DP Why is Exporting Hard in Some Sectors? Anders AKERMAN
Transcription
DP Why is Exporting Hard in Some Sectors? Anders AKERMAN
DP RIETI Discussion Paper Series 13-E-015 Why is Exporting Hard in Some Sectors? Anders AKERMAN Stockholm University Rikard FORSLID Stockholm University OKUBO Toshihiro Keio Univesity The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/ RIETI Discussion Paper Series 13-E-015 March 2013 Why is Exporting Hard in Some Sectors? * Anders AKERMAN † Stockholm University Rikard FORSLID ‡ Stockholm University OKUBO Toshihiro § Keio University Abstract This paper models the market entry cost of exporters as dependent on the size of the export market as well as on sector specific factors. We introduce these features in a Melitz trade model with heterogeneous firms. The predictions of our model are tested using Swedish and Japanese firm level data. We find that sector level advertising or sales promotion intensity is an important component of the market entry cost. A larger market size, if anything, lowers entry costs. Keywords: Heterogeneous firms, Market size, Market entry costs JEL classification: D21, F12, F15 RIETI Discussion Papers Series aims at widely disseminating research results in the form of professional papers, thereby stimulating lively discussion. The views expressed in the papers are solely those of the author(s), and do not represent those of the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry. * Financial support from the Swedish Research Council and Handelsbanken research foundation is gratefully acknowledged by Akerman and Forslid. † Stockholm University, email: anders.akerman@ne.su.se. ‡ Stockholm University, CEPR; email: rf@ne.su.se. § Keio University; email: okubo@econ.keio.ac.jp This study is conducted as a part of the project “Study of the Creation of the Japanese Economy and Trade and Direct Investment” undertaken at Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI). 1 Introduction It is empirically well established that exporting …rms tend to be more productive, larger, and endure longer than domestic …rms; see Tybout (2003) for a survey.1 One of the proposed reasons for this is the costs of entering a foreign market. The purpose of this paper is to investigate the nature of market entry costs. We employ a heterogeneous …rms and trade model a la Melitz (2003), where the market entry cost is modelled as having a …xed and a variable part as well as a sector speci…c component. While the standard models of heterogeneous …rms employ a …xed and exogenous market entry cost, Arkolakis (2010) proposes a model with an endogenous market entry cost. He uses a model of advertising where the probability that an advertising message is received by one consumer increases with the size of the population. Thus, a …rm gets a relatively larger payo¤ for a small investment in marketing when exporting to larger countries. The marginal exporter that is just su¢ ciently productive to export will therefore prefer to export to a large rather than to a small market. A small …rm will therefore …nd it easier to enter a large market, and this is consistent with the empirical observation by e.g. Eaton, Kortum, and Kramarz (2005) that show that many small …rms typically export a small amount to large markets. As in Arkolakis (2010), we allow the market size to a¤ect entry costs, but while a large market may be easier to enter because it is easier to …nd consumers that match a particular product, it may also be the case that it is more di¢ cult to enter a large market e.g. due to higher advertising requirements. Our speci…cation allows for both these possibilities. We also model the market entry cost as a product group or sector dependent. It may e.g. require more marketing to establish a branded consumer good, such as soft drinks or clothes, in a foreign market than to establish a more standardised product. We test the predictions of our model using data on Swedish …rm level export to Japan combined with Japanese …rm level data. We use the Japanese data to calculate market speci…c advertising outlays, sales promotion and …rm sales. We also have sector level data for tari¤s. Our empirical part support the notion that higher average adverting outlays at the sector level makes it more di¢ cult to enter a foreign market. A larger market size, if anything, makes it easier to enter a market. However, this e¤ect is not signi…cant in the regressions. The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 contains the model. Section 3 contains empirical tests. Finally, section 4 concludes the paper. 2 The Model This paper introduces a formulation of the market entry cost that is sector and market speci…c in a multisector version of Melitz (2003) monopolistic competition trade model with heterogeneous …rms. 1 Other studies include Aw, Chung, and Roberts (2000), Bernard and Jensen (1995, 1999a, 1999b) Clerides, Lach, and Tybout (1998) as well as Eaton, Kortum, and Kramarz (2004). 1 2.1 Basics There are two countries (Home and Foreign) and multiple sectors. The A-sector (traditional sector) is a Walrasian, homogeneous-goods sector with costless trade. There is also a continuum of M-sectors (manufactures) marked by increasing returns, Dixit-Stiglitz monopolistic competition and iceberg trade costs. M-sector …rms face constant marginal production costs and three types of …xed costs. Each country has a single primary factor of production labour, L, used in each sector. For simplicity, there is no comparative advantage across the M-sectors. All manufacturing sectors have an identical structure but …nal demand for each sector di¤ers. Firms in the manufacturing sectors are heterogeneous a la Melitz(2003). In essence, there is heterogeneity with respect to …rms’marginal costs. Each Dixit-Stiglitz …rm/variety is associated with a particular labour input coe¢ cient – denoted as ai for …rm i. After sinking FE units of labour in the product innovation process, the …rm is randomly assigned an ‘ai ’from a probability distribution G(a). On the other hand there are three types of …xed costs. The …rst …xed cost, FE , is the standard Dixit-Stiglitz cost of developing a new variety. The second and third …xed costs are ‘beachhead’costs re‡ecting the one-time expense of introducing a new variety into a market. These costs are here assumed to depend on the size of the market. Consumers in each nation have two-tier utility functions with the upper tier (Cobb-Douglas) determining the consumer’s division of expenditure among the sectors and the second tier (CES), dictating the consumer’s preferences over the various di¤erentiated varieties within each Msector. All individuals have the utility function Uj = 0 ln CA + is the set of manufacturing sectors, Z Z j ln CM j dj (1) j2 where j dj =1 0, and CA is consumption of the j2 homogenous good. Each manufacturing sector j enters the utility function through the index CM j ; de…ned by CM j 2 ZNj 6 ( = 4 cij 1)= 0 3 7 di5 =( 1) ; (2) Nj being the mass of varieties consumed in sector j, cij the amount of variety i consumed in sector j; and > 1 the elasticity of substitution. Each consumer spends a share j of his income on sector j, and demand for a variety i in sector j is therefore xij = pij Pj1 j Y; where pij is the consumer price of variety i in sector j, Y is income; and Pj (3) N Rj 0 the price index of manufacturing goods in sector j. 2 p1ij ! di 1 1 The unit factor requirement of the homogeneous good (Agriculture) is one unit of labour. This good is freely traded and since it is chosen as the numeraire pA = w = 1; (4) w being the nominal wage of workers in all countries. Shipping the manufactured good involves a frictional trade cost of the “iceberg” form: for one unit of a good from one country to the other, > 1 units must be shipped. It is assumed that trade costs are equal in both directions and that = 1: Pro…t maximization by a manufacturing …rm i leads to consumer price pi = 1 ai . Manufacturing …rms draw their marginal cost, a; from the probability distribution G(a) after having sunk FE units of labour to develop a new variety. Having learned their productivity, …rms decide on entry in the domestic and foreign market, respectively. Firms will enter a market as long as the operating pro…t in this market is su¢ ciently large to cover the beachhead (market entry) cost associated with the market. Because of the constant mark-up pricing, it is easily shown that operating pro…ts equal sales divided by . Using this and (3), the critical ’cut-o¤’ levels of the marginal costs in sector j are given by: 1 Bj = Fd (Dj ); aDj 1 aXj (5) Bj = Fx (Dj ); (6) where Dj (Dj ) is Home (Foreign) demand in sector j, i.e. Dj represents trade freeness. Bj Dj j jL 1 and represents market potential where j ( 1 1 ) 2 [0; 1] P1 . The market entry cost (beachhead cost) is assumed to depend on the demand size, and we will parametrize this dependence below. However, note that it is natural that the beachhead costs F s are sector speci…c. For example, branded consumer goods may require more marketing than raw materials. Finally, free entry ensures that the ex-ante expected pro…t of developing a new variety in sector j equals the investment cost: aDj Z 0 2.2 a1 Bj Fd (Dj ) dG(a) + aXj Z a1 Bj Fx (Dj ) dG(a) = FE : (7) 0 Solving for the Long-run Equilibrium First, our model is two-country with multiple sectors but the model is solvable in terms of a representative sector since the sector level expenditure shares, j; are …xed . We focus on one of Manufacturing sectors. Without loss of generality we drop subscript j, since sectors are mirror 3 images. Second, we follow Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (2004) in assuming the probability density function to be a Pareto distribution, which a cumulative density function given by2 : a a0 G(a) = where : (8) is shape parameter and the scale parameter, a0 , is normallised as unity. Substituting the cut-o¤ conditions (5) and (6) into the free-entry condition (7) gives B, B= where 1 > 1, and FE Fd 1 1 (D) ( 1) (1 1 (D) (D ) Fx (D) Fd (D) (D) 1 (D )) !1 ; (9) 2 [0; 1] is a measure of openness (See Baldwin and Forslid (2010)). Using (9) and the cut-o¤ conditions gives the cut-o¤ marginal costs: aD = aX = ( ( (1 1) FE Fd (D) (D )) (D) (D ) 1 1) (D )FE Fx (D ) (1 ; (10) (D)) (D) (D ) 1 : (11) From these, it is seen that, contrary to the standard model by Melitz (2003), the market size will a¤ect the cut-o¤ marginal costs. We will assume that FX (D ) 1 (D ) 1 (D) 1 > FD (D) for all sectors j:3 This assumption implies that aX < aD . may be written as = 1 1 naD (1 +n aD ) aX aD +1 ! ; (12) and the mass of …rms in each country can be calculated using (9), (10), and (11) together with the fact that B = D : n= ( 1) D (1 Fd (D) (1 (D)) D (D) (1 (D )) : (D) (D )) (1 (D)) (13) Welfare may be measured by indirect utility, which is proportional to the real wage It su¢ ces to examine Pj . Using (10), (11), (12), and (13), we have P =( 1 ) D Fd 1 (D)FE ( 1) 1 1 (D ) (D) (D ) R wj ln P : 1 ( 1) : (14) This expression shows that, as in the Melitz (2003) model, welfare always increases (P decreases) with trade liberalization; that is, with a higher or a lower FX (D ) FD (D) . 2 This assumption is consistent with the empirical …ndings by e.g. Axtell (2001). 3 The corresponding condition in Melitz (2003) is that 4 FX > FD : 2.3 Parametrisation of the market entry cost In the following, we parametrise the sector level market entry costs as: Fdj (D) j fd + Dj ; Fxj (D ) fx + Dj j ; j > 0; 7 0: (15) The variable component of the beachhead cost is dependent on market size, while the constant terms picks up costs that are independent of market size. It is quite natural that the beachhead cost would have one …xed and one variable component. The constant f represents the …xed cost of standardizing a product for a particular market or the cost of producing an advertisement tailored to a particular market with its culture and language. We assume that these costs are larger when a …rm enters a foreign market: fX > fD : The variable cost term Dj represents the fact that the cost of entry depends on the demand (market size), Dj ; in each sector j. >0 implies that the cost of entry increases in the size of the market. For instance, because the number of free product samples or advertising posters increases in the size of the market. <0 implies that the cost of entry decreases in the size of the market. This may be e.g. because it is more likely that at least some consumers buy your product in a large market (Arkolakis (2010)). The sign of may depend on the type of product, but as in previous studies, data only allows us to identify the sector level average Finally, the sector speci…c parameter j in the empirical part below. represents the possibility that market entry costs di¤er among di¤erent product groups or sectors. Branded consumer goods may e.g. require more more marketing than standardised inputs or raw materials. 2.4 Export cuto¤s and the foreign market The cut-o¤ marginal cost of an exporter in sector j is from (11) given by aXj = ( 0 1) FE @ (1 1 Fx (Dj ) (D j) 1 (Dj )) A : (Dj ) (16) Substituting in the market entry cost for the foreign market from (15) gives aXj = ( j 1) FE fx + Dj 0 B B B @ (1 fx +Dj fd +Dj 1 (Dj )) 1 (Dj ) C C C: A (17) A …rst result, which can be seen directly from the expression, implies that the export cut-o¤ is tougher in markets with a high j. Proposition 1 The cut-o¤ productivity of exporters increases in 5 j: Proof: The result follows directly from (17). The e¤ect of the foreign market size, , D ; is given by the following proposition Proposition 2 The cut-o¤ productivity of exporters increases in D if D if > 0 and decreases in < 0 given that fX > fD : Proof: See Appendix. We now turn to data to test these predictions. 3 Empirics Our theory should in principle be tested using cross country …rm level data. However, such data is hard to …nd. There would in any case be a problem of unobserved heterogeneity among countries that makes it di¢ cult to establish the source of varying entry costs. We therefore here use Swedish …rm level export to one country, where each sector is considered a separate market. We use Swedish export to Japan combining Swedish …rm level data with Japanese data. Sweden is one of the most successfully export countries in the world, and most Swedish …rms are exporters. On the other hand, Japan is one of the most closed economies, with a market that is di¢ cult to penetrate for foreign …rms. Furthermore, there is a substantial physical and cultural distance between Sweden and Japan, and we therefore expect …xed market entry costs to be relatively important for Swedish exports to Japan. 3.1 Data We use manufacturing census data for Sweden. The census data contain information on a large number of variables such as export (tSEK), employment (number of employees), capital stock (tSEK), use of raw materials (tSEK), value added and production value (tSEK) at the …rm level from 2000-2007. We can therefore calculate …rms level productivity as the residual from sector-speci…c production functions estimated by the Levinson Petrin method. We have information about the Japanese market from two data sources. One is sectoral aggregation from …rm level data, entitled the Results of the Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities (Kigyou Katsudo Kihon Chosa in Japanese) of year 2005 from Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry of Japan (METI). This dataset provides information on the activities and organisation for all Japanese …rms with more than 50 employees and a capital of more than 30 million yen. The sample includes not only Japanese …rms (i.e. domestic …rms) but also foreign owned …rms, which is de…ned as …rms with a foreign ownership of more than 33 percent. We aggregate this …rm level data to the 3-digit sector level. The other data source is the Japanese Industrial Productivity Database (JIP data) prepared by the Research Instutute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI). This dataset contains sectoral information about the Japanese market (108 sectors in agriculture, mining, manufacturing and service). We calculate the sales promotion ratio and the advertising cost ratio at the sectoral level, using 6 sales promotion costs, advertisement expenditure and total sales from the Results of the Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities dataset. It is possible that the advertising and marketing requirements di¤er among foreign and domestic …rms in Japan, and we therefore both use the average sales promotion of foreign …rms in Japan by sector and a measure of advertising per sales for all …rms. From the JIP data we use data on demand and tari¤ rates at the sectorial level. Finally, we match these sectoral variables to the Swedish data. 3.2 Results Consider …rst the relationship between the marketing intensity in a market and exporter productivity. We use the advertising ratio (advertising per sales) as well as the sales promotion ration (sales promotion per sales) as measures of marketing intensity. The main di¤erence being that the sales promotion data is collected only among foreign …rms in Japan, whereas the advertising ratio is for all …rms in the market. We have estimated …rm productivity using the Levinson Petrin method. To have an impression of the importance of the marketing intensity of a market for the productivity of exporters we divide the markets (sectors) into two groups: those above and those below the mean advertising ratio (advertising per sales) and those above and below the mean sales promotion ratio. We then make a kernel density plot for exporters belonging to the two groups of exporter. Figure 1 shows how the entire productivity distribution of exporters to markets with intense advertising or sales promotion is shifted to the right compared to exporters to the less marketing intensive markets. This pattern is present for both measures of marketing costs. 7 0 Kernel density .2 .4 .6 .8 Adv ertisement ratio 2 3 4 5 6 7 5 6 7 0 Kernel density .2 .4 .6 .8 Sales promotion ratio 2 3 4 Below median Abov e m edian Figure 1: Productivity distributions of Swedish exporters to Japan. Turning to sector level averages, Figure 2 and Figure 3 plot our two measures of marketing intensity against sector average exporter productivity. Both …gures show a marked positive relationship between exporter productivity and the market intensity in a market. A very similar pattern emerges when plotting productivity calculated at the 3-digit sector level as shown in Appendix. The pattern of Figure 2 and Figure 3 is consistent with Proposition 1: the exporting cut-o¤ productivity being higher in markets with a higher marketing intensity ( 8 j ). 5 1 2 Productivity (log) 3 4 5 4 Productivity (log) 3 2 1 -10 -8 -6 Advertising exp./sales (log) -4 -2 -2 -1.5 Sales promotion exp./sales (log) -1 Figure 2: Advertising intensity and exporter Figure 3: Sales promotion intensity and exporter productivity. productivity. We turn to next to the e¤ect of the size of the export market. Figure 4 plots the size 1 Productivity (log) 2 3 4 5 (demand) of Japanese sectors against the average productivity of the exporters. 8 10 12 Market size (demand) (log) 14 16 Figure 4: Market size and exporter productivity. Figure 4 shows a negative relationship between average productivity and market size (a negative ): That is, this pattern is consistent with entry costs being lower in large markets, as proposed by Arkolakis (2010). However, the relationship between exporter productivity and market size will not turn out signi…cant in the regressions below. Finally, Table 1 shows a set of regressions with exporter productivity as the dependent 9 variable. We use sector level demand and average sector level tari¤s as controls alongside with our two measures of marketing intensity. We show regressions with and without clustering at the sector level, as well as one regression where the data has been collapsed by sector. In particular sales promotion per sales by foreign …rms in Japan has a very strong and signi…cant e¤ect on average exporter productivity. Also advertising per sales averaged over all …rms in a sector has a signi…cant e¤ect in two of the three regressions. The point estimate at the sectoral regression in (3) is larger than in the …rm level regression but we lack the precision to estimate it with statistical signi…cance. Table 1: Regressions results Dependent variable: Advertisement ratio (log) Productivity (log) (1) (2) (3) 0.110*** 0.110* 0.177 (0.0183) (0.0593) (0.140) Sales promotion ratio (log) Demand (log) (4) (5) (6) 0.476*** 0.476* 1.333** (0.0812) (0.255) (0.555) -0.0275 -0.0275 -0.0204 -0.0113 -0.0113 0.0493 (0.0170) (0.0734) (0.157) (0.0180) (0.0692) (0.144) 0.128 0.128 -0.0975 0.178** 0.178 -0.195 (0.0833) (0.299) (0.586) (0.0817) (0.279) (0.508) Observations 785 785 18 785 785 18 R-squared 0.06 0.06 0.115 0.06 0.06 0.30 Clustered standard errors NO YES NO NO YES NO Tari¤ (log) Note: Standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. 4 Conclusion This paper has introduced a market and sector dependent market entry or beachhead cost in the heterogeneous …rms and trade model of Melitz (2003). We model this cost as having one variable component that depends on the market size, and one …xed component. The …xed component could e.g. be interpreted as the cost of standardizing a product for a particular market, while the variable cost term e.g. represents the fact that the advertising cost of introducing a new product may depend on the size of the market (the number of consumers). We do not put any restriction on the e¤ect of the market size. A larger market may be easier to enter because it is easier to …nd consumers for a particular product, or it may be harder to enter due to higher costs of e.g. sampling. We also introduce a sector speci…c component in the formulation of the market entry cost. This component picks up sector level di¤erences e.g. in advertising intensity. 10 In essence we make a relatively small change to the framework of Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (2004), which preserves the analytical solvability of the model. We combine Swedish …rm level data with Japanese data to test the predictions of the model. The empirical part suggests that exporting is harder when there is a high advertising intensity in the export market. If anything, we …nd a negative relationship between exporter productivity and size of the export market, but this e¤ect is not signi…cant in the regressions. 11 References Arkolakis, C. (2010): “Market Penetration Costs and the New Consumers Margin in International Trade,” Journal of Political Economy, 118(6), 1151–1199. Aw, B., S. Chung, and M. Roberts (2000): “Productivity and Turnover in the Export Market: Micro Evidence from Taiwan and South Korea,” World Bank Economic Review, 14(6), 65–90. Axtell, R. L. (2001): “Zipf Distribution of U.S. Firm Sizes,” Science, 293(6), 1818–1820. Baldwin, R. E., and R. Forslid (2010): “Trade liberalisation with heterogeneous …rms,” Review of Development Economics, 14(2), 161–176. Bernard, A. B., and J. B. Jensen (1995): “Exporters, Jobs and Wages in U.S. Manufacturing, 1976-1987,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Microeconomics, 14(6), 67–119. (1999a): “Exceptional Exporter Performance: Cause, E¤ect, or Both?,” Journal of International Economics, 47(6), 1–26. (1999b): “Exporting and Productivity: Importance of Reallocation,” NBER Working Paper, 7135(6), 67–119. Clerides, S. K., S. Lach, and J. R. Tybout (1998): “Is Learning by Exporting Important? Microdynamic Evidence from Colombia, Mexico and Morocco,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(3), 903–947. Eaton, J., S. Kortum, and F. Kramarz (2004): “Dissecting Trade: Firms, Industries, and Export Destinations,” NBER Working Papers, 10344(3), 150–154. (2005): “An Anatomy of International Trade: Evidence from French Firms.,” 2005 Meeting Papers, Society for Economic Dynamics, 197. Helpman, E., M. J. Melitz, and S. R. Yeaple (2004): “Export versus FDI with Heterogeneous Firms,” American Economic Review, 94(4), 300–316. Melitz, M. J. (2003): “The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity,” Econometrica, 71(4), 1695–1725. Tybout, J. (2003): “Plant- and Firm-level Evidence on "New" Trade Theories,”in E. K. Choi and J. Harrigan (eds) Handbook of International Trade Blackwell, Oxford. 12 5 Appendix 5.1 Proof of proposition 2 Taking logs of (11) gives 1 ln aXj = fln(( 1) FE )(1 (Dj )) ln(Fx (Dj )) ln( 1 (Dj ) (Dj ))g: Di¤erentiation of ln aX in terms of D gives d ln aX = dD 1 dFx (D ) + Fx (Dj ) dD ( 1 1 (Dj ) 1 (Dj ) (Dj )) !2 d (D ) : dD To sign this expression note …rst that dFx (D ) dD dFx (D ) dD > 0 for >0 < 0 for < 0; from the de…nition of Fx : Next, to determine the sign of ln (D ) = (1 d (D ) dD we take the logarithm of ) ln(fx + Dj ) (1 (D ): ) ln(fd + Dj ) + ln : Di¤erentiation w.r.t. D gives d ln (D ) = (1 dD ) D 1 1 fx + Dj Given the assumption that fx > fd we have: d ln (D ) dD d ln (D ) dD < 0 for >0 > 0 for <0 Combining these results gives d ln aX dD d ln aX dD < 0 for >0 > 0 for < 0: 13 1 fd + Dj ! 4 Productivity (log) 3 2 1 1 2 Productivity (log) 3 4 5 Exporter productivity and the intensity of marketing 5 5.2 -10 -8 -6 Advertising exp./sales (log) -4 -2 -2.5 -2 -1.5 Sales promotion exp./sales (log) -1 Figure 2b: Advertising intensity and exporter Figure 3b: Sales promotion intensity and productivity at the 3-digit level. exporter productivity at the 3-digit level. 14 -.5