Inviting Free-Riders or Appealing to Prosocial Behavior? Game
Transcription
Inviting Free-Riders or Appealing to Prosocial Behavior? Game
Inviting Free-Riders or Appealing to Prosocial Behavior? Game-Theoretical Reflections on Communicating Herd Immunity in Vaccine Advocacy Cornelia Betsch, Robert Böhm, and Lars Korn University of Erfurt Running Head: COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY Health Psychology, in press Author Note Cornelia Betsch, Center for Empirical Research in Economics and Behavioral Sciences (CEREB), University of Erfurt; Robert Böhm, Center for Empirical Research in Economics and Behavioral Sciences (CEREB), University of Erfurt; Lars Korn, University of Erfurt. CB and RB contributed equally to this paper. The authors are grateful to the master students of the fall 2011 term, who helped set up the study and collect data. Tilmann Betsch, Wasilios Hariskos, Fabian Kleine, Frank Renkewitz, Heather Fuchs, and the CEREB research group made helpful comments on an earlier draft of the paper. Correspondence concerning this article should be addressed to Cornelia Betsch, University of Erfurt, Nordhäuser Str. 63, D-99089 Erfurt, Germany. E-Mail: cornelia.betsch@uni-erfurt.de. COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 2 Abstract Vaccination yields a direct effect by reducing infection but also has an indirect effect, herd immunity: If many individuals are vaccinated, the immune population will protect unvaccinated individuals (social benefit). However, due to a vaccination’s individual costs and risks, individual incentives to free-ride on others’ protection also increases with the number of individuals who are already vaccinated (individual benefit). Objective was to assess the consequences of communicating the social and/or individual benefits of herd immunity on vaccination intentions. We assume that if social benefits are salient, vaccination intentions increase (prosocial behavior), whereas salience of individual benefits might decrease vaccination intentions (free-riding). Methods: In an online-experiment (N = 342) the definition of herd immunity was provided with one sentence summarizing the gist of the message, either making the individual or social benefit salient or both. A control group received no information about herd immunity. As a moderator we tested the costs of vaccination (effort in obtaining the vaccine). Dependent measure was intention to vaccinate. Results show that when a message emphasized individual benefit, vaccination intentions decreased (free-riding). Communication of social benefit reduced free-riding and increased vaccination intentions when costs to vaccinate were low. Conclusions: Communicating the social benefit of vaccination may prevent free-riding and should thus be explicitly communicated if individual decisions are meant to consider public health benefits. Especially when vaccination is not the individually (but instead collectively) optimal solution, vaccinations should be easily accessible in order to reach high coverage. Keywords: public health, immunization, social dilemma, advocacy, communication strategies COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 3 Inviting Free-Riders or Appealing to Prosocial Behavior? Game-Theoretical Reflections on Communicating Herd Immunity in Vaccine Advocacy Vaccination is typically treated as an individual decision making task. In addition to motivational factors such as adherence to social norms (Brown et al., 2011; Liao, Cowling, Lam & Fielding, 2011; Sturm, Mays & Zimet, 2005; Ajzen & Fishbein, 1980), a vaccination’s (perceived) individual costs and benefits are especially predicative of vaccination intention. This is proposed by several theoretical models of preventive health behavior (for an overview see Weinstein, 1993) and has been confirmed by empirical work (e.g. Brewer et al, 2007; Brewer & Fazekas, 2007; Nguyen, Henningsen, Brehaut, Hoe & Wilson, 2011). Costs (barriers) of vaccination can be monetary and non-monetary, such as the time needed to obtain a vaccination, but also include the risks associated with vaccination such as the occurrence of vaccine-adverse events. Benefits of vaccination vary according to the vaccine’s effectiveness as well as the likelihood and severity of the disease the vaccine protects against. Vaccination yields a direct effect by reducing infection. Moreover, vaccination against contagious diseases has an additional indirect effect (Fine, Eames & Heyman, 2011): The transmission of a disease is reduced with an increasing number of vaccinated individuals. An indirect effect of vaccination can have two major implications: On the one hand, each vaccination reduces the transmission of an infection in the population (Anderson & May, 1991), which protects other susceptible individuals (for instance, those who are too young to vaccinate or immunocompromised). With a critical vaccination level, herd immunity and disease eradication can be reached (e.g. 95% vaccine coverage will allow for eradication of the measles in Europe; Christie & Gay, 2011; Smith, 1970). Hence, vaccination yields a social benefit, as vaccine coverage above the critical level is optimal from the collective perspective. On the other COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 4 hand, if everyone else is directly protected by vaccination, free-riders (or free-loaders; see Fine et al., 2011) can benefit from the indirect effects of vaccination and henceforth avoid individual costs of vaccination (e.g. money, time, vaccine-adverse events, inconvenience). The indirect effect of vaccination, therefore, also yields an individual benefit. The presence and awareness of both individual and social benefit from herd immunity result in a mixed-motive situation that renders vaccination a strategic interaction (Schelling, 1960). As high vaccination uptake is of major importance for society in order to reach public health goals, it is a fundamental question how societies can increase vaccination uptake. This contribution investigates how the communication of herd immunity may affect vaccination uptake. More precisely, we examine how the awareness of a vaccination’s individual benefit, social benefit, or both affects vaccination intention. According to the theory of reasoned action and the theory of planned behavior, salient beliefs determine an individual’s attitude towards a behavior and behavioral intentions (Ajzen & Fishbein, 1980). An individual’s awareness of herd immunity may therefore either increase or decrease vaccination uptake, depending on the salience of individual and social benefits that result from the indirect protection of herd immunity. Vaccination as a strategic interaction The interactive structure of vaccination decisions has recently been discussed in the literature (e.g. Bauch & Earn, 2004; Bhattacharyya & Bauch, 2010; Galvani, Reluga, & Chapman, 2007; Manfredi et al., 2010). Based on this literature we devise a simple model of vaccination as strategic interaction which is illustrated in Figure 1. The expected costs of a disease (E[cD]) are typically treated as the product of the severity of the disease and the probability to contract the disease. Similarly, the expected costs of a vaccination (E[cV]) are the COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 5 product of its costs (monetary and non-monetary) and their probability (e.g. the likelihood of adverse advents): E[cD] = SEVD × PROBD and E[cV] = SEVV × PROBV (Weinstein, 1993). The expected utility from vaccination (EUV) and non-vaccination (EU¬ V) results from the difference between the expected costs of the disease and the expected costs of vaccination: EUV = E[cD] E[cV] and EU¬ V = E[cV] - E[cD]. Consequently, small differences in expected costs of the disease and vaccination yield larger differences in the expected utility of vaccination and nonvaccination, since EUV - EU¬ V = 2(E[cD] - E[cV]). Furthermore, the probability of contracting a contagious disease, and therefore also the expected costs of the disease, over-proportionally decreases as a function of the number of vaccinated individuals, because the lifetime incidence for unvaccinated individuals decreases (e.g., Fine et al., 2011). At the same time, the expected costs of the vaccination remain constant, since, for instance, the probability and severity of sideeffects is not affected by the number of vaccinated individuals. Therefore, when the number of vaccinated individuals (vaccine coverage) increases, the expected costs of the vaccination will at some point exceed the expected costs of the disease (E[cD] - E[cV] < 0; cf. intersection in Figure 1; Chen, 1999). From an individual perspective, non-vaccination then becomes the best response as EUV < EU¬ V. In contrast, it is collectively optimal to vaccinate until a vaccination level is achieved that eradicates the disease, as the expected cumulative incidence is zero if coverage is maintained above the critical vaccination level (Vc; Fine et al., 2011). Therefore, as soon as E[cD] - E[cV] < 0 the vaccination decision contains a motivational conflict between the individual and collective interest. If Vc is reached, non-vaccination is the best response from an individual and collective perspective. Within these boundary conditions, vaccination constitutes a N-person prisoner’s dilemma in which individuals may decide whether or not to contribute (i.e. vaccinate) to a public good (i.e. herd immunity); see shaded area in Figure 1. COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 6 It is important to note that expected costs are subjective variables and can therefore deviate from objective cost parameters. Today, wild forms of severe vaccine-preventable diseases are rare and most individuals lack a concrete, vivid representation of the disease (= low perceived costs of disease). At the same time, vaccination costs are more visible, vivid and tangible due to high vaccination rates and immediate effort and inconvenience (= high costs of vaccination; Chen, 1999). Many modern vaccination decisions (e.g. against polio or the measles) can therefore be framed as a social dilemma. As discussed, herd immunity can have two potential effects. On the one hand, if the individual benefit of herd immunity is communicated, the individual’s selfish/egoistic preferences might be activated (Dawes, 1980; Hardin, 1968) and accordingly affect behavior (Ajzen & Fishbein, 1980). Therefore, the first hypothesis predicts: H1. If the individual benefit of herd immunity is salient (but not the social benefit), participants will show lower vaccination intentions compared to when the individual benefit is not salient (free-riding hypothesis). On the other hand, by making the social benefit of one’s own vaccination salient, individuals’ positive, other-regarding preferences might be activated (for an overview see Fehr & Schmidt, 2006). This leads to the second hypothesis: H2. If the social benefit of herd immunity is salient (but not the individual benefit), participants will show higher vaccination intentions compared to when the social benefit is not salient (prosocial behavior hypothesis). This study extends prior work (e.g., Hershey, Asch, Thumasathit, Meszaros & Waters, 1994; Shim, Chapman, Townsend, & Galvani, 2012) by orthogonally manipulating the salience COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 7 of individual and social benefits. We are, therefore, also able to explore the interaction between the salience of individual and social benefits. In Figure 1, if the expected costs of vaccination increase or decrease (grey dashed line moves up or down, respectively), ceteris paribus, the intersection of E[cD] = E[cV] shifts further to the left or right, respectively. Consequently, the difference in expected utility between vaccination and non-vaccination on the right-hand side of this intersection increases or decreases, respectively. This effect occurs due to the indirect effect of vaccination. If individuals are unaware of this indirect effect (e.g. because herd immunity is not communicated), the expected costs of the disease will not depend on the vaccination of others and will therefore be constant. As, in this case, the solid grey line would be parallel to the dashed grey line, selfish or other-regarding preferences should thus have no effect. The (perceived) costs of vaccination should therefore interact with the effects of communicated herd immunity: Free-riding entails the benefits of vaccination (due to others’ immunization) without carrying the costs. It follows that the incentives for free-riding are especially high if costs to vaccinate are high. Likewise, individuals who vaccinate due to a prosocial motivation (to protect the unimmune) take over costs for the society. Hence, if these costs are high, prosocial behavior may be less likely. This leads to our third hypothesis, which integrates the structurally equivalent sub-hypotheses of individual and social benefit salience: H3. If the individual benefit of herd immunity is salient, participants are more inclined to free-ride when the costs of vaccination are high than when the costs of vaccination are low. Similarly, if the social benefit of herd immunity is salient, participants are more inclined to prosocial behavior when the costs of vaccination are low than when the costs of vaccination are high (vaccination costs interaction hypothesis). COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 8 Experiment The hypotheses were tested in an online experiment that assessed vaccination intentions regarding hypothetical diseases (for a similar methodological approach, see cf. Betsch & Sachse, 2012; Betsch, Renkewitz, & Haase, in press; Betsch, Ulshöfer, Renkewitz, & Betsch, 2011; Vietri, Li, Galvani, & Chapman, 2012). The definition of herd immunity was provided along with one sentence summarizing the gist of the message (Reyna, 2012), making salient either the individual benefit, social benefit, or both. A control group received no information about herd immunity. Additionally, we tested if the cost of getting vaccinated, operationalized as the amount of effort required to obtain the vaccine, interacts with the communicated benefits. Method Participants and design. Participants were recruited via mailing lists and social network websites (e.g. Facebook). As compensation, all participants took part in a raffle for one of five gift certificates (25 Euro; ~ $ 31). N = 371 participants completed the questionnaire. 29 participants were excluded from the sample due to excessively long (> 30 min) or short (< 5 min) duration of participation, resulting in a mean duration of 12.76 minutes (SD = 5.14). Hence, the final sample consisted of 342 participants, both students and non-students. Eightyeight percent of the sample had an Abitur (German University entrance diploma) or higher level of education. The mean age of the sample was 30.34 years (SD = 12.5); 221 (64%) participants were female. The experiment used a 2 × 2 × 2 between-subject design with individual benefit of herd immunity (communicated vs. not communicated), social benefit of herd immunity (communicated vs. not communicated), and costs of vaccination (low vs. high) as factors. It was COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 9 realized with an online software program (EFS survey), which randomly allocated participants to the eight conditions. Herd immunity. In the control condition (individual and social benefits of herd immunity were not communicated), participants received no information about herd immunity. In the remaining three conditions, participants received the following definition of herd immunity: “Herd immunity denotes the effect that occurs when acquired immunity against a pathogen, generated through infection or vaccination, within a population (the “herd”) has reached such a level that non-immune individuals in this population are also protected, because the pathogen can no longer be transmitted”. Furthermore, depending on condition, one additional sentence summarized the gist of the message, manipulating the salience of the individual benefit, social benefit, or both. Individual benefit was highlighted by the sentence “The more people are vaccinated in your environment, the more likely you are protected without vaccination”. Social benefit was highlighted by the sentence “If you get vaccinated, then you can protect others who are not vaccinated”. Vaccination costs. Participants were either informed that they could get vaccinated immediately (low cost) or that they would have to set up an appointment with the local hospital and that this appointment would take almost three hours (high cost). Measures. Dependent measure. Vaccination intention was assessed (“If you had the opportunity to vaccinate against [the illness] next week, what would you decide?”) on a 7-point Likert-type scale ranging from 1 = definitely not vaccinate to 7 = definitely vaccinate.1 COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 10 Manipulation check. As a manipulation check, one additional item assessed the perceived costs of the vaccination (“How do you estimate your personal vaccination costs?”; 1 = very low to 7 = very high). Procedure. After giving informed consent, participants were informed that all presented information is fictitious. The questionnaire began with the measurement of demographic characteristics. They were then asked to imagine a fictitious scenario: During a routine physical examination, the general practitioner informs them about the severe infectious disease Cornicoviszidosis. This recently discovered illness had been diagnosed increasingly often. The participants received additional information about the origin of Cornicoviszidosis, the name of the responsible virus (Cornicovi), the path of infection (smear infection), and the symptoms of the disease (severe vomiting and diarrhea, severe dehydration, and high fever). Participants received a data sheet for a fictional vaccine termed Macentat containing information about vaccine-adverse events: hypersensitivity reaction of the skin with probability p = .1; headache, p = .0001 to .001; vomiting, vertigo, and skin rash with a probability less than .0001. Information about herd immunity was displayed afterwards. Before participants indicated their intention to get vaccinated, they were informed about the costs of the vaccination. Finally, the manipulation checks were recorded and participants fully debriefed. Results We present eta-squared as an effect size indicator along with all statistically significant results. All non-significant comparisons have an F < 1 if not stated otherwise. Manipulation check. As intended, the vaccination costs in the high cost condition were perceived as significantly higher than in the low cost condition (Mhigh = 4.67, SD = 1.69; Mlow = 2.20, SD = 1.36; F(1, 340) = 222.06, p < .001, η2 = .40). COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 11 Vaccination intention. The mean values and standard deviations of vaccination intention by experimental condition are displayed in Table 1. Inspection of the means in Table 1 suggests that the control condition (without any herd immunity information) showed, on average, higher vaccination intentions than when herd immunity was communicated in either manner. Indeed, a post-hoc simple contrast analysis (control group vs. all other conditions) yields a significant difference, F(3, 363) = 3.69, p = .012, η2 = .030. Still, what are the specific effects of communicating individual vs. social benefits on vaccination intentions? H1 and H2 predict lower vaccination intentions when the individual benefit is salient (free-riding hypothesis), and higher vaccination intentions when the social benefit is salient (prosocial behavior hypothesis). H3 suggests an interaction between benefit salience and costs. To test the hypotheses, we conducted a 2 × 2 × 2 analysis of variance with vaccination intention as the dependent variable. Results support the free-riding hypothesis (H1): when individual benefit of herd immunity was communicated, vaccination intentions were significantly lower than when it was not communicated, Mcomm = 3.72, SD = 1.84; M¬ comm = 4.18, SD = 1.77; F(1, 334) = 4.33, p = .038, η2 = .012. There was no difference in vaccination intentions whether the social benefit was communicated or not, Mcomm = 4.01, SD = 1.86; M¬ comm = 3.89, SD = 1.78, yielding no evidence in support of the prosocial behavior hypothesis (H2). However, there was a significant interaction effect between the individual and social benefit communication conditions, F(1, 334) = 3.90, p = .049, η2 = .011. As Figure 2A shows, when social benefit was not communicated, vaccination intentions varied as a function of the communicated individual benefit: the vaccination intention was significantly lower when the individual benefit of vaccination was communicated than when it was not communicated, F(1, 177) = 9.38, Bonferroni-corrected p = .006, η2 = .051, indicating the tendency to free-ride on COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 12 others’ indirect protection. When the social benefit of herd immunity was communicated, however, there was no such difference, regardless of whether the individual benefit was additionally communicated. 2 In general, vaccination intentions were lower when vaccination costs were high than when they were low, Mhigh = 3.83, SD = 1.87; Mlow = 4.10, SD = 1.79; F(1, 334) = 4.57, p = .033, η2 = .013. As expected, vaccination costs interacted with the social benefit communication, F(1, 334) = 7.43, p = .007, η2 = .021. As Figure 2B shows, when the social benefit of herd immunity was communicated, vaccination intentions were higher when costs were low than when costs were high, F(1, 163) = 11.07, Bonferroni-corrected p = .002, η2 = .064, indicating conditional prosocial vaccination behavior. There was no such difference when social benefit was not salient. However, vaccination intentions under individual benefit salience did not differ between the low vs. high cost conditions. Taken together, results partially confirm the vaccination costs interaction hypothesis (H3). The three-way interaction was not significant, F < 1.6, ns. Discussion The goal of this paper was to assess if and how the communication of herd immunity may affect vaccination uptake. We devised a simple theoretical model of (non-)vaccination utility as a function of the perceived costs of the disease and the vaccination contingent on the number of vaccinated individuals in the population. Furthermore, some of the model’s implications were tested in an experiment. The data shows that communicating the concept of herd immunity can have two effects, depending on the gist of the message: First, when a message emphasized the individual benefit of indirect protection through the “herd”, individuals’ inclination to free-ride increased (H1). This was especially the case when the social COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 13 benefit of herd immunity was not communicated. Second, communicating the social benefit did not result in a general increase in vaccination intentions (contradicting H2). However, communicating the social benefit reduced free-riding and also had the potential to increase vaccination intentions when the costs of vaccinating are perceived as low. Thus, depending on which implication of herd immunity was made salient, vaccination intentions differed. The lacking overall positive effect of communicated social benefit along with the obtained free-riding effect pose the question whether the communication of herd immunity is advisable at all. Strong emphasis on the social benefit, however, still seems advisable: even if it might not have an overall positive effect, it might at least prevent free-riding. This becomes even more clear when we consider that many cues in the decision structure may invite free-riding: recent game-theoretic models of vaccination uptake have shown that the level of vaccination may decrease dramatically and fall below the social optimum if the expected costs of vaccination increase (e.g. due to a vaccine scare or anti-vaccination activism; Bhattacharyya & Bauch, 2010) or if the costs of the disease decrease (Jansen et al., 2003). This occurs mainly because of free-riding on the immunized herd (e.g., Bauch & Earn, 2004, Galvani, Reluga, & Chapman, 2007; Manfredi et al., 2010). Furthermore, individuals are sensitive to different levels of immunity in the population if these are varied in a withinsubjects’ setting (Vietri et al., 2012): the more people were vaccinated, the less likely participants were to vaccinate themselves. Our results contribute to this literature by showing that quite subtle communications are also sufficient to suggest a free-riding opportunity. Again, this implies that strategies that prevent free-riding are needed. The current results suggest that appealing to prosocial motives might be such a strategy to reduce free-riding tendencies (see also Shim et al., 2012). COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 14 As previous research focused particularly on the negative effect of indirect protection through herd immunity (free-riding; e.g., Bauch & Earn, 2004), more scientific attention should be directed to its positive effect (i.e. prosocial behavior), in order to assess the boundary conditions under which the communication of the social benefit of vaccination does increase vaccine intentions (for instance, as in the present experiment, under low perceived costs of vaccination; or when the risk for the self is low as shown by Vietri et al., 2012). This becomes particularly important if the direct effect of vaccination is very small or even absent and the indirect effect has important consequences for eradicating a disease (as in the most extreme case of malaria control; Carter, Mendis, Miller, Molyneux, & Saul, 2000). Limitations and Further Research A number of possible limitations to the results should be noted. First, the hypothetical scenario and the self-report data (intentions) might limit the external validity of the results. Additionally, online-experiments may be subject to self-selection bias. Indeed, the participants in our sample were typically well educated. However, including education in the analyses did not affect the pattern of results. Moreover, the present study tests hypotheses derived from a general game theoretical model. We do not assume different relations between utility functions for individuals with different levels of education. We therefore conclude that external validity of the results is given even though the sample might be skewed towards higher educated participants. Further, we neither manipulated nor measured the individual perception of vaccine coverage and could therefore not test its impact on perceived costs of the disease. This should be a next step in further research. For instance, an experimental public goods setting of vaccination (see Chapman et al., 2012) may be a viable framework to test the dynamic relationship between COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 15 vaccination uptake and the number of others vaccinated. Nevertheless, the perceived risk of both the vaccination and the disease were assessed in this study and can serve as proxies for perceived costs (see footnote 1). As expected, the effects were stronger if E[cD] - E[cV] < 0 than if E[cD] - E[cV] > 0 (see footnote 2). The presence of the effects in the total sample suggests that, even if only a sub-sample of the population perceives higher vaccination than disease costs, communicating the social benefit can have positive effects on vaccination intentions. The present experiment was ambiguous regarding whether the other protected individuals were not able to get vaccinated (because they are too young or immunocompromised) or simply not willing to do so (free-riders) when the individual benefit of herd immunity was communicated. A large amount of research in economics has shown that people are willing to cooperate if others are also expected to do so (conditional cooperation; e.g., Bolton & Ockenfels, 2000; Fehr Gächter, & Fischbacher, 2001; Fehr & Schmidt, 1999). Moreover, in social psychology there is evidence that prosocial behavior is more likely when uncontrollable factors created the situation of need (Weiner, 1980). Thus, if it is communicated that others are explicitly not able to protect themselves, the communicated social benefit of herd immunity should have a larger effect. Similarly, the way in which costs were manipulated represents only one out of several possibilities. As said before, costs accrue due to time, money, side effects, inconvenience, etc. Future studies should use different approaches to manipulate costs. The perception or fear of potential side effects (such as elicited in vaccine scares) decreases vaccination intentions and are among the most prominent reasons against vaccination (Betsch, Renkewitz, Betsch, & Ulshöfer, 2010; Brown et al., 2010a, 2010b). Thus, it is possible that if costs are manipulated via potential side effects of the vaccine, the obtained effects may be stronger. COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 16 Practical Implications Overall, it seems advisable to stress vaccination’s social benefit in vaccine advocacy. This is especially the case if the concept of herd immunity is communicated to the public, such as during the process of eradicating diseases, e.g. the measles and rubella in Europe until 2015 (Christie & Gay, 2011). If the indirect effects of vaccination become obvious, free-riding might increase, as vaccine coverage is usually already high (but not high enough). Therefore, stressing the social benefit may help to reach critical vaccination levels in order to eradicate diseases. Protection of others is especially important in contexts with highly vulnerable individuals, such as immunocompromised patients in a hospital. For this reason, the WHO recommends vaccination against influenza for health care personnel (HCP). Despite the availability of an effective and well-tolerated vaccine, low seasonal and pandemic influenza vaccine acceptance among HCP is a major problem detailed in many studies from all over of the world (Salgado, Giannetta, Hayden & Farr, 2004; Talbot et al., 2010). The perception of vaccination risks in addition to other expected vaccination costs are major reasons why HCP do not get vaccinated against influenza (Betsch & Wicker, 2012; Wicker, Rabenau, Doerr & Allwinn, 2009). One could speculate that HCP may generally be more prosocially oriented (e.g., Van Lange, 1999). Thus, building on the idea of tailoring health messages (Noar, Benac & Harris, 2007), appeals to the social benefit of vaccination could be a viable strategy to increase HCP’s vaccination rates. Conclusions We conclude that the social benefits of vaccination need to be explicitly communicated if the individual decisions are meant to consider public health benefits. Even if it does not generally raise vaccination intentions, it can prevent free-riding and has the potential to increase COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 17 vaccination intentions when the costs to vaccinate are low. A recent approach for vaccine advocacy suggests that ‘Vaccination Adoption = Access + Acceptance’ (Thomson & Watson, 2012). Acceptance can be understood as E[cD] - E[cV] > 0 or as prosocially oriented behavior under E[cD] - E[cV] < 0. Access can be understood as low costs to obtain the vaccine. The latter also proved to be an important variable in our study. Especially when vaccination is not the individually optimal solution and public health considerations suggest a collective benefit of vaccination (e.g. cocooning newborns against pertussis, preventing school children from spreading influenza to the elderly), access should be very easy in order to obtain high vaccination coverage. COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 18 References Ajzen, I., & Fishbein M. (1980). Understanding attitudes and predicting social behaviour. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Anderson, R. M., & May R. M (1985). Vaccination and herd immunity to infectious diseases. Nature, 318, 323–329. Bauch, C. T., & Earn, D. J. D. (2004). Vaccination and the theory of games. PNAS: Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 270, 1573-1578. Betsch, C. & Sachse, K. (in press). Debunking vaccination myths – Strong risk negations can increase perceived vaccination risks. Health Psychology. Betsch, C., Renkewitz, F. & Haase, N. (in press). Effect of narrative reports about vaccine adverse events and bias-awareness disclaimers on vaccine decisions: A simulation of an online patient social network. Medical Decision Making. Betsch, C., Renkewitz, F., Betsch, T., & Ulshöfer, C. (2010). The influence of vaccine-critical internet pages on perception of vaccination risks. Journal of Health Psychology, 15, 446455. Betsch, C., Ulshöfer, C., Renkewitz, F. & Betsch, T., & (2011). The influence of narrative vs. statistic information on perceiving vaccination risks. Medical Decision Making, 31, 742753. Bhattacharyya, S., & Bauch, C. T. (2010). A game dynamic model of delayer strategies in vaccinating behaviour for pediatric infectious diseases. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 267, 276-282. Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review, 90, 166-193. COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 19 Brewer, N. T., Chapman, G. B., Gibbons, F. X., Gerrard, M., McCaul, K. D., & Weinstein, N. D. (2007). Meta-analysis of the relationship between risk perception and health behavior: The example of vaccination. Health Psychology, 26, 136-145. Brewer, N. T., & Fazekas K. I. (2007). Predictors of HPV vaccine acceptability: A theoryinformed, systematic review. Preventive Medicine, 45, 107-114. Brown, K., Fraser, G., Ramsay, M., Shanley, R., Cowley, N., van Wijgerden, J., … Sevdalis, N. (2011). Attitudinal and demographic predictors of measles-mumps-rubella vaccine (MMR) uptake during the UK catch-up campaign 2008-09: Cross-sectional survey. PLoS ONE, 6. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0019381 Brown, K. F., Kroll, J. S., Hudson, M. J., Ramsay, M., Green, J., Long, S. J., ... Sevdalis, N. (2010a). Factors underlying parental decisions about combination childhood vaccinations including MMR: A systematic review. Vaccine, 28, 4235-4248. Brown, K. F., Kroll, J. S., Hudson, M. J., Ramsay, M., Green, J., Vincent, C. A., … Sevdalis, N. (2010b). Omission bias and vaccine rejection by parents of healthy children: Implications for the influenza A/H1N1 vaccination programme. Vaccine, 28, 4181-4185. Carter, R., Mendis, K. N., Miller, L. H., Molyneux, L., & Saul, A. (2000). Malaria transmissionblocking vaccines: How can their development be supported? Nature Medicine, 6, 241244. Chapman, G.B., Li, M., Vietri, J., Ibuka, Y., Thomas, D., Yoon, H., & Galvani, A.P. (2012). Using Game Theory to Examine Incentives in Influenza Vaccination Behavior. Psychological Science, 23, 1008-1015. Chen, R. T. (1999). Vaccine risks: Real, perceived and unknown. Vaccine, 17, 41-46. Christie, A. S., & Gay, A. (2011). The measles initiative: Moving toward measles eradication. The Journal of Infectious Diseases, 204, 14-17. Dawes, R. M. (1980). Social dilemmas. Annual Review of Psychology, 31, 169-193. COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 20 Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817-868. Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (2006). The economics of fairness, reciprocity and altruism – Experimental evidence and new theories. In S.-C. Kolm & J.M. Ythier (Eds.), Handbook on the Economics of Giving, Reciprocity and Altruism (pp. 615-691). Amsterdam: NorthHolland Publishing. Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiments. Economic Letters, 71, 397-404. Galvani, A. P., Reluga, T. C., & Chapman, G. B. (2007). Long-standing influenza vaccination policy is in accord with individual self-interest but not with the utilitarian optimum. PNAS: Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 104, 5692-5697. Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162, 1243-1248. Hershey, J.C., Asch, D.A., Thumasathit, T., Meszaros, J., Waters, V.V. (1994). The roles of altruism, free riding, and bandwagoning in vaccination decisions. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 59(2), 177-187. Jansen, V. A., Stollenwerk, N., Jensen, H. J., Ramsay, M. E., Edmunds, W. J., & Rhodes, C. J. (2003). Measles out-breaks in a population with declining vaccine uptake. Science, 301, 804. Liao, Q., Cowling, B. J., Lam, W. W. T., & Fielding, R.(2011). Factors affecting intention to receive and self-reported receipt of 2009 pandemic (H1N1) vaccine in Hong Kong: A longitudinal study. PLoS ONE, 6. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0017713 Manfredi, P., Della Posta, P., d’Onofrio, A., Salinelli, E., Centrone, F., Meo, C., & Poletti, P. (2010). Optimal vaccination choice, vaccination games, and rational exemption: An appraisal. Vaccine, 28, 98-109. COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 21 Nguyen, T., Henningsen, K.H., Brehaut, J.C., Hoe, E., Wilson, K. (2011). Acceptance of a pandemic influenza vaccine: a systematic review of surveys of the general public. Journal of Infection and Drug Resistance, 4, 197-207. Noar, S. M., Benac, C. N., & Harris, M. S. (2007). Does tailoring matter? Meta-analytic review of tailored print health behavior change interventions. Psychological Bulletin, 133, 67393. Reyna, V.F. (2012). Risk perception and communication in vaccination decisions: A fuzzy-trace theory approach. Vaccine, 30, 3790-3797. Salgado, C. D., Giannetta, E. T., Hayden, F. G., & Farr, B. M. (2004). Preventing nosocomial influenza by improving the vaccine acceptance rate of clinicians. Infection Control and Hospital Epidemiology, 25, 923-928. Schelling, T. C. (1960). The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Shim, E., Chapman, G.B., Townsend, J.P., Galvani, A.P. (2012). The influence of altruism on influenza vaccination decisions. Journal of the Royal Society Interface, 9(74), 2234-43. Smith, C. E. G. (1970) . Prospects of the control of disease. Proceedings of the Royal Society of Medicine, 63,1181-1190. Sturm, L. A., Mays, R. M., & Zimet, G. D. (2005). Parental beliefs and decision making about child and adolescent immunization: From polio to sexually transmitted infections. Journal of Developmental and Behavioral Pediatrics, 26, 441-452. Talbot, T. R., Babcock, H., Caplan, A. L., Cotton, D., Maragakis, L. L., Poland G. A., … Weber, D. J. (2010). Revised SHEA position paper: Influenza vaccination of healthcare personnel. Infection Control and Hospital Epidemiology, 31, 987-995. Thomson, A., & Watson, M. (2012). Listen, understand, engage. Science Translational Medicine, 4. Van Lange, P. A. M. (1999). The pursuit of joint outcomes and equality in outcomes: Integrative COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 22 model of social value orientation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 77, 337349. Vietri, J., Li, M., Galvani, A. P., & Chapman, G. B. (2012). Vaccinating to help ourselves and others. Medical Decision Making, 32, 447-458. Weiner, B. (1980). A cognitive (attribution)-emotion-action model of motivated behavior: An analysis of judgments of help-giving. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 39, 186-200. Wicker, S., Rabenau, H. F., Doerr, H. W., & Allwinn, R. (2009). Influenza vaccination compliance among health care workers in a German university hospital. Infection, 37, 197-202. COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 23 Footnotes 1 Prior to intention we also assessed the perceived risk of the disease and the vaccination (general risk [0-100], respectively). We did not expect any effects of the manipulations on the assessed variables, as we did not provide any information about vaccine coverage. We used the risk variables as proxies for the expected costs of the disease and vaccination. The mean perceived risk of the disease was Mdisease = 41.18 (SD = 23.92); the risk of the vaccination was Mvaccination = 26.65 (SD = 22.14; t(341) = 7.89, p < .001). This mirrors the experiment materials, as the disease was described as having severe symptoms, while potential vaccination side-effects were rather moderate. As a consequence, 100 participants perceived a higher risk of vaccination than of the disease, while the majority of 237 participants perceived higher disease than vaccination risks; for 5 participants the costs of disease were equal to the costs of vaccination. 2 Strictly speaking, the pre-conditions for considering vaccination as a social dilemma are only given for those participants who perceived the costs (risk) of the vaccination to be higher than the costs (risk) of the disease (see Figure 1). In support of this, two separate analyses showed that the effects were indeed consistently stronger if E[cD] - E[cV] < 0 than if E[cD] - E[cV] > 0. The effect sizes if E[cD] - E[cV] < 0 were η2 = .014 for individual benefit communication (vs. η2 < .01 if E[cD] - E[cV] > 0) and η2 = .055 (vs. η2 = .001) for the interaction between social and individual benefit communication. We conclude that this demonstrates the validity of the proposed model. COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 24 Table 1. Means and standard deviations (in brackets) of the intention to vaccinate as a function of communicated individual and social benefit as well as costs to obtain the vaccination. individual benefit social benefit communicated not communicated high vaccination cost communicated 3.44 (1.86) 3.62 (1.92) not communicated 3.75 (1.91) 4.20 (1.63) low vaccination cost communicated 4.54 (1.50) 4.40 (1.92) not communicated 3.30 (1.83) 4.42 (1.51) COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 25 Figure 1. Simplified general model of vaccination as a strategic interaction. Note: n refers to the number of all other individuals in the population (N - 1) who decide to vaccinate. The grey dashed line indicates the expected individual costs of the vaccination (E[cV]) and the grey solid line indicates the expected individual costs of the disease (E[cD]). The black dashed line indicates an individual’s expected utility if he/she decides to vaccinate (EUV), whereas the black solid line indicates the individual’s expected utility if he/she decides not to vaccinate (EU¬ V). Vc refers to the critical vaccination level (herd immunity threshold) that must be achieved to eradicate the disease, which is simplified 1 - 1/R0, with R0 being the basic reproduction number of the infectious disease (Fine et al., 2011). The shaded area indicates a conflict between individual and collective interest, transforming the vaccination decision into a N-person prisoner’s dilemma. COMMUNICATING HERD IMMUNITY IN VACCINE ADVOCACY 26 Figure 2. Intention to vaccinate as a function of communicated social benefit and communicated individual benefit (A) or vaccination costs (B).