Controlling the Floor: Parties as Procedural Coalitions in the House
Transcription
Controlling the Floor: Parties as Procedural Coalitions in the House
Controlling the Floor: Parties as Procedural Coalitions in the House Author(s): Eric Schickler and Andrew Rich Source: American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 41, No. 4 (Oct., 1997), pp. 1340-1375 Published by: Midwest Political Science Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2960492 . Accessed: 01/02/2011 20:08 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at . http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=mpsa. . Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Midwest Political Science Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to American Journal of Political Science. http://www.jstor.org Controllingthe Floor: Parties as ProceduralCoalitions in the House* Eric Schickler, University of California, Berkeley Andrew Rich, Yale University Theory:Partisancontrol of House organizationis contested by ideological cross-party coalitions thatvary in strengthwith the size of the majoritypartyand its homogeneity,as well as the natureof the issues underconsideration. Hypotheses: Key House rules are responsive to changes in the balance of power on the floor, even in the face of majoritypartyopposition.Majoritypartydefectorson votes on key rules are unlikely to be sanctionedunless the partyhas a strongmajorityand is relatively unified. Methods: An analysis of rules changes since 1919 pertainingto the dischargeprocess, Rules Committee,and committeejurisdictions,and of the conditionsunderwhich majority partymembersare sanctionedfor disloyal behavior. Results: The development since the mid-1970s of majority party control over House rules is a substantialdeparturefrom priorexperience,and appearsto be a precariousstate of affairs. Thetransformations wroughtby the Republicantakeoverof Congressin 1995makethis a propitioustimefor theoriesemphasizingthe importanceof politicalpartiesin shapinglegislativepolitics.Politicalscientistshavein recent yearsput fortha burgeoningliteraturereconsideringandelevatingthe place of Congressional parties in legislative studies (Davidson 1988; Kiewiet and McCubbins1991; Rohde 1991). Cox and McCubbins(1993, 1994)provideone of the moretheoreticallyambitioustreatmentsof political parties. They argue (1993, 278) that the majorityparty is, among other things,a proceduralcoalitionthatsettlesthe key structuraldecisionsfacing the House, therebystackingthe legislativeprocessin favorof logrollsbeneficial to the party. Cox and McCubbins(1994, 216) observethat social choice theorems "seemto predictever-shiftingmajoritycoalitions,with each new majority coalitionimplementinga differentpolicy."The most prominenttheoretical responseto this "problem"of instabilityis thatinstitutionsstructurallyinduce stability(Shepsle and Weingast1981). Following Riker(1980), Cox and McCubbins(1994) arguethis solutionis unsatisfyingbecauseinstitu*The helpful suggestions of David Mayhew, Keith Krehbiel, Stanley Bach, Richard Beth, Terri Bimes, Jacob Hacker,David King, Daniel Palazzolo, David Rohde, and two anonymousreviewers are gratefullyacknowledged.The data used in this paperand all documentationnecessary to replicate the analyses is available upon request from the authors.A previous version of this paper was presented at the 1995 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago Hilton and Towers,August 31-September 3, 1995. American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 41, No. 4, October1997, Pp. 1340-1375 C)1997 by the Boardof Regents of the Universityof Wisconsin System. PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1341 tions-committee systems,chamberrules,andso on-are themselvesdeterminedon the floorby majorityrule.As such,the selectionof institutionsinheritsthe samepotentialfor cycling thatexists in the realmof policy. Cox and McCubbins(1994, 215) addressthis problemof endogenous institutionsby arguingthatthe majoritypartycaucus constitutesan extralegislativeorganizationthatstabilizeslegislativeinstitutions,which in turn stabilizepolicy coalitions.Their"thesisis thatthe rules of the Democratic Caucusin the Houseof Representativesdictatethatall membersof the caucus are bound,if they wish to retaintheirmembership,to supportcaucus decisions in the House on a varietyof key structuralmatters-such as the electionof the Speakerandthe designandstaffingof the committeesystem" (1994, 218). Since membershipin the caucus is valuableto members,the threatof expulsiondiscouragesdefectionson importantstructuralvotes.As a result,"constitutional changeof the Houserulescouldbe effectedonly by a groupcomprisinga majorityof the caucus and a majorityof the House" (1994, 223). This reduces,thoughdoes not eliminate,the potentialfor cyruleschanges. cling in deliberationssurrounding In the past20 years,Housemajoritypartycaucusesappearto havebeen strongorganizationswith the capacityto determinekey Houserules and to discipline dissident members (Rohde 1991; for a dissenting view, see Krehbiel1991, 1993). But Cox and McCubbins'morepowerful,and more coaliquestionable,claim is thatpartieshave operatedas structure-setting tions even whenpartieshave appearedto be weak andineffectual.In LegislativeLeviathan(1993), they examineCongressionalpoliticsdatingbackto 1945;othershaveattemptedto applytheirmodelto earliertimeperiods,and even to the non-majoritarian Senate(ForgetteandSala 1995). The thrustof Cox andMcCubbins'argumentis thatthe conventionalwisdomthatpolitical partieslost controlof Congressionalinstitutionsin the aftermathof the overthrowof SpeakerCannonandthe demiseof the strongDemocraticcaucus of the Wilsonyearsis simplyincorrect. We drawon historicalevidenceto evaluatetwo interdependentclaims centralto Cox andMcCubbins'theory:(1) the majoritypartydeterminesthe key features of House organization.For example, Cox and McCubbins (1993, 278) writethatthe majoritypartymanagesto "usurpthe rule-making power of the House."(2) The majoritypartycrediblythreatensto punish partymemberswho side with the oppositionpartyon votes thatdetermine the key featuresof Houseorganization(1994, 224). Ouralternativeperspectivefocuses on the risk thatdefectorson procedural votes may credibly threatento move closer to the minority party shouldthey be punished.This leads to the predictionthatdefectorson critical proceduralvotes will not be punishedif therearea sufficientnumberof partydissidentsto constitutea permanentmajorityshouldthey ally with the 1342 Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich minorityparty.As a result,we hypothesizethatchangesin Houserules are likely to occurwhen the balanceof forces on the floor changes,even if the majoritypartycaucusmedianremainsunchanged.We maintainthatthe majoritypartycan crediblythreatento punishits dissidentspreciselywhen the partyleast needsto do so: whenit has a substantialmajorityandis relatively unified.Otherwise,therisksto the majoritypartyof punishingdissidentsare likely to counterbalance anybenefitsgainedthroughcreationof a reputation for refusingto toleratedefectors.We believe partyproceduralcontroltherefore varies considerablyover time, and is dependentupon the size of the partymajorityandits homogeneity(Rohde1991;Binder1996).1 We also arguethatpartyproceduralcontrolvariessignificantlyin scope, dependingupon the natureof mattersunderconsideration.Caucusdissidentsarefarmorereluctantto carrytheiroppositionto the floorwithrespect to personnelmatters(the election of the speakerand of committees)than withrespectto otherimportantorganizationalmatters,suchas the designof committeejurisdictions.Voting againstpartypersonnelconstitutesmore thana threatto Houseorganization;it is an act of opendisrespectfor public symbolsof the partythatis difficultfor the majorityleadershipto tolerate. Whenwe turnourattentionto the conditionsunderwhichmembersarepunished, we find thatoppositionto the party'spresidentialcandidateis the action most likely to resultin partysanctionsagainsta member.This supports the notionthatmembers'test of partystandinghas moreto do with respect for partysymbols thanwith upholdingpartylogrolls embeddedin House I structures. Ourevaluationof thesecompetingperspectivesis basedon two sortsof evidence:first,we examineHousedecision-makingduringthepast75 years concerningcentralHouse rules. Second, we examine efforts to sanction membersof the majoritypartyfor disloyalbehavior.We attemptto identify the ramificationsof defectingon key rulesvotes duringthe period. Parties and House Organization Cox andMcCubbins(1994) makeit clearthatthe realmof partisanproceduralcontrolencompassesthe selection of House officers and committees, the designof the committeesystem,andthe structureof agendapower more generally (e.g., the determinationof committeejurisdictions, and specification of the agenda-settingpowers of the Speaker,legislative committees,andRulesCommittee).Together,these featuresof Houseorganizationare said to entrencha set of logrollsbeneficialto the majorityparty (1994; 220-1). 1Inour usage, partyproceduralcontrol means that the majorityparty is at a minimumable to block changes that a majorityof its members oppose, and at best is able to force changes that its memberssupport. PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1343 To evaluatethis claim, we considerproceduralpolitics for the period 1919-94. We choose 1919 as our startingpoint becauseit allows us to test whetherDemocraticpartytroublesduringthe 1940s-60s were a productof a regional stalematethat constitutedan aberrationin an otherwisestrong recordof partyproceduralcontrol,or were representativeof long imperfect partyproceduralgovernance.2 Forevidence,we firstexaminedthe CongressionalRecordfor the opening of eachCongresssince 1919.Fortheperiodbefore1945,we also combed the relevantscholarlyliteratureon House organization(e.g., Cooper1960; Damon1971;GallowayandWise 1976;Hasbrouck1927),andnewsreports, whereapplicable.Forthe periodafter1945,we reliedheavilyuponthe Congressional QuarterlyAlmanac for information on each Congress. Electing Officers The evidenceon the electionsof the Speakerandcommitteesposes the fewestproblemsfor Cox andMcCubbins'model.This shouldnotbe surprising, given that skeptics of partisanstrengthhave long arguedthatparties hold togetherfor the electionof officers and committees,and thenbecome farless influential(Young1958, 57, 61). Ourinvestigationof the electionof the Speakerin eachCongresssince 1919 findsthatthreatsby majorityparty membersto defeatthe majoritycaucusnomineehave been rare.In December 1923, a groupof roughly20 progressiveRepublicansrefusedto vote for the partynomineefor Speaker,FrederickGillett (R-MA),on the first nine ballots. The insurgentsprovided Gillett with the votes he needed to be electedonly afterpartyleadersagreedto allow thema reasonableopportunityto alterkey Houserules(CongressionalRecord,December5, 1923, 14). Since thattime, therehavebeen occasionalrumorsof dissidentfactions in the majoritypartyflirting with minorityleadersto defeat the majority partynomineefor Speaker(Manley1973, 243-4; Moser 1979, 51-3). Nothing has come of these rumors,althoughone of the moreinterestingtests of the seriousnessof sucha possibilitywas avertedwhenthe Democrats,rather thansimplylosing seatsto the Republicansin 1994, also lost theirmajority status.3Nonetheless,it is intriguingto note thatin 1989, cross-partycoalitions rebelledagainstmajoritypartycontroland elected the Speakerof the 20ur choice of dates excludes two noteworthycases of rules changes in the twentiethcentury: the changes forced by the insurgent-Democraticcoalition in 1909-10 over the objections of the Republicanmajority,and the rules revision of 1911 put forwardby the new Democraticmajority.The latterpassed on a party-line vote; but the rules changes were an amalgamof partisanchanges and concessions to reformers(Hasbrouck1927, 11-3, 38-9, 145). 3TelevisioncommentatorJeff Greenfieldreportedrumorsin Capitol Hill circles of a possible alliance between a handfulof conservative Democrats and the GOP,if the Republicanshad found themselves 10 seats shortof a majority(see Political Hotline, November 1, 1994). 1344 Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich Housein the statelegislaturesof ConnecticutandNorthCarolina,two states with traditionsof stronglegislative parties.4Developmentsin these states sent a signalthatmajoritypartyleadersin otherlegislaturesmustat least be cognizantof the potentialfor cross-partycoalitionsto takecontrol. The election of House committeesand selection of committeeleaders also appearsto be underrelativelyfirmpartisancontrol.5As Rohde(1994) pointsout, the floor has neveroverturnedpartydecisionson committeeassignments.Threatsto vote againstcaucusnomineeshave been few and far between,and both major"partieshave shown a delicacy aboutinterfering with each other'scommitteenominations"(Hasbrouck1927, 44). This was illustratedin 1971 when severalliberals,angeredat theirfailureto unseat Districtof ColumbiaChairmanJohnMcMillan(D-SC) in the Democratic Caucus, attemptedto have the floor overturnMcMillan's nominationas chair.Only 15 Republicansvoted to allow the amendment,andmanyparty membersrefusedto vote on the motionfor fearof settinga precedentof minoritypartyinvolvementin the selectionof chairs(CQAlmanac1971, 18). A furtherindicationof the broadsupportfor the belief thatsuchmatters do not belong on the floor is thatwhen the majoritypartycaucushas been dividedon committeenominations,the partyhas nonethelessstoodtogether on the floor.In the case of McMillan,96 Democratsopposedhim in caucus, yet only 17 did so on the floor.Whenthe partyvotedto stripthe seniorityof presidentialboltersJohnBell Williams(D-MS) andAlbertWatson(D-SC) in 1965, there were 115 members opposed in caucus (facing 157 who backedthepunishment),yet the losing side did not appealto the floor.Similarly,no floor appealoccurredin 1975, when threechairmenwere deposed in the purgebroughton by the aggressivefreshmanclass swept into office by Watergate(GallowayandWise 1976, 77).6 40n the North Carolinarevolt, see the WallStreetJournal,April 17, 1989, A12. See the Hartford Courant,January8, 1989, on the Connecticutrebellion.A cross-partycoalition also elected the Speakerof the MassachusettsHouse in 1996, over the objections of most membersof the majority party. 5Majority party control over selection of party members on committees does not necessarily imply that committee composition is biased toward the majorityparty median and away from the floor median (Krehbiel 1993). 6Partycontrol over personnelmattershas been challengedonly in unusualcircumstances.For example, in 1981, the Democratswantedto strip Pennsylvania'sEugene Atkinson of his committee assignments when he became a Republican. To do this would have requiredfloor approval, and Democraticleaderswere uncertainwhethersouthernconservativeswould go along with the move in the currentpolitical atmosphere.Atkinson held onto his assignments as a Democrat for the rest of the Congress,even thoughhe had repudiatedhis ties to the party(CQAlmanac 1981, 11). To prevent such occurrencesin the future,the Democratsamendedthe rules in 1983 to make continuedassignment to committees contingent upon being a member of the partycaucus grantingthe assignment (CQ Almanac 1983, 596-7). PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1345 The Committee System and Agenda Power Partycontrolover the designof the committeesystemandof rulesconcerningagendapower has been considerablymoretenuousthanhas party controlover personnelmatters.As is the case with personnelselections,we find severalinstancesin which the majoritypartyhas been divided in the caucus.Unlikethe electionof the Speakerandof the committees,however, these disagreementshave tendedto carryover to the floor,underminingthe party'sproceduralcontrol. As suggestedabove,Cox andMcCubbins(1994, 223) predictthatshifts in the position of the caucus majority are necessary preconditions for changes in importantelementsof legislative organization.Ouralternative perspectiveholdsthatchangesin the floormedianabsentchangesin the positionof the caucusmajorityareoften sufficientto resultin ruleschanges.It is only in recentyears,as the threatof majoritypartypunishmentfor defectors has increased,thatthe majoritypartyhas become capableof blocking rules changeseven in the face of a potentiallyopposingfloor majority.But this threatof punishmentis precarious;in the presence of a narrowfloor majorityor a dividedparty,it recedessignificantly. One naturalfocus for an investigationof controlover these elementsof House structureis the beginningof each Congresswhen the House must adopta set of rules.The chairmanof the Rules Committeetypicallymoves thattheHouseadopttherulesof thepreviousCongress,at timeswithspecific amendments.This is the only time duringthe sessionthata simplemajority can amendthe rules, absentthe cooperationof the Rules Committee,recourseto the dischargeprocess,or the willingnessto overrideseveralvalid points of order.Therefore,it is at the beginningof each new Congressthat proceduralcontrolby themajoritypartyis mostcritical.Cox andMcCubbins (1994, 221) observethat "thevote on adoptionof the House rules is taken immediatelyafterelection of a speakerandbeforecommitteeassignments arehandedout.At leaston initialadoptionthereseemto be ampleincentives for majoritypartymembersto supportthe rulesproposedby theirparty,and empiricallythe majoritypartyalmostalwaysdoes sticktogetheron the bulk of the standingrules." Tobeginto test thisclaim,Table1 presentsa list andbriefdescriptionof all roll calls takenon the initial adoptionof rules from 1919 to 1993. The tableincludesthe cohesionof each partyon the roll call, as well as the outcome. Figure 1 graphsmajoritypartycohesion on these initialrules-adoption votes. The datasuggestfirstthat,since the mid-1970s,majoritypartysuccess on rules-adoptionvotes has been considerable.The Democratsused these votes to put throughrules changes that were vehementlyopposed by the u" U, u,, U, Iot CI cl It O r. >o~~~~~~ )~~~~~~ C) C) - O 00 It > O U ct = ? ] : S o N N> tn 00 C1 m tn r- C1 C1 O C1 C, 00 01. 0 01. C O mtn 00 C) CI O O cn I' >~~~- m DX Xt ??> t o E N = e ~~~~~to' o o Q st X~~~~0 ~~~~~71 o o u E a n r- 00 C\ t E, N ? C1 11 00 Xtm^n O =t E O tn O -4 ^c m 11 tn m CN 00 O -4 -4 0 1^o Nm 0 o) E -4 -4 ON z =0 s Q)s Qto u .. 00 C. r- C1 Nt E E; E E E X- u u 01 0 C1 .. C1 C, O .. t C, u t- . ... .. ~~~~~~~~~~n tn r- D Q tr kn cn .. C 4 tn tn 00 O r- Y . ul" o 0 4tE 5 o a o o y E XE &n = )== 22 02 2 ~ ~ O ZZZooZ 0O~ ~ 22 ~ ~ ~ c O0O Zoo C) O o t oO O OC mo t C)C ) , OOO )CoN C Ct 11O ZZO o 00 00 E- 2 OZZZ oO )Co ncO C) C 00 0 c to C o 00 0 O N C) (01 C) (0 N C) C) (01 (01 00 n , o 843 m . . -4 m It = tf U 3U= C)4 83 = 0$- U()= a) 00 a) X q3 i 1-1 ; i ~ 0 C000 ~~-00 UX 00 4- m C=U=Q4 ~~~~~~cn 0 4- ~~~~ 0~~~~~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ ~~ N C C) COON C CI C) C) X~~~~~~~~~1 tf U~~ ~ 2 N C) C) (0N 00 C) (01 C) C) cl E4 o ) C0C00)0 'tZ Zn O C) (1 E 22 > 0000 C) 00 E~= = 22 o,,ooo0 NO C) 2 Z o O OCOC n C) C 22 Z oO O ooZZoZooZZZ00O NC)It 22 3 4- 00 003 00 00 0 O 0 4- Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich 1348 Figure 1. Majority Party Cohesion: Rules Adoption Votes 8 1 0.9 ??0 0.8 00 0 o 0 I ? 0 0 0 0 0.7 0 0 0.6 0 0~~~~~~ 0.5 - 0 0.40 0.30 0.2 -0 0 0.1 _ 0 N N N 000000000 - C'l Cl Cl Cl Cl cl c~c~c~c~ ~ o~ o^ om o~o^ on o o~o^ on o o~o^ on o o~o^ on o o~\O o^ \C on ~C o ~C o~~C o^ on o o~o^o - ~o ~~ O. O l year o MajorityPartyCohesion Note: Majorityparty cohesion is the absolute difference between the percentageof majorityparty memberswho vote "yes" and the percentageof majoritypartymembers who vote "no."Members who do not vote or who are pairedare excluded. Republicans. For example, the Democrats increased their opportunities to suspend the rules during the session, curtailed the range of available dilatory tactics, and tightened restrictions on appropriationsriders.7 7Democraticsuccess even in this period has requiredpartyleaders to be wary of pushing too far; Democrats did not seek to limit appropriationsriders in 1981 due to the fear of antagonizing conservatives in the party who held the balance of power in the House. Partyleaders waited until their majoritywas enhancedin the 1982 election to push throughthe change (CQAlmanac 1981, 5, 1983, 596-7). PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1349 Second, it is only in the past 25 years that the rules votes at the beginning of each Congress have become routinely controversial. The rules were typically adopted on voice votes from the 1920s into the 1960s, with only sporadic controversy. In 16 of 26 Congresses from 1919 to 1970, the rules were adopted without so much as a recorded vote.8 This includes several instances in which partisan control of the Congress changed in the preceding election; in four of six cases in which partisan control of the House shifted, no contested rules changes were made. This is interesting in light of the numerous controversial changes made by Republicans in 1995. Several of these recent changes were indications that the Democrats had in the 1970s and 1980s restructuredelements of the legislative process in favor of their priorities. The absence of such changes in 1919, 1947, 1953, and 1955 reveals, however, that new majority parties do not necessarily confront a structure stacked in favor of the former majority party's priorities. Third, in the 10 sessions opening with contested rules changes from 1919 to 1970, the majority party was triumphantin only six of the sessions. An examination of the specific cases involved reveals that important rules changes affecting agenda control have on several occasions followed shifts in the floor median in the absence of changes in the party median. To structure our analysis, we have divided the rules changes into three substantive domains: the discharge process, the powers of the Rules Committee, and committee jurisdictions more generally. These three areas encompass the bulk of the efforts to change rules that appear to fit Cox and McCubbins' category of "key structural matters" pertaining to agenda control.9 Discharge Process The discharge process was a center of controversy between party leaders and cross-party coalitions for much of the first 40 years of this century. Following Republican losses in the 1922 elections, the Democrats held a sufficient number of seats to constitute a majority should they unite with progressive Republican members. At the opening of the new Congress in January 1924, progressive Republicansjoined the Democrats to force througha series of rules changes, including a reduction in the numberof members requiredto support the discharge of a committee from 218 to 150. This change challenged agenda control by the majority party and the standing committees (Beth 1994), and was opposed by 78% of the Republicans voting. At the next 8In most of these 16 cases, the CongressionalRecordreveals no evidence of controversyduring floor debateon the rules. 90ur discussion also includes those rules changes affecting the areas in question that were adoptedat times otherthan the opening of a new Congress. 1350 Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich election, the 1924 Coolidge landslide gave the regular Republicans a sufficient floor.majority to control the next Congress without the help of the progressive Republicans' votes. As a result, the regulars in 1925 reversed the 1924 rules changes and renderedthe discharge process ineffective. Dissident Republicans cast 22 votes against the rules changes, but this left them several votes short of the number needed to preserve the rule. The Democrats continued to call for a liberalization of the discharge process while in the minority. When the party gained a slim majority in 1931, they had their opportunity to implement such a change, reducing the number of members required to support bill discharges from committees from 218 to 145. This rules change passed on a near-perfect partisan vote, yet it is unclear that liberalizing the discharge process was done in order to facilitate majority party priorities. After all, as the majority party,the Democrats would presumably be the ones threatenedby discharge petitions (given that they controlled the committee system, as is assumed in the Cox and McCubbins formulation). It is better to view the 1931 change as part of an effort to maintain consistency in positions: the Democrats, having advocated a rules change to benefit the minority party while in the minority, were unable to switch sides on the issue quickly once they were in the majority. By 1933, Democratic leaders came to believe that the party needed to return to the requirement for 218 signatures on discharge petitions. The Democrats now had a large, unruly majority, and leaders were concerned that members would use the discharge process to force ill-advised bills to the floor that benefited special interests while undermining the general Democratic recovery program (WashingtonPost, April 13, 1933). Despite a clear majority of the caucus favoring the rule change, a large number of Democrats promised to fight the move on the floor. Facing the prospect of an embarrassingfloor defeat, party leaders deferred action until 1935, when the once-more increased Democratic majority led to a renewed effort to restrict the discharge process. Before the opening of the new Congress, the Democratic caucus voted 225-60 to make the rule change a binding party position (WashingtonPost, January3, 1935). The change then passed on the floor by a 245 to 170 vote. Seventy-two Democrats defected on the critical procedural vote shutting out amendments to the rules package, and 70 defected on the vote on final passage of the rule change. Thus, although the party leaders were successful, the force of the so-called "binding" vote is difficult to judge. As the "conservative coalition" of Republicans and southern Democrats gained control of several critical committees in the late-1930s, some mainstream Democrats sought a liberalized discharge rule as a mechanism to pry party programs loose from recalcitrant committees (see for example, Congressional Record, January 3, 1939, 13-4). Party leaders successfully re- PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1351 sisted such efforts, believing that a liberalized discharge rule held the danger of disrupting the House agenda too seriously to be a well-tailored tool to challenge the growing conservative ascendancy. Still, the calls by liberal Democrats to ease the discharge rule underscore the extent to which a strong faction within the Democratic party believed that the party lacked effective control over the proposal behavior of House committees. Beyond these occasional liberal demands, one finds no serious effort to alter the discharge rule until 1993.10 The 1993 change makes public the names of representatives who sign discharge petitions, thus undermining party leaders' ability to discourage members from signing petitions for politically popular proposals opposed by the majority Democrats. Republican James Inhofe's (R-OK) success in amending the rule was rooted in his ability to use the media to raise the visibility of the issue. Democratic leaders, sensing an impending defeat, dropped their pleas for members to fight Inhofe's proposal, and reluctantly accepted this minority party-forced change (CQ Almanac 1993, 10). To sum up, rules surroundingthe discharge process were changed twice following changes in the balance of power on the floor absent changes in the majority party (1924, 1925), once following a change in the majority party that arguably coincided with a change in the balance of power on the floor (1931), and once when a minority party member successfully manipulated the visibility of House decision-making to his advantage (1993). The Rules Committee While the discharge process was the major agenda control issue plaguing the House in the 1920s and 1930s, efforts to limit the power of the Rules Committee were central to House rules battles in the 1940s through the 1960s. In the 1948 election, the Democrats regained majority party status, with their largest majority since the 77th Congress of 1941-42. As Cox and McCubbins (1993, 259) observe, at the opening of the new Congress in 1949, the Democratic caucus voted 176-48 to bind its members to vote for a 21-day rule to curtail the power of the then-conservative Rules Committee and thus to assist in the enactment of liberal programs. The rule allowed legislative committees to bring bills to the floor on specified days if the Rules Committee had held up the bills in question for more than three weeks. The Democrats succeeded in passing the change on the floor. This is where Cox and McCubbins' (1993) discussion of the 21-day rule ends. Thirty-one 101nDecember 1982, the Democratscontemplatedseeking a rules change increasingthe number of signaturesrequiredfor a dischargepetitionon constitutionalamendmentsto two-thirdsof the membership.The move was intendedto hinderRepublicanefforts to bringpolitically embarrassing constitutionalamendmentsto the floor, but the effort was droppeddue to fierce oppositionby some Democrats(CQAlmanac 1983, 596-7). 1352 Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich Democrats, however, defected on the floor vote, disregarding the binding caucus decision. These defections were insufficient to affect the outcome, given the substantial Democratic majority. But Rules Committee member Eugene Cox (D-GA) attempted to overturn the 21-day rule a year later, and attracted the votes of 85 Democrats. Cox's bid fell short only because 64 Republicans voted to retain the rule. Republican gains in the 1950 election provided a floor majority for the conservative coalition, however. This is precisely the sort of situation in which the stability-inducing quality of a party caucus is presumed to shut out rules changes. A majority of Democrats, including the majority leader and whip, opposed Cox's 1951 proposal to delete the 21-day rule. But 39% of voting Democrats united with 81% of voting Republicans to make way for the Cox substitute to pass at the opening of the new Congress. Further evidence of the importance of floor majorities, as opposed to caucus majorities, is suggested by the 21-day rule's reenactment in 1965 when Democrats had a greatly increased floor majority and could again afford numerous southern defections. The caucus approved the package of rules changes 189 to 71.11The changes passed on the floor despite the opposition of 78 Democrats. Sixteen Republican votes provided the Democrats with their margin of victory. The caucus voted to retain the rule in 1967, but it was once again repealed by the full House since Republican gains had shifted the floor majority in favor of the conservatives (CQ Almanac 1967, 180). This time, 18.5% of the Democrats voting cast ballots with the Republicans to open the rules to amendment, and 32% voted for the amendment to delete the 21-day rule. This defeat for a substantial majority of the Democrats again illustrates the party's inability to control key structuralmatters during this period.12 There is a single instance of a major rules change affecting the Rules Committee that was not done through amending the rules at the start of a new Congress. This was the 1961 decision to enlarge the Committee, which enabled the Democrats to put two additional liberals on Rules. Cox and McCubbins (1993, 257) correctly observe that this is perhaps the premier instance of the majority party manipulating committee sizes for partisanpurposes. Nevertheless, its passage also illustrates some of the limitations on partisan control. Although more than two-thirds of the Democrats favored enlarging the Committee, Speaker Sam Rayburn (D-TX) did not ask for a "The 1965 rules also preventedthe Rules Committeefrom blocking bills from being sent to conference. 12The Democratsmade a final attemptto pass what had become a 31-day rule in 1971. By this time, the rule was of limited importancebecause the Rules Committeewas no longer a conservative power base. Still, 40% of the Democratsunited with the Republicansto delete the proposed31-day rule. PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1353 bindingtwo-thirdscaucusvote on the issue for fearof furtherantagonizing conservative Democrats (MacKaye 1963). The floor vote on the rules change was postponedfor five days due to the belief that the leadership lackedthe votes to prevail.The leadersfinally succeededin an extremely tight 217-212 vote.13While this was an importanttriumphfor the majority party,64 Democratsdefectedfrom the party'sposition,and as a resultthe Democratscould not have prevailedwithoutthe supportof 22 Republicans who defected from their fellow partisans.FormerRepublicanleader Joe Martin(R-MA)providedhis friendRayburnwith crucialassistancein gainpressurefromthe WhiteHousewas ing the Republicanvotes. Furthermore, appliedin the closing days before the vote, includingoffers of side-payments to waveringmembers(Peters 1990). Had the White House been in Republicanhands,such side-paymentswould likely have been used to foil the majorityparty. In 1963, the ruleswere amendedto makepermanentthe increasein the size of the RulesCommitteeinitiallyapprovedin 1961. On the initialproceduralvote to shut off furtheramendments,the Democratsprevailedeasily with only seven defectors.On the vote on adoptionof the new rules, the Democratsagainprevailed,althoughthis time with 48 defectors.The vote on the firstmotion,with its mereseven dissidents,is one of the firstindications in the datawe haveexploredof numerousmajoritypartymembersapparentlyvotingagainsttheirpolicy preferencesin orderto follow the majority of theirfellow partisans.14 The Democratsgained a much greaterdegree of controlof the Rules Committeeduringthe 1970s. Particularlyimportantwas the Democratic caucusrule adoptedin 1975 grantingthe Speakerthe powerto appointmajority partymembersto the Committee.Thereis little doubtthatmajority partymemberson the Rules Committeenow have strongincentivesto be responsiveto partyleaders.It shouldalso be noted thatsince shortlyafter the 1910 enlargementof Rules,the majoritypartyhas maintainedan advanThecrucialpoint,however,is thatin tageouspartyratioon the Committee.15 spite of a favorablemajoritypartyratio,Republicansand dissidentDemocratsenjoyeda workingmajorityon the Committeethroughoutthe 1937-61 period (Rohde 1991, 98), and the Democraticleadershipdid not gain unequivocalcontrolof Rulesuntilthe 1970s. 13Observers estimated that Rayburnhad between two and five pocket votes ready should he have needed them (MacKaye 1963). Still, even with the pocket votes, the outcome was extremely close. '4One reason for the low numberof defectors on the previous question motion was that the vote shut out a package of "fair-play"proposalsthat the Republicanswere planningto offer, which included such provisions as increasedminoritystaffing. 15Thisratiowas increasedfrom 2-1 to 11-5 in 1975. 1354 Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich The evidenceon ruleschangespertainingto the RulesCommitteetherefore offersonly limitedsupportfor the hypothesisof majoritypartycontrol. Importantchangeswere madein 1951 and 1967 despiteclearmajorityparty oppositionto change.It also appearsthatmostRepublicansopposedchanges adoptedin January1924restrictingthepowersof theRulesCommitteechairman (Hasbrouck1927). The majoritypartysucceededin alteringthe Committeein 1949, 1961, and 1965, butthe lattertwo triumphswere dependent on minoritypartysupport,andthe 1949and 1965changeswerereversedtwo yearslaterby cross-partycoalitions.Not until caucuschangesin the 1970s did the majoritypartyfinallygainfirmcontrolof the Committee. CommitteeJurisdictions Turningto changes in committeejurisdictions,one finds surprisingly few cases of eitherpartyusingthe adoptionof rulesat the startof the session to put forwardchanges.Nevertheless,importantchangeshave been considered and, on occasion, approvedin the past 75 years. Jurisdictionchanges areof threetypes:formalrulechanges,changesbasedon bill-referralprecedents,and alterationsbased on more-or-lessformalunderstandingsamong committeeleaders (Evans and Oleszek 1995). King (1992, 1994) argues convincinglythatbill-referralprecedentshave been a majorinstrumentof jurisdictionchange,andthatthis processhas been largelynonpartisansince of the parliamentarian's office in the yearsfollowing the institutionalization the overthrowof SpeakerCannon. changes,we attempt To supplementKing'sanalysisof precedent-based to identifyevery case in which the jurisdictionof a committeewas altered througha rule changefrom 1919 to 1993. We rely primarilyon the House RulesManual,whichis publishedwith each new Congress.We use the versions of the Manualfor the 65thCongress(1917-19), 68thCongress(192325), 75th Congress (1937-38), 79th Congress (1945-46), 80th Congress (1947-48), 84th Congress(1955-56), and 103rdCongress(1993-94). We comparethe jurisdictionlisted in the Manualfor each committeeat each pointduringthe period.To reducethe likelihoodof missingany changes,we use the detailednotes aboutjurisdictionchanges includedin the Manual, and the discussions of committeejurisdictionsin Joint Committeeon the Organizationof Congress(1993) andHouse Select Committeeon Committees (1974). Table 2 presents a brief description of each rule-basedjurisdiction changethatour searchuncovered.16Of the 26 items, the only instancesof 16Ourtable omits one case: between 1920 and 1921, Ways and Means'jurisdictionwas tightened to include matters"purportingto raise revenue."We were unable to find any informationon this change. PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1355 party-line voting on committee changes are two cited by Cox and McCubbins (1993, 254)-the 1975 abolition of the House Internal Security Committee and the 1977 decision to dissolve the Joint Committee on Atomic Energy (JCAE)-along with the decision to strip the Standardsand Conduct Committee of its legislative jurisdiction (which was folded into the same rules changes as the Internal Security and Atomic Energy changes). 17These examples are rightly taken as indications of majority party strength. Particularly impressive, in sharp contrast to rules votes in the 1940s-60s, is that although 97 members voted against dissolving the JCAE in caucus, only two Democrats voted to save the committee on the floor. We also find two instances in which the majority party provided the bulk of the support for the proposition, but could not have prevailed without the help of numerous minority party members. These cases are the recentralization of the appropriationsprocess in 1920 and the Hansen committee reforms of 1974.18 But there are also important cases in which controversy crosscut partisan lines, such as the changes to energy jurisdiction adopted in 1980 (King 1992; Uslaner 1980), and the creation of the Budget Committees in 1974 (Schick 1980; Wander 1984). Furthermore,there are many cases of jurisdiction change that appear to have been non-controversial. These include the 1927 decision to merge the 11 Committees on Expenditures in the Executive Departments (Galloway and Wise 1976), the Legislative Reorganization Act of 1946 (Cooper 1960), and the creation of the Science and AstronauticsCommittee in 1958 (CQAlmanac 1958, 164). Floor debates about many of the changes in our table indicate that the absence of controversy stemmed from members' belief that the changes would increase the efficiency of the committee system (cf. King 1992). This suggests that informational models of committee organization can be helpful in illuminating jurisdictional changes (Krehbiel 1991). Perhaps most importantly,cross-party coalitions have on occasion overwhelmed the proceduralcontrol of the majority party: the classic case of this is the creation of the House Un-American Activities Committee (HUAC) in 1945. When the 79th Congress convened in 1945, conservative Democrat John Rankin (D-MS) sponsored a surprise floor amendment to the rules, 17Onepossible additionalexample is the 1977 vote to make the IntelligenceCommitteea Permanent Select Committee, which pitted most Republicans against most Democrats. Nonetheless, therewere 43 Democraticdefectorson the vote. Republicanoppositionto the resolutionwas due to displeasureover the partyratio on the committee and concern about guidelines for handlingclassified information(CQ Almanac 1977, 376-7). '8Althoughmost Democrats opposed the special rule to consider the 1920 changes, several Democraticleaders supportedthe rule and the most recent DemocraticPartynationalplatformendorsed the change (Congressional Record, June 1, 1920, 8113). See Sheppard(1985) and King (1992) for discussions of the Hansenreforms. Table 2. Rule-basedChanges in CommitteeJurisdictions, 1919-1993 Year Case 1920 Recentralize Appropriations 1924 Create World War Veterans, along with minor changes to Civil Service and Irrigation and Reclamation Merge 11 Expenditures Committees, and abolish five minor committees Create Memorials Committee Merchant Marine jurisdiction over radio given to Commerce, and Commerce jurisdiction over water transportation transferredto Merchant Marine Jurisdiction of Pensions, Invalid Pensions, and Veterans Affairs adjusted Expand World WarVeterans' jurisdiction 1927 1929 1935 1939 1944 1945 1946 1946 1953 1954 1958 1967 1967 1969 1971 1971 1974 1974 1975 Creation of HUAC Legislative Reorganization Act (Davidson 1990; King 1992) Joint Committee on Atomic Energy creation Minor changes to Armed Services jurisdiction to account for creation of Department of Defense Atomic Energy Committee granted authorization power Science and Astronautics creation Standards and Conduct creation Veterans Committee given jurisdiction over veterans' cemeteries from Interior Clarify HUAC jurisdiction and change its name to Internal Security (HISC) Banking and Finance given jurisdiction over impact on the economy of tax exempt foundations and charitable trusts Small Business made Permanent Select committee Creation of Budget Committee and related budget jurisdiction changes Hansen committee reforms (King 1992; Sheppard 1985) Abolish HISC and strip Standards and Conduct of its jurisdiction over campaign contributions Partisan context Majority party provided most support, but minority votes essential to passage Cross-party coalition victory or noncontroversial (see footnote 19 of text) Noncontroversiala Noncontroversial Noncontroversialb Noncontroversial (see Congressional Record, January 13, 1939, 13-15) Cross-party coalition victory or bipartisan controversy (see footnote 20 of text) Cross-party coalition victory Noncontroversial Noncontroversialc Noncontroversial Noncontroversial, but with partisan elementd Noncontroversial (CQ Almanac 1958, 164) Noncontroversiale Noncontroversial (Congressional Record, October 20, 1967, 29560-29566) Minor cross-party coalition victoryf Noncontroversialg Noncontroversialh Bipartisan controversy1 Majority party provided most support, but minority votes essential to passage Majority party forced change (see text) Table 2. Rule-based Changes in CommitteeJurisdictions(continued) Year Case 1977 Abolish Joint Atomic Energy and strip Standards and Conduct of its jurisdiction over lobbying Permanent Select Intelligence Committee created 1977 1980 1983 1993 Energy changes (King 1992; Uslaner 1989) Tightened Ways & Means jurisdiction over tax matters Dissolve select committees, including Permanent Select Committee on Aging Partisan context Majority party forced change Noncontroversial, but with partisan element (see footnote 17 of text) Bipartisan controversy NoncontroversialJ Cross-party coalition victory aThejurisdictionof the resultingExpendituresCommitteewas modified slightly in 1928. The Rules Committeeunanimouslyreportedthe change, which passed withoutdissent (CongressionalRecord, March 17, 1928, 4930). bTheRules Committee'sDemocraticchairmanand RankingRepublicanmembereach endorsedthe change, which was agreed to on a voice vote (Congressional Record, February26, 1935, 26272631). cSenatorArthurVandenberg(R-MI), a memberof the minorityparty,originatedthe proposalto create a JointCommittee,which was made partof the Atomic EnergyAct of 1946 (CQ Almanac 1945, 674, Hewlett and Anderson 1962, 435, 507). We found no indicationof a dispute over the creation of the Joint Committee or its jurisdiction in Hewlett's lengthy description of the Act's travails (Hewlett andAnderson 1962, 482-530). dSee discussion in footnote 21 of the text. The Committee'sauthorizationpower was expanded in June 1957. This change was also noncontroversial(Greenand Rosenthal 1963, 179-80). eThe committee was createdon April 13, 1967 on a 400-0 vote. The House made the committee a permanentstandingcommittee and expanded its jurisdiction on April 3, 1968. The 1968 proposal was praisedby members of both parties and passed 406-1 (Congressional Record,April 3, 1968, 8776-8812). Lobby reform was added to the committee'sjurisdiction on July 8, 1970 by a 382-0 vote (CQ Almanac 1970, 1020). fDemocratson the JudiciaryCommitteecomplainedthat the changes infringedon Judiciary'sjurisdiction (CQ WeeklyReport,February21, 1969, 274, 277). The previous question on the resolution passed with the Democratsevenly split, and the Republicansunited in favor of the motion. gSee CongressionalRecord,April 27, 1971, 12080-1. The proposalwas cosponsoredby the chairmen and rankingminoritymemberson the two affected committees. hThe change was incorporatedinto the package of new rules passed by the Democrats. The rules were controversialbut thereis no indicationin the CongressionalRecordor in CongressionalQuarterly thatthis particularchange was opposed by anyone. Small Business was made a standingcommittee with legislative jurisdiction in a floor amendmentto the Hansen reform proposal passed in 1974. The amendmentpassed on a standingvote. iSee Wander(1984). The 1974 Budget Act also made modifications to the responsibilities of the AppropriationsCommittee.A provision in the 1985 Budget Act modified the Budget Committee's jurisdiction to provide for responses to presidential sequestration orders (House Rules Manual, 103rdCongress,pp. 376-7, 423). Budget law changes over the years also necessitatedminormodifications in the jurisdiction of Ways and Means, GovernmentOperationsand Rules (House Rules Manual, 103rdCongress, 387-8, 404, 412-3). JAlthoughincluded in the Democraticpackage of rules changes, the Republicanskept this proposal in their substituteversion of the rules (Congressional Record, January3, 1983, 39). There was no discussion of this change duringthe floor debate on the rules changes (see also CQ Almanac 1983, 597). 1358 Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich revivingthe Dies SpecialCommitteeon Un-AmericanActivities,andmaking it a standingcommittee.Democraticleaders,includingMajorityLeader JohnMcCormack(D-MA), condemnedthe Rankinamendment,and more thantwo-thirdsof Democratsvoted againstthe Rankinmotion (CQAlmanac 1945, 79-82). However,70 Democratsjoined the bulk of the Republicans to create the standingcommittee.Althoughthe Democratsdid tame HUACsomewhatwithcaucuschangesadoptedin 1949,the committeecontinuedto use its substantialbudgetto plague the Democraticleft for some time to come (Goodman1968). In additionto the case of HUAC, the 1924 creationof the WorldWar VeteransCommittee,19andthe 1944 decisionto expandthe VeteransComeach appearto be cross-partyvictoriesover majority mittee'sjurisdiction,20 partyleaderseagerto preventexcessive largesseto a powerfulpoliticalconstituency.A morerecentcase of a cross-partycoalitiontriumphoccurredin 1993 whenRepublicansattractedenoughDemocraticvotes to doom several select committeesthathad long servedas politicalplatformsfor Democrats (CQ Almanac 1993, 13). This diversityof experiencesupportsthe view thatmajoritypartycontrol of committeejurisdictionshas been variableat best. Nonetheless,Cox andMcCubbins(1993, 255) arguethat"themajoritypartyhas reshuffledjurisdictionalresponsibilitiesseveraltimes since the LegislativeReorganization Act of 1946."For evidence,they cite Dodd and Oppenheimer(1977), who discuss the 1974 Hansenreformsand the 1974 creationof the Budget Committee,but no otherfull committeejurisdictionchanges.Beyond this, the only cases offeredin defenseof this claim arethe Democrats'depriving theirWaysandMeanscommitteemembersof theirrole as the party'sCommitteeon Committees,andthe Republicans'1954 expansionof thejurisdiction of the Joint Committee on Atomic Energy.Whetherthe Ways and Meanscase is properlyregardedas a changein committeejurisdictionis unclear, and while the atomic energy change was to some extent a partisan Similarly,the creationof move, it passedwithoutsubstantialcontroversy.21 19SeeHasbrouck(1927). Democratshad pushedfor creationof a WorldWarVeteransCommittee since 1919, but Republicans buried these measures in the Rules Committee (Congressional Record, December 3, 1919, 100). The Rules Committeeincludedthe change in its package of rules changes in January1924. 20TheRules Committee refused to reportDemocrat John Rankin's resolution to expand the Committee'sjurisdiction,but Rankinobtainedthe 218 signaturesrequiredto dischargeRules. Republicansprovided 131 signaturesfor the petition, as opposed to 84 from Democratsand threefrom membersof thirdparties.Several Republicanleaders, and few Democraticleaders, signed the petition. The resolutionpassed on a division vote-doubtless few memberswantedto oppose the veterans publicly.Despite a draftingerror,the change was treatedas a valid precedentfor subsequentreferrals(House Rules Manual, 79th Congress, 326). 21Section261 of the Atomic EnergyAct of 1954 grantedthe JCAE the power to reportauthorizationbills for certainAtomic EnergyCommissionprojects.Democraticleaderson the Committee PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1359 the Budget Committee was hardly dominated by partisan forces (Wander 1984). Even in the case of Hansen, Democrats were so deeply split that reform advocates made several concessions to Republicans to attract needed votes (Sheppard 1985). The reason that partisancoalitions have put through few major revisions in committee jurisdictions may be that membership on committees creates crosscutting cleavages that are viewed as a legitimate basis for opposing party leaders. Unlike assignments of members to committees, the determination of committee jurisdictions appears to be a matterthat is with rare exceptions left to the membership as a whole ratherthan restricted to the majority party caucus. Even the Republican-designed changes to committee jurisdictions adopted in 1995 were limited by fear of trouble on the floor. David Dreier (R-CA) devised an ambitious plan to reshape jurisdictions to correspond to Republican priorities. But the Republican leadership dramatically scaled back the proposal due to fear that the Dreier plan would "endanger unanimous Republican support for the opening day reforms, and potentially complicate timely passage of the Contract with America" (Evans and Oleszek 1995, 17). The Republicans did eliminate three minor committees with primarily Democratic constituencies; however, few other changes to jurisdictions were adopted. Evans and Oleszek argue that the fierce divisions in the Republican caucus surrounding the committee changes paralleled the Democrats' earlier experiences with jurisdiction reform, and seriously limited leaders' ability to reshape the committee system in a partisan direction. They conclude that "in the House Republican experience with jurisdictional change, constituency interests and the personal power stakes of key legislators dominated partisan motivations" (Evans and Oleszek 1995, 21). Our evidence on jurisdictions challenges the view that the committee system is designed to protect majority party logrolls. Clearly, committee jurisdictions have been shaped through more party-centered processes in recent years than in the past. It is hard to imagine in 1995 that a major revision in committee jurisdictions could be adopted that was essentially proposed by a member of the minority party,as was the case with the Legislative Reorganization Act of 1946 (Evans and Oleszek 1995). But it is not at all clear that had sought a similarchange startingin 1949, but had been dissuadedfrom pursuingit by AEC objections (Green and Rosenthal 1963, 169-71). The 1954 change had a partisanelement: it was tailored to the Republicangoal of limiting the AEC's ability to initiatelarge-scalepublic nuclearpower projects.But Section 261 was not a particulartargetof Democraticobjections. Indeed, the AECchaired by an Eisenhower appointee-was the primaryopponent of the authorizationprovision. Green and Rosenthal(1963, 172) write that despite the Eisenhower"administration'sopposition to inclusion of [thejurisdictionchange], therewas little public discussion of the matter.In lengthy debate on the 1954 act, the legislators raised no objection to the authorizingprovision"(see Hewlett and Holl 1989, 142-43 for a similarassessment). 1360 Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich the majorityDemocratsbuilta set of committeejurisdictionssystematically biasedto favorDemocraticpartylogrolls.Cox andMcCubbins(1994, 220) arguethat"thekey logrolls of a U.S. majoritypartyare often protectedby the judicious allocationof committeepower (e.g. the dominanceof organized laboron the EducationandLaborCommittee;the requiredsupportof the oil-depletion allowance for a Democratic assignment to Ways and Means; the dominanceof the InteriorCommitteeby westerners;and the dominationof theAgricultureCommitteeby membersfromagriculturedistricts)."In ourview, threeof the fourcases citedby Cox andMcCubbinsare characteristicof cross-partydistributivecoalitions, as opposed to Democraticpartylogrolls. The oil-depletionallowancewas createdin 1926 by a RepublicanCongress. It was attackedvigorouslyby threeDemocraticpresidents,and for severaldecadesit was defendedagainstliberalDemocrats'attacksby CongressionalRepublicansin alliance with conservativeDemocrats(Oppenheimer 1974). Why Democraticpresidentswould repeatedlyattackwhat scholarstaketo be a key elementof Democraticlogrollsin Congressis unclear.While SpeakerRayburnprotectedthe provision,Oppenheimer(1974, 72-3) reportsthatafterRayburn'sdeathin 1961,committeeappointments to Ways and Meansno longerwere based on supportfor the allowance.Furthermore,liberalDemocratswere finally successfulin scalingback the allowance in 1975 (CQ Almanac 1975, 98-110). The dominanceof memberswith a strongconstituencyintereston AgricultureandInteriorhas long held truefor bothDemocratsandRepublicans (Fenno 1973; Jones 1961). The new RepublicanCongressof 1995 did not challengethejurisdictionof eithercommittee.RepublicanDreierproposed removingnutritionjurisdictionfromAgriculture.But incomingAgriculture ChairPat Roberts(R-KS) and other farm state Republicanssuccessfully blocked the change,indicatingthatthe famouslinkagebetweenfood programsand farmbenefitsis valuedby some prominentRepublicansas well as Democrats(EvansandOleszek 1995, 14). Of the four cases cited, only Educationand Laboris an element of a party-specificlogrollof sorts.22Althoughthe committeewas underconservativecontrolfor the firstdecadeafterits creationin 1946,Democraticleaders soughtto appointonly liberalsto the committee,andby 1959, the committeehada liberalmajority.But this did not stopthe floorfromsubstituting bill for the committee'smore liberal 1959 the antilaborLandrum-Griffin proposal (Reeves 1993). Indeed, notwithstandingsuccesses in 1964-66, 22Still,creationof Educationand Laborwas includedin RepublicanJamesWadsworth'scommittee realignmentplan, which served as the basis for the jurisdictionchanges adoptedin the Legislation ReorganizationAct of 1946. PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1361 EducationandLaborhas long been notoriousfor havingits productstaken aparton the floor(Fenno1973;Mayhew1974).Althoughlaborinfluenceon the committeeprobablypreventedsome antilaborlegislationoverthe years, it also mustbe acknowledgedthatlaborhas neverachievedits goals of reversingrestrictionsin Taft-Hartley(1947) andLandrum-Griffin (1959). We concludefrom our examinationof House rules thatdecisions surroundingthe dischargeprocessandRules Committeehave been only incidentallyparty-based.Theyhavebeenfundamentallyideological,andcan be representedon a single underlyingdimensionfor muchof the periodunder consideration.ConservativeRepublicansopposedDemocratsandprogressive Republicansin the 1920s, while liberalDemocratsopposedconservative Democratsand theirRepublicanallies for much of the 1940s-60s. As the balanceamongthese coalitionsshifted,so (in general)did the relevant rules.IncreasedDemocratichomogeneityin the 1970s and 1980s,however, allowed the majoritypartyto gain controlover the Rules Committeeto a degreethatappearsto be less susceptibleto changesin the coalitionalbalance on the floor.A secondtype of ruleschangehas been moreconsistently partisan:Democratshave been quiteunitedwhenit comes to deprivingRepublicansof committeestaffandopportunitiesto offerdilatorymotions(see Table1). A thirdtype of rulechange,involvingcommitteejurisdictions,has tendedto be less partisanthaneitherof the firsttwo categories.The distribution of committeeturfinvolvesmultiple,crosscuttingevaluativedimensions for members.Only rarelyhas the majoritypartybeen sufficientlystrongto dominatethe cross-partycleavagesin this realm. Punishing Defectors Ourinvestigationof changesin Houseorganizationrevealsthatthe majoritypartyhas enjoyedconsistentcontrolof the electionof the Speakerand committee assignments,but that partisancontrol of key House rules has been farmoretenuous,particularlypriorto the mid-1970s.The weaknessof partisancontrolover rulesin the 1919-70 periodmightrelateto limitations in the majorityparty'sabilityto punishdefectorson rulesvotes duringthis period. Cox andMcCubbins(1994) arguethatmajoritypartycontroloverrules is safeguardedby a party'sabilityto sanctiondefectorson key procedural votes. They writethat"theDemocraticcaucushas madea very publiccommitmentto expel (or discipline)memberswho fail to supportthe featuresof House structurethatundergirdthe party'slogrollingabilities"(1994, 224). The centralquestionis whetherthe majoritypartyis willingto punish"pivotal"defectors-that is, dissidentswho constitutea majorityif they unite with the minorityparty(1994, 223). Cox andMcCubbinsobservethatpunishing pivotaldefectorscarriesthe risk thatthe partywill lose its majority 1362 Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich statuspermanently,but they arguethatthe partywill neverthelesscredibly threatenpunishmentto dissidentsbecausea reputationfor toughnessis essentialto the party'sorganizationalviability.The way to build a reputation fortoughnessis to use a rangeof punishments:"ifnonpivotalgroupsarepunished,possiblywith sanctionsless severethanexpulsion,thenmembersof a prospectivedissidentgroupwill be concernedwith the group'sunityof purpose andpivotalness"(1994, 224). This suggeststhatdefectorson important rulesvotes will not necessarilybe expelled,butthatdefectionon suchvotes shouldhave adverseconsequencesfor some members.These consequences shouldbe visible to othermembers-otherwise,the partywill not createthe reputationfor toughnessthatis requiredfor an effectivedeterrent. Testingthe claim thatpartyleadersare able to use a rangeof sanctions to makethe threatof punishmentcredibleeven to potentiallypivotalgroups is difficult;thereis no ideal methodto determinethe numberof members deterredfrom defectingby the threatof punishment.We focus on one particulartype of punishmenthere:seniorityviolations.We do so becauseseniorityviolationsarethe mostvisibleformof punishment,shortof expelling membersfromthe party(whichhas not been done since the 1924 case discussed below). For Cox and McCubbins'hypothesisto be testable,there mustbe observablepunishmentsthatarepredictedto be used underspecifiableconditions.Cox andMcCubbins'(1994) essay suggeststhatsome form of punishmentis predictedto be metedout to at least some of the defectors on a given rulevote on a key structuralmatterundergirdingthe party'slogrollingabilities.Thispredictionis challengedif it turnsoutthatthe mostvisible formof punishment-seniorityviolations-was not used to punishdisloyaltyon importantrulesvotes for severaldecades. We assess the likelihoodof visible punishmentin the event of various forms of disloyal behaviorby majoritypartymembers:oppositionto the party'spresidentialcandidate,oppositionto the partyon the electionof the Speaker,anddefectionon the vote to adoptthe Houserulesat the openingof each new Congress.23In Table3, we list the numberof membersengaging in each of these activitiesfor eachCongressfrom 1919 to 1993 in whichdefectionsoccurred,alongwith whetherthese activitieswere followedby any loss of committeeassignmentsor committeeseniority.This does not fully respondto the problemof membersbeingdeterredfromdefectingdueto the anticipationof punishment.The tableindicates,however,the conditionsun23Forthe periodup through1944, we relied on Berdahl(1949) for our list of presidentialelection defectors. For the 1948 election, we relied upon Garson (1974), Key (1962), and Bolling (1968). For informationon subsequentpresidentialelections, we relied primarilyupon CQAlmanac and CQ WeeklyReport. We believe our list covers a substantialmajorityof cases of defections in presidentialelections by majoritypartymembers. PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1363 der which membersare likely to be punished,which in turnshouldinform memberexpectationsof punishment.If memberssee thatdefectorsin presidentialelectionshave often been punished,while manymembershave defectedon rulesvotes withoutapparentsanctions,this will presumablyshape members'beliefs aboutwhatthe partyexpectsof them. Sanctions The aftermathsof the 1922 and 1924 elections providean interesting test for the conditionsunderwhich the majoritypartycrediblythreatensto punishdissidents.As notedabove,progressiveRepublicansheldthe balance of powerfollowing the 1922 elections,andrefusedto back the Republican candidatefor Speakeron the firstseveralballotsin December1923.The insurgentsalso allied with the Democratsto force throughseveralimportant ruleschangesin January1924.Yetwe find no evidencethattheseinsurgents were punishedfor theirbehaviorduringthe Congressin question.Indeed, insurgentleaderJohnNelson (R-WI)was placed on the Rules Committee. Fearof losing theirmajoritystatusforcedRepublicanleadersto makeconcessions to the insurgentswithin theirranks,ratherthansanctioningthese members.This inabilityto punishdissidentsin a closely dividedHouse is evidence thatthe credibilityof the threatto punishis seriouslyreducedin the case of potentiallypivotaldefectors. In 1925, the greatlyincreasedRepublicanmajorityallowedpartyleaders greaterleverage.Partyleadersmadeit clearthatearliermisbehaviorin December1923, and January1924, was not now at issue.24Leadersstated that the tests to be applied to memberswere supportfor Coolidge in the 1924 presidentialelectionand supportfor the Republicaneffortto organize the House in December1925 (Berdahl1949). Elevenof the 12 presidential election defectorsrefusedto vote for RepublicanNicholas Longworthof Ohiofor Speakeron the floor.Eachlost committeeseniority,andthoseservto minorasing on majorcommittees,with one exception,were transferred signments(Berdahl1949). A twelfth presidentialelection defector,Oscar Kellerof Minnesota,voted for Longworthfor Speakerbut defectedon the rules adoptionvote at the openingof the Congress.Keller apparentlywas 24TheRepublicanspassed a caucus rule in 1925 preventingcommittee chairs from serving on the Rules Committee(Hasbrouck1927). This change led two membersof Rules to leave the Committee. One of the two-Royal Johnson(R-SD)-had defected on one of the four floor votes on the rules in January1924. We were unable to document whether the caucus rule change was done to oust Johnson. The change was one of a handful of restrictions passed by the Republicans in the 1920s to preventmembersfrom serving in more than one "leadership"position (Hasbrouck1927), and it was enforcedin subsequentsessions, forcing reliablepartysupporters,such as WallaceWhite (R-ME), off of Rules. Still, we cannot rule out the possibility that the caucus change was a party leadermove to enhancetheir control of the Committee. 0 - ~ C) It 00X N E r V ~ C)4 N N C, t ~ t B 00 C) 00 00 0 C) C) 00 ) 00 tn 00 0 - 00 m ~~~~~~ 0> 00 ~ C) C) C) C CD ^ ~ 00 m ~ ~ ~ U:~ ~ 00 tn 0C,0, 00 "C C) \C) C) 0^ I-? 0 >0 06~~0)0 1))~411 0) 0 00 cO~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~c a) 4) CO t4 ~ 0)00 C >~~~~~~OO ~ 0 0) C 0) 0 0 tb~~~~0 0 0 ~~~ CO.-~~~~ 0~C, ~ ~ ~~ ~ ~ ~ * 0 1 (ic 1.) .0Q c0) CO00 ~ Q ~~~~~c Ho0 CZ~ ~ C's 0 ' -" u -C co o 0 . o.~~~~~~~~c 0) 0) 0)0 0~~~~~~~c 0 0 S S01)~~~~~~~~ 0),-~~~~01) 4-CO .O> 0CC~ O In) O O O 0 0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ o-0 r0 C)0 03~ 01~64 o- -.1: C1 00- tc . 0 ) J 1 CO~ >~5 > O- >~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~I 0))0 C, ~0)~~~~~~~~~~~~C ~ O~l ~ S *~~~~~0 0)00 SU (iCO0) C) 0 C) C) C) 0)C) ~C.) C 0 C)0 ~~~ ~ Z E~ 00 00 n o- ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ <) 0 0)0 C -) C) S0.000)-,.0> 0)5 4C- CNCN C 0C oo ooo M C\ CN 0. 0) 00 r- OC)00 o , C's~~~~~~~~C O 00 N It CO c0 0 -0~:~ ~~ 0)H - ) C 0 C) St oc ) Ct 1 0 C) ~~~O~C)C) CN CaN - - - .0 0)C 0)'C cS CO CO -b CO 0 1366 Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich not punished.25The other 14 Republicans who defected on one or both of the 1925 rules votes, but who had backed Longworth for Speaker and Coolidge for president, also were not punished.26 The message sent by these actions would seem to be that while a divided party with a slim majority did not punish its dissidents, a more secure majority looked to supportfor the party's presidential candidate and Speaker nominee as the criteria for good standing. Disloyalty on rules votes, while perhaps affecting future advancement, did not portend severe punishment. When asked in 1937 what makes a "bona-fide Republican," Congressman Hamilton Fish (R-NY) responded that since 1910 the clear criterion had been that "it is one who supports his party's candidate for the presidency" (as quoted in Berdahl 1949, 504). Senate Republicans in 1936 also concluded that the "generally accepted definition of what makes a party man is that he shall have supported the Presidential candidate of the party in which he claims membership" (Berdahl 1949, 505). The absence of defectors on votes to elect the Speaker after 1925 suggests that this too was a criterion for good party standing, following Longworth's disciplining of the 1925 bolters. These loose standardswere not a mere aberrationused by Republicans due to their regional divisions: before the Democrats' deep regional split emerged, the Democrats did not punish any of the 72 party members who in 1935 disobeyed a binding caucus vote to reinstitute the requirementfor 218 signatures on discharge petitions. Although the Democrats did succeed in increasing the discharge requirement,party leaders had been unable to do so two years earlier because many of the same members had made it clear they would defect on the floor. During the era of deepest Democratic regional divisions (1937-65), the party punished only a handful of its presidential election bolters and none of the members who defected on rules votes. Based on this record of party discipline since 1919, Ripley noted in 1967 that caucuses violated seniority only in isolated instances where members "supported the presidential nominee of another party" (1967, 53). By 1975, this conclusion no longer held. Although the three chairmen who lost their positions in 1975 were not punished for disloyalty on rules votes, these were the first clear instances of seniority violations in the majority party for reasons having to do with conduct within the House of Repre25Kellerretainedhis chairmanshipof the Railways and Canals Committee, remained as the rankingmember on Claims when the chair of that committee became vacant, and moved up from fourthto second place on the District of ColumbiaCommittee.He did not become chair of Claims, presumablydue to the practicethat no memberchair more than one committee. 26Nonetheless,the fall in the numberof defectors on the dischargevote-from 44 in 1924 to 22 in 1925-might indicate that the increasedRepublicanmajorityallowed partyleaders to intimidate several potential dissidents. Hasbrouck(1927) surmises that this threatsuccessfully deterred freshmenfrom defecting. PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1367 sentatives-as opposedto presidentialelection defections,frail health,or personalscandals-in several decades.The operationof recentlyadopted caucusrules facilitatingattackson sittingchairmen,the restlessnessof the largefreshmanclass, andDemocrats'substantialmajorityin 1975likelyeach contributedto the successof the 1975effortto deposethe threechairmen. It appearsfromTables 1 and 3 thatmemberbeliefs aboutthe level of loyalty expectedfromthem on rules votes changeddramaticallyfollowing the 1975 seniorityviolations.Therecontinuedto be substantialnumbersof defectorson the vote on initialadoptionof Houserulesup through1975.Yet immediatelyafter 1975, defectionsfell to minusculelevels until 1993. The most interestingfeatureof this developmentis thatDemocraticloyalty on substantivemattersdid not rise significantlyuntil 1983 (Rohde 1991, 53). This suggeststhatthe emergenceof a crediblethreatto sanctiondefectors (afterits absencefor many decades)-though rootedin rising Democratic homogeneityandin the largemajoritiesof the mid-1970s-had an independentimpacton partisanproceduralcontrol.Majoritypartymembersapparently were relativelyfree to disobey the partyon even the most important proceduralmattersup throughthe mid-1970s,until the partyfinally made memberssubjectto seniorityviolationsfor theirconductin the House.This changeresultedin a dramaticincreasein partyproceduralcontrol,andlikely createdincentivesfor memberloyaltyon other,substantiveissues as well. Ourevidenceon the credibilityof partythreatsto sanctiondefectorsis indirectandthus shouldbe interpretedwith caution.It is possiblethateven beforethe 1970s, the majoritypartyhad access to sanctionswhichperhaps wereless visiblethanseniorityviolations,yet weresufficientto detera large is suspectbecausethe proportionof would-bedefectors.This interpretation majoritypartydid lose severalimportantrulesvotes duringthisperiod.Still, our evidence is sufficient only to call into question, not refute, Cox and McCubbins'view of sanctions. Rewards The senioritysystemdid not leave partyleaderswithoutany tools to induce loyalty priorto 1975. For example,scholarshave long observedthat partyloyalistsare advantagedwhen it comes to initialassignmentsto committees(Cox andMcCubbins1993;Ripley 1967;SmithandRay 1983).But it is anopenquestionhow muchimpactthepotentialloss of futurerewardsas opposedto the threatof an immediateloss in existingassignments-had on memberloyaltyon rulesvotes. To begin to answerthis question,we examinethe likelihoodof receiving a favorablecommitteeassignmentfor Democratsin the 79th Congress (1945-46) in the aftermathof Rankin'ssuccessful amendmentto create HUAC.We selectedthis case becausethe vote to createHUACwas one of 1368 Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich the clearesttests of partyloyalty on a committeejurisdictionmatterin the twentiethcentury.The previouslyexisting Dies Select Committeeon UnAmericanActivitieshad a recordfor successfullyunderminingthe reputationandelectoralsuccessof liberalDemocrats(Goodman1968).As a result, voting to createHUAC was an actionlikely to lead to directelectoralharm to fellow Democrats. Table4 presentsourresults.Basedon Galloway(1946, 54, 90), we classify 10 committeesas majorHousecommittees.We thenexaminethe likelihood of receivingan assignmentto one of these 10 committees,given a yes or no vote on the Rankinamendment.The first notableresultis thatmembers alreadyon the 10 committees(none of whom were removedfromthe committeesin the aftermathof the vote), voted 65 to 37 againstthe Rankin amendment.27 The rate of defections of these members(36%) is slightly higherthanthe 28%defectionratefor partymembersnot on the 10 major committees,althoughthe differenceis not statisticallysignificant(p = .26). If one restrictsthe analysis to the Rules, Appropriations,and Ways and Meanscommittees,the disparityis a bit stronger:membersalreadyon these committeesvoted 20 to 15 againstthe Rankinamendment,a lower proportion thanthatfor the restof the party,whichvoted 129 to 55 againstRankin southern (p =.19). Theseresultsmostlikely aretraceableto disproportionate representationon leading House committees, but they also indicate that membersserving on key committeeswere hardlyparagonsof loyalty on rulesvotes. One hundredseventeenDemocratsvoting on the Rankinamendment werenot on any of the 10 majorcommitteesat the openingof the 79th Congress.Thesemembersvoted84 to 33 againsttheRankinamendment.Wefind that34.5%of the membersvotingagainstRankinreceivedan assignmenton one of the top 10 committees,while 27.3%of the membersvotingin favorof Althoughthis differenceis smalland Rankinreceivedsuchan assignment.28 is farfromstatisticalsignificance(p = .59), thereis someevidenceto suggest 27Twomembers who voted against the Rankin amendment, Mike Mansfield (D-MT) and Donald O'Toole (D-NY), moved from slots on one of the 10 committeesto places on several minor committees. One memberwho voted in favor of Rankin,E.C. Gathings(D-AR) was transferredin 1945 from MilitaryAffairs to Agriculture.Both committees are on our list of 10 majorcommittees. We lack informationon whetherGathingssought the transfer.Finally, CliffordDavis (D-TN), who voted in favor of Rankin,moved from MilitaryAffairs to Public Worksin 1947 when MilitaryAffairs and Naval Affairs were consolidatedinto the Armed Services Committee.Two lower ranking membersof MilitaryAffairs in 1945, both of whom also voted in favor of Rankin,were appointed to Armed Services in 1947. 28Wealso used a logit model to predictwhethermembersnot on the 10 committees in 194344 received assignmentsto the committees in 1945, controllingfor region and whetherthe member was a freshmanin 1945. The coefficient for the vote on the Rankinamendmentwas tiny and insignificant (.025; p = .83). 4-wi Po0 0 - C) 0 0 c ~~~ 4-4 u ~ c~~~~~~~ rn "0~~~~~~~~~~C'3 ~ 0 4-4~~~~~~~~~c 'tt~ ~~~" 003 pa ~~~~ -~~~~~~~~~ ~ ~ ~~C' ~ ~ ~"0 0S~~~:~~n ' "00 co;c C's0 1370 Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich thatthe desireto receivefavorablecommitteeassignmentsplayedsomerole in the vote. FreshmenDemocrats,who presumablyhad the most to gain or lose by theirconduct,voted 51 to 5 againstthe Rankinamendment.Region andideologyundoubtedlywerein partresponsiblefor this strongleadership support:only 16%of freshmenDemocratswho voted were fromthe South. But even controllingfor region,freshmenvoted againstthe RankinamendIt seems fairto conclude mentin greaternumbersthandid non-freshmen.29 thatthe desirefor rewardsfromthe leadershipwas at least a mild incentive forpartyloyaltyon thisvote. Nonetheless,the extentof thisincentiveis open to question:afterall, threeof the five freshmenwho voted for Rankinreceived assignmentsto a majorcommittee(as opposedto 19 of the 51 who wereopposed). Ouranalysisof the 1945 case is subjectto the problemthatthe decision to defectmightdependon whethera memberis seekingto transferto a new committee.Still, ourdataprovidesome supportfor the view thatthereis an asymmetrybetweenpartyleaders'abilityto rewardloyal behaviorandleaders' abilityto punishdisloyalbehavior(Sinclair1983).A likely explanation for this is thatpartyleadersneed to balancethe goal of enforcingunitywith "keepingpeace in the family"(Sinclair 1983). Withholding,rewards from dissidentsposes muchless of a threatto "peacein the family"thandoes directpunishment. But the threat of withholding possible rewards apparentlywas not nearly as stronga deterrentto defection on critical votes as has been the post-1975additionalthreatof specificsanctions.Our1945 dataindicatethat the effecton futureadvancementof defectingon thisparticularkey rulevote was farfromoverwhelming.The successesof cross-partycoalitionsin 1924, 1945, 1951, and 1967 speakto the limitedeffectivenessof the merethreatof reducedprospectsfor futureadvancement. Weconcludethatthe partythreatto punishdissidentshas variedsignificantly in scope and severity.The 1923 and 1925 evidence indicates that memberswho defecton the electionof officerssuchas the Speakeraresubject to punishment,but thatleadershave been reluctantto jeopardizepartisan controlof the House in orderto enforce strictdisciplineon these matters. Memberswho defect on rules votes have only rarelybeen subjectto directpunishment.The threatof sanctionsfor variousforms of disloyalty, however,appearsto have increasedsignificantlysince 1975, contributing morethanlikely to the dramaticrise in partyloyaltyon rules-adoption votes. By contrast,memberswho defectedto supportthe opposingparty'spresidentialcandidatehave long been subjectto visible punishment.This set of 29Weused a logit model to predict the vote on the Rankin amendment(yes = 0, no = 1; n = 219). The dummy variablefor freshmenhad a coefficient of 1.54 with a standarderrorof .52. PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1371 findings suggests that the primary test of party status for roughly 50 years starting in 1919, had far more to do with deterring open disrespect for public symbols of the party, than with safeguarding the majority party's procedural control of the House. Discussion and Conclusions Onepossibleresponseto ouranalysisis thatwe areexamininga period in which the majoritypartyhas often been unusuallydivided,andthatthis the degreeof majoritypartyproceduralcontrol.It leadsus to underestimate is certainly true that the Democrats were extremely divided during the 1937-75 period,andthatthe Republicansfaced importantdivisionsduring the 1919-31 period when they were in the majority. The question is whether the relatively unified parties of recent Congressional experience or the divided parties of these earlier periods are more characteristic of Congressional politics. In fact, with the exception of the 1983-92 period and a short-lived era of Democratic strength in 1911-17, which suffered a severe setbackwith the outbreakof WorldWarI (GallowayandWise 1976), the Democraticpartyhas faced serious divisions at all times since the Civil Warwhen it has held majoritystatusin Congress.For example,the Democratswere the majoritypartyin the House for all but four yearsfrom 1875 to 1895. The partywas forced to grapplewith a strong,regionally-based, protectionistwing for much of this period, and was torn aparteven more severelyby the silverissue in the early 1890s. Its recordof proceduralcontrol duringthis periodcould be characterizedas mixed, at best (Alexander 1916; Wolf 1981). As for the Republicans,after facing serious divisions throughoutthe 1870s and 1880s (CooperandBrady1981;Wolf 1981),they did enjoy perhaps the longest period of strong party governance in Congressional history, lasting roughly from 1895 to 1909. Yet as early as 1905, the party began to face serious fissures rooted in regionally-based divisions over President Theodore Roosevelt's ambitious program (Hatch 1967). Al- thoughRepublicanleaderswere able to delay the progressive-conservative split which eruptedin 1909-10, this breach was not fully repairedfor nearlythreedecades(Berdahl1949). Clearly,it has not been at all unusual to have a sizable bloc of opposition-pronedissidentswithin the majority party. Evidence from the 103rd Congress (1993-94) indicates that the fairly long recentperiod of Democraticunity and proceduraleffectiveness was beginning to unravel before the Republican takeover of the House, revealing once again the frailty of strong party government in Congress. The numberof Democratsdefectingon the initial adoptionof the House rules increasedsubstantiallyin 1993. Granted,the Democraticleadershipwas pushinga numberof controversialchanges,andthe leadershipdid triumph 1372 Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich over Republicanobjections.Nonetheless,the willingnessof 14 Democrats to vote for the Republicanrecommittalmotion on the rules, and of 27 Democratsto vote againstfinal adoption,is suggestiveof a rebelliousspirit withinthe party.This rebelliousspirithad concreteeffects laterin January 1993, when one-thirdof the Democratssurprisedthe leadershipby joining with the Republicansto deny fundingfor the Select Committeeon Narcotics. By March,Democraticleadersconcededthey lackedthe votes to preserve fundingnot only for the Narcoticscommitteebut also for the Select Committeeson Hunger,Aging, and Children,Youthand Families(CQAlmanac 1993, 13). Restiveness among conservativeDemocratsalso led to floor defeatsfor six specialrules to considerlegislationin the 103rdCongress, a dramaticcontrastto the Democrats' record of success on these votes in previoussessions. A furthersign of decliningDemocraticproceduralcontrolwas Inhofe's victoryon the dischargepetitionsecrecyfight in September1993. The dischargechangeno doubtcontributedto leadershipdifficultiesin fightingyet anothermanifestationof frayingproceduralcontrol:the so-called"A to Z" spendingreductionsplan(Krehbiel1995).Themeasure,proposedby Robert Andrews(D-NJ)andBill Zeliff (R-NH)aimedto set asidea 56 hourbloc of time for considerationof any floor amendmentto reducefederalspending. Andrews and Zeliff filed a discharge petition to bypass the Rules Committee'seffortto block the measure.AlthoughAndrewsandZeliff fell 14 signaturesshortof the 218 required,it is likely thathad the Democrats retaineda reducedmajorityin the ensuing104thCongress,the Republicans wouldhavefounda sufficientnumberof Democraticalliesto bring"Ato Z" to the floor.30This opportunityfor open floor considerationof untoldnumbersof amendmentsto reducespendingwouldhave doubtlessthreatenedall sortsof Democraticand cross-partylogrolls.It might well have been 1910 all over again,with the partylabelsreversed. TheDemocrats'troublesin the 103rdCongress,alongwiththe evidence on rules changesand committeejurisdictionspresentedabove,revealsthat the Housemajoritypartyhas not consistentlybeen able to entrencha set of partisanlogrollsin Houserules.Instead,partisancontrolof Houseorganization is ordinarilycontestedby ideologicalcross-partycoalitionsthatvaryin strengthwith the size of the majoritypartyandits homogeneity,andby bipartisandistributivecoalitionsthatappearto be somethingof a constantin Congressionalpolitics. This complexitygoes againstthe view thatthereis any coherentprincipleof Congressionalorganizationthat "solves"the cycling problem.It also points the way for models of legislative politics in 30SeeNational Journal Congress-Daily, "Andrews,Zeliff to Renew Spending Cut Effort in 1995," October7, 1994. PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1373 which innovative representatives battle to manipulate the design of institutions to suit partisan, ideological, distributive, and other goals. Manuscript submitted 18 October 1995. Final manuscript received 18 June 1996. REFERENCES Alexander,De Alva. 1916. Historyand Procedureof the House of Representatives.Boston and New York:HoughtonMifflin. "Andrews,Zeliff to Renew SpendingCut Effortin 1995." 1994. National Journal'sCongressDaily. NationalJournalInc. 7 October.Nexis. Berdahl, ClarenceA. 1949. "Some Notes on Party Membershipin Congress."American Political Science Review 43:309-21, 492-508, 721-34. Beth, RichardS. 1994. "Controlof the House Floor Agenda: Implicationsfrom the Use of the Discharge Rule, 1931-1994." Presentedat the annualmeeting of the AmericanPolitical Science Association, New York. Binder,SarahA. 1996. "ThePartisanBasis of ProceduralChoice: Allocating ParliamentaryRights in the House, 1789-1990." AmericanPolitical Science Review 90:8-20. Bolling, Richard.1968. Power in the House. New York:Dutton. Cooper,Joseph. 1960. "Congressand Its Committees."Ph.D. diss. HarvardUniversity. Cooper, Joseph, and David Brady. 1981. "InstitutionalContext and LeadershipStyle: The House from Cannonto Rayburn."AmericanPolitical Science Review 75:411-25. Cox, Gary, and Mathew D. McCubbins. 1993. Legislative Leviathan: Party Governmentin the House. Berkeley:University of CaliforniaPress. Cox, Gary, and Mathew D. McCubbins. 1994. "Bonding, Structure,and the Stability of Political Parties:PartyGovernmentin the House."Legislative Studies Quarterly19:215-31. Damon, RichardE. 1971. "TheStandingRules of the House of Representatives."Ph.D. diss. New York:ColumbiaUniversity. Davidson, Roger. 1988. "TheNew Centralizationon CapitolHill."Review of Politics 50:345-64. Davidson, Roger. 1990. "TheLegislative ReorganizationAct of 1946 and the Advent of the Modern Congress."Legislative Studies Quarterly15:357-73. Dodd, LawrenceC., and Bruce I. Oppenheimer.1977. "The House in Transition."In CongressReconsidered,ed. LawrenceC. Dodd and Bruce I. Oppenheimer.New York:Praeger. Evans, C. Lawrence, and WalterJ. Oleszek. 1995. "ReformRedux: JurisdictionalChange and the New RepublicanHouse." Presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago. Fenno, RichardF. 1973. Congressmenin Committees.Boston: Little, Brown. Forgette,Richard,and BrianR. Sala. 1995. "ThePartisanModel of Legislative Organizationand the Emergenceof Legislative Leviathanin the U.S. Senate: 1870-1933." Presentedto the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago. Galloway,George B. 1946. Congressat the Crossroads.New York:Crowell. Galloway,GeorgeB., and Sidney Wise. 1976. History of the House of Representatives.2nd ed. New York:Crowell. Garson,RobertA. 1974. The Democratic Party and the Politics of Sectionalism, 1941-1948. Baton Rouge: LouisianaState UniversityPress. Goodman,Walter.1968. The Committee:TheExtraordinaryCareerof the House Committeeon UnAmericanActivities.New York:Farrar,Straus. 1374 Eric Schicklerand AndrewRich Green,Harold,andAlan Rosenthal. 1963. Governmentof the Atom.New York:AthertonPress. Hasbrouck, Paul D. 1927. Party Government in the House of Representatives. New York: MacMillan. Hatch, CarlE. 1967. TheBig Stick and the CongressionalGavel. New York:PageantPress. Hewlett, RichardG., and Oscar E. Anderson. 1962. A History of the United States Atomic Energy Commission.University Park,PA: PennsylvaniaState University Press. Hewlett, RichardG., and Jack Holl. 1989. Atomsfor Peace and War.Berkeley: Universityof CaliforniaPress. Hotline. 1994. AmericanPolitical Network,Inc. 1 November.Nexis CampaignLibrary. Jones, Charles0. 1961. "Representationin Congress:The Case of the House AgricultureCommittee."AmericanPolitical Science Review 55: 358-67. Key, V. 0. [1949] 1962. SouthernPolitics in State and Nation. Reprint.New York:Vintage. Kiewiet, RoderickD., and Mathew D. McCubbins. 1991. The Logic of Delegation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. King, David C. 1992. "CommitteeJurisdictionsand InstitutionalChange in the U.S. House of Representatives."Ph.D. diss. Universityof Michigan. King, David C. 1994. "TheNatureof CongressionalCommitteeJurisdictions."AmericanPolitical Science Review 88:48-62. Krehbiel,Keith. 1993. "Where'sThe Party?"BritishJournal of Political Science 23:235-66. Krehbiel,Keith. 1991. Informationand Legislative Organization.Ann Arbor:University of Michigan Press. Krehbiel,Keith. 1995. "Cosponsorsand Wafflersfrom A to Z." AmericanJournal of Political Science 39:906-23. MacKaye, William R. 1963. A New Coalition TakesControl:The House Rules CommitteeFight of 1961. New York:McGraw-Hill. Manley, John F. 1973. "The Conservative Coalition in Congress."American Behavioral Scientist 17:223-47. Mayhew,David R. 1974. Congress: TheElectoral Connection.New Haven:Yale UniversityPress. Moser,CharlesA. 1979. TheSpeakerand the House. Washington,DC: Free Congress Researchand EducationFoundation. Oppenheimer,Bruce I. 1974. Oil and the CongressionalProcess. Lexington,MA: LexingtonBooks. Peters, Ronald. 1990. TheAmericanSpeakership.Baltimore:Johns HopkinsUniversityPress. Reeves, AndreeE. 1993. CongressionalCommitteeChairmen.Lexington:UniversityPress of Kentucky. Riker, William H. 1980. "Implicationsfrom the Disequilibriumof MajorityRule for the Study of Institutions."AmericanPolitical Science Review 74:432-47. Ripley, Randall B. 1967. Party Leaders in the House of Representatives. Washington, DC: BrookingsInstitution. Rohde, David W. 1991. Parties and Leaders in the PostreformHouse. Chicago:University of Chicago Press. Rohde, David W. 1994. "Partiesand Committees in the House: Member Motivations, Issues, and InstitutionalArrangements."Legislative Studies Quarterly19:341-59. Schick, Allen. 1980. Congressand Money. Washington,DC: UrbanInstitute. Sheppard,BurtonD. 1985. RethinkingCongressionalReform.Cambridge,MA: SchenkmanBooks. Shepsle, KennethA., and Barry Weingast. 1981. "Structure-InducedEquilibriumand Legislative Choice."Public Choice 37:503-29. Sinclair,Barbara.1983. MajorityLeadershipin the U.S. House. Baltimore:Johns HopkinsUniversity Press. Smith, Steven S., and Bruce A. Ray. 1983. "The Impact of Congressional Reform: House DemocraticCommitteeAssignments."Congress & ThePresidency 10:219-40. PARTIESAS PROCEDURALCOALITIONSIN THE HOUSE 1375 U.S. Congress.Joint Committeeon the Organizationof Congress. 1993. JurisdictionalEvolution of House and Senate Committees.Washington,DC: GovernmentPrintingOffice. U.S. Congress. Select Committee on Committees of the House of Representatives. 1974. Monographs on the Committeesof the House of Representatives. Washington,DC: Government PrintingOffice. Uslaner,Eric. 1989. Shale Barrel Politics. Palo Alto: StanfordUniversityPress. Wander,ThomasW. 1984. "ThePolitics of CongressionalBudget Reform."In CongressionalBudgeting, ed. W. ThomasWander,F. Ted Hebert,and GaryW. Copeland.Baltimoreand London: Johns HopkinsUniversityPress. Wolf, Thomas W. 1981. "CongressionalSea Change:Conflict and OrganizationalAccommodation in the House of Representatives,1878-1921." Ph.D. diss. MassachusettsInstituteof Technology. Young,RolandA. 1958. TheAmericanCongress.New York:Harper.