Exchanges must perform at least minimal risk adjustment (initial risk adjustment would be based on age) and/or rely on other mechanisms to limit the financial rewards to plans for engaging in practices that encourage risk selecti on , to preserve choice among plan types and create incentives for plans to enroll and care for high-cost patients. Exchanges also must participate in risk adjustment between insurance exchanges in a region or state. • Exchanges must require participating plans and providers to meet minimum standards for measuring quality. • Exchanges must make available comparative information on plan benefits, pricing, quality measurement, quality improvement initiatives,and other aspects of plan performance in an effort to help members make informed, high-value choices. Employers that would prefer not to fulfill these minimum requirements can choose not to become an insu ra n ce exchange. If they chose this option, they would continue to be regulated by ERISA, and they could not participate in the tax credit program. States would continue to regulate the non-insurance exchange market; most states have guaranteed issue and some rating requirements in the small-group market. For purposes of defining “companies” and “products,” exchanges that contract directly with provider groups would be counted as contracting with multiple companies, as long as a sufficiently large number of different risk-bearing provider groups in an area could be chosen. For example, Buyers Health Care Action Group’s (BHCAG’s) “care groups” would meet this definition. 2 159 Group-purchasing arrangements and many employers that provide health insurance today meet most of these requirements. Most offer a choice of plans and products and provide guaranteed issue to all participating employees. Many independent insurance brokers and/or consortiums of brokers could meet this requirement, as well. PacAdvantage, a small group-purchasing organization in California, performs risk adjustment, using demographic and administrative health data, to protect products and plans that attract high-risk individuals. Benefits Alliance, a group-purchasing organization for midsize employers in California, helps to en su re that health risks are spread evenly among participating plans by requiring that each plan offer both an HMO and an open-network produ ct . Many such groups offer comparative inform a ti on that is becoming more sophisticated as it migrates toward electronic forms. For example, California Consumer HealthScope, a web site by Pacific Business Group on Health, provides consumers with comparative quality information and the ability to search for information about physicians and the health plans through which they are accessible. HealthScope also provides comparative information about drugs available through health plan formularies. Our proposal includes incentives to en co u ra ge the growth of electronic insurance exchanges. Today, such exchanges offer electronic procurement, enrollment, administration (for example, eligibility verification and bill payment), and inform a ti on about health insurance options. For instance, Ehealthinsurance. com claims to offer products from about carriers and sells insurance to individuals and small employers in states.3 EbenX and Sageo, two additional electronic insurance exchange companies, facilitate transactions for employees on behalf of employers and health plans. According to industry analysts, online individual and small-group sales currently represent approximately percent of total policy sales.4 Additional e-commerce companies, such as TriZetto and HealthAxis, provide traditional insurers,insurance exchanges, brokers,and employers with electronic capabilities to purchase health i n su ra n ce . Six of the nation’s largest insurers have formed MedUnite to develop online enrollment, physician selection, claims approval and processing, and prescription services. Individual insurers are developing similar capabilities. Even in the absence of new subsidies to help them increase en ro ll m ent and, thus, spread fixed costs, electronic insurance exchanges and e-commerce companies may be able to achieve the administrative savings that many group-purchasing arrangements have failed to achieve thus far. Projected long-term administrative savings from electronic insurance exchanges range from percent to percent of administrative costs.5 In a survey of large employers, percent of respondents indicated interest in using the Internet to help employees enroll in a health plan or choose a physician group.6 According to industry research, many consumers also strongly prefer to purchase health insurance online.7 The advantages to enrollees of joining insurance exchanges (that is, subsidies, choice, and lower-cost coverage) likely will drive demand for such services; this demand, in turn, will encourage entrepreneurs and employers to seek certification as insurance exchanges. Brokers, who have traditionally served the small and mid-size market, but who have often been denied the ability to form purchasing groups, may find this a particularly attractive opportunity. We would not prohibit insurers from sponsoring an insurance exchange, nor would we prohibit exchanges from becoming insurers themselves. However, the IEC would monitor exchange sponsorship and report concern about abuses to the Frank Cerne. “Reaching Out on the Web.” Insurance Networking (April 2000). Journal Sentinel (October 4, 2000). 3 4 Ibid. 5 Tara Ashish et al. “Opportunity for Health Care Savings through Internet Technology.” Stanford, CA: Graduate School of Business. Independent student research, May 24, 2000; Jason Gertzen. “Blue Cross Steps into Internet Territory to Sell Health Insurance.” Milwaukee “Despite Costs, Employers Stick with Health Benefits.” Reuters Health (October 13, 2000). 6 7 Cybercitizen Health. “Internet Users Want to Manage Health Insurance Benefits Online.” Press release, New York: CyberDialogue, www.cyberdialogue.com/resource/press/releases/1999/08-25-cch-insurance.html, August 25, 1999. 160 The benefits of purchasing through the exchanges likely will make them the predominant mode of health insurance purchase, especially for employees of small and mid-size firms and for individuals. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission, and could establish firewalls against anti-competitive practices if necessary. Given the high degree of flexibility in sponsorship and benefit design, we expect that many individuals and employees will use an insurance exchange to enroll in a health plan. Our proposal requires that at least one insurance exchange serve every geographic region in the United States. With new subsidies and flexibility in sponsorship and benefit offerings, we expect existing private purchasing group arrangements to expand to meet this requirement. The benefits of purchasing through the exchanges likely will make them the predominant mode of health insurance purchase, especially for employees of small and mid-size firms and for individuals. Most employees of large employers will purchase through exchanges, as well, because their employers are likely to seek qualification as exchanges to make it possible for low- and middle-income employees to obtain subsidies (in the form of refundable tax credits). If, despite these advantages, insurance exchanges do not materialize in parts or all of a state within several years, that state can work with the IEC to develop alternatives. The IEC can waive the insurance exchange requirement and authorize one or more alternatives. For example, exchanges may develop more slowly in rural areas. To serve residents in these areas, the IEC could work with states to promote expansion of insurance exchanges specializing in plans for rural areas to cover multiple states. Alternatively, if no private insurance exchanges are available in particular regions of a state by three years after enactment of the proposal, a state can request authorization from the IEC to implement a national program parallel to the FEHBP, called the U.S. In su ra n ce Exchange (USIX), in these areas. Individuals and employers with up to employees would be eligible to participate in USIX; at the dis- cretion of the states (and with authorization from the IEC), the maximum size of participating employers could be incre a s ed . Much like FEHBP, USIX would be required to offer all plans in the region that meet specified, reasonable standards (negotiated with USIX), and each plan would set its own price. Start-up administrative costs in each state for USIX would be financed primarily by each state, but states also could receive some limited federal funding. After a start-up period of,at most,several years, administrative costs would be incorporated into the premiums charged by USIX in the state. Coverage/Eligibility: Coverage of Unaffiliated Individuals through Default Plans Low-income individuals who are eligible for full subsidies (see below), but who are ineligible to purchase through an insu ra n ce exchange, or who are eligible but fail to purchase a health insurance plan during a defined en ro ll m ent peri od , would be enrolled automatically in a “default plan” developed by the state.8 Individuals who are eligible for both the subsidies and Medicaid or S-CHIP, and who fail to en ro ll in any program or plan, also would be enrolled in the default plan. States would identify the default plan providers and distribute payments to them. We expect that default providers in most states will be public hospitals, community clinics, and other “safety net” providers. Because states would have considerable flexibility in targeting default plan payments to providers, they might 8 B. Madrian and D. Shea. “The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) Participation and Savings Behavior.” NBER Working Paper 7682, May 2000. This research found that an automatic enrollment approach raised pension participation rates from 37 percent to 86 percent. For lower-wage ($20,000-$29,000) and younger (age 20–29) workers, participation increased from 25 percent to 83 percent. 161 make other choices, such as low-cost private plans. Default plans would be expected to meet certain minimum standards in order to receive federal payments. For example, default plans would be required to conduct outreach to default plan members, encourage and provide primary and preventive services, and en co u ra ge eligible individuals and families to enroll in private plans offered through insurance exchanges or employers. Our plan provides for considerable state flexibility and financial incentives to achieve these goals. New federal payments to states for the default plan would be set equal to percent of the value of the refundable tax credit (see below) multiplied by the number of individuals presumed eligible for the full tax credit who do not actively enroll in a health insurance plan. A percent subsidy for these individuals is generous compared with current payment levels for the uninsured and their expected use of services. A percent subsidy also preserves incentives for individuals to join conven ti onal health insurance plans.States that increase this group’s rate of active enrollment in insurance plans would retain a portion of the affected default plan payments (for example,the payments would be reduced by percent multiplied by the improvement in covera ge , rather than percent). The default payments to states also would include incentive components related to a state’s performance in providing clearly effective health care to its population, particularly higher-risk population groups (for example, low-income children and adults). States that improved performance (after accounting for trends in income and state economic performance) would receive ad d i ti on a l incremental payments; states with worsening performance would face incremental payment reductions. Initially, measures could be selected from health measures already being co ll ected to track Healthy People performance goals, which are likely to be particularly sensitive to uninsurance rates and/or the quality of public outreach programs. Such measures include rates of pre-natal care (collected from birth records), vaccination rates (obtained from state public health records), and avoidable hospitalization rates (collected from hos- pital discharge data). Additional measures might be added from the Na ti onal Health Care Quality Report Card, which probably will be published annually beginning in several years. As a condition for receiving default plan payments, states also might be required to co ll ect some measures of the services they are providing to uninsured patients. Changes in Tax Incentives to Improve Equity and Affordability in Health Insurance Purchasing Current federal tax law does not count employerpaid health premiums as taxable income for employees. This unlimited tax exclusion has helped to promote the purchase and availability of health insurance, particularly employment-based insurance, but it also weakens incentives to control health plan costs, because the added costs are in pre-tax dollars. Over time, our proposal would transform the unlimited exclusion into a capped exclusion. Individuals could take either the capped exclusion or, if they are eligible, the new refundable tax credit (described below). In year one, the exclusion would be capped at double the price of the median-cost plan premium in the previous year. (Depending on data availability, the median-cost plan premium of a representative sample of plans analyzed by actuaries working with the IEC, or the median-cost plan of FEHBP premiums, would be used for this calculation.) For the next eight years, the exclusion would be cap ped at whichever is lower: the level of the cap in the previous year or percent, percent, percent, etc., of the price of the median-cost plan premium in the previous year (adjusted for any demographic changes). In the th and subsequent years, the cap would be equal to the median-cost plan premium in the previous year, plus percent. Implementation will require employers to impute employer premium payments (which would be su bj ect to Internal Revenue Service [IRS] and Department of Labor [DOL] audits) and to report employer-paid premiums that they have excluded from taxable business income (up to the cap) on the employee’s W-. Employees then could exclude any 162 SCHEDULE FOR THE HEALTH INSURANCE EXCLUSION CAP PHASE-IN Year Percent of median plan premium in the previous year percent Lesser of percent, or level of cap in Year Lesser of percent, or level of cap in Year Lesser of percent, or level of cap in Year Lesser of percent, or level of cap in Year Lesser of percent, or level of cap in Year Lesser of percent, or level of cap in Year Lesser of percent, or level of cap in Year Lesser of percent, or level of cap in Year and following percent additional premium payment, up to the cap on the exclusion. We would expect the IEC, with the technical assistance and advice of accountants, to develop standards for imputation of employer health care expenses to employees. A question of regional cost variations would ari s e .G en erally, the tax laws do not provide for regional variations, but they could. As is the case for other things (for example, sales taxes, when they were deductible, or business meals), the Treasury could publish tables with applicable caps by ZIP code. There are arguments on both sides of this issue. We would favor allowing regional variations based on factor prices, analogous to those used in the Medicare Prospective Payment System. The cap on the exclusion will be adjusted geographically, using a formula determined by Congress and administered by the IEC. A formula based on insurance premium variations by metropolitan statistical area (MSA) and non-MSA regions is a potential starting point. These geographic ad ju s tm ents could be based on actual prem iu m costs in the area (for example, demographically adjusted FEHBP premiums) or on geographic cost adjusters, such as those used in the Health Care Financing Administra ti on (HCFA) Prospective Payment System (PPS). If the ad ju s tm ent is to be based only or primarily on geographic cost differ- ences, and not on health plan cost differences across areas after accounting for differences in input costs, then a long transition period would be required. The transformation of the unlimited employer exclusion into a capped exclusion is attractive for several reasons. First, the capped exclusion discourages employer contribution policies that inhibit cost consciousness. Second, since the value of the tax exclusion rises with the marginal tax rate, capping the exclusion makes it less regressive. Third, the cap provides a significant source of financing for the proposed health insurance tax credits, which also will contribute to greater equity in government subsidies for private health insu ra n ce purchases. Without this provision, our proposal still could be enacted. However, the new budget costs of the proposal would be significantly higher, and/or the new tax credits would be significantly smaller or restricted to a lower income range. Subsidies Low- and Middle-Income Individuals and Families Our proposal would create a new refundable tax credit for low- and middle-income individuals and families. The base credit amount would be equal to percent of the median-cost plan premium for single coverage (adjusted to the demographic charac- 163 teristics of the el i gi ble population) in the previous year. Tax credits could be taken on a single, dual, or family basis. We envision a credit equal to twice the single credit for dual coverage,and . times the single credit for family coverage (that is, equivalent to the relative single, dual, and family premiums of many large employers). Subsidies would vary by region, and they would be adjusted geographically in the same manner as the tax exclusion cap described above. Tax credits would not vary by age (see following discussion of risk adjustment of premiums). Individuals eligible for Medicare would not be eligible for the new tax credit. Individuals eligible for Medicaid or S-CHIP could take the credit and enroll in a certified exchange plan or an employer-covered plan,though this would require that they relinquish their Medicaid or S-CHIP benefits. Thus,individuals or families currently eligible for Medicaid or S-CHIP could continue to participate in these programs if they chose, and they would have an incentive to continue, because the average subsidy is considerably greater. However, financial disincentives to enroll in a private plan provided by an exchange or employer would be reduced substantially. If many Medicaidor S-CHIP-eligible individuals and families chose to en ro ll in such a private plan, the state and federal government likely would realize significant net cost reductions. Given the difference in the level of subsidy between the average Medicaid and S-CHIP benefit and the proposed tax credit, this would be true even if relatively healthy individuals switched out,as is likely to be the case. States would be required to maintain support for Medicaid and S-CHIP beneficiaries who enroll in a private plan, contributing percent of the median-cost plan.Eligible individuals in employer-provided plans could choose either the tax credit or the capped exclusion. The tax credits would begin to be phased out at incomes of , (single) and , (couples and families). They would be phased out fully at income levels of , (single) and , (couples and families). These amounts would be indexed in the same way as tax brackets. The phase-out is structured to begin at income levels above the phase-out of earned income tax credits and most other means-tested benefits, so that the implicit marginal tax rate applied to an increased income does not rise steeply. Setting the subsidy equal to percent of the median-cost plan premium, rather than an alternative, such as the full price of the low-priced plan, maintains an incentive to limit the prices of lowpriced plans. In many markets today, several health insurance plans are available at percent of the median-cost plan. We assume that health plans will offer products priced to meet the needs of this new, large p opulation of potential enrollees, even if this means adjusting benefits or changing cost-sharing provisions to reduce premiums. Insurance exchanges and USIX could encourage insurers to offer such plans. Because we propose only limited standardization of health plan benefits, setting the tax credit as a percentage of the median-cost plan provides some assurance that the reference benefits package provides a reasonable level of coverage. Employed individuals would claim the credit through an additional few lines of paperwork for their current W- filing, which determines their tax withholding. Individuals who do not receive the credit through their employer (that is, individuals who purchase through an insurance exchange that they choose individually and, thus, to which they pay premiums directly) would attach proof of coverage through a certified exchange to a W- to claim the credit. States would be allowed to use some of their uninsured funds to develop capacity to assist unemployed individuals with the credit. And, along with Consolidated Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act (COBRA) notification, those terminated from a job would be notified of potential eligibility for this assistance. All individuals also would be required to provide similar documentation of coverage on their tax return. In the absence of a presumption of eligibility, insufficient income tax withholding due to improper credit claims would be subject to the usual IRS interest and penalties. To increase take-up rates,simple prospective criteria would be used to create a presumption of eligibility, based on wages and hours worked (for example, full-time workers earning less than an hour who purchase a family policy would be presumed eligible), and based on last year’s family tax 164 returns (for example, workers eligible in the previous year who have not indicated new employment or earnings on their current W- form — which they would need to fill out to claim the credit in advance — also would be presumed el i gi bl e ) . Individuals who meet the eligibility presumption, but who turn out to be ineligible in their end-of-year tax filings, would not be subject to penalties; they simply would be required to repay the amount credited on a reasonable repayment schedule. Precedent for this policy comes from the IRS, which forgives tax penalties for insufficient withholding for those whose tax liabilities are much higher than they were the year before. Some state health insurance programs for lower-income families, for example, Wisconsin, also have implemented steps similar in spirit to this presumption. For employed individuals, credits would be transferred directly to employers. The credit would be made available to employers in advance for individuals with insufficient tax liability. Making these payments to firms rather than individuals (as in Earned Income Tax Credit [EITC] payments) would improve accuracy and simplify administration for the IRS. Also, relatively few employers would owe negative taxes as a result of any incorrect payments. Certified insurance exchanges also could collect credit-based payments monthly or quarterly on behalf of the individuals enrolled through their exchanges via the IEC. We expect this option to be used most often by individuals (along with their families) who do not receive coverage through their employers. The IEC would receive an annual appropriation from Congress for this purpose. In this case,the certified insurance exchange would submit proof of coverage on behalf of the eligible individual. Thus, these individuals would have to pay only the portion of their premium not covered by the credit. Such individuals would not be allowed to receive the credit through their employer also. The IEC would forward the tax identification numbers of all individuals receiving subsidies through insurance exchanges to the IRS for audit purposes, and would assist the IRS in detecting other types of fraud. The IEC and the IRS would have the authori- ty to impose sanctions on exchanges that use tax credits fraudulently. Although recent studies have suggested a significant fraud rate with the EITC, it seems unlikely that fraud will occur at a similar rate here. First, to be eligi bl e , an indivi dual must doc u m ent covera ge in a certified exchange. The number of certified exchanges is likely to be small compared with the number of individuals and businesses filing tax documents related to the EITC, thus creating simpler oversight. Second, sanctions against exchanges — including losing certification and criminal penalties—presumably would deter their participation in fraud. Third, in contrast to dollars, individuals are not likely to want more than one health insurance plan. Administra ti on of the tax credits will require employers to collect some ad d i ti onal information from their employees. However, the process represents a relatively minor addition to the information on wages and other benefits employers currently provide to the federal government, so this should create a relatively minimal burden. No other private entity is as well situated to provide this needed information about employees, and any additional preparation costs could be deducted as a business expense. Payments to Default Plans Payments to states for individuals enrolled in their default plan will be administered by the IEC. The default plan payment will be equal to percent of the value of the tax credit for eligible individuals in the state who do not actively enroll in an insurance plan. These payments, and the associated incentive payments, were described earlier. Insurance, Risk Selection, and Risk Adjustment Our proposal attempts to strike a balance between protecting health plans and insurance exchanges from adverse risk selection and stifling innovation, variation, and flexibility. Because we have attempted to minimize complexity by maintaining tax credits that do not vary with risk status, and by fixing premiums that indi- 165 Critical to this proposal is an ongoing quality measurement and public reporting program, including risk-adjusted outcome studies and comparison of actual care patterns with recommended guidelines. viduals pay when they purchase insurance through an exchange, there is substantial potential for adverse selecti on . Some aspects of our proposal, such as the large subsidies available up to relatively high-income levels, will mitigate adverse selection by attracting large numbers of average and low-risk enrollees. However, additional efforts are likely to be necessary. Consequently, the IEC will develop minimum standards for risk adjustment of plan premiums within insurance exchanges, and the IEC will provide risk adjustment among insurance exchanges in a particular region or state. Among Plans within Insurance Exchanges A key ch a ll en ge is to ensure that plans do not face financial penalties for attracting enrollees who are likely to have above-average health expenditures, or, conversely, are not rewarded for attracting low-cost enrollees. An ideal risk-adjustment procedure would remove the disincentives to attract high-cost en ro ll ees without rewarding health plans whose costs are high because they are inefficient or unable to limit use appropriately. Obviously, such an ideal system does not exist;thus considerable flexibility in dealing with risk-selection problems within exchanges is desirable. Because of variation in plan features, such as the groups of participating providers, services reimbursed, and breadth of choice of prescription drugs, different plans within an exchange are likely to attract enrollees who would be expected to generate different levels of expenditures. Insurance exchanges would be required to meet minimum standards for risk adjustment of payments to their participating plans, based on differences in the expected use of populations of enrollees that they attract. The IEC would specify minimum standards. Individual exchanges and states would be free to use additional methods, such as partial reinsurance. Initially, the risk adjustment is likely to be based on age alone. As risk-adjustment technology improves, and as experience with other methods accumulates, the IEC may implement alternative standards. Note that within-exchange risk adjustment will redistribute payments within the exchange from lower-risk to higher-risk plans; it does not include any cross-exchange subsidies. Among Insurance Exchanges in a Region or State The IEC would oversee risk adjustment across insurance exchanges in each region or state. The IEC would develop methods for measuring selection effect s ,b a s ed on data provided by health plans and exchanges. If necessary, the IEC would con du ct demographic risk ad ju s tm ent and, possibly, more sophisticated risk adjustment, to redistribute premiums among insu ra n ce exchanges. In effect, plans with higher-risk demographics would be subsidized by lower-risk plans in the same region. The IEC also would have some authority to work with states to adapt high-risk pools and other state initiatives to the insurance exchange program. Adverse selection could affect exchanges, despite these measu re s ,i f , for example,non-exchange employers encouraged sicker employees to seek coverage through exchanges as individuals. Exchanges also could attract high-risk en ro ll ee s , who are more likely to be sick, simply because they are open to individuals. Consequently, the IEC would monitor adverse selection between insurance exchanges and the non-exchange market a n d ,i f necessary, would recommend the inclusion of the non-exchange market in the risk-adjustment calculations. An alternative solution could be to provide stop-loss protection for employers functioning as exchanges that had very high-cost employees. Note that for these purposes, all employers that qualify as insurance exchanges would be included in the risk-adjustment calculations and prem iu m redistribution. 166 STRUCTURE OF THE INSURANCE EXCHANGE COMMISSION IEC Steering Committee Coverage Committee Risk-Adjustment Committee Oversight of Insurance Exchanges: The Insurance Exchange Commission The federal Insurance Exchange Commission (IEC) will be created to oversee the proposed new subsidies and the insurance exchanges eligible to benefit from them. Its broad mission is to help the market provide access to high-quality health care; however, its powers for achieving this goal would be relatively narrow and tailored to en su ring that insurance exchanges and the competition they foster function effectively and with minimal intervention. The IEC would be an independent agency structured like the Securities and Exchange Commission. An appointed board of directors, whose members would be selected for their professional qualifications, would serve for fixed, staggered five-year terms. Board members would be appointed by the President, with the advice and consent of the Senate. A Steering Committee, made up of individuals with experience and expertise in health care financing and organization, would direct the IEC’s activities. In addition, the IEC would operate four standing committees: () Coverage, () Risk-Adjustment, () In su ra n ce Exchange Opera ti ons and Compliance, and () Quality Measurement and Improvement. Committee membership would include indi- Insurance Exchange Operations and Compliance Committee Quality Management and Improvement Committee viduals from the payer and provider communities, industry (including pharmaceutical and device manufacturers), consumers,and health care experts. Some of the IEC’s responsibilities could be contracted out to other agencies, such as the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality (AHRQ), or private-sector organizations, such as the National Committee for Quality Assurance (NCQA). Committee members would meet usual conflict-of-interest standards for senior government officials. Among the main functions of the IEC would be distributing tax credit payments toward premiums to insurance exchanges and distributing default plan payments to states. By assigning these responsibilities to the IEC,our proposal minimizes new burdens for the IRS. The four standing committees of the IEC, shown in the chart ab ove, would have the following responsibilities. The Coverage Committee would issue recommendations and set minimum standards for benefits covered by health plans offered through certified insurance exchanges. The minimum standards will be designed to ensure that par ticipating plans cover medical goods and services that are known to be effective and that are provided at reasonable cost, but they also will be sufficiently general and flexible 167 to allow plans to create a wide range of coverage options. The Risk-Adjustment Committee would be responsible for developing and implementing new approaches to risk ad ju s tm en t . They would be expected to draw on a wide range of expertise and consult broadly in developing and testing new methods. Although risk adjustment will be limited to simple age adjustment initially, the Risk-Adjustment Committee will review existing and developing riskadjustment methods on an ongoing basis, test such methods, and implement the best ones, based on their feasibility and their ability to overcome adverse selection within and among insurance exchanges. The Insurance Exchange Operations and Compliance Committee would en co u ra ge development of insurance exchanges, and would develop and administer incentives to create and con ti nue the exchanges. It also would establish and enforce minimum standards for the formation and operation of insurance exchanges to en su re that they serve the interests of m em bers. The new federal minimum standards would replace state laws for plans offered by insurance exchanges. This committee would certify private insurance exchanges as eligible to receive subsidies. Based on proposals from affected states, it also would be responsible for ensuring the development of at least one insurance exchange to cover every geographic region in the country. In addition, it would make sure that residents of regions that failed to establish exchanges within three years would be able to enroll in health care plans through USIX. The committee also would be responsible for monitoring market concentra ti on and detecting abuses of either monopoly or monopsony power that an insurance exchange might develop. The committee also would have the ability to obtain price information from the exchanges to detect evidence of abuse of m on op s ony power, such as contract prices with plans that fall well below the prices paid to plans in other markets. The committee would monitor exchanges for abuses by sponsors who also offer insurance through their exchange. It would provide information on such questionable competitive conditions to the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission. To date, group-purchasing arrangements and similar en ti ties have not accounted for a large share of i n su red lives in any geographic area, so concern about market power is based on the potential growth of the exchanges, rather than on current problems. We would not prohibit insurers from sponsoring an insurance exchange, nor would we prohibit exchanges from becoming insurers themselves. However, the IEC would monitor exchange sponsorship and report concern about abuses to the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission, and could establish firewalls against anti-competitive practices if necessary. The Quality Measurement and Improvem en t Committee would establish minimum quality measurement and reporting standards for health plans participating in insu ra n ce exchanges and for those acting as default plans. Health plans would report quality data directly to the IEC. Insurance exchanges also might be required to report some measures of quality, for example, disenrollment, complaint,and satisfaction rates. The IEC would ensure that such data could not be used to compromise individual patient confidentiality and would provide these data for use by government agencies, consumer groups, consultants, benefit managers, and others in evaluating the quality of insurance products and exchanges. The committees’ operating budget would be determined and appropriated by Congress. Staffing for the IEC would include the IEC director and seven members of the steering committee, full-time chairs for the four standing committees, and fulltime staff supporting the steering committee and each of the standing committees. The budget also would include funds for operations, an annual budget for development activities, and incentive funds for exchanges. The operating budget,as shown below, is approximately million annually. Financing the Proposal Costs of the proposal include the new tax credits for low- and middle-income Americans, ad d i ti on a l payments to the IRS to administer the tax aspects of the plan (with assistance from the IEC), limited 168 ANNUAL BUDGET* OF THE INSURANCE EXCHANGE COMMISSION Staffing (s) Steering Committee Director and members Salary + full benefits Senior (professional) staff () , , Standing Committees Average . FTE per committee member Director and members of each , committee Senior (professional) staff , ( for each committee) Administrative staff ( total) , Office expenses , Travel , Risk-adjustment development Quality measurement and improvement , , Exchange Incentives Fund* , , *Initial-year budget; will be reduced in subsequent years. start-up costs for USIX,and an operating budget for the IEC. These costs will be financed by: • capping the current unlimited exclusion of employer-paid health insurance; • savings over time through behavioral effects among consumers and health plans because of increased cost-consciousness and improved valuebased competition among health plans; and • general revenues. Fit within Existing System and Transition from Present to Future This proposed plan for near-universal health insurance relies primarily on existing institutions, and preserves the best features of the existing health insurance system while closing gaps in covera ge .O u r proposal retains the employer-based system and the option for all those eligible for low-income state and federal health care programs to continue in them if they so desire. Our proposed default plan would improve support for “safety net” providers and provide new incentives for preventive services that might help lower their costs. This proposal also builds on what we know works best today and is most acceptable to the American public, that is, large-scale group-purchasing arrangements such as FEHBP and CalPERS, and independent agencies with limited authority to help competition work well in complex industries, such as the SEC. Competition among private health plans and among private insurance exchanges with minimal federal oversight fits American values be s t .E conomic theory also suggests that this is the most effective way to expand ch oi ce ,l ower prices, and improve quality of care and service. Where such arrangements fail to develop, our proposal offers USIX as a backup program that also would create competition and choice. Where we recommend a significant departure from the current system, we propose a gradual transition. In particular, we recommend a -year trans i ti on period to adjust the tax exclusion of health insurance premiums fully. We also recommend a minimum of three years for development of private insurance exchanges before introducing USIX in a market. Political Feasibility Opposition to such a plan is likely to emerge from these major features: . The cost of the plan is substantial; the bulk of its costs come from the tax credits used to subsidize insurance coverage. Furthermore, some opponents would claim that a tax credit mechanism like the one proposed here is “inefficient” because it provi de s new subsidies for many low- and middle-income families that are currently purchasing private health insurance. The claim of inefficiency is easily misunderstood, and applies only in the narrow sense of government expenditures for health insurance. The system of tax credits proposed here gives tax credits to low- and middle-income individuals, regardless of whether they already have insurance individually or through their employer, as long as the employer is certified as an insurance exchange. Even non-eligible 169 employers may encourage low- and middle-income individuals to seek coverage outside the firm to avail themselves of the tax credit. The purpose of giving tax credits to all low- and middle-income individuals is to compensate those low- and middle-income individuals and families who purchase insurance (or obtain it through an employer), giving up either premium payments or wages to do so. Offering the subsidy only to those who lack insurance is,in our view, short-sighted and inappropriate policy, since it strongly en co u ra ges employers to drop coverage, thus “crowding out” private insurance and distorting incentives. Moreover, it is unfair to the many families that con ti nue to struggle to make their monthly health insu ra n ce premiums. Funds spent on lowand middle-income individuals under this plan are transfer payments, and they provide social benefits even if the low-income individuals would have purchased insurance in the absence of the subsidy. The cost per additional insured individual may be higher than under plans that crowd out private insurance, but the added costs represent socially desirable transfer payments (like the EITC) rather than waste. This tax reduction also would achieve a second goal—improving health insurance coverage while reducing incentives to switch to even more heavily subsidized government plans. Educating the public and policy makers about the reasons for the costs and the advantages of the plan will be challenging. . The plan limits the tax exclusion for health insurance expenditures. The current tax exclusion is popular, and particularly benefits high-income individuals and families who purchase high-cost plans. Such people will not favor the cap on the exclusion, which reduces the overall cost of the plan. We believe that the gradual phase-in of the cap, and pegging the cap to the cost of a reasonably representative and generous private health plan, will help to overcome objections to it. . The plan creates an independent federal agency to oversee health insurance. Some critics will object to creation of the IEC, claiming that it will be another federal bureaucracy that imposes undue burdens on employers,health plans, and health care providers and provides poor service to the public. Some also may object to what they perceive to be the IEC’s complexity. However, the IEC’s authority is limited to a small set of specifically designated powers, and its main functions are to assist in implementing the tax credits and developing better data on risk adjustment and health plan quality. In setting minimum standards for use of the tax credits, the IEC will play a relatively hands-off role, setting standards more like those used by the FEHBP, rather than, for example, the very detailed recommendations of President Clinton’s health care task force. At the same time, by extending the ERISA preemption to insurance e xchanges and plans that will serve many small employers and individuals, we remove an inequitable set of regulatory burdens that currently face small employers and individuals seeking coverage. . The plan will not provide coverage for every single American. Although our goal is universal health insurance coverage, this plan does not contain a mandate to cover every American. Thus,those who seek immediate universal coverage will object that this plan falls short. We believe that plans that propose percent coverage typically do not achieve access for all individuals, and that attempts to do so require some combination of high costs, restrictions on choice of plans or providers, limited coverage, and a constrained role for the private sector. We also believe that our proposal to offer new funding to states to provide “basic” and preventive care to individuals who do not choose to enroll in a subsidized plan (and so may be less likely to use health care until they really need it) will improve their access to care, as well. We believe that the political objections to a plan that would come closer to immediate universal coverage would be far greater than to our plan. . Groups that favor either a single-payer system or another form of comprehensive government interven ti on in health care will oppose the heavy reliance on existing private institutions. Some of them will argue that administrative costs will be lower with a government-run plan, and that equity in access to health care will be put at risk by a plan that promotes choice among private health insurers. We believe that many of those groups, however, will see the appeal of our plan, which achieves much 170 broader health insurance covera ge , despite their objections to specific features, and that this proposal will enjoy far broader political support than the alternatives they favor. . The plan will change the mechanism through which safety net providers receive payment. Under this proposal,safety net providers would receive payments for care for the uninsured by participating in default plans. In addition, to receive payments,states will be required to meet minimum requirements and will have financial incentives to conduct outreach to facilitate enrollment of unaffiliated individuals in private plans. The payments outlined are more generous than safety net providers receive today, and they promote high-quality care and expanded coverage. However, many safety net providers like the current system and may resist change. Overall, the plan represents little threat to existing interests and little change in familiar institutions and structures. Its key features—preserva ti on of private health insurance, expansion of choices and flexibility, use of targeted tax credits, improvement of markets for individual insurance, and protection of safety net providers like public hospitals—are also features of plans that already have demonstrated bipartisan support. Like those plans, it does not attempt to solve every problem in the current health insurance system. Because our proposal represents a fine balance between the achievable and the ideal, it has the potential to attract broad political support. Quality, Cost, and Efficiency Critical to this proposal is an ongoing quality measurement and public reporting program, including risk-adjusted outcome studies and comparison of actual care patterns with recommended guidelines. Much of this effort would be conducted or promoted by the IEC, which would set standards for information collection and dissemination. It would build on existing best practices in quality measurement, whether public- (for example, Medicare) or privatesector (for example, the Consumer Assessments of Health Plans Study [CAHPS] and the Foundation for Accountability [FACCT]), and would sponsor development of new measures. It also would encourage standardization of data collection across exchanges and other public or private purchasers. These efforts would help plans and providers to develop improved measures of processes and outcomes of care by plans and providers. Finally, the IEC would develop and enforce standards for data security and confidentiality. Also critical to this proposal is effective cost containment, requiring conditions in which all Americans have a personal reason to care about health care costs, support serious cost-containment efforts, and economize. This is partly a matter of cultural attitudes, but it is also a function of the economic structure of health plan choice. Our strategy for containing costs and increasing value rests on competi ti on among health care organizations to serve price-sensitive consumers. Recognizing wide variations in quality and economy of health care delivery systems, the proposed economic structure of health plan ch oi ce would encourage greater cost consciousness, and the proposed quality measurement program would increase consumers’ confidence in their choices. We anticipate that informed and cost-conscious consumers will migra te , gradually and voluntarily, to models that offer the greatest value, as they have done in exchange models such as FEHBP and CalPERS. Equity Use of the tax credit to subsidize low-income individuals and families promotes equity by direct income transfer. Qualification for the tax credit is broad,and it is available to low- and middle-income individuals who are not enrolled in Medicare, Medicaid, or S-CHIP. Individuals with qualifying income who are now adequately insured,along with those who are uninsured or underinsured, would qualify for the tax credits. In addition, the middleincome individuals who would purchase insurance if they could do so at costs similar to those available to groups would now be able to obtain insurance at more favorable rates via the insurance exchange. Making the tax exclusion for health insurance universal will lower the after-tax cost to those lowerincome individuals who currently must pay health 171 insurance premiums with after-tax dollars. The cap on the tax exclusion will affect primarily highincome individuals who purchase very generous health insurance policies. An additional protection for at-risk populations, most of which are lower-income,is explicit designation of the default plan. We believe that most default plans will provide access to county and other public hospitals, which will then have a reliable source of revenue that can be used to subsidize the costs of uncompensated care. Such institutions routinely provide care to individuals who are uninsured and unable to pay for medical services,and undoubtedly have mitigated the adverse consequences of lack of insurance. The continued viability of such institutions is critical unless and until it is possible to ensure that all Americans can receive care at other institutions. An additional source of equity concerns is the treatment of persons with chronic illnesses and others who are expected to have disproportionately high health expenses. Many such individuals now face exceedingly high health insurance premiums or may not be able to purchase insurance at all. The proposed system emphasizes development of riskadjustment mechanisms for health insurance premiums that would make community rating feasible and thus enable such high-risk individuals to purchase insurance at the same rates as other people. Overall,the proposed plan provides substantial protections to those who are unable to obtain insurance at reasonable rates, either because their incomes are too low or their expected medical costs are too high. Acknowledgments This paper was prepared in consultation with Mark B. McClellan of the Department of Economics and the Center for Health Policy, Stanford University. n 173 Weil Proposal Key Elements Alan R. Weil proposes creating a Medical Security System (MSS) to provide health insurance coverage to every legal resident under age . His plan would: - access to a basic health coverage package at no cost to them, by requiring employers either to provide coverage or pay a payroll tax to finance coverage purchased through insurance exchanges. designed to organize the insurance market. The exchanges would operate in defined geographic areas and contract with health plans that would offer all their products on a guaranteed-issue, community-rated basis. through a health insurance exchange or their employer. At their option, employers could opt out of the MSS financing system by providing part- and full-time employees with a health plan equal to or greater in value than one of the standard benefits packages. ’ Insurance Program (S-CHIP) and the low-income and adult components of Medicaid, folding those beneficiaries into the MSS, while waiving copayments and providing wraparound coverage for services not included in the basic package. , existing government funding sources, individual premium payments, and additional appropriations for financing. 174 About the Author . , .., ..., is Director of the Assessing the New Federalism project at the Urban Institute. This project—the largest in the Institute’s -year history—monitors, describes and assesses the effects of changes in federal and state health, welfare, and social services programs. Mr. Weil was formerly Executive Director of the Colorado Department of Health Care Policy and Financing. This cabinet position is responsible for Colorado’s Medicaid and Medically Indigent programs, health policy development, and health data collection. Mr. Weil was a member of President Clinton’s Advisory Commission on Consumer Protection and Quality in the Health Care Industry and served on Mrs. Clinton’s health care task force. He was the lead Democratic staff during negotiations of the National Governors’ Association policy on Medicaid reform and the NGA policy in support of universal health insurance. Mr. Weil received his bachelor’s degree in economics and political science from the University of California at Berkeley. He holds a master of public policy degree from the John F. Kennedy School of Government at Harvard University, and a J.D. from Harvard Law School. 175 The Medical Security System: A Proposal To Ensure Health Insurance Coverage For All Americans by Alan R. Weil System Overview This paper sets forth a proposed Medical Security System (MSS) that would provide health insurance coverage to all non-elderly Americans. System Design The Medical Security System combines funds from a payroll tax, existing government funding sources, and additional appropriations to provide a basic insurance plan to all individuals. Private health insurance exchanges structure the insurance market, allowing individuals to select a basic plan at no charge or pay an additional amount to obtain enhanced covera ge . A medical savings account option is also available. Employers can avoid the payroll tax (their own and their employees’) if they provide and pay for a significant portion of a comprehensive insurance option for their employees and their dependents. All legal residents, regardless of employment status, who do not obtain coverage through their employer have free access to a plan through an exchange, and can purchase higher-cost coverage if they desire. Waivers of cost sharing are available to low-income families through a stateadministered system. The Medical Security System is financed primarily through a payroll tax. Tax rates are set originally to approximate current private insurance spending. For illustration, tax rates of . percent for employers and . percent for employees applied to the Social Security wage base would generate approximately the amount spent on private insurance premiums and would distribute the costs between employers and employees in accordance with the national average contributions for family coverage. A portion of existing state and federal Medicaid and State Children’s Health In su ra n ce Program (SCHIP) funds for poverty-related eligible populations, along with additional general revenues, will also be required. A set of nationally standardized model benefits packages will be developed (for example, tightly managed with limited copayments,less tightly managed with higher copayments). One benefit option will be structured as a medical savings account (MSA), with a high-deductible health plan combined with mandatory contributions to a savings account that can be used only for medical costs. The standard benefits package with the lowest actuarial value (other than the MSA) is referred to as the benchmark pack a ge . The value of the benchmark package determines the revenue necessary to provide universal coverage under the MSS. This amount, less other funding streams, will ultimately determine the actual payroll tax rate. The MSS operates through health insurance exchanges that serve to organize the insurance market. Exchanges operate in defined geographic areas designed to encompass one or more health care markets. Exchanges are assumed to be private, but there are no requirements as to their form of governance or ownership. Any exchange that meets basic requirements can obtain a license to operate,meaning that multiple, competing exchanges may exist within any given market. Exchanges have no regulatory power. Exchanges bear no insurance risk; instead, they contract with licensed health plans. To operate, an exchange must offer all standard benefits plans; however, exchanges may also offer additional plan designs. All products must be offered to all partici- 176 pants on a community-rated basis. At least one plan must be offered free-of-charge. Through the MSS, exchanges receive a fixed amount per enrollee adjusted for the age and gender composition of the en ro ll ee s . On average, the MSS provides each exchange with sufficient funds to offer the benchmark plan at no cost to the enrollee. As a practical matter, the specifics of the no-cost plan in any exchange will be determined by the bids the exchange receives. It is important to emphasize that the actual design of the no-cost plan may or may not match the benchmark plan, and it may vary across exchanges. Exchanges also co ll ect premium payments from individuals who select enhanced plans, and they provide information to participants about their plan options. The notion of a health insu ra n ce exchange is borrowed loosely from the stock exchange. Stock exchanges create a marketplace for highly regulated goods (securities). To succeed,these exchanges must attract buyers and sellers (firms and shareholders). While exchanges impose significant contractual requirements on buyers and sellers,they do not have any regulatory authority themselves. This analogy has its limits, but it does suggest the type of role envisioned for the exchanges. Employers may be exempt from the payroll tax s ys tem if they provide all part-time and full-time employees with a health insurance pa ckage equal to or greater than one of the standard benefits packages described above. Employers must contribute a minimum of percent of the cost of individual coverage and percent of the cost of dependent coverage, and employees are required to participate in coverage offered by exempt employers. Employer exemptions are given for three-year periods and cannot be revoked during that time. The continuation coverage requirement under the Consolidated Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of (COBRA) is eliminated. Every legal American resident, regardless of work status or earnings, may obtain any no-cost insurance package through any exchange operating in his or her area (unless the resident is covered by an exempt employer). At the time of enrollment,the person may select a plan that requires a premium payment, in which case premium billing is handled by the exchange. Non-payment results in the exchange moving the person into a no-cost plan. Enrollment cycles are annual, with exceptions for people who move into or out of the region. Health care providers may arrange with exchanges and health plans to provide for enrollment at the point of service for anyone who has not gone through the enrollment process. Any person may elect the medical savings account option, but the election is irrevocable for five years. Families with income below current mandatory Medicaid eligibility income standards qualify for a copayment waiver, allowing them to obtain medical services without making copayments or deductibles and to obtain certain otherwise uncovered services. Waiver applications are processed by states based on recent earnings data. Copayment waivers are valid for one year and must be renewed annually. The low-income child and adult components of Medicaid are eliminated, as is the State Children’s Health In su ra n ce Program (S-CHIP). Medicare remains intact. The portion of Medicaid that serves people with disabilities is reconfigured as wraparound coverage beyond the basic benefits available through the MSS. System Principles The Medical Sec u ri ty Sys tem is built on three principles. Health insurance coverage should be universal. Putting this principle into effect requires two important conceptual shifts within the health care system.First, we must acknowledge that no amount of public covera ge , whether in the form of public programs such as Medicaid or financial support such as tax credits,can expand from the base of our existing voluntary, employer-based insu ra n ce system into a universal system. Efforts to build from the voluntary employer-sponsored insu ra n ce base have yielded many innovative approaches, such as sliding premium scales, waiting periods for enrollment in public programs, and tax credits to purchase coverage in the non-group market or to apply 177 toward the employee’s share of the health insurance premium. While each incremental step is important and can benefit many people, this approach cannot reach universality. Substantively, the two systems cannot mesh to provide true universal covera ge , and, politically, sharing financial responsibility between the government and employers without clearly defined roles for each creates a constant battle to shift costs to the other payer. Second, we must separate financing from enrollment. A variety of financing sources must be called on to support the health care system. In addition, effective enrollment mechanisms must reach all people. But the two systems must be separated, so that income tests and applications with cumbersome verification requirements are no longer barriers to program enrollment. Similarly, we should encourage the separation of enrollment and health benefit administration from the workplace, thereby facilitating more efficient labor markets and eliminating employers’ access to personal health information about their employees. The MSS is built around the critical American value of choice, which is available at three level s .F i rs t ,i n contrast to the circumstances facing most Americans today, individuals are able to choose their health plan and delivery system. Secon d ,i n d ividuals are able to choose their health care provider. They can choose a plan based at least in part on whether that plan includes the providers on whom the individual relies. They may always obtain services outside of the MSS if they are willing to pay for those services. Third, individuals can determine the level of financial risk they are willing to bear. Individuals can choose from a range of insurance structu re s ,f rom catastrophic to comprehensive. They pay according to the risk they are willing to take, and they are able to join a risk pool with others with similar tastes for risk. The political process will determine the parameters of the benchmark plan and the funds necessary to support universal access to that plan. The definition of the guarantee is fundamentally a social decision that should be made in the political arena. The combination of individual choice and competi ti on among health plans will yield efficiencies within that core system. Spending decisions beyond the core are made by individuals, without tax subsidies, reflecting their desire to obtain more health insurance coverage than the MSS provides. The MSS retains the third-party payment system. While third-party payment is inherently inflationary, it provides a very real value to people by reducing the financial risks they face. Coverage and Eligibility The Medical Security System is universal for legal residents of the United States under age . The system fully uncouples financing and enrollment,making a basic health insurance package available to every American, regardless of employment status or income. Some people will continue to receive their insurance coverage through their employer. Others will obtain coverage through new health insurance exchanges that structure the market for health insurance. Everyone will have an insurance option available at no charge, but will also be able to use his or her own money to purchase a higher-cost, more comprehensive product. Design All Americans (except those covered by an exempt employer) will have the option of obtaining health insurance through new entities called health insurance exchanges. A health insurance exchange is a market organizer for health insurance products. The exchange receives funds (as described below) and enters into contracts with multiple insurance companies. Exchanges can take any ownership or governance form (for example, private, public, corporate, not-for-profit). Health insurance exchanges are licensed by the federal government. Each exchange must offer all standard plans (as described below) and at least one health plan that can be obtained free-of-charge by the enrollee. The exchange may also offer additional benefit designs. All plans, standard or otherwise, must be offered at 178 All Americans will have the option of obtaining health insurance through new entities called health insurance exchanges. Each exchange must offer at least one health plan that can be obtained free-of-charge by the enrollee. a community rate to all exchange participants with no underwriting. Exchanges may not tie participation in the exchange to purchase of any other goods or services,and exchanges may not sell any goods or services other than health insurance. The federal government will define a set of geographic regions, known as catchment areas, designed to approximate health care markets. An exchange that wishes to operate within a catchment area must serve the entire area. A single exchange can serve one or more catchment areas, or even operate nationwide. There is no restriction on the number of exchanges that may operate; in fact, competing exchanges may operate in any given catchment area. An exchange operating in a catchment area must accept enrollment from any resident in that catchment area. Exchanges contract with health plans and pay them for each enrollee in the exchange who selects that plan. The exchange bundles the funds it receives through the Medical Security System with the premium contributions made by individuals and passes them along to health plans. An exchange that performs its functions well— contracts with a variety of plans, informs enrollees of their choices, handles premium co ll ections— should obtain a sufficient enrollment base to be financially self-sustaining. However, since the MSS cannot function without the exchanges, states will be required to create an exchange if none exists in the state. A national board will create a series of standard benefits plans. These plans will reflect a range of options with respect to delivery system (for example, tightly managed,loosely managed,unmanaged) and cost sharing. As noted above, all health exchanges must offer all standard plans. Based on the funds available to it through the MSS, each exchange must also offer at least one nocost plan.A no-cost plan is one in which any person may enroll without being required to make any premium payment from his or her own funds. A nocost plan may or may not correspond with one of the standard plans. As a practical matter, the exchange, knowing the funds it will receive per member, will solicit bids from participating health plans at a price that matches those funds (less administrative costs absorbed by the exchange). The benefit design of the received bids will determine what the exchange can offer at no cost. Given this method, it is important to note that the specifics of the no-cost plan may vary among exchanges. Every exchange must offer an MSA option. Under this option,a high-deductible plan is provided, with the balance of the funds placed into a savings account. Funds in the account roll forward indefinitely and are available only for medical costs. The MSA option is available to all MSS participants, but a participant who elects that option must remain in the MSA for five years. No rebates are permitted for below-cost plans; that is, exchanges may not offer plans that cost less than the funds they have available, and then refund those excess funds to the enrollee. The only exception to this is the MSA. In the MSA option,all funds other than those used to purchase the highdeductible insu ra n ce are deposited into the MSA, which is available to the en ro ll ee only for healthrelated purposes. Employers may con ti nue to provide health insurance to their employees. An employer that provides all part-time and full-time employees with a health insurance package equal to or greater in value than one of the standard benefits packages, and con- 179 tributes a minimum of percent of the cost of individual coverage and percent of the cost of family coverage, can become exempt from the MSS. This exemption means that the employer does not pay the payroll tax into the MSS. Exempt employers must make employee participation in the company’s health plan automatic and mandatory. Employer exemptions are granted for renewable three-year periods, and the employer must abide by the terms of the exemption for the entire period. Rationale The MSS relies heavily on health insurance exchanges because of the demonstrated value of pooled purchasing arrangements. These arrangements pool risk, offer a choice of plans, and organize the insurance market in a manner that increases competition. The limited success of purchasing pools in the current health insurance system is primarily a reflection of the environment in which these pools must opera te . The MSS offers these pools a large number of members and a set of market rules under which they do not face any competitive disadvantages. Under these conditions, health insurance exchanges can provide value and choice. In the MSS,health insurance exchanges can take any organizational form, and any number of exchanges can exist side-by-side with identical or overlapping catchment areas. There is no reason to restrict organizational form or create monopsony purchasers as long as all exchanges are required to fo ll ow appropriate market rules. Competi ti on among exchanges will occur on the basis of information provided to enrollees,the range of insurance options offered to enrollees, and the overall quality of service provided. In the short run, exchanges will be created and some will fail, imposing a cost on the health care system. Over time, a limited number of exchanges are likely to survive. The process of exchange competition, and the possibility of new entrants if existing exchanges do not meet the needs of their customers, should yield good-quality service. A natural corollary of having multiple, competing exchanges is that those exchanges have no government or regulatory power. The series of standard benefits packages is designed to enhance the efficiency of the market. The goal is to create sufficient standardization that consumers can evaluate the relative value of various options. One alternative would have been to permit only standard benefits plans to be sold. This option was rejected because the process that defines these plans will inevitably be political and potentially slow-moving and could prevent the adoption of innova ti ons (such as the emergence of point-ofservice plans). To ensure the viability of the standard plans,the MSS requires that all benefit designs offered by the exchange, standard or not, be offered on a community-rated basis without underwriting. One alternative would have been to permit risk rating for non-standard products. This option was rejected because of the concern that a health plan could offer a minor va ri a ti on on a standard plan, underwrite the plan, and offer it at a low cost while higher-risk populations are placed in the almost identical standard plan. This would yield the sort of risk segmentation the MSS must avoid to be successful.A more appealing option would be to permit underwriting for any plan with a premium of, for example, more than percent above the benchmark plan, as long as the plan is guaranteed renewable. This option would allow people who want to bear less financial risk to enroll in a more comprehensive plan without facing the risk that premiums for this plan will be artificially high because of people switching into the plan at the last minute when they anticipate needing health care services. If stable, such a structure could segment people with a low tolerance for financial risk without fully segmenting health care risk. This option was rejected for its complexity, but is worth more explora ti on as a vehicle for offering more insurance options. Nothing in the MSS explicitly bars the con ti nu ed existence of the non-group insurance market. If state regulations permit it, that market could offer Medigap-style coverage without conforming to the precise requirements of the MSS. In the MSS, neither exchanges nor health plans are permitted to refund to the individual any funds that may be available because the enrollee selected a low-cost plan. This provision is designed to create a true floor for insurance covera ge . This provision 180 does limit the extent of health plan competition in a very low-cost market. That is, since rebates are not available, all an efficient plan can do is add benefits, which may have an inflationary effect on overall health care spending. Despite this risk,the provision was adopted to en su re that competitive pressure does not result in poorer people, who may prefer cash in hand to better insurance covera ge , from becoming concentrated in a very low-cost, very lowquality plan that refunds a large portion of the premium to the enrollee, but offers little in the way of health insurance protection. The MSA option offers a realistic insurance option for people who are willing to take significant personal financial risk, while limiting the likelihood of risk segm en t a ti on . Strong opponents of MSAs argue that people willing to accept financial risk have disproportionately high incomes, and, because income is correlated with health status, they are likely to have lower-than-average costs. Removing this population from the larger risk pool yi el d s higher premiums for everyone else. Strong proponents of MSAs argue that they are the only realistic mechanism for creating price sensitivity and full choice of provider among individual users of health care services. While MSA proponents claim that MSAs have not shown great success in the market because of the regulatory burdens associated with the existing MSA demonstration, evidence from the rest of the health insurance market suggests that the more likely reason is that only a relatively small portion of the population is willing to bear the amount of financial risk inherent in the MSA st ructure. The MSS includes an MSA option because it is believed that the cost to the rest of the population is small compared with the gain that will accrue to MSA participants. The five-year lock-in requirement for MSAs is designed to reduce their risk segmentation aspects,although the requirement will not eliminate such aspects entirely. Employers may continue to offer health insurance benefits to their employees even after establishment of the MSS for the same reasons that they choose to do so today: to gain a competitive advantage when recruiting employees, or to pursue particular wellness goals among their workforce. Employers should be encouraged to play this role if they can offer their employees benefits that go beyond those available from health exchanges. Some of these benefits could include improved health plan selecti on , oversight, and information, or reduced employee cost sharing. Employees working for exempt employers are barred from the health insurance exchange system. This provision exists to prevent employers from en co u ra ging their highest-cost employees to shift their costs to the publicly financed program, either through the structure of their employee subsidies or through more direct pressure on the employee. This restriction on employee choice is unfortunate, but it is necessary to protect the integrity of the system. The existence of this restriction provides a strong justification for enforcing the standards imposed on employers that wish to be exempt. It also creates a need for individual premium subsidies, discussed below. Financing The Medical Security System relies on three sources for financing. The primary source of funding is a payroll tax. Additional government revenues supplement the payroll tax, and individual prem iu m contributions by some participants also finance the system. Design The payroll tax forms the core of MSS financing. It is designed to emulate the current system by having employers co ll ect the portion paid by employees and combine that amount with the employer’s contribution. However, as a tax, the system operates in an equitable manner by requiring the participation of all firms, in contrast to the current voluntary structure. The precise structure of the payroll tax is not critical to the design. To illustrate, a financing system is presented with the split between employer and employee contributions divided percent/ percent, approximately the same division that exists today for family coverage at the t ypical firm. Again, 181 for illustration, the proposal applies the tax to the current Social Security wage base. A combined employer/employee tax rate of percent applied to the Social Security wage base in would yield approximately the billion spent on private health insurance premiums that year. While participation in part of the Social Security system is currently optional for state and local government employees, that would not be the case for the MSS, thereby providing a larger tax base. Consistent with how Social Security taxes currently opera te , selfemployed persons would pay the combined employer and employee rate. Public financing beyond the payroll tax will be necessary to generate sufficient funds to provide coverage to all Americans. If the payroll tax genera te s approximately the resources currently spent on private coverage, additional resources will be needed to cover those currently without health insurance and those covered through public programs. One source of public financing is a portion of current expenditures on Medicaid and the State Children’s Health In su ra n ce Program (S-CHIP). Since coverage for these populations comes through the MSS, appropriations to these programs can be redirected to the MSS. Some current public expenditures will be needed for special subsidies, discussed below. Thus, current spending on Medicaid and S-CHIP, less the amount needed to provide other subsidies, will be available to fund the MSS. The MSS provides every individual with the opportunity to participate in any health plan offered by any health exchange. However, only some insurance options available through the exchange will be available at no cost. For higher-cost plans, individual contributions will be necessary. These funds will be paid to the exchange and passed on to the appropriate health plan. Rationale The MSS fully uncouples financing from enrollment in health insurance. Thus, the MSS could function using any funding source, ranging from a portion of general tax revenues to a per capita assessment. The decision to rely primarily on a payroll tax is an effort to balance various implications of these different funding mechanisms. The payroll tax has the advantage of emulating the current system of financing health insurance reasonably closely. Most non-elderly Americans receive coverage through work, meaning that we already rely on an employment-based financing system. Despite the view of most economists that employees pay the full cost of insurance provided through the workplace, as a practical matter employees perceive that they share costs with their employer. To minimize disruption,the MSS emulates this division. The MSS includes a major shift by imposing a flat tax rate on a capped portion of earnings. This stands in contrast to how health plans charge firms, which varies by employee age and family structure, but not by income. It also stands in contrast to how employees observe their payments, which are generally based only on family structure, with no variation in employee (or employer) contribution based on the employee’s salary. How the underlying costs of health insurance are actually borne by employees within a firm depends at least on labor market conditions, the complex tax treatment of health benefits, and, probably, on the market for the firm’s goods. It is impossible (and not necessarily desirable) to determine the precise incidence of health care costs today and create a tax system that emulates it. In the MSS, the goal is to approximate the current structure while achieving the added goals of equity and universality. Setting aside the problem of disrupti on , and, therefore, of likely political opposition, some would argue that all funding for the MSS should come from general revenues, generated from the relatively progressive federal income tax. This funding option has the advantage of greater vertical equity (higherincome people pay a much larger share of total income taxes collected than they do of total Social Security taxes collected). It also presumably has less of a negative effect on job creation than a significant payroll tax. Yet, it is difficult to imagine this large a shift in the financial burden associated with health 182 insurance. The salary base of the MSS payroll tax is capped for the same reason: concern that a new financing system with dramatically increased costs for high earners is not politically viable. All payments into the MSS are based on earnings and decisions about the type of coverage an individual desires; none is based on the enrollee’s health status. Some people believe this is an inefficient design, because it reduces the financial incentive for people to adopt healthful behaviors. The MSS rejects incorporating health status into the financing mechanism, based on the notion that other financial consequences associated with unhealthful behavior remain,and that individuals should not be penalized for incurring health care costs that are not attributable to individual behavior. Total funding for the MSS is determined by the cost of providing the benchmark plan to all eligible people. The amount of revenue the payroll tax generates will vary with the cycles of the economy. Since general tax revenues must make up the balance, the MSS design creates some uncertainty in projecting future federal budget demands.Given the size of the MSS, even a modest degree of error could have significant implications for the overall federal budget. The MSS retains a significant role for individual expenditures for health insurance. This design feature is important for two reasons.First, while health insurance exchanges can exert some bargaining pressure on health plans and providers to hold down costs, real pressure for efficiency will come from individuals selecting from among their plan options to obtain their preferred combination of price and quality. Second, to be affordable,a universal coverage system must guarantee to everyone a level of coverage that is less generous than some people will desire. The individual purchasing option allows those who wish to spend more than average on health care to do so. Relationship between Financing and Benefits From among the standard benefits plans, the one with the lowest actuarial value is termed the benchmark plan. The total resources necessary to pay pre- miums for all Americans en ro ll ed in the MSS are determined by multiplying the cost of the benchmark plan (including health care and administrative costs) by the number of Americans under age , less those covered by exempt employers. The premium do ll a rs are allocated to each health exchange based on the number of enrollees in that exchange, with allocations weighted to reflect the age and gender mix of each exchange’s enrollees. Knowing the per capita premium dollars available, each exchange contracts with participating health plans. The exchange must offer at least one no-cost plan, so the exchange must solicit bids that exactly equal the per capita premium dollars available. By design, the no-cost bids on average should precisely match the benchmark plan. However, depending on health care costs in that market and the efficiency of the plans that operate there,the nocost bids could be for a plan somewhat ri ch er or somewhat leaner than the benchmark plan. Plans will also bid to offer higher-cost benefit designs, with the individual enrollee required to pay the cost differential between the benchmark and the highercost plan. It must be emphasized that the MSS opera te s with a defined contribution design. That is, while various benefit packages are defined,and the level of funding is designed to be sufficient to cover the benchmark package for everyone, the actual coverage available to any person will be whatever health plans can offer, given the premium payments they receive on behalf of their enrollees. Other Subsidies Two groups will find that a standard package of insurance benefits does not meet their needs. One is made up of people with very low incomes for whom the modest copayment and deductible provisions of a standard package create barriers to access to care. The second group includes people with disabilities who need services that go beyond those provided by traditional health insurance benefits. The MSS includes sep a ra te subsidy systems to address the needs of these two groups. In addition, the tax system subsidizes low-income employees of exempt 183 employers whose premium burden may be more than they can afford to bear. Design Since at least one plan in every exchange is offered at no cost,there are no premium subsidies to individuals based on income. However, in the MSS, states will administer a system that permits individuals in low-income families to obtain a copayment waiver, allowing them to obtain medical services without making copayments or meeting deductibles. Eligibility for waivers is guaranteed for everyone with income below poverty and all other current mandatory Medicaid eligible populations, but states may adopt broader eligibility standards.Eligibility is for one year and must be renewed annually. While individuals who qualify for the waiver will likely be concentrated in no-cost plans, some may choose to enroll in plans that charge premiums. These plans could have larger cost-sharing requirements than the no-cost plan. Complete forgiveness from cost-sharing requirements could create a windfall to the enrollee and add incentives for plan design and selection. Therefore, the waiver will be designed based on its application to the benchmark plan. For qualifying individuals in other plans, the waiver will be a credit against cost sharing designed to have the same actuarial value as the complete waiver for the benchmark plan. All administration of the cost-sharing waiver will be the responsibility of the health plans and the state, with no financial risk to or involvement of the provider or the exchange. Under Medicaid, low-income children are currently el i gi ble for a broader range of health care services than are found in a typical private insurance plan. As a part of the MSS,all children in families that receive the cost-sharing waiver will also receive state-administered fee-for-service coverage for that additional set of services. People who qualify for Medicaid on the basis of disability currently receive a set of medical and supportive services that are not found in private insurance plans. This portion of the Medicaid program will continue to exist. However, since everyone will be eligible to participate in the MSS, the disability component of Medicaid will function as a wraparound to the core set of benefits. Financing for all of these subsidy programs will retain the existing Medicaid matching structure between the federal government and the states. Matching funds are available to states that extend copayment subsidies beyond the mandatory populations. Matching funds (for premium costs only) are also available if a state chooses to offer premium subsidies to low-income individuals, even though the MSS has no provision for such subsidies. Beyond these requirements, states may use their own funds to offer whatever subsidies they wish to low- and moderate-income individuals or people with special health care needs. Low-income employees of exempt employers are required to participate in their employer’s health plan. While an exemption is available only if the employer pays a large portion of the premium, the employee may still face a significant financial burden to pay for coverage—a burden that low-income employees whose firms are not exempt do not face. Therefore, the MSS includes a refundable tax credit for these employees. The credit would cover percent of the actual cost to the employee of enrolling in the employer’s plan for people with adjusted gross incomes below the poverty line, with the amount of the credit phasing out to zero when income reaches percent of the poverty line. Rationale The goal of these provisions is to ensure that lowincome populations can participate in the mainstream health care delivery system. Underlying the MSS design is the notion that all Americans should have access to a good health insurance plan,and that empirical evidence shows that all Americans are sufficiently price sensitive that a relatively heterogeneous group of people will select a no-cost plan. Cost-sharing exemptions and wraparound benefits permit low-income populations to participate in the same health plans as the rest of the population. These provisions create some administrative complexity and raise concerns about coordination of benefits and service delivery systems. However, those risks are viewed as less substantial than the 184 risk of an inadequate or substandard health care system for low-income people and/or for people with disabilities if these groups are segregated from the general system. The decision to fold Medicaid and S-CHIP into the MSS is sure to be controversial. There has always been a tension within the Medicaid program based on whether it should seek to provide mainstream health care to its enrollees or cultivate relationships with a limited set of providers that have the experience and cultural competence to serve a financially disadvantaged population. A case can be made for either approach; however, in the context of true universal coverage, the former approach is more sustainable and defensible. In a universal system, a special set of rules for a needy group will always be under attack. The MSS seeks to eliminate these boundaries and keep the en ti re population in one system. It is likely that within the MSS, groups of what we now think of as safety net providers will form health plans, as they have done in the Medicaid program, to compete for the population accustomed to obtaining services from them. This is consistent with the benefits of keeping the en ti re population in a single financing system. Of particular importance is the decision to have no direct special subsidies of premiums for lowincome individuals. Isolating such subsidies from the rest of the health care system creates serious risks that the subsidy will decline over time or in times of budget pressure, leaving this group in a de facto segregated system. It creates arbitrary distinctions among people with different incomes who must be deemed deserving of the subsidy, often on the basis of very limited information about their real health care needs or the real costs they face purchasing health care. If they are large, such subsidies can also create the risk of significant work disincentives as income increases and the subsidy is phased out. Such subsidies also create tremendous administrative burdens. The decision to include a refundable tax credit for low-wage workers in exempt firms is an effort to make the best out of a difficult challenge. For riskselection reasons, employees in exempt firms are not permitted to participate in the health exchange. However, they will then face premium costs that may be prohibitive. Subsidizing employees based on their salary is inefficient, because it adds an administrative burden for the employer, and an individual’s salary may not reflect his or her family resources. Therefore,the tax system is used to transfer funds to truly needy families who are required to purchase coverage through their employers. The System as Viewed by Various Actors Individual Enrollees Individuals may choose to obtain their coverage through any exchange operating in their area, and they may choose from among any of the plans offered by the exchange. There will always be at least one no-cost option, but other plans will require a premium payment on the part of the consumer. Most people will presumably take active steps to select an exchange and a source of insurance coverage from among the various options available. However, some people will fail to fo ll ow this process. Health care providers will have the option (and the strong financial incentive) to enter into an arrangement with one or more exchanges and health plans to permit people who present for services and are not yet enrolled in a plan to be enrolled at the time of servi ce . Unlike existing public programs, the MSS has no recertification or reapplication processes. Enrollment in an exchange and a health plan are continuous until an active step is taken to enroll elsewhere. Therefore, over time, enrollment in the system will be essentially universal. While this paper uses the term,“individuals,” to refer to enrollees,most people will enroll as families. A series of issues arises when a family has one member who works for an exempt employer, and another member who either does not work or works for a firm without an exemption. I have not attempted to work out the details of the family choices and cash flows in such a circumstance; however, this is an important area for further work. Employers Employers must choose whether to seek an exemption. The system is designed to make exemption a 185 In a universal system, a special set of rules for a needy group will always be under attack. The MSS seeks to eliminate these boundaries and keep the entire population in one system. reasonably attractive option, as large employers can serve as innovators in the health care system. Employers may also wish to offer a higher level of benefits than the MSS does, and there should be no barriers to a firm that wishes to do so. Non-exempt employers must collect and pay the payroll tax. This function will be similar to the activities currently performed in the Federal Insurance Contributions Act (FICA) system, and will add administrative and financial burdens to firms. Exempt employers may contract with health plans or self-insure, as they may do today. Health Plans Insurance plans face a very different environment under the MSS than they do today. The MSS brings into the insurance system the tens of millions of Americans who are currently uninsured and whose demand for health care services is not fully known. Guaranteed issue and community rating for all products is an environment unfamiliar to most plans. Contracting with many potential health insurance exchanges creates new responsibilities. The possibility of large swings in plan enrollment in the early years creates significant risks. At the same time,plans operating in a universal-coverage system have a large new pool of potential customers. Disruption could be significant in the short run. The va ri ety of new risks taken on by health plans comes at a cost, suggesting the need for relatively generous assumptions about program financing in early years. After a transition peri od , it is reasonable to expect that the MSS actually would reduce the risk health plans face. Churning of en ro ll ees should decline substantially as insurance provision is uncoupled from the workplace. Continuous insurance coverage should reduce the cost health plans face because the build-up of demand for servi ce s during spells without insurance should disappear, and increased disease severity due to delayed medical treatment should decline. Movement toward community rating should force plans that rely heavily on underwriting out of the market, leaving a more heterogeneous risk pool for the remaining plans. In the early years, plans can expect their contracts and nego ti a ti ons with health insurance exchanges to be similar to current practices among purchasing pools. For example, payments to the exchanges through the MSS will be adjusted for age and gender, so plans will submit bids to health insurance exchanges that emulate the age and gender categories used by the MSS. If plan bids are higher than the amount available through the MSS, the balance will be charged to the individual enrollee as a premium. Over time these relationships may change. For example, one could imagine exchanges developing a cost-neutral risk-adjustment payment system for health plans. If effective, such systems would benefit the plans, since premium payments received would reflect expected costs more accurately. The value of this benefit would be reflected in lower bids for coverage through the innovative exchange, attracting more en ro ll ees and ultimately ben ef i ting the consumer. Federal and State Governments The federal government has five responsibilities in the MSS. First, it must collect payroll taxes. With a structure parallel to that used in FICA,it seems natural to give this task to the Social Sec u ri ty Administra ti on , or a partner agency operating in conjunction with the SSA. Tax receipts would function in essentially the same manner as Social Security receipts. Second, the government must define distinct geographic areas that serve as the catchment areas for health insurance exchanges. This is an extremely 186 complex and important task. The goal is to balance two competing interests: On the one hand, all insurance products are community rated within the area, and, as discussed below, payments to exchanges may be adjusted by region. Therefore,the areas must correspond somewhat with existing health care market boundaries. On the other hand, exchanges benefit from scale and a minimum number of borders with other areas. This argues for relatively large regions. Third, the government must license health insurance exchanges. While the formal requirements for exchanges are limited, they can create trem en dous problems if they fail, misappropriate funds, or use risk-se gmenting behaviors. Therefore, oversight of the exchanges will be required.A federal license will be necessary to receive any funds from the MSS. Fourth, the government must define the process for making payments to licensed exchanges. Among other items, the government must determine the relative payments to be made for enrollees in each age and gender grouping used to define payments. Fifth, the government must grant exemptions to qualifying firms. State governments have roles, as described above, in operating subsidy systems for low-income enrollees and people with disabilities. State governments are responsible for establishing one or more health insurance exchanges if the private market does not do so. In addition, states retain their existing authority to license health plans that operate in their states and enforce market con du ct , solvency, and network adequacy rules. Health Care Providers As a modification of the financing system, the MSS has no direct effect on health care providers, but many implications flow from the system. Under the MSS, levels of uncompensated care should fall significantly, affecting the financial strength of many health care institutions. By uncoupling financing from enrollment, changes in health insurance coverage should be less frequent, thereby creating more stable medical and financial relationships between patients and providers. The MSS raises the possibil- ity of increased consolidation in the health plan market with its attendant benefits of reduced complexity, but perhaps lower reimbursement ra te s because of the reduced relative negotiating power of providers. System Calibration While the paper thus far has set forth the general structure of the Medical Sec u ri ty System, certain details are crucial to the program’s success. In addition, in a dynamic economy and health care environment, the MSS must have built into it balancing tensions that will ensure the system’s proper functioning. This section examines in more detail three aspects of the MSS: the benchmark benefits package,the balance between payroll tax and other funding sources, and regional variation. The Benchmark Benefits Package The various standard benefits packages exist to create a series of comparable options that facilitate an effective market for health insurance. These packages will be most helpful in this role if they represent typical plans that people obtain today through their place of employment or in the individual market. Beyond that, the details of each package are unimportant, because plans are free to offer any benefit design. Failure to specify these plans well will have limited effect on the overall MSS. The one standard package that serves as the benchmark plan plays a very substantial role. The cost of this plan for an average-risk person multiplied by the number of people in the MSS determines the total funding necessary to support the system. On avera ge , the benchmark plan is what participants in the MSS will receive at no cost. Proper definition of the benchmark plan is critical for political reasons. It is not credible to propose a universal health insurance plan where the guaranteed coverage is far below what most people experience today. Even if, in the end, the payroll tax were set lower than the current contribution toward coverage through employer-sponsored insurance, and individuals had sufficient resources left over to buy their way into a plan comparable to what they have 187 today, the politics of a scaled-back standard package would be unacceptable. An adequate benchmark plan is also critical for substantive reasons. If the benchmark plan is too lean, most Americans will want to purchase a richer plan, leaving the lowest-income group that cannot afford to pay for premiums out of their own pockets segregated in inadequate, no-cost plans. An inadequate benchmark plan also creates concerns about risk selection, discussed below. Similar problems arise if the benchmark plan is too rich. The political problem is that the tax levels necessary to support the MSS will be high—more for many people than they are paying for premiums today. Substantively, an excessively rich benefits package will stifle competi ti on among plans and allocate society’s resources toward health care above the value those resources provide. Between these two bounds, the appropriate level of benefits in the benchmark plan is a matter of social choice: How much of the cost of health care should be spread across all Americans, and how much should be borne by the individual? At the outset,the benchmark plan and its actuarial value must be determined through an administrative process. But the political process must be relied on to maintain the appropriate balance between the extremes. The benchmark package is very visible. Failure of the MSS to provide most Americans with benefits at least as good as the benchmark package will create political pressure to expand the resources available to purchase the package. Health plans will compete to offer the most desirable no-cost plan, helping to maintain the strength of the package available to enrollees at no charge. Yet, as the package becomes richer, there will be strong pressures to reduce the payroll tax. The universality of the system, in terms of benefits received and taxes paid, helps prevent significant erosion or expansion of the benefits. Balance Across Funding Sources Most firms that choose to be exempt are likely to make this decision based on negotiated benefits in a labor contract or a desire for greater control over benefit costs. However, two groups of employers could select exempt status for simple financial rea- sons: firms with a healthier-than-average workforce and firms with higher-than-average salaries. For the first group, insurance purchased on the open market will cost less than average. Since the payroll tax assessment is based on broad averages,there is a cost advantage to having an exemption. For the second group, the payroll tax assessment will impose a higher-than-average burden that can be avoided if the firm purchases its own coverage. For both groups,the problem is the gap between the cost of participating in the payroll tax-based system and the benefits the firm’s employees gain from the insurance provided in that system. Of course, a firm takes on substantial administrative costs when it administers its own health insurance benefits, and the three-year lock-in for the exemption means the firm must be confident that its status is fairly stable. Still, if a significant number of firms are in either of these positions,they could start a death spiral in the MSS in which lower-risk and higher-revenue populations withdraw, leaving high-cost and low-revenue people in the system. The best mechanism to prevent this dynamic is to set the payroll tax to collect only a portion of the program’s costs and rely on general revenues to fill in the balance. Under this design,a firm that chooses to be exempt avoids the cost of the payroll tax, but gives up a benefit that is greater than the cost to the average firm. The proper mixture of revenue sources is difficult to determine in advance. If a large number of employers seek to change their exemption status, that may be a sign that the system is out of balance, and the funding mixture needs to be adjusted. Regional Variation As described thus far, the funding provided to health insurance exchanges for the average-risk enrollee is the same around the country. While the system could work this way, the result would be a no-cost plan that is much ri ch er than the benchmark plan in low-cost regions, and a very lean nocost plan in high-cost areas. This outcome has political and practical problems. One solution is to adjust payments to exchanges by region based on va ri a ti on in health care costs. This would lead to 188 more comparable benefits around the country. An alternative is to adjust payment to exchanges based on general salary levels. This provides regional equity, since each region in essence keeps the funds it raises through the payroll tax. While either solution assures some comparability of benefits around the country, neither addresses a more complex issue: the possibility that people in different regions place a different value on health care spending. These different values could reflect the wealth of the region—people in wealthier regions may feel they can devote more of t h ei r resources to health than to other priorities. Alternatively, these values could reflect the efficiency of the health care system, with people in some regions feeling that an inefficient health care delivery system does not yield solid value for the money. If there were an effective political process that could capture these regional va ri a ti on s , it would make sense for the payroll tax rate to vary by region to reflect these differences. As a practical matter, this process could be undertaken by states, but state boundaries generally do not correspond with health insurance market boundaries. Therefore, while desirable in theory, it may not be possible in practice to design a system that varies taxing and spending levels around the country. Thus, the MSS as proposed provides areaadjusted payments to health insurance exchanges. This is not a perfect solution to the dilemmas discussed above, but it does assure a reasonable amount of equity until a better design emerges. Other Issues Risk Selection One purpose of a universal health care system is to spread the risk of health costs across a broad population. If the system leads to a concentration of relatively high- or low-risk groups into one health plan, the benefits of that risk sharing are lost. One opportunity for risk selection is through s el ective marketing of insurance products and/or benefit packages designed to appeal particularly to certain low-risk populations. Through these techniques, a health plan, or a plan in conjunction with an exchange, could direct low-risk populations to specific plans where they would have low premiums, forcing higher premiums on participants in other plans. Three features of the MSS are designed to reduce this risk. First, all products offered by all exchanges must be community rated and must be offered on a guaranteed-issue basis. At the outset, this feature prevents explicit underwriting that would guide only certain populations into certain plans. In addition, it creates instability for any successful risk segmentation endeavors. If an effort to select favorable risk succeeds,the benefits of that selection are available to anyone who wishes to enroll. This reduces the incentive for plans to select, because their benefits are transitory, and it reduces the likelihood that such efforts would succeed even if they were to be undertaken. Second, a plan is limited in how much financial reward it can provide its enrollees as a result of successful risk selection. That is,no rebates are available to program participants, so a plan with very low costs can reward its low-risk enrollees with lower premiums only to a certain point. But that point is not likely to be particularly low, because the benchmark plan will represent a decent benefits package for a mixed-risk population. Beyond that point, all the plan has to offer its enrollees is richer benefits— precisely the sort of behavior that runs counter to its risk-selecting objectives. Of course, the plan can benefit from selection, by making profits on the gap between the premiums it receives and the health care costs it incurs. But it is not clear why even healthy people would choose a lean benefits package over a richer one. Thus, even though plans have an incentive to obtain low-risk enrollees,plans will find it difficult to target this population. Third, size requirements argue against extensive risk-selection activities. It is reasonable to project that a modest number of fairly large health plans will dominate each health care market under the MSS. These plans require such a large number of en ro ll ees to succeed that it is difficult to imagine them having significant, effective risk-selection efforts. Smaller plans, to succeed, will need to differentiate themselves. While marketing based on net- 189 work quality or service might be successful for a small plan,it is difficult to imagine a successful risksegmentation campaign on behalf of a small plan. A related concern is that a health insurance exchange could become a front for an aggressive risk-selecting health plan. While complying with exchange requirements by offering a full range of plans, the exchange could market very selectively, perform some informal underwriting activities, and channel low-risk people to a preferred health plan. As with the plans themselves, exchanges would find that the potential rewards of this behavior are quite small, yielding very little incentive to seek out lowrisk enrollees. Aside from inten ti onal efforts by plans or exchanges to find low-risk enrollees, selection can occur as a natural event when enrollees are offered different health plans. People with greater health care needs have good reason to select plans with more comprehensive benefits. Evidence from the Federal Employees Health Benefits Program (FEHBP) and other large employers confirms that health plans offering more comprehensive benefits experience adverse risk selection. The best buffer against these risk-selection problems is to develop and maintain a strong benchmark plan. The benchmark plan must represent good enough coverage that a heterogeneous profile of individuals will enroll in it. While it is unavoidable that some share of higher-risk individuals will seek more comprehensive covera ge , the incentives to do so must not be so great that they result in total risk segmentation in the market. Annual open enrollment creates some barrier to people moving to richer plans when they anticipate having higher health care costs. However, beyond annual enrollment and a good benchmark, the MSS has no formal mechanism to prevent risk selection or to compensate plans or enrollees for risk selection taking place. Despite the likelihood that this will occur, no obvious alternative presents itself. Given the state of the art in risk-adjustment techniques,the administrative complexity of operating such systems for a large population, and their susceptibility to political manipulation,I conclude that no mandatory risk-adjustment system should be imposed as part of the MSS. (The incentive for health insurance exchanges to develop risk adjustment systems voluntarily is discussed above.) If the MSS succeeds in providing universal coverage at a cost to the individual that is primarily, but not entirely, separated from his or her personal risk of incurring health care costs, it will represent a significant step forward that can be improved on over time. Transition The MSS is a comprehensive insurance system that differs fundamentally from the current health care system in the United States. As such, movement to the MSS would require a substantial transition. The MSS was designed to illustrate a model, not to offer a straightforward path from the current system to one like it. There are two incremental steps that could be taken, however, that would represent significant movement toward the MSS, thereby smoothing the prospects for the transition. First, incremental steps could be taken to en co u ra ge the creation of entities like health care exchanges. Specifically, new requirements could be placed on employer-sponsored health insurance payments for them to retain their tax-exempt status. Modest steps would include requirements that employers offer standardized benefits packages or a ch oi ce of plans. A more substantial step would be permitting the tax exemption only if firms purchased insurance through some sort of a pooled purchasing arrangement. Alternatively, if a new system of individual tax credits for health insurance were developed, those credits could be made larger for people who purchase insurance through a pooled arrangement.Of course, obtaining support for these measures would be difficult, but they would begin to restructure the market in a manner consistent with how it would function under the MSS. Second,incremental steps could be taken to create a more equitable financing system for employersponsored health insurance. Employers could be rewarded for offering a larger subsidy to their lowerwage employees than they do to their higher-wage employees. Employers could be required to pay at least a specific portion of the cost of insurance for any of their expenditures to retain their tax-exempt 190 status. Employers that do not provide health insurance to their employees could face other requirements, such as a higher minimum wage. Setting aside incremental steps, a few features of the MSS are designed to minimize the disruption involved in the transition. Specifically, the level and split of the employer and employee payroll taxes are designed to emulate the dominant practice in the marketplace. The use of age- and gender-adjusted premium payments to exchanges, and then passing them along to health plans,is designed to retain the approximate structure of risk in the group insurance market. The employer exemption provisions are designed to encourage continuity among employers that are adding significant value to the health care system, not only by providing their employees with coverage, but also by promoting quality, choice, and information. These provisions, however, leave a substantial transition burden. Three major (and many minor) areas of risk arise in the transition. First, as noted above, in the early years of the MSS substantial risks are associated with premium and enrollment levels for health plans. Aside from the cost implications of these risks,there are broader system implications that create the possibility of program failure. The system will require sizable administrative systems to manage the many tasks associated with the program. Second, projections of tax revenue could be erroneous. Financing certainty is essential for effective opera ti on of the system. Health plans must know what resources are available when constructing their bids. The government may need to use general appropriations to cover the possibility of errors in this area. However, very large potential costs and much budgeting uncertainty are associated with the government taking on this responsibility. Third, the MSS shifts the cash flow of hundreds of billions of dollars in the health care system. Rather than making direct, monthly payments to health plans, employers will pay taxes to the government, which will transfer those funds to exchanges, which will then pass the funds to health plans. These additional steps introduce time and, given the sums involved ,s i gnificant cash flow costs.Once the system has been operating for a time, cash flow expectations can be adjusted. However, at the outset, the potential delay in cash flow could create significant costs. Cost Containment The MSS relies on two types of forces to contain costs. Political forces will determine the funds devoted to the guaranteed benefits package, with tax rates and appropriations to the program set through the political process. The program is designed to create broad interest among the general population that will ensure its continued political support. The expectation is that a large number of Americans will enroll in no-cost or very-low-cost plans, thereby ensuring that the value of the benchmark plan does not erode. In addition, the benchmark plan will form the base for people purchasing more expensive coverage, so all participants will have an interest in retaining a solid base. At the same time, aggressive competition among plans to serve that group will ensure that the benchmark plan is valued appropriately. With a defined contribution design,there is no direct translation between loading up the benchmark benefits package with additional services or providers and having those providers receive any benefit. Market forces will determine people’s willingness to pay for coverage beyond the basic package. This will be a large, contested market with plans charging premiums ranging in cost from zero to substantial. Competition among plans to provide an attractive no-cost plan will be intense. The limited evidence available today suggests that employees at all income levels are quite sensitive to price when selecting health plans if they have to bear the full cost of their decisions. All funding for health insurance beyond the no-cost plan will come from individuals making their own choices about the relative value of an additional bit of health insurance compared with their other priorities. Total health care spending will reflect the outcome of a political process that probably has somewhat expansionary tendencies, combined with a market process that creates much greater price sensitivity among individuals than exists today. It is impossible to know whether this total is larger or smaller than current health care spending. 191 Political Feasibility It is difficult to evaluate the political feasibility of the MSS in the current environment, in which serious health reforms are not even being discussed. Based on recent history, opposition to the plan would be strongest from the employer community, which would resist the payroll tax-based financing system. In the political debates, it would be easy to demonize the proposal by portraying it as highly disruptive to people’s current covera ge , as representing a federal takeover of the health care system, and as encouraging employers to drop covera ge , leaving people at the mercy of an untested government program. These rhetorical devices simply show that any serious reform of the health care system can be criticized. In fact, the MSS was designed with an eye toward minimizing disruption, while pursuing principles, such as equity and ch oi ce , that Americans value. Whether it has achieved these goals is a reasonable question. One area of political feasibility requires a bit more attention: the creation of horizontal equity. In the current voluntary, employer-based insurance system, employers can offer their employees anything from no coverage to very comprehensive coverage. A payroll tax shifts all employers to an equal financial burden (except those that choose to be exempt, but they retain a significant financial burden, as well). Proponents of market-based efficiency should applaud this move toward equity, because it will prevent one firm from gaining a competitive advantage in its product market at the expense of imposing a social burden by leaving its employees without health insurance. However, despite the logical argument behind horizontal equity, we can expect significant opposition to this change in practice. One reason for the opposition is the fear that firms have of moving from a system where they can control their health expenditures, scaling them up in good economic times and when the labor market is tight,and scaling them down when the opposite is the case. Unfortunately, data on the range of costs employers incur for health care are limited. Based on the available data, we can say that the average insurance cost per employee across various meas- ures, such as firm size, industry, and average wage, rarely varies from the national mean by more than percent. These data do not tell us how much variance there is around the mean within any category. However, they do offer some evidence that, despite the control employers have over their costs, employers that offer coverage tend to spend (combining employer and employee contributions) within a reasonably narrow range. This suggests that enforced horizontal equity, while having a very real effect on those firms that do not offer coverage at all, will have a modest effect on firms that already provide coverage. Equity, Efficiency, and Choice A fair system has horizontal equity—people in like circumstances are treated the same—and vertical equity—people with more ability to bear a burden take on a larger share. Equitable systems, however, often come at the cost of efficient use of resources. And when discussing health insurance where certain actors can benefit financially from risk segmentation, it is tempting to achieve equity at the cost of reducing or eliminating choice. No single plan can achieve perfect equity, efficiency, and choice, but the MSS is designed to maximize all three va lu e s . The system has horizontal equity by requiring financial participation from all actors. It has vertical equity through the payroll tax financing system. Efficiency emerges from the economic pressures inherent in health plan and health insurance exchange competition for enrollees, and individual price sensitivity for benefits beyond the benchmark level. Ch oi ce is constrained in some regards, but most people will observe much greater health plan and provider ch oi ce than they have today. Quality and Access The MSS is structured around health plans. I consider this a positive step for pursuit of health care quality. Despite heated debates about HMOs and the quality of care they provide, it is difficult to dispute the notion that organized systems of care are essential to creating data and systems that have the potential to improve health care quality. These systems are 192 a necessary, although not a sufficient, condition for improving quality. Because the MSS encourages development of those systems, it encourages the conditions that support quality improvement efforts. By structuring market competi ti on around health plans,the MSS does more to promote quality than do reforms that rely on market forces at the point of service. With extremely poor data currently available on individual providers, reforms that expect individuals to make value-sensitive choices every time they select a provider are certain to encourage competition almost exclusively on price. While we are far from the potential in this area, it is possible that competitive health plan selection could occur on the basis of quality as well as price. A uniform payroll tax applied around the country with proceeds directed locally will tend to push health care spending to a uniform proportion of the economy. Other funding sources, such as general federal appropriations and federal matching funds to assist people with low incomes and with disabilities, may have a more skewed distribution. Still, the payroll tax base could be a significant force for generating more equitable distribution of health care resources. In the end, the MSS is designed as a health care financing system, not as a mechanism for directly addressing the distribution of health care resources. Eliminating the problem of uninsurance, and dramatically reducing the phenomenon of underinsurance, should yield substantial improvements in access and quality. However, these areas require additional atten ti on beyond reform of the health care financing system. Conclusion The Medical Security System is offered as a proposal for achieving true universal health insurance coverage in the United States. It is an imperfect proposal, with many complex areas still to be defined. The trem en dous importance people place on health security makes any transition from the current system difficult to achieve. Yet, a vision of a fair and efficient system can help us think about the direction incremental steps should take today, and help prepare us for a time when universal coverage returns to the center of the American political agenda. n 193 Wicks, Meyer, and Silow-Carroll Proposal Key Elements Elliot K. Wicks, Jack A. Meyer, and Sharon Silow-Carroll have outlined a proposal to achieve universal health coverage while maintaining a market-based system and simplifying administration. Key elements of the proposal include the following: , payable in advance, for all households, with the credit varying by income, sufficient for those below the federal poverty level to cover the full cost of coverage comparable to Medicaid and gradually reduced for higher-income people. at least as comprehensive as Medicare plus drugs and well-child care. Those not meeting the requirement would be automatically covered by Medicare as a backup but would have to pay a premium plus a penalty (at tax time) for every month without private coverage. (but not necessarily pay for) a minimum benefits plan no less comprehensive than Medicare. that permits employees to exclude from their taxable income the amount that their employer pays for health coverage. , or aggregate purchasing arrangements, to serve as a source of health coverage for individuals and small employers. Insurers are required to participate and offer a standard benefits plan comparable to Medicare. , coordination of benefits, etc., to reduce administrative duplication and inefficiency. 194 About the Authors . , .., is Senior Fellow at the Economic and Social Research Institute and Senior Consultant with Health Management Associates. Dr. Wicks specializes in analysis of policy reforms to help bring affordable health coverage to more Americans,especially workers in small firms. He has extensive knowledge of arrangements of pooled purchasing of health coverage and recently directed a project to investigate the barriers to the success of health purchasing cooperatives. Other recent research includes a study of small-group market reform and employers’ and consumers’ use of health plan report cards. Dr. Wicks is the author of numerous articles and monographs on these and other subjects related to health care financing and delivery. Dr. Wicks has worked for health care consulting firms, policy research institutes, a trade association, and state government, and he was formerly a faculty member at Michigan State University. He has a Ph.D. in Economics and Social Policy from Syracuse University and an M.A.in Economics from Northwestern University. . , .., is the founder and President of the Economic and Social Research Institute. Dr. Meyer has conducted policy analysis and directed research on health care issues for several major foundations as well as federal and state government. He has led projects developing policy options for reforming the overall health care system and directed research on community-wide reforms covering all regions of the U.S. Many of these projects have highlighted new strategies for overcoming barriers to health care access and innovative designs for extending health insurance coverage to the unin- sured. Dr. Meyer is the author of numerous books, monographs, and articles on topics including health care, welfare reform, and policies to reduce poverty. He has also directed recent studies on the viability of safety net providers, Medicaid managed care for people with disabilities, the conversion of public hospitals to private status, and assessments of reform proposals to extend health coverage to workers in small firms. Dr. Meyer holds a Ph.D. in Economics from Ohio State University. - , ..., ..., is Senior Research Manager at the Economic and Social Research Institute. She has conducted health policy analysis for more than ten years, specializing in assessing health care reform strategies that expand coverage to vulnerable populations. Recent projects include examining employers’ attitudes about their current and future involvement in providing health coverage, reviewing community-based health plans for uninsured individuals, and profiling state and local initiatives to expand employer-based health coverage among the working uninsured. Ms. SilowCarroll is the author of In Sickness and In Health? The Marriage Between Employers and Health Care, which analyzes the corporate/employer role in providing health care coverage from economic, social and cultural perspectives. She has written numerous reports and articles reviewing public and private sector programs aimed at enhancing access, containing costs, and improving quality of care. Ms. Silow-Caroll received an M.B.A. in Health Care Management from the Wharton School, and an M.S.W. from the University of Pennsylvania School of Social Work. 195 A Plan for Achieving Universal Health Coverage Combining the New with the Best of the Past by Elliot K. Wicks, Jack A. Meyer, and Sharon Silow-Carroll No Americans should be denied access to needed medical care because they lack health insurance coverage, and no health care providers should go unpaid because they treat people who lack the means to pay for care. This proposition is the guiding principle underlying the proposal for universal health coverage that we develop in this paper. We have designed a system that achieves universal coverage by (a) providing generous subsidies in the form of tax credits for those with limited ability to pay, (b) mandating that everyone buy coverage from one source or another, (c) establishing Medicare as a temporary backup payer for those who fail to purchase coverage, and (d) establishing aggregate purchasing arrangements. The system is built on the foundation of current private health plans and employment-based coverage. Our plan addresses only the non-elderly population; the Medicare program for the elderly would remain as a separate program. Objectives Our approach is based on a vision of the way health care financing should look. It seeks to achieve the following objectives. Universal Coverage Large numbers of Americans are without health coverage—about million by the latest count— and this number has been rising, even in the face of the longest period of sustained prosperity in U.S. history. Many other citizens have inadequate coverage that does not protect them from incurring unaffordable medical bills in the case of a serious illness or injury or does not encourage use of costeffective preventive and primary care services. Many people lose coverage when they lose or change jobs. Although there are programs to cover poor children and families, many low-income individuals and working families are not eligible for public subsidy programs and cannot afford to buy coverage privately. We are proposing a plan to correct these problems. We believe that any plan to achieve universal coverage must include two features: a federal mandate that everyone have covera ge , and substantial subsidies to make coverage affordable for everyone. Those features are already embodied in Medicare, the plan that covers essentially everyone over the age of . In enacting Medicare, we decided as a society that ensuring access to needed medical care for the elderly population was so important that we were willing to impose a degree of compulsion to achieve universal covera ge . Using the same rationale, we believe that a mandate for coverage can be justified as a way to ensure access for people of all ages and to achieve fairness—by eliminating “free-riders,” those who do not buy coverage but use the medical system’s resources in em er gencies. Our plan would en su re that no one is ever “between” coverage or otherwise falls through the cracks. This objective is achieved by establishing an individual mandate and by making Medicare the default payer for those who nevertheless fail to get coverage (with disincentives for individuals to rely permanently on Medicare coverage). Reduced Fragmentation, Duplication, and Inequities of Public Subsidy Programs The current public financing system is highly fragmented and unduly complicated. There are many different types of subsidy programs, each with dif- 196 ferent el i gi bi l i ty criteria and benefit structures. As people’s circumstances change, they become ineligible for one program but may not be eligible for others, or they may be eligible but not know they are. Some people are reluctant to enroll because of the stigma associated with public programs. As a consequence, people fall through the cracks. The subsidy system is far from seamless. Few people can keep track of all the system’s features, especially because of constant policy changes,and it inevitably is bureaucratic, duplicative, and expensive to administer. Current subsidies are also unfair. Because the major public financing progra m s ,e s pecially Medicaid, permit substantial local discretion in setting eligibility standard s ,i n equities abound. People in equal circumstances are not treated equally. Needy people in some parts of the country have no coverage, while similarly situated people in other parts of the country have comprehensive coverage. We have a multitiered system of care based in part on income and in part on where people live and their state’s eligibility and benefits standards. If the objective is to provide access to appropriate care to all needy people, it is hard to defend the current system. In addition, the subsidy system for the nonpoor—the income tax provisions that allow employer-paid health premiums to be excluded from employees’ taxable income—favors higher-income people over lower-income people. Higher-income people often work for employers who pay more toward coverage, so more income is tax-exem pt ;a n d because they have higher marginal tax rates, the tax exclusion is worth more to them. Government’s taxexpenditure cost is very high—. billion in federal money and . billion in state tax losses in .1 The approach we propose eliminates the patchwork of subsidy approaches and multiple public programs, the burdensome and expensive administrative procedures for determining eligibility, and the myriad complicated and constantly changing regulations. This objective is achieved by replacing 1 John Sheils, Paul Hogan, and Randall Haught. Health Insurance and Taxes: The Impact of Proposed Changes in Current Federal Policy. Report of The National Coalition on Health Care, October 18, 1999. most subsidy programs with a tax credit, basing eligibility for the credit on income alone. Simplified Administration The current administrative system for private health insurance is unnecessarily inefficient, wasteful, and burdensome for patients and providers. Time and resources are wasted because there is no centralized system for determining eligibility, identifying benefit limits, submitting claims for payment, and coordinating benefits. Many of the costs are borne by patients as they try to wend their way through the maze of claims submission and administration, and surely many costs that are legal obligations of insurers are actually paid out of pocket by patients because claims are never submitted or are not settled accurately. The system we propose would substantially reduce the burdens and costs borne by providers and patients related to determining the limits on benefits, filing claims, and coordinating benefits. This objective is ach i eved by establishing a nati onal cen tra l i zed electronic mechanism for paying claims and coordinating benefits. Maintaining the Role of Private Health Plans and Insurers as Sellers of Health Insurance Coverage The current system of private health plans and insurers works well for most Americans. Competition among health plans and insurers for business helps to promote efficiency and better service. In addition, recent changes in state and federal laws governing the sale of insurance to small employers have improved some aspects of performance. Though further changes may be needed, there seems to be little reason or political desire to abandon the basic structure of a private insurance system, and there is no obvious alternative on the horizon. The case for retaining the basics of the current system is strong. Continued Reliance on Employer-Sponsored Coverage and the Role of Employers as Poolers of Risk Employers play a major role in pooling risk; that is, they bring together people with different levels of risk who all pay a similar premium. Avoiding seg- 197 mentation of risk is a major challenge for any system, so it seems wise not to abandon a system that meets the need for risk pooling for a large portion of the population. In addition, much of the pressure and many of the ideas for cost control and quality improvement have origins in the employer community. The case is strong for con ti nuing to have employers be advocates for employees in purchasing coverage that offers good value. Features of the System Subsidies Every (non-elderly) American would be eligible for a health coverage subsidy in the form of a “refundable” tax credit that could be used to offset costs of covera ge , whether the premium is paid by the insured person (including those buying individual coverage) or by an employer on behalf of an employee. That is, a family’s income tax liability would be reduced by the amount of the credit, as long as the total of the employer and employee premium was equal to or greater than the credit. However, any premiums paid by the employer would be considered taxable income to the employee. Although the size of the tax credit would be larger for lower-income people, everyone would be eligible for the minimum credit. That minimum credit would be equal to the average value of the current federal income tax exclusion to those who have employer-sponsored coverage, or approximately per year for an individual or , per year for a family.2 Larger subsidies would be available to people below the median family income (currently about , per year). People with incomes at or below the federal poverty level would get a total tax credit sufficient to pay the full premium for coverage comparable to the costs of effi- In 2000 the average employer premium contribution was about $4,600 a year for family coverage and about $2,100 for single coverage. (Computed from Jon Gabel et al. “Job-Based Health Insurance in 2000: Premiums Rise Sharply While Coverage Grows.” Health Affairs 19 [5] [September/October 2000]: 147). For someone in the 32 percent marginal tax bracket, the tax savings are about $1,500 for family coverage and $700 for single coverage. 2 ciently provided Medicaid benefits.3 For those between the poverty level and the median income, subsidies would be reduced gradually as income rises so that those at the median income would receive the minimum subsidies indicated above. The tax credit subsidy needs to be “refundable” and payable in advance. That is, people whose income tax liability is less than their credit would receive the difference in the form of a “refund.” And because premiums have to be paid monthly beginning more than a year before tax time,a mechanism is needed to make coverage affordable during the year as premiums come due. We propose that the amount of the subsidy be based on the previous year’s reportable income. People whose reportable income is low enough to qualify them for advance payments would receive a federal voucher every month that could be applied to the cost of coverage. Vouchers could be transferred to and redeemed by either employers or insurers, depending on whether the person has coverage through an employer or in the individual market. (This voucher process and redemption generally would be handled electronically through the centralized administration system described later.) If a family that is not receiving vouchers experiences a decline in income that would make it el i gi ble for advanced payments, it could apply for eligibility at that time. Any government overpayments would be reconciled at the next tax filing, with minor amounts (for example, under per year) being forgiven. An important issue is how to adjust the subsidies over time as the cost of medical services increases. For people below the poverty level, the subsidy should be adjusted so that it is always adequate to purchase coverage equivalent to current Medicaid benefits. We propose that the Office of the Actuary in the Health Care Financing Administra ti on be assigned the task of developing an appropriate 3 Because Medicaid-covered services vary from state to state, the federal enabling legislation would define a uniform benefits package. But the intent is that the covered services would be equivalent to what is now typically available to Medicaid enrollees. Any changes in benefits over time would be defined by changes in federal law or regulations. 198 The most compelling reason for mandating that everyone be covered is that this requirement is necessary to ensure universal coverage. index to increase the subsidy over time. For people earning above the median income, we would propose that the subsidy not be indexed to increase automatically but could be increased at the discretion of Congress. For those between the poverty level and median income, the subsidy would increase automatically when it was increased for those below the poverty level. The current tax policy that excludes employer premium contributions from employees’ taxable income is widely acknowledged to be an inequitable and inefficient way to subsidize the purchase of health insurance. It is inequitable because many low-income people do not have employer-sponsored covera ge , so they get no benefit; h i gh erincome people tend to have more comprehensive coverage and thus more excludable income; and higher-income people have higher marginal tax rates, so they benefit more from every dollar that is excluded from tax. The subsidy is inefficient—that is, its cost is high relative to the objective—because much of the forgone tax revenue pays for subsidies to people who could afford to pay for coverage out of pocket. It is also inefficient because it encourages people to consume more health care services relative to other goods and services than they would if employer-paid premiums were not “tax sheltered.” Substituting a tax credit for the tax exclusion substantially reduces the inequity, especially because the credit we propose is larger for lowerincome people but fixed for those with incomes above the median. Though a case could be made for entirely phasing out the credit for higher-income people on equity and efficiency grounds, this would produce a large tax increase for politically influential middle- and high-income people. Retaining a substantial subsidy for these income groups should lessen political opposition to the change, although high-income people whose employers contribute generously to comprehensive coverage would still have a higher tax liability with the tax credit than with the tax exclusion. The current Medicaid program provides comprehensive medical coverage to families that qualify. (It also includes coverage of some non-medical services, about which more is said later.) We believe that such comprehensive medical coverage should be subsidized fully for all families below the poverty level,and that substantial though gradually decreasing subsidies should be available to families up to the median income level. Without such subsidies, many will find the cost of paying for the nowmandatory coverage to be burdensome if not impossible. The graduated phasing-out of lowincome subsidies is justified on the grounds of ability to pay and to ensure that the system does not include strong work disincentives. If the subsidy were reduced too quickly, some people would be reluctant to take higher-paying jobs that would make them ineligible for the low-income subsidy because they actually might have lower net incomes after paying more for health insurance. The feature of the proposal that may need more explanation is the provision that allows the credit to be applied not only to premiums paid by employees or individuals but also to those paid by employers. This provision would appear to make the budgetary cost of the subsidy higher, but that is not likely to be the case in the long run. Since employer-paid premiums would be taxable income to employees,there is no reason for employees to prefer being compensated in the form of employer-paid premiums rather than money wages. If the tax credit could not be applied to employer-paid prem iu m s , employees would urge employers to stop paying the premium and give them the equivalent in money wages. Employees then could pay for coverage themselves and use the tax credit to offset the cost,leaving them 199 with more net income. Over time employers likely would stop paying anything for premiums because doing so would benefit their employees without adding to the employers’ costs. (Economists argue that employers are largely indifferent to the form of compensation; what counts is the cost of the total compensation package,including money wages plus employee benefit costs.) At the point where employees pay all of the prem iu m , the credit could be applied to the entire premium;so the budgetary cost is the same as if the credit could be applied toward both the employer and employee portions of the premium. But if employers stopped paying for premiums, they might be tempted simply to abandon en ti rely their role as purchasing agents acting on behalf of their employees. For reasons noted earlier, we think this would be a bad result. But if the credit applies equally to employer-paid or employee-paid premiums, employers may continue to pay a portion of the premium and to pursue good value in purchasing health coverage for their employees. Regarding changes in the subsidy over time, the rationale for increasing the subsidy for impoverished people as medical costs rise is straightforward: We want to ensure that they can afford the coverage they are required to buy. For the group between the poverty level and median income, the same rationale justifies increasing their subsidy, which would happen more or less automatically, since it is tied to the subsidy for those below the poverty level, with a phase-out as income rises. We do not propose, however, to automatically increase the tax credit subsidy for people above median income. The main reason for creating the credit for them in the first place was not because the subsidy was needed to make coverage affordable, but to avoid the political objections that would occur if this group had to give up its current tax exclusion subsidy without having anything else in its place. On equity grounds, a case could be made for having the real (after-inflation) value of the tax credit subsidy decline over time. If the credit is increased for this higher-income group, we favor having Congress explicitly decide to raise it rather than having it increase automatically as medical costs rise. Individual Mandate Every individual and family would be required to have health coverage—that is, at a minimum, as comprehensive as Medicare benefits (Parts A and B) with the addition of a drug benefit and well-child care.4 To en su re that such plans are available, all insurers offering health coverage would be required to offer a policy that includes the services covered by Medicare plus prescription drugs and well-child care and to price the policy on an actuarially defensible basis. A mandate without effective enforcement would not achieve the desired result. We propose that everyone be required to show proof of purchase of coverage as part of his or her annual filing of federal income tax forms. In the case of families, proof of coverage would be required for the person filing the return, his or her spouse, and all dependents listed on the tax return. Insurers, health plans, and selfinsured employers would be required to issue a standard form to all policy holders that serves as the proof of purchase and is attached to income tax returns (comparable to W- forms now issued by employers to show earnings). The forms would indicate the months during which each person is insured. Individuals who have no taxable income and, therefore, do not now file a tax retu rn , s ti ll would be required to send in proof of coverage when federal tax returns are due. Those who fail to show proof of coverage incur the fo ll owing penalty: for every month they are without coverage, they would be required to pay a fee, to be included with their tax retu rn , that is equivalent to the monthly cost of coverage for Medicare benefits plus a percent surcharge. The fee would be levied whether or not the individuals use any medical services during the time they are uninsured. The fee would be based on the actuarial cost of providing the augmented Medicare benefits package to a non-Medicare population under age 4 In referring to Medicare benefits, we are referring only to the services covered, not to the kind of system that delivers these services. An individual could meet the mandate requirement by choosing an indemnity plan, a preferred provider organization (PPO), a health maintenance organization (HMO), etc., as long as the benefits were as extensive as those covered under Medicare. 200 . The premium assessment would be adjusted to reflect family size and composition and regional differences in medical costs, but not age of the adults (explained under “Insurance Regulation” below). The tax credit applicable to the family or individual (discussed in the previous section) can be applied against this liability. To achieve the objective of universal coverage requires that one of two conditions be met: either everyone must be required to purchase coverage, or a mechanism must be in place that automatically covers everyone (as is the case with social insurance systems). In a sense, we have chosen to build in both conditions. We would mandate that everyone buy private coverage, but, in addition, we propose that anyone who is not privately covered, for whatever reason, would default into Medicare coverage and pay a premium for the time he or she is covered under that system. In a sense, this approach can be thought of as an individual (as contrasted with an employer) “play or pay”mandate: one either “plays” by purchasing private coverage or “pays” by being assessed for Medicare coverage. (The mechanism by which this is accomplished is discussed in the next section.) The most compelling reason for mandating that everyone be covered is that this requirement is necessary to en su re universal covera ge . But there are other reasons,as well. Even if they have the means to buy coverage, some people will choose not to do so if there is no mandate;yet when they need expensive care for life-threatening or emergent conditions, society is not willing to deny them access to essential services. They then become “free-riders” who do not bear their fair share of the costs.Our approach prevents this. In ad d i ti on , no one has been able to devise a practical mechanism for making the individual insurance market work well without mandating that everyone have coverage. The individual market falters without a mandate because individuals can predict when they will need certain expensive kinds of medical care—for example, elective surgery or maternity benefits. Some people will choose to buy coverage only when they expect to need care, which creates severe problems of adverse selection. The ability to buy coverage only when the insured person is likely to incur expenses negates the insurance principle, which involves pooling of risk among individuals who cannot predict when they will need expensive services. Moreover, it is not fair to require people who want to stay insured permanently to pay for the costs of care provided to individuals who become part of the insurance pool only when they know they will be incurring major medical expenses. Individuals who go in and out of coverage on that basis are not paying their fair share. Since our approach includes the “mandate” that everyone who does not buy private coverage is automatically covered by Medicare and must pay a premium for that coverage, why, then, do we also propose to mandate the purchase of private coverage? Without such a mandate,the number of people who default into Medicare coverage would almost surely be greater (even though they must pay a premium plus a penalty for the time they are covered by Medicare). Because we seek to encourage coverage acquired in the private market rather than having large numbers of people defaulting into Medicare, we propose a mandate to buy private coverage to promote that objective. On the other hand, our proposal would still achieve universal coverage, even without this requirement. The mandate to purchase private coverage is desirable but not necessary. We propose to use the federal income tax filing mechanism to enforce the mandate because it is a relatively simple approach and would be an add-on to a process that most people complete routinely each year. Of course, some people who do not file returns now would have to do so, but they also would be required to do so to verify the amount of tax credit subsidy for which they are eligible (explained above). Because virtually all of these people would have very little income, the form could be very short and easy to complete. Some people would fail to comply, and they would be subject to the same penalties as people who do not file returns: if they owed an obligation—in this case, if they failed to buy coverage, and the cost of coverage exceeds their tax credit—they would be subject to 201 interest penalties identical to those for unpaid or overdue taxes. Some people—for example, the h om el e ss—might fail to file, but because of their very low income, they normally would have no premium obligation anyway. The percent penalty above and beyond the actuarial cost of coverage for those who fail to get coverage on their own is imposed to create incentives to buy private coverage. Because we want to maintain the privately based insurance system, we want to make the default position of having Medicare pay the bills more expensive than getting coverage through the private system. The base premium amount is based on a community-rated premium, with ad ju s tm ents for family size and differences in regional costs. The ra ti onale is to make the rate comparable (not counting the surcharge) to what could be purchased privately in the region. (As we explain later, we propose that community rating be required in the private insurance market for individuals and small groups.) A requirement that individuals be insured must be coupled with a definition of a minimum benefit package that fulfills the requirement. We have chosen Medicare coverage (Parts A and B) plus a drug benefit and well-child care. We add drug benefits because we believe that prescription drugs should be covered, and because there seems to be strong support for adding such a benefit to Medicare. We add well-child care because it is cost-effective coverage that is not applicable,and therefore not covered, under Medicare. We favor this definition of minimum benefits for several reasons.First,this is a benefit package that already applies to the elderly population. If it is good enough for the elderly, it should be good enough for everyone else. It would be inappropriate to have a benefits package minimum for the non - el derly that was more compreh en s ive than that available under Medicare for seniors. Second, the Medicare benefits package reflects a political decision about what constitutes an appropriate level of services. Relying on that decision avoids going through the very controversial and politically charged process of defining a new benefits package, with the inevitable intense lobbying from disease-specific advocates and provider groups. Third, Medicare benefits are not so comprehensive as to make the cost of the minimum package very high, nor is the coverage so generous as to encourage “excess” consumption of medical services. Fourth,having the minimum benefits package be the same as Medicare benefits simplifies administration of the “fallback” coverage system for people who fail to get private coverage (explained later). Procedures related to claims review, reimbursement of providers, cost-control measures, etc., would be identical for the fallback system as for the existing Medicare system. No new mechanisms or bureaucracies would be required. Even though we favor using Medicare benefits as the minimum standard for everyone, our approach would work well even if some other benefit standard were adopted. The merits of our approach do not depend on using Medicare coverage to define minimum benefits for the individual mandate. If it is decided that the peculiarities of the Medicare benefits pack a ge , even with the additions we suggest, make it unsuitable for use as the standard,a number of alternatives could be substituted. For example, the minimum coverage package could be based on the services covered under the Federal Employees Health Benefits Plan (FEHBP). Or Congress could devise an en ti rely new set of benefits just for this program. If it is simply the association with Medicare that carries negative political connotations, the program could be identified with an entirely different name. Medicare as a Source of Backup Coverage Anyone who lacks coverage at any point for whatever reason would be automatically covered by Medicare. The benefits package available would be identical to the minimum benefits required under the individual mandate, which in this proposal are the equivalent of Medicare coverage plus drug coverage and well-child care. People who default into this arrangement do not become Medicare enrollees, but Medicare is responsible for any (covered) medical expenses they incur during the time they lack other coverage. Medicare pays providers on the same basis and through the same mecha- 202 nisms that are used currently, but the money does not come out of the present Medicare trust fund. Instead, a new fund would be established for this purpose. This fund would be financed primarily by the assessments imposed on people for the months they lack coverage and that are paid as part of the federal income tax filing process, as explained earlier. Even though the assessment is equal to an actuarially determined premium plus a percent penalty, some funding shortfall is likely because some people covered through this system will not actually pay any assessment. Their income will be so low that the tax credit for which they are eligible will fully offset the full cost of their assessment. Funds to cover this shortfall would have to come from other sources, essentially general tax revenues. Even when everyone is required to have coverage, some people inevitably will not be en ro ll ed in a health plan for some period of time. They will be between jobs and fail to get individual covera ge , they will fail to pay a premium and subsequently will be disenrolled, or they simply will fail to sign up, even though they are required to by law. These people still need to have a source of coverage if they are to get the care they need, and if providers are to be paid for the services they provide to them. Having Medicare provide backup coverage solves this problem. We would not make these people Medicare enrollees because we want to encourage them to get private coverage. That is also the reason for imposing the percent penalty above and beyond the actuarial cost of coverage. Some people probably will default into Medicare coverage for long periods—the homeless, for example—and they are likely to be people of above-average risk. But this is probably an appropriate way to spread risk. We propose Medicare benefits as the coverage package available to those who default to the fallback system, but there are obviously other alternatives. The coverage could be more or less generous. For example, the FEHBP benefits package could be used as a model. But whatever the benefits, they should be identical to the minimum benefits pack- age required for the individual mandate. The coverage should be no less comprehensive because the notion of universal coverage implicitly requires that everyone have access to a societally determined minimum set of benefits. On the other hand, if the fallback benefits were more generous, people would have incentives to default to the fallback system rather than buying coverage on their own. Even under our preferred option of using the Medicare benefits package, it would be possible to choose an administrator for the default system other than Medicare—for example, FEHBP—if that is thought to be politically desirable. The advantage of having Medicare as the administrator is that the program already has contractual agreements with nearly all providers and has mechanisms in place for administering claims,setting reimbursement amounts, and making payments. Thus, no new bureaucracy and few administrative changes would be necessary to administer the system. We would not propose to cover undocumented immigrants through this system. The incentives for people to enter the country illegally to get access to treatment would be too strong. We understand that some undocumented peop l e ,e s pecially children ,a re covered by Medicaid or the State Children’s Health Insurance Program (S-CHIP), even though they are not officially eligible for these programs. Some of them would lose coverage if this proposal were adopted. We acknowledge that meeting the health needs of undocumented people, especially for primary and preventive care, deserves attention and that better ways need to be found to cope with the problem. But finding a solution is beyond the scope of this proposal, because the problem has many dimensions other than those related to health coverage. Employer Mandate to Offer (But Not Pay for) Coverage We would require employers to offer coverage to their employees and employees’ dependents, but they would not be required to pay anything toward the premium, though many would choose to do so just as they do now. Employers would be free to design any benefits package they thought appropri- 203 ate, as long as the coverage was at least as comprehensive as Medicare coverage plus a drug benefit and well-child care. The requirement to offer coverage could be met by offering it through an aggregate purchasing arrangement (APA) that would be available in each state (as explained below) and would offer benefits packages equivalent to Medicare and Medicaid, among others. Employers that offer their own plan rather than purchasing through the APA would be required to a ll ow employees who are eligible for the lowerincome tax credit (those with incomes below the family median) to purchase coverage equivalent to Medicaid coverage through the APA. That is,if eligible lower-income employees request it, employers would be required to withhold premiums from paychecks and send the withheld amount to the APA, along with the same dollar contribution that the employer makes for the firm’s standard plan. Inclusion of this mandate to offer coverage ensures that every employee would have the option of being covered by an employer-sponsored plan, with the risk-pooling advantages and administrative economies of scale that group purchasing achieves. Employers would have a reason to seek a good value for their employees’ benefit, even if the employer pays nothing. And having the employer withhold premiums from paychecks and pay the insurer or health plan is more efficient and less expensive for health plans and relieves employees of the burden of doing this themselves. Having a plan available through an employer makes it easy for most people to meet the requirement that they buy covera ge . They avoid the need to incur burdensome transaction costs—finding a plan for themselves or finding an agent who will help them do so, making difficult ju d gm ents about the value of various plans, and then paying individual premiums to the plan they choose. We see no substantial advantage to requiring employers to pay for coverage.Economists generally believe that employers of fs et the cost of paying insurance premiums by paying lower money wages than they otherwise would. If that is so, there is no advantage to requiring employers to nominally pay the cost of the premium (now that employer-paid premiums would not be tax-excludable income). Moreover, a requirement to pay for coverage likely would cause some employers who pay only the minimum wage to lay off some workers because the workers’ contribution to productivity would not be great enough to justify paying the now-higher total compensation. We allow employers to choose the aggregate purchasing arrangement (described next) as the vehicle for offering employees coverage. This makes it easy for employers that do not offer coverage now to meet their obligation, but still ensures that employees are not forced into the less efficient and potentially confusing individual market. We require employers to allow lower-income employees to purchase coverage equivalent to Medicaid coverage through the APA because the employer’s own benefit package may not be suitable for lower-income employees. For example, the deductibles and copayments may be unaffordable, or primary care services may not be covered adequately. Aggregate Purchasing Arrangements Each state would be required to establish an aggregate purchasing arrangement that would serve small employers and individuals (though larger employers could opt to purchase coverage through this mechanism). The federal government would establish general guidelines for these organizations, but states would be given wide flexibility in deciding what kind of arrangement to establish. For example, they could establish a traditional health purchasing cooperative,a HealthMart, or a similar organization of their own design. They could establish just one or as many as they thought feasible. They could be private, quasi-public, or public entities, at the state’s opti on . As an alternative, the state could allow employers and individuals to buy into the state’s existing employee plan or a different state plan designed for this purpose. Each aggregate purchasing arrangement would be required to offer, at a minimum,a benefits package equal to Medicare benefits plus drug coverage 204 and well-child care and another equal to Medicaid coverage. Each participating health plan would be required to offer at least these two benefits packages. No insurer or health plan offering insured plans in the state could refuse to offer coverage through the APA, but the APA (under state-determined regulations) would establish its own criteria for deciding which plans to include. People getting coverage through the APA, whether individuals buying for themselves or employees in a group, would individually be able to choose any health plan that offers coverage through the APA. Each insurer selling through the APA would price coverage on a community-rated basis (with the minimal adjustments explained below), and that coverage would be available at that price to all individuals and all groups with or fewer employees. The rates health plans charge inside the APA could be no higher than the rates they offer for comparable coverage to groups outside the APA. But the APA could negotiate with insurers for a lower price than their outside pri ce , reflecting administrative savings, volume discounts, or other efficiencies that insurers and health plans realize by selling coverage through the APA. Insurers contracting with the APA would be subject to all the rules that apply in the small-group and individual markets, as explained below. Employers with or fewer employees would be required to offer coverage exclusively through the APA. Groups of any size could participate, but the state would have the option of choosing to establish a mechanism for the APA that would allow insurers and health plans to charge groups with more than employees a premium that reflected the specific group’s risk and administrative costs. Individuals could also buy coverage through the APA. No group or individual seeking coverage through the APA could be excluded; the APA and all participating insurers would have to accept all applicants. When individuals and small employers want to purchase health coverage on their own,they are at a disadvantage. They lack the specialized knowledge and resources that large employers can allocate to this task,so they are not in a good position to determine whether they are receiving good value and buying a plan that best fits their needs. In addition, because of the diseconomies that health plans face in serving small groups and individuals, most notably high marketing and administrative costs, these buyers pay more for coverage than large employers. Aggregate purchasing arrangements have the potential for giving individuals and small employers some of the advantages that large employers enjoy—not only lower administrative costs, but also the power to nego ti a te with health plans to ensure that purchasers are buying high-value coverage. Fu rt h er, APAs could provide the kinds of cost and quality comparisons that individuals and employees need to choose wisely among health plans. But previous experience with purchasing cooperatives and similar organizations has been discouraging. For the most part, they have not realized the expected economies, and they have had trouble attracting sufficient numbers of employers and maintaining health plan participation. Most observers agree that the problems of aggregate purchasing arrangements would be largely solved if they could become big enough, and if they could be assured of health plan participation. We attempt to solve the first problem by requiring all very small employers to participate. These are the employers least capable of buying cost-effective health coverage on their own, but there are enough of them to create a large pool of business when all of them participate and all their employees get coverage, as required. The size of this market might be sufficient by itself to attract many health plans, but to ensure continued participation, we would require that all plans participate if asked to do so by the APA. States might decide to establish criteria for limiting the number of plans that participate in the APA, because,if all plans were to participate, administrative costs might be excessive and the range of choices might be overwhelming. Further, APAs might want to limit participation as a nego ti a ting ploy: they could bargain with plans to give all of their business to the few health plans that offer the best deal. We propose to allow every individual or employee buying coverage through the APA to choose any 205 The problems of aggregate purchasing arrangements would be largely solved if they could become big enough, and if they could be assured of health plan participation. plan that participates in the APA. Especially in the era of managed care, we think people should be able to select the plan that best matches their needs, and they should be able to switch plans periodically (for example, once a year) if they become dissatisfied. This individual-choice provision also puts competitive pressure on plans to perform well. Moreover, when employees can choose their own plan, they will often be able to stay in the same plan when they change employers. We allow groups of any size to buy coverage through the APA if they wish to do so. Having larger groups be part of the APA could help it to achieve greater economies of scale and give it more negotiating clout when dealing with health plans. The APA would also serve as a convenient vehicle for providing coverage for those employers that wish to adopt a defined-contribution approach to paying for health coverage. But if large groups are community rated with the smaller groups in the plan, there is a danger that the APA will be adversely selected against: higher- ri s k , larger groups would have an incentive to join the APA to get a lower premium rate. We therefore propose that these larger groups be separately rated if the state chooses to take this approach. Insurance Regulation Federal law would require all health plans to accept all individual and small-group applicants (a guaranteed-issue requirement) and to provide immediate and full coverage for all covered benefits. In other words,there could be no waiting periods, exclusions for prior conditions, or other limits on coverage that would be applied differently for new enrollees. In su rers and health plans selling coverage to individuals and groups with or fewer enrollees would be required to price premiums on a commun i ty - ra ted basis. Adjustments would be permitted only for family size and composition and for regional differences in medical expenses. In other words, each insurer would put all individuals and groups of or fewer in a single pool for a defined geographic area, and the insurer’s premium would be based on the medical claims experience of all of the people in that pool. The guaranteed-issue requirements are consistent with current federal policy in the small-group market, but,more important,are absolutely necessary to en su re universal covera ge . Justification for any of the current limits on coverage having to do with prior conditions, waiting periods, coverage portability, and so forth is negated by the individual mandate requirement. Insurers traditionally have included these provisions to protect themselves against people who would wait to buy coverage until they knew or suspected they would be incurring major medical expenses. This problem has been acute in the individual market, but insurers believe it is also a problem in the market composed of very small groups (those with no more than four or five employees). Under our proposal, however, everyone will have coverage because of the individual mandate, so this justification for limiting coverage for new enrollees disappears. Insurers, however, could be permitted to establish reasonable waiting periods for conditions not covered under the Medicarebased minimum benefits package but covered by an optional, more comprehensive benefits package. Since coverage for these additional benefits would be voluntary, adverse selection problems could arise if insurers were not allowed to impose any restrictions on access to coverage. In the interest of avoiding churning and associated administrative costs, it also would make sense to limit plan switching to an open enrollment period or at the time of s om e change in job status or family condition, such as 206 marriage or the birth of a child. The decision to require community rating is based in part on a value judgment and in part on efficiency grounds. The value judgment is that people should not be rewarded or penalized (in the form of premium differences) for risk characteristics over which they have little or no control. People cannot change or influ en ce their age, gender, or genetic predisposition, all of which make them more or less vulnerable to illness and injury. They cannot affect their past medical experience and associated medical expenses. They can influence current behavior, which can affect future medical expenses and,therefore, risk, but health insurers seldom consider personal behavior, aside from smoking, in assessing risk. And if they were to consider personal behavior and life ch oi ce s , the practice would raise difficult ethical issues about what is “good” behavior and what is “bad.” (For example, should overweight people and sky divers be charged higher rates than thin people and long-distance runners or skiers, and would that be fair?) On the whole,it seems more fair to use community rating than risk rating if there are no practical reasons not to do so. The essence of the insurance principle is to share risk—those who do not need expensive medical care during a period subsidize those who do. If the risk is not shared “at the front end” through community rating, then it has to be shared “at the back end”through some other mechanism, such as a more direct subsidy to those who have incurred very high medical expenses. But the cost of financing that subsidy has to come from the people who do not incur high medical expenses in either case. Community rating is simpler and fairer than the alternative ways of sharing risk. Objections to community rating that have merit in today’s insurance market are largely negated by the provisions of our approach. People argue that community rating raises rates for lowrisk populations (as it undoubtedly does to some degree), and that, as a result, some of these people find that the higher price exceeds the value they attach to having coverage. So they drop coverage, which increases the number of uninsured. But our proposal would require that everyone buy coverage and would help them to do so with subsidies based on financial need. People also argue that the current age-rated system achieves a kind of rough equity: low-risk people are more likely to be young, and younger people have lower incomes, on average; so it is fair that they should pay less, because they have less ability to pay. But our approach addresses this concern by linking subsidies to income so that everyone has the ability to pay. The efficiency argument for community rating and against risk rating is that risk rating is a wasteful process. It requires expenditure of resources to segregate people into risk categories, a process that does nothing to enhance the welfare of insured people. It does not expand the amount of medical care, improve quality, or enhance efficiency. If risk rating were allowed, some higher- ri s k groups and individuals would face rates that could make coverage unaffordable unless the subsidies were va ri ed according to risk. Linking the size of subsidies to the level of risk would pose immense administrative complications and would be an expensive undertaking. On the other hand, a practical argument for risk rating is that it allows individual insurers to offset at least partially the effects of drawing a population whose risk is not representative. Insurers that happen to attract higher-risk people can afford to cover the higher medical costs they incur by charging enrollees above-average premiums. But this is not a practical long-run solution because, as they raise their premiums, insurers will lose the lower-risk people they cover because those people will switch to less expensive health plans. This practical argument needs to be addressed through a risk-adjustment process that somehow compensates insurers that cover a disproportionate number of higher-risk people. We would allow premiums to be adjusted for family size and composition, a provision that is virtually a universal practice now and is presumably not controversial. The other rating factor we would a ll ow is for differences in regional medical costs. This also fo ll ows current practice and is en ti rely consistent with the community rating principle. The very term implies that uniform rates should apply to 207 a limited geographic area. Most purchasers tie the rates they pay HMOs to local medical costs. Since medical costs vary significantly from region to region,and insurers’ business is concentrated in different regi on s , insurers need to be able to protect themselves by charging rates that reflect those regional differences. Further, it could be argued that people who live in higher-cost areas should have to pay more so that they have incentives to seek ways to hold costs down. Their costs should not be subsidized by people who live in lower-cost areas. Although the more common practice is to define small groups as firms with or fewer employees, we choose to include groups with or fewer employees within the community rating pool. The inclusion of larger employers broadens the risk pool substantially, which means that the costs of covering higher-risk individuals and small groups is spread over a larger portion of the pop u l a ti on . It is also questionable whether groups of between and employees are large enough to be risk rated separately or to self-insure and be at risk for the costs of their employees’ medical expenses. Elimination of Medicaid, S-CHIP, and Other Public Programs as a Source of Coverage Medicaid, S-CHIP, and similar programs to fund coverage for low-income people would be eliminated and would be replaced with subsidies in the form of refundable tax credits (described earlier) that allow people who otherwise would be eligible for these programs to purchase coverage in private markets just as everybody else does. (The important exception would be that Medicaid would continue to fund and administer the long-term care portion of the program. States would have increased responsibility for financing long-term care, as described later.) We recognize that not all low-income people will be well equipped to deal with the private market, especially because some will be unemployed and thus will not have coverage through their jobs. For these people, the APAs that each state must establish can serve as an appropriate source of coverage. In fact, the state may decide to make an APA responsible for negotiating with health plans, per- haps through a competitive bidding process, to offer managed care coverage that is specially tailored to the needs of this population, but open to anyone who chooses it. States would be required to con ti nue to have mechanisms to integrate services, provide case management, and otherwise meet the unique needs of many of the people with disabilities receiving Supplemental Security Income (SSI) cash assistance and Medicaid. They also would need effective outreach programs to identify these special populations — which might be somewhat more difficult, because they could no longer be identified as they en ro ll in Medicaid. In most instances, existing Medicaid program structures would con ti nue to serve these functions, but Medicaid would no longer be the source of funding. Some supplemental funding might be necessary from the states to cover services that normally are not considered to be medical in nature but that these people need if they are to improve their health. Examples include speech therapy and transportation services. Because our proposed system provides low-income people with tax credits adequate to purchase coverage equivalent to the benefits provided by Medicaid, there is no ongoing need for Medicaid, S-CHIP, and other similar programs that subsidize care for the poor. An argument could be made for phasing out these programs in stages, especially Medicaid, to ensure a smooth transition for vulnerable populations that may not be well equipped to find private coverage in a private system that may not be fully prepared to meet their needs. On the other hand, phasing out one system while phasing in another adds a layer of complexity—for example, the need to establish a mechanism to let people choose between getting tax credits or temporarily retaining coverage under Medicaid or S-CHIP. Programs providing highly specialized services that aid very specific populations, such as Maternal and Child Health Block Grants and the Ryan White program, could be retained. The tax credit subsidy makes private marketbased coverage affordable for low-income people. 208 Having them purchase coverage just as higherincome people do eliminates the stigma often associated with medical “welfare,” and it gives these people access to the same providers available to the rest of the population. The multi-tiered arrangement that characterizes our current system is eliminated. Lowincome people get “mainstream” care in the same way that elderly people do. They will not face the discrimination from providers and lack of access that is now often the lot of Medicaid recipients, because,as far as providers are concerned, they will be indistinguishable from the population that receives smaller subsidies (the tax credit available to everybody). Elimination of these low-income programs also eliminates the expensive and burdensome process of determining and redetermining eligibility and moving people from one insurance system to another as their eligibility status changes. Everyone is eligible for tax credits,and the amount of the credit is determined through the income tax reporting system. Low-income people are like everybody else except that they receive a larger tax credit. Substituting private insurance for Medicaid coverage will increase the budget cost, at least in the short run, because providers will be reimbursed at market rates rather than lower government-constrained rates—though presumably health plans and employers will negotiate vigorously to keep provider rates as low as possible throughout the system, just as they do now. But in terms of equity and ensuring access, there is no defensible justification for paying providers less for serving the low-income population than for serving any other population. The extra cost associated with higher provider reimbursement rates may be at least partially offset, for two reasons. First, providers currently try to recoup some of the fee discounts they have to accept from Medicaid by charging other payers more. Such attempts at cost shifting will no longer be necessary, which should benefit current non-Medicaid payers. Second, people who are now uninsured will get better care, which should have a favorable impact on costs. They will have access to primary care and preventive services, which not only will improve their health status, but also reduce costly use of hospital em er gency rooms and prevent simple probl em s from developing into acute problems that are expensive to treat. Centralized Electronic Administration Determination of eligibility, claims submission, coordination of benefits, and similar administrative processes would be channeled through a centralized electronic clearinghouse that would serve all insurers and health plans. The role of this entity would be analogous to the role the Federal Reserve System fills for the nation’s banking system plus the role served by centralized administration of credit card transactions. All health plans and insurers would be required to participate, to accept the common data format and procedures of the system, and to share in the costs of the clearinghouse. All transactions would be handled electronically. Every person en ro ll ed in a health plan would be issued a card (comparable to an automatic teller machine [ATM] card or “smart card”) with electronically embedded information sufficient to serve the functions of the system. Every health care provider would have a card reader connected to the centralized system (just as most retailers are connected to a centralized administra ti on for credit card transactions), and every patient encounter would begin with reading the pati en t’s card. That reading would provide all necessary inform a ti on about eligibility, covered benefits, amount of copayment, whether the deductible has been met, etc. Any payments made by the patient at the time of the visit would be entered. Although it might be desirable to include information of a medical nature as part of this smart-card mechanism, this raises important privacy and confidentiality issues that are beyond the scope of this analysis. Patients who mispla ce, forget, or lack an identifying card would be entered into the system by name, Social Security number, and mother’s maiden name. Services could not be denied to patients because they lack a card, and Medicare would guarantee that providers are paid for covered services if no other insurer can be identified for the patient. Federal legislation would be required to put this 209 system in place to ensure that the infrastructure is created and that health plans and providers comply with the requirements for standardization. We have no strong preference about whether the organization that carries out these activities is government or private. We noted that somewhat analogous institutions are the Federal Reserve check-clearing system, which is public, and the credit card clearing system, which is private. Both seem to work well. In either case, the ongoing costs of operating the system should be recovered through fees levied on health plans, insurers, and other risk-bearing entities, including self-insured employers. The federal government probably would need to appropriate funds to cover some of the initial costs of establishing the system. The current system for administering submission of claims, determining el i gi bi l i ty, calculating copayment obligations, and coordinating benefits is woefully deficient, duplicative, and inefficient. Patients often are responsible for keeping track of and submitting claims from many different providers for each serious episode of care. They get bi ll ed for services that are obligations of insurers, and they neglect to submit many claims that insurers should be paying. Providers waste huge amounts of time and money submitting and resubmitting claims and billing patients and insurers, processes that are especially inefficient when the patient is covered by multiple insurers. Insurers have to send multiple reports to patients and providers indicating what has been paid and what is the patient’s obligation. Using a centralized clearinghouse along with electronic submission of information would greatly reduce these administrative burdens and costs borne by patients, providers, and insurers. Administration still would be complicated and expensive: insurers still would have to approve treatment plans,authorize services, etc. But much of the inefficiency and cost and many of the hassles of the current system could be eliminated. In particular, patients would be relieved of the administrative burdens that now rest on them. Financing Health care coverage would continue to be financed by employers ,i n d ividuals and families, and government, but the ways in which the federal and state governments finance subsidies would change radically. Programs of medical coverage for specific population groups now subsidized by federal and state governments—most notably, Medicaid and S-CHIP— would be eliminated, with the important exceptions of Medicare for the elderly and Medicaid for longterm care. Medicaid and S-CHIP would be replaced with tax credit subsidies, as explained earlier. The revenues to finance tax subsidies (which are available to everyone but at different levels, depending on income) would come from two federal sources—general tax revenues and the special tax assessments on individuals defaulting to Medicare coverage. The general revenue money would not be pri m a ri ly new net spending, however. The federal government would experience large revenue increases by eliminating the tax exclusion of income that employees receive in the form of employer-paid health insurance premiums. Both income tax and payroll tax revenues would rise when the exclusion provision is removed. In addition, the federal government would no longer finance Medicaid or SCHIP. These changes would result in more money in the general fund, which would go far toward financing the new income tax credits. Some additional new public resources probably would be required, however—a political challenge that is easier to manage in a period of large budget surpluses. Eliminating Medicaid and S-CHIP would relieve states of substantial funding burdens. We would propose that, in exchange, states be required to assume greater responsibility for current long-term care services provided under Medicaid. States initially would be required to finance the costs of this program fully, with the benefit limits as currently defined, if they can do so without exceeding their present Medicaid and S-CHIP obligation. They also would be required to finance certain non-medical but medically related services now covered by Medicaid for special needs populations and the near-poor elderly. Initially states would be required 210 to maintain their current level of Medicaid effort, and, if the cost exceeded that level, the federal government would make up the difference. Over time, states’ obligation would be phased gradually to a system in which their share is based on some measure of ability to pay, such as state per capita income, rather than on previous levels of funding. The effect would be to cap their obligation, with the federal government assuming costs beyond the states’ levels of obligation. The changes in funding proposed are based on two judgments: () that income redistribution activities (which any subsidy program is) should be the responsibility of primarily the federal government, and () that the levels of subsidies should be based on need, not on the recipient’s place of residence. We take the position that, for equity reasons, the amount an individual contributes in the form of taxes to fund the subsidy program should be based on ability to pay (that is, income), not on the state where the individual lives. Likewise, the amount of subsidy provided to an individual should be based on that person’s ability to pay for coverage, not on where he or she lives or on a state’s ability and willingness to provide such subsidies. The capacity of states to fund subsidies varies widely, and their ability to pay is likely to fluctuate widely with changes in state or regional economic conditions. This proposition leads to the conclusion that establishing subsidy standards and funding the cost is primarily a federal responsibility. It is not unreasonable,however, to require states to maintain some level of effort rather than experiencing a large windfall gain, with all of the subsidy cost falling on the federal government. Thus we propose increased state responsibility for long-term care, but, consistent with our earlier line of reasoning, we would propose a gradual transition from requiring states to maintain current levels of effort to contributing according to their citizens’ ability to pay, which we measure by state per capita income.States may be wary of accepting the responsibility for funding long-term care, because, given the aging of the population and other trends,long-term care costs are likely to rise more rapidly than most other parts of the health care system. A federal cap on states’ longterm obligation, with the federal government picking up the excess, may be a reasonable trade for states’ continued acceptance of meeting federal standards for quality and other aspects of long-term care. Risk Adjustment Because our proposal requires insurers to use community rating for the individual and small-group markets,they cannot use rate adjustments to protect themselves against getting a disproportionate number of h i gh - risk en ro ll ee s . Under these circumstances, a strong case can be made for developing a mechanism to compensate insurers operating in these markets for differences in the risk profiles of the people they insure. The public interest requires that insurers be rewarded for being efficient in administering and providing high-quality medical services, not for being skillful in selecting and attracting low-risk populations and avoiding highrisk populations. Without some method for compensating insurers for differences in the risk of the populations they cover, insurers have strong incentives to risk-select; and experience suggests that it is very difficult to prevent risk selection through legislative prohibitions. But even if insurers did not inten ti on a lly seek to attract low-risk people and avoid high-risk people, some would get more than their fair share of high-risk people,partly because of random factors and partly because certain kinds of plans appeal to people with certain kinds of risk profiles. Health plans that gain a rep ut a ti on for being particularly skilled at treating people with certain kinds of severe medical conditions, for example, could be especially vulnerable to adverse selection. In su rers drawing higher-risk people would be at a competitive disadvantage unless a mechanism were in place to compensate them, essentially through some kind of money transfer from insurers with a relatively high proportion of low-risk enrollees to insurers with a disproportionate share of high-risk enrollees. The problem is that the state of the art in risk adjustment is still in the developmental stage. Much conceptual work is being done, and a number of 211 experiments are underway, but there is still some question whether these techniques are sufficient for the job. There is no way to predict risk completely so that insurers can be compensated fully and accurately before the fact, and techniques that compensate on the basis of after-the-fact incurred expenses decrease incentives for health plans to contain costs. We are not prepared to endorse any particular riskadjustment mechanism or approach; we leave that task to people with expertise in this area. But we do think that efforts to develop workable approaches should be continued and accelerated. It is uncertain how critical a risk-adjustment process is to the success of our approach (or, for that matter, to most other approaches that depend on private insurers). Most of the market operates now without risk adjustment, with at least some success. The fact that everyone would be required to have coverage under our plan helps in some respects, because it en su res that everyone, both high- and low-risk people, will be in some pool. The problem of having people buy insu ra n ce only when they anticipate needing expensive care also is eliminated. Transition The reform proposed here is not an incremental change. It does not build on existing programs of public coverage. It requires some major restructuring, particularly at the government level, and imposes new obligations on individuals, employers, and health plans. Designing a gradual transition from the current system to the new system is not an easy task because many of the changes must become operational at the same time. Some steps can be taken before the program is implemented fully. The APAs can be established in each state, and, once they are ready to begin operations,all small employers with fewer than employees could be required to use them as the vehicle for offering coverage. Those that provide coverage already would switch to the APA when their existing health plan comes up for renewal. At the same time, the requirement that all employers offer (but not necessarily pay for) coverage for their employees could be implemented .E m p l oyers with or fewer employees would be required to use the APA, and many others probably would choose to do so. The requirement that all health plans price premiums on a community-rated basis for employers with or fewer employees can and should be implemented gradually. States vary considerably in the extent to which they limit health plans’ ability to vary premium rates for small employers, and it would be too disruptive to require them all to move from their current position to full community rating over a short period of time. In fact,implementation of full community rating should not begin until the individual mandate is in place. Otherwise, premium rates for low-risk groups may rise to such an extent that significant numbers of them would drop coverage. Thus the requirement for community rating should be phased in over a period of several years for the small-group market. Any movement toward community rating and guaranteed-issue requirements for the individual market, however, probably will have to wait until the individual mandate and tax credits are in place. Otherwise, health plans likely would suffer adverse selection because sicker people would take advantage of the community rates to buy covera ge , while healthier people would wait until the individual mandate required them to do so. A number of the most important features of the reform must become operational at the same time to avoid creating severe problems. They include the individual mandate, full community rating, tax credit subsidies, elimination of the tax exclusion of employer-paid premiums,health plan premium risk adjustment,and requirements that individuals show proof of coverage as part of the tax-filing process. It would be highly desirable to implement the electronic system for paying and reconciling medical claims at the same time these other features of the s ys tem are put in place, but it probably would be possible to begin the rest of the new program without having the electronic system fully operational. Cost Containment Because this proposal would extend coverage to everyone currently without insurance, it likely 212 would increase the demand for medical services and raise the total level of health expenditures. But apart from that, nothing in the proposal should be a strong force to increase costs. Nevertheless, private funders of insurance coverage obviously would continue to be concerned about costs, and cost escalation would have special implications for the federal government,since rising costs would create pressure to increase the size of the tax credits and, thus, the revenue loss associated with this form of subsidy. Without tax credit increases, coverage would become unaffordable for many people if health costs rose appreciably. Clearly, continued attention will need to be directed to efforts to contain medical cost escalation. The proposal does not include any new forms of cost control, but it does incorporate features that should strengthen existing competitive market forces and create stronger incentives for consumers to be cost-conscious. One necessary condition for market forces to work to contain costs is the presence of incentives that encourage cost-conscious behavior. This proposal helps to create appropriate incentives by eliminating the tax exclusion for employer-paid health premiums, which en co u ra ges people to buy more comprehensive health insurance than they would otherwise. The current tax exclusion subsidizes any level of health coverage paid for by the employer and, thus, encourages employees to prefer extensive coverage, making it almost costless for them to consume any well-insured health care services. The proposed reform provides subsidies only for purchasing the standard coverage package; that is, individuals who choose to buy more comprehensive coverage would pay all of the cost difference between that benefit package and the standard coverage pack a ge . As a consequence, they would be more likely to carefully weigh the benefits against the costs,and fewer people would buy very compreh en s ive covera ge . Because they would be paying more out of pocket than they do now for at least some services, people are likely to reduce their rates of utilization, especially for services that are only marginally beneficial. For the same reason that people would tend to choose less comprehensive plans, they also would have strong incentives to choose plans that are efficient and offer high value. The new tax credit subsidy would be a fixed amount unaffected by the cost of the health plan chosen. Thus people who chose a plan that costs more than their subsidy (which would be most people) would have to pay the full extra cost out of pocket. That is a strong incentive not to choose an inefficient, costly plan. Of course, incentives to choose a higher-value plan have little effect when people have few plans from which to choose, as is often true today. The proposed approach would give many people more plan options: everyone acquiring coverage through the APA could choose from a number of plans. To a greater extent than currently, health plans would be in head-to-head competition for consumers’ business, so they would have stronger incentives to offer plans that provide high value. Moreover, health plans would not have the option available to them now of being able to compete on the basis of risk selection, because for employers with fewer than employees, premiums would be determined on a guaranteed-issue, community-rated basis; and the risk-adjustment process, to the extent that it is accurate and effective, would greatly reduce the rewards associated with being skillful at risk segmentation. Fewer resources would be devoted to finding ways to avoid high-risk enrollees, an effort that produces no real social benefit. The only remaining basis for competi ti on would be to offer good-quality care and high levels of service at reasonable prices. Apart from the fact that people previously uninsured would use more medical services than before, there is nothing obvious in this proposal that is likely to cause cost escalation. It is true that a significant portion of medical payments now subject to government price administration—namely, for services covered through Medicaid—would be reimbursed at market rates, which are likely to be higher than administered-price rates. A one-time price increase is a likely result, but over the longer term, reimbursement rates are not likely to rise at a greater rate than they would under an administered-price arrangement, because even administered pri ce s have to rise at roughly the same rate as market prices to induce providers to offer services. 213 Whether market forces will be adequate to contain costs remains to be seen, but nothing in this proposal is likely to reduce the prospects for success— quite the contrary. But if additional cost containment strategies have to be pursued, it is likely that they would have been necessary even in the absence of the implementation of this proposed reform. Quality of Care Implementation of this proposal is likely to have a positive effect on quality of care in two ways. First and most obvious, by ensuring that everyone is covered, the reform eliminates financial barriers to access. People who now defer or deny themselves care because they lack coverage will no longer have any reason to do so, so problems can be detected sooner, when treatment is more effective and less expensive. People now enrolled in Medicaid and similar public programs often have difficulty finding providers willing to accept them, either because the providers do not participate or because they already have a full roster of public-program patients. This constraint would be greatly reduced. Now covered by private insurance, these people would have access to the wider range of providers serving their area. Second,the increased head-to-head competition among health plans just described will force them to prove that they provide good-quality care as part o f their efforts to convince potential enrollees that the plans offer a high-value product. Implementation of this reform is likely to leave largely unchanged the other forces that influ en ce quality. Employers still will have reason to be concerned about quality, since they will be the source of coverage for much of the population. Medicaid no longer will fund care for low-income people (apart from long-term care), so government’s responsibility for quality will need to be extended beyond concerns about low-income populations to the entire population. Activities of government organizations such as the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality will be even more vital than they are now. Special attention should be directed to the effects of the reform on low-income populations formerly served by Medicaid and S-CHIP to ensure that the new system meets their needs,as well as those of the general population. Political Feasibility Like any proposal that represents a major departure from the status quo, this approach to reform would not be free of opposition. Nevertheless, the proposal does offer a number of significant political advantages. Advantages The reform model presented here should appeal to traditional conservatives for several reasons. First, it puts everyone into the mainstream medical system rather than into a government-run “bureaucratic” system. Second, it eliminates existing governmentrun programs like Medicaid and S-CHIP, which, because they are subsidy programs directed essentially at the poor, are often perceived negatively as “welfare” programs. In place of these programs, the proposal substitutes tax credits, which conservatives tend to favor over direct government-financed programs and which can legitimately be sold as a form of tax reduction. Third,the proposal places few constraints on employers. Apart from being required to allow their employees to opt into the aggregate purchasing arrangement and to offer but not pay for health coverage, employers’ role in providing coverage for their employees remains largely unchanged. Fourth, the proposal relies on competitive market forces to contain health care costs, rather than introducing new forms of government-administered price regulation or cost controls. Moreover, by eliminating the tax exclusion for employer-financed health premiums, the proposal would require people to bear more responsibility for their health care costs. Major stakeholders who are often threatened by proposals that would extend coverage broadly may find that this proposal is more attractive than other reform alternatives. Insurers and health plans would continue to play the role they do now, and, in fact, they would have as new customers large numbers of people who currently are covered by government 214 programs. Providers, too, should find many aspects of this proposal appealing. Most notably, providers that now serve large numbers of Medicaid patients would be paid at market rates rather than at the normally lower government-determined rei m bu rs ement rates. In addition, there would no longer be any uncompensated care, because everyone would be required to have insurance coverage, and even those individuals who failed to meet the requirement would have their medical bills paid by Medicare. Providers who now serve recipients of public programs also would be freed from the administrative burdens of dealing with the government bureaucracies that administer programs for low-income patients. And all providers would be freed of many administrative burdens when the integrated electronic claims handling system is in place. Advocates for low-income and disadvantaged populations obviously would find the universal coverage feature of this program to be highly desirable. They also would likely look favorably on the feature that provides tax credit subsidies to everyone, so that there is no income test for eligibility and, therefore, no stigma for the poor in accepting such subsidies. The multi-tiered system of care that characteri ze s our current system would be eliminated. Everyone would be served by “mainstream” providers, and providers would be unable to distinguish among patients according to the subsidy they receive. Access for low-income people also would be improved. Those whose access is now limited to providers who accept patients from public programs would benefit by being able to choose from the same range of providers as the rest of the population. Extension of choice is obviously desirable for its own sake, but the greater choice of providers also should enhance the quality of care available to people who are now served by public programs. Disadvantages Although the proposal is likely to appeal to many groups, it also faces formidable political obstacles. First, the program involves a large tax expenditure. Even though the tax credits that subsidize purchases of health coverage for the entire population can be characterized as a form of tax reducti on , it is still true that the subsidies under this program would cause large losses in tax revenue. While it is probably easier for politicians to defend off-budget tax expenditures than on-budget appropriations, people who look with disfavor on policies that expand the role of government are not likely to be mollified. And, of course, to the extent that this proposal reduces tax revenues, it reduces the revenue available to spend on other public programs. Offsetting the negative effects of increased tax expenditures for tax credit subsidies is the fact that other changes, particularly taxation of employer-paid health insurance premiums and elimination of Medicaid and SCHIP, will have a large positive effect on the budget position of the federal and state governments (and, incidentally, alleviate some of the revenue problems of Medicare and Social Security, since payroll tax revenues will also increase). Some people will view this program as more “big government.” Even though it requires no significant buildup of new government bureaucracy or personnel, relies on private-sector forces, and actually increases the number of people who will be buying coverage in the private sector, it will be characterized by some as a major expansion of governm en t’s role and influ en ce . Some will criticize the idea of using Medicare as a fallback for those who have no coverage, even though, in most cases, this would be a temporary arrangement. Vexed by the current rules and regulations of the Health Care Financing Administration, they would not eagerly greet the idea of having the agency administer coverage for even more people. Critics with this perspective also may fear that if cost increases begin to appear in the health care sector, government cost controls will not be far behind. This approach also involves a degree of compulsion that some will find objectionable. The requirement that everyone purchase health care coverage is a restriction on individual liberty, and while it is certainly possible to marshal persuasive arguments to justify this level of compulsion, the arguments will not convince everyone. The proposal also requires employers to take certain actions. Specifically, they are required to offer (but not pay for) coverage to all employees and to allow individual employees to opt 215 into the aggregate purchasing arrangement.Employers that do not offer coverage now, or those who have well-established insurance programs of their own, will have to make changes that may appear burdensome to them. Like any major reform,this proposal creates various kinds of financial redistribution that are likely to be opposed by people who view themselves as being worse off as a result of the change. Eliminating the tax exclusion for employer-paid premiums is likely to cost higher-income people with comprehensive employer-paid coverage more than they gain in the way of a tax credit. Thus, they may oppose this change in the approach to financing subsidies for health covera ge . Opposition to eliminating the tax exclusion is likely to be particularly strong from labor unions that have bargained successfully for generous health coverage programs. The requirement that all firms with fewer than employees be part of a single risk pool will raise the cost of health coverage for lower-risk employers and their employees: Because all employers in the pool will be charged the same community rate, low-risk employers and their employees will no longer be able to realize their current risk advantage. Although insurers and health plans would play a larger role in the revised system, some will still object to specific provisions. In general, insurers are not enthusiastic about community rating because they believe that constraints on their ability to adjust rates in accordance with the risk of the populations they insure can jeopardize their ability to remain profitable. Even if an appropriate riskadjustment process is in place, as proposed, it may be hard to convince insurers that their worries are groundless. Moreover, some insurers have carved out a profitable niche for themselves that is based on their effectiveness in selecting low-risk populations. Since their competitive advantage up to now has been attributable to their being more skillful in selecting risk, rather than in being cost-effective in managing care, these insurers and health plans may oppose the changes envisioned in this proposal. Advocates for low-income populations may be wary of the proposal because it does away with much of Medicaid. They have worked long and hard to en su re that Medicaid incorporates fe a tu res to protect lower-income populations and to be attentive and responsive to their special needs. Even though we propose retaining certain elements of Medicaid to meet these special needs, advocates may still worry that placing these vulnerable populations into mainstream care may leave them without all the protections and special services they need. n