ECON337901: Solutions to First Final Exam, Spring
Transcription
ECON337901: Solutions to First Final Exam, Spring
Solutions to Final Exam ECON 337901 - Financial Economics Boston College, Department of Economics Peter Ireland Spring 2015 Thursday, April 30, 10:30 - 11:45am 1. Risk Aversion and Portfolio Allocation An investor has initial wealth Y0 = 100 and allocates the amount a to stocks, which provide return rG = 0.35 in a good state that occurs with probability 1/2 and return rB = −0.15 in a bad state that occurs with probability 1/2. The investor allocates the remaining Y0 − a to a risk-free bond which provides the return rf = 0.05 in both states. The investor has von Neumann-Morgenstern expected utility, with Bernoulli utility function of the logarithmic form u(Y ) = ln(Y ). a. In general, the investor’s portfolio allocation problem can be stated mathematically as max E{u[(1 + rf )Y0 + a(˜ r − rf )]}, a where r˜ is the random return on stocks, but under the particular assumptions about the Bernoulli utility function and stock returns made above, the problem can be written more specifically as max(1/2) ln(105 + 0.30a) + (1/2) ln(105 − 0.20a). a b. The first-order condition for the investor’s optimal choice a∗ is (1/2)(0.20) (1/2)(0.30) − = 0. 105 + 0.30a∗ 105 − 0.20a∗ This first-order condition leads to the numerical solution for a∗ as (1/2)(0.30) (1/2)(0.20) = 105 + 0.30a∗ 105 − 0.20a∗ (1/2)(0.30)(105 − 0.20a∗ ) = (1/2)(0.20)(105 + 0.30a∗ ) (0.30)(105) − (0.30)(0.20)a∗ = (0.20)(105) + (0.20) ∗ (0.30)a∗ (0.10)(105) = 2(0.30)(0.20)a∗ a∗ = (0.10)(105) = 87.5. 2(0.30)(0.20) 1 c. A second investor also has vN-M expected utility with Bernoulli utility function of the logarithmic form u(Y ) = ln(Y ), but has initial wealth Y0 = 1000 that is ten times as large as the investor considered in parts (a) and (b) above. Although it is possible to re-solve the entire problem after replacing the first investor’s Y0 = 100 with the second investor’s Y0 = 1000, we know from class that because the logarthimic utility function implies that the coefficient of relative risk aversion is constant, both of these investors will allocate the same fraction of their wealth to stocks. Since this fraction equals 0.875 for the first investor, it will equal 0.875 for the second investor as well. With Y0 = 1000, this second investor will therefore choose a∗ = 875. 2. Portfolio Allocation and the Gains from Diversification Asset 1 has expected return equal to µ1 = 10 and standard deviation of its return equal to σ1 = 4; asset 2 has expected return equal to µ2 = 7 and standard deviation of its return equal to σ2 = 2. The fraction of wealth in the portfolio allocated to asset 1 is w1 and the fraction of wealth allocated to asset 2 is w2 . a. Assuming that the correlation between the two returns is ρ12 = 1, the portfolio that sets w1 = 1/2 and w2 = 1/2 has expected return equal to µp = w1 µ1 + w2 µ2 = (1/2)10 + (1/2)7 = 5 + 3.5 = 8.5 and standard deviation of its return equal to σp = [w12 σ12 + w22 σ22 + 2w1 w2 σ1 σ2 ρ12 ]1/2 = [(1/2)2 16 + (1/2)2 4 + 2(1/2)(1/2)(4)(2)(1)]1/2 √ = (4 + 1 + 4)1/2 = 9 = 3. b. If instead the correlation between the two returns is ρ12 = 0, the same portfolio will have still have expected return µp = 8.5, but the standard deviation of its return will equal σp = [w12 σ12 + w22 σ22 + 2w1 w2 σ1 σ2 ρ12 ]1/2 = [(1/2)2 16 + (1/2)2 4 + 2(1/2)(1/2)(4)(2)(0)]1/2 √ = (4 + 1)1/2 = 5 = 2.24. c. A risk-free asset has return rf = 5. Still assuming, as in part (b), that the correlation between the two random returns is ρ12 = 0, the expected return on the portfolio that allocates the fraction w1 = 1/4 of wealth to asset 1, w2 = 1/4 of wealth to asset 2, and the remaining fraction wr = 1/2 to the risk-free asset is µp = w1 µ1 + w2 µ2 + wr rf = (1/4)10 + (1/4)7 + (1/2)5 = 2.5 + 1.75 + 2.5 = 6.75. There are a number of different ways of calculating the standard deviation of the return on this portfolio of assets, but perhaps the easiest is to note that since the two risky asset returns are assumed to be uncorrelated, and since the correlations between the 2 risk-free return and each of the risky returns are zero, all of the “cross-products” in the formula for the portfolio’s standard deviation equal zero, so that √ σp = (w12 σ12 + w22 σ22 )1/2 = [(1/4)2 16 + (1/4)2 4]1/2 = (1 + 1/4)1/2 = 5/2 = 1.12. 3. Modern Portfolio Theory The graph below traces out the minimum variance frontier from Modern Portfolio Theory. a. No investor with mean-variance utility would ever choose to hold portfolio C, since portfolio A offers a higher expected return with the same standard deviation. b. Investor 2, holding portfolio B, is more risk averse than investor 1, holding portfolio A, since investor 2 is accepting lower expected return in order to reduce the standard deviation of his or her portfolio’s random return. c. No, portfolio A does not exhibit mean-variance dominance over portfolio B since, while it does have a higher expected return, the standard deviation of its return is higher as well. 3 4. The Capital Asset Pricing Model The random return r˜M on the market portfolio has expected value E(˜ rM ) = 0.07 and the return on risk-free assets is rf = 0.02. a. According to the capital asset pricing model, the expected return on an asset with random return that has βj = 1 is E(˜ rj ) = rf + βj [E(˜ rM ) − rf ] = 0.02 + 1(0.07 − 0.02) = 0.07. b. The expected return on an asset with random return that has βj = 0 is E(˜ rj ) = rf + βj [E(˜ rM ) − rf ] = 0.02 + 0(0.07 − 0.02) = 0.02. c. The expected return on an asset with random return that has βj = −0.20 is E(˜ rj ) = rf + βj [E(˜ rM ) − rf ] = 0.02 − (0.20)(0.07 − 0.02) = 0.01. 5. The Market Model and Arbitrage Pricing Theory This version of the arbitrage pricing theory is built on the assumption that the random return r˜i on each individual asset i is determined by the market model r˜i = E(˜ ri ) + βi [˜ rM − E(˜ rM )] + εi . a. The APT implies that a well-diversified portfolio with beta βw will have random return r˜w1 = E(˜ rw1 ) + βw [˜ rM − E(˜ rM )]. b. The APT also implies that the well-diversified portfolio with beta βw will have expected return E(˜ rw1 ) = rf + βw [E(˜ rM ) − rf ]. c. If you find another well-diversified portfolio with the same beta βw that has an expected return E(˜ rw2 ) that is lower than the expected return given in the answer to part (b), you can take a long position worth x in the portfolio described in parts (a) and (b) and a short position worth −x in this new portfolio. This strategy is self-financing, and since both portfolios are well-diversified and have the same betas, the strategy is free of risk as well. It is therefore profitable for sure, and the larger the value of x, the larger the profit you will make. 4