Career Women and the Durability of Marriage
Transcription
Career Women and the Durability of Marriage
Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Andrew F. Newman Boston University and CEPR Claudia Olivetti Boston College and NBER September 2015 Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Motivation Link between work, women and divorce rates is complex and controversial. Some believe that families with a working wife are more prone to divorce than those without. Indeed, as women entered the labor force in great numbers during the 1960s and 1970s, divorce rates increased, helping cement this notion. However ... Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage 7 LFP rates of married women and divorce rates by state - 2005-2009 6 Divorce Rate (per 1000 population) NV Correlation= -.524 AR OK 5 WV WY ID AL NM KY FL TN MS COAK 4 WA AZ OR NC VA UT TX 3 GA MT MI OH SC NY ME HI MO DE NH VT KS CT MD NJ NE MN RI SD ND WI PA IA IL DC 2 MA 0.60 0.65 0.70 0.75 0.80 LFP Married Women LFP is from the American Community Survey 5-year sample- 2005-2009. Divorce rate is from the U.S. National Center for Health Statistics- National Vital Statistics Reports. We use the average over 2005-2009. Missing observations on divorce rate for CA, IN and LA. For GA, HI and MN, divorce rate used is from 2000. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Divorce and labor force participation of married women across U.S. states: 2005-2009 Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Motivation To summarize: By early 2000s: negative correlation between divorce rate and the rate of married female labor force participation. Robust to various controls, including age at first marriage and education both of which have been shown to be negatively correlated with divorce (Lehrer and Chen, 2011; Rotz, 2011; Isen and Stevenson, 2010). Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Motivation To summarize: By early 2000s: negative correlation between divorce rate and the rate of married female labor force participation. Robust to various controls, including age at first marriage and education both of which have been shown to be negatively correlated with divorce (Lehrer and Chen, 2011; Rotz, 2011; Isen and Stevenson, 2010). Could it be that “career” women are good for marriage? Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Main Idea Higher marriage durability of “career” women can be explained at least partly by increased bargaining flexibility in families in which the wife has a higher labor force attachment. A marriage with two earners (particularly when their incomes are relatively equal) is more stable than a marriage with one earner, simply because it is easier for the two earners to compensate each other (with money) and reach a new agreement in response to preference shocks or outside opportunities. Money as the best instrument for utility transfer Retrospective and longitudinal data broadly support our hypothesis and help us rule out alternative explanations. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Literature Women’s LFP and divorce could be positively correlated because: Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Literature Women’s LFP and divorce could be positively correlated because: MLFP ⇒ Divorce Lower returns to/higher stress in marriage (Becker, Landes and Michael, 1977; Mincer, 1985; Spitz and South, 1985) Working women less tolerant of low quality marriages because there is no ’leisure’ benefit Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Literature Women’s LFP and divorce could be positively correlated because: MLFP ⇒ Divorce Lower returns to/higher stress in marriage (Becker, Landes and Michael, 1977; Mincer, 1985; Spitz and South, 1985) Working women less tolerant of low quality marriages because there is no ’leisure’ benefit Spurious correlation MFLP and Divorce both driven by technology (Ogburn and Nimkoff, 1955; Greenwood and Guner, 2004; Stevenson and Wolfers, 2007) Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Literature Women’s LFP and divorce could be positively correlated because: MLFP ⇒ Divorce Lower returns to/higher stress in marriage (Becker, Landes and Michael, 1977; Mincer, 1985; Spitz and South, 1985) Working women less tolerant of low quality marriages because there is no ’leisure’ benefit Spurious correlation MFLP and Divorce both driven by technology (Ogburn and Nimkoff, 1955; Greenwood and Guner, 2004; Stevenson and Wolfers, 2007) Divorce ⇒ MLFP Lower incentives to invest in marriage capital (Stevenson, 2008). Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Literature Women’s LFP and divorce could be positively correlated because: MLFP ⇒ Divorce Lower returns to/higher stress in marriage (Becker, Landes and Michael, 1977; Mincer, 1985; Spitz and South, 1985) Working women less tolerant of low quality marriages because there is no ’leisure’ benefit Spurious correlation MFLP and Divorce both driven by technology (Ogburn and Nimkoff, 1955; Greenwood and Guner, 2004; Stevenson and Wolfers, 2007) Divorce ⇒ MLFP Lower incentives to invest in marriage capital (Stevenson, 2008). Self insurance motives (cf. Greene and Quester, 1982; Johnson and Skinner, 1986, Johnson, 2004). Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Literature Women’s LFP and divorce could be positively correlated because: MLFP ⇒ Divorce Lower returns to/higher stress in marriage (Becker, Landes and Michael, 1977; Mincer, 1985; Spitz and South, 1985) Working women less tolerant of low quality marriages because there is no ’leisure’ benefit Spurious correlation MFLP and Divorce both driven by technology (Ogburn and Nimkoff, 1955; Greenwood and Guner, 2004; Stevenson and Wolfers, 2007) Divorce ⇒ MLFP Lower incentives to invest in marriage capital (Stevenson, 2008). Self insurance motives (cf. Greene and Quester, 1982; Johnson and Skinner, 1986, Johnson, 2004). More recent empirical literature has found mixed results linking divorce and labor supply of married women (see Stevenson and Wolfers, 2007) Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conceptual Framework Standard set-up: marriage produces “local public good” enjoyed by each adult; in addition each enjoys private consumption Outside income or household produced goods can be used for transfers within household. Intra-household allocations subject to renegotiation (bargaining). Monetary income from working facilitates transfers Allows purchase of all goods, not just household produced ones (solves “double-coincidence of wants” problem) Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conceptual Framework Standard set-up: marriage produces “local public good” enjoyed by each adult; in addition each enjoys private consumption Outside income or household produced goods can be used for transfers within household. Intra-household allocations subject to renegotiation (bargaining). Monetary income from working facilitates transfers Allows purchase of all goods, not just household produced ones (solves “double-coincidence of wants” problem) Money allows immediate settlement, less risky and subject to moral hazard than future goods transfers Direct purchase of goods may avoid bargaining inefficiencies Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conceptual Framework, cont. Two household members, each with utility u(c) + φ, where c = private goods that can be purchased on the market φ is marriage quality Household monetary income is I , typically earned by producing a good that is not consumed by the household One member is endowed (or generates at zero marginal cost up to a ceiling) monetary income v , 0 ≤ v ≤ I The other generates I − v Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conceptual Framework, cont. Two household members, each with utility u(c) + φ, where c = private goods that can be purchased on the market φ is marriage quality Household monetary income is I , typically earned by producing a good that is not consumed by the household One member is endowed (or generates at zero marginal cost up to a ceiling) monetary income v , 0 ≤ v ≤ I The other generates I − v Money can be used for private consumption or transfer to the other partner; once it’s exhausted additional transfers are generated through more costly means Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conceptual Framework, cont. Generates a symmetric (about 45◦ line) utility possibility frontier W (x) for the household, where x is the first member’s utility (pictures coming soon) Autarky payoff is (v , I − v ) W (x) is transferable (W 0 (x) = −1) when x ∈ [φ, I + φ]. Elsewhere, W (x) is non-transferable: x < φ ⇒ 0 ≥ W 0 (x) > −1 x > I + φ ⇒ W 0 (x) < −1 Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Bargaining When marriage begins, a bargain regarding private consumption is struck Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Bargaining When marriage begins, a bargain regarding private consumption is struck Subsequently there are shocks (, η) to the value of the local public good, which is then worth φ − to one, φ − η to the other , η ∼ F (·) with log-concave density f (·) Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Bargaining When marriage begins, a bargain regarding private consumption is struck Subsequently there are shocks (, η) to the value of the local public good, which is then worth φ − to one, φ − η to the other , η ∼ F (·) with log-concave density f (·) This generates a new frontier for bargaining If autarky point lies inside new bargaining set, marriage continues; if not there is divorce Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Bargaining When marriage begins, a bargain regarding private consumption is struck Subsequently there are shocks (, η) to the value of the local public good, which is then worth φ − to one, φ − η to the other , η ∼ F (·) with log-concave density f (·) This generates a new frontier for bargaining If autarky point lies inside new bargaining set, marriage continues; if not there is divorce Main theoretical result: Marriage durability (i.e. the probability that it stays together) is maximized at v = I /2. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Utility possibilities and response to shock I I Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Utility possibilities and response to shock Φ Φ Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Utility possibilities and response to shock Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Utility possibilities and response to shock Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Utility possibilities and response to shock Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Utility possibilities and response to shock -‐ε -‐η η ε Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Utility possibilities and response to shock Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Utility possibilities and response to shock Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Utility possibilities and response to shock ........ I/2 ........ I/2 Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Utility possibilities and response to shock Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Utility possibilities and response to shock Δ Φ+I/2-Δ Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Utility possibilities and response to shock Δ Φ+I/2-Δ Δ Φ+I/2 Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Main theoretical result Given , the probability that η is small enough to preserve the marriage is Pr {I − v + η < W (v + )} = F (W (v + ) − (I − v )) Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Main theoretical result Given , the probability that η is small enough to preserve the marriage is Pr {I − v + η < W (v + )} = F (W (v + ) − (I − v )) Integrating over gives durability, the probability the marriage survives: Z ∞ D(v ) ≡ F (W ( + v ) − I + v )f ()d −∞ Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Main theoretical result Given , the probability that η is small enough to preserve the marriage is Pr {I − v + η < W (v + )} = F (W (v + ) − (I − v )) Integrating over gives durability, the probability the marriage survives: Z ∞ D(v ) ≡ F (W ( + v ) − I + v )f ()d −∞ Proposition Let W (·) be any symmetric frontier transferable on [φ, I + φ] and non-transferable elsewhere, and assume the shock density is log-concave. Then D(v ) is maximized at v = I /2. Proof Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Remarks Asymmetry: if one partner values the marriage more, durability maximization may require that partner to have higher monetary earnings. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Remarks Asymmetry: if one partner values the marriage more, durability maximization may require that partner to have higher monetary earnings. Log concavity is not indispensable; if W is concave, it’s enough that f is non-increasing on [φ, ∞) Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Remarks Asymmetry: if one partner values the marriage more, durability maximization may require that partner to have higher monetary earnings. Log concavity is not indispensable; if W is concave, it’s enough that f is non-increasing on [φ, ∞) It’s not just about inequality; transferability is essential: Newman & Olivetti Example Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Remarks Asymmetry: if one partner values the marriage more, durability maximization may require that partner to have higher monetary earnings. Log concavity is not indispensable; if W is concave, it’s enough that f is non-increasing on [φ, ∞) It’s not just about inequality; transferability is essential: Example earnings equality is good for marriage not because equality per se is durability maximizing, but because equality maximizes transferability within the household. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Remarks Asymmetry: if one partner values the marriage more, durability maximization may require that partner to have higher monetary earnings. Log concavity is not indispensable; if W is concave, it’s enough that f is non-increasing on [φ, ∞) It’s not just about inequality; transferability is essential: Example earnings equality is good for marriage not because equality per se is durability maximizing, but because equality maximizes transferability within the household. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical Challenges Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical Challenges Causality may be running from the state of the marriage to the labor supply decision (i.e., some high share wives may be “remedial earners”). Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical Challenges Causality may be running from the state of the marriage to the labor supply decision (i.e., some high share wives may be “remedial earners”). Focus on “career women” defined as those who are in the labor force a substantial fraction of the time during marriage. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical Challenges Causality may be running from the state of the marriage to the labor supply decision (i.e., some high share wives may be “remedial earners”). Focus on “career women” defined as those who are in the labor force a substantial fraction of the time during marriage. Lower cost of working Lower uncertainty of monetary income Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical Challenges Causality may be running from the state of the marriage to the labor supply decision (i.e., some high share wives may be “remedial earners”). Focus on “career women” defined as those who are in the labor force a substantial fraction of the time during marriage. Lower cost of working Lower uncertainty of monetary income Use panel data which allows us to follow couples over time and separate career from remedial earners. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical Challenges Causality may be running from the state of the marriage to the labor supply decision (i.e., some high share wives may be “remedial earners”). Focus on “career women” defined as those who are in the labor force a substantial fraction of the time during marriage. Lower cost of working Lower uncertainty of monetary income Use panel data which allows us to follow couples over time and separate career from remedial earners. Selection effects: career women may have attributes that lead them to have higher quality marriages. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical Challenges Causality may be running from the state of the marriage to the labor supply decision (i.e., some high share wives may be “remedial earners”). Focus on “career women” defined as those who are in the labor force a substantial fraction of the time during marriage. Lower cost of working Lower uncertainty of monetary income Use panel data which allows us to follow couples over time and separate career from remedial earners. Selection effects: career women may have attributes that lead them to have higher quality marriages. Exploit battery of quality-of-marriage questions. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical analysis Key labor concept: Labor force attachment during marriage. Two data sets: Survey of Income and Program Participants (SIPP) Retrospective information on marriage and work histories. But, information about husband and marriage characteristics completely lost for women who divorced before the survey year. Marital Instability over the Life Course (MILC) Relatively long panel of marriages with information on marriage and husband characteristics (for example, fraction of household income earned by wife). It also contains a rich battery of qualitative questions on marital happiness or marital problems that can be used to rule out alternative explanations. SkipSIPP Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical Analysis: SIPP Use retrospective questions about marriage and work to obtain a measure of labor force attachment. Main measure: “Worked during marriage” = 1 if worked for at least some time of 1st marriage, 0 otherwise. Calculated using both work and marriage start/end dates. 80% of women in our sample. Women who “Worked during marriage” are more likely to: Have a college or post-graduate degree Marry and have children later Work full-time Earn more Experiment with alternative (more refined) definitions but noisier. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical Analysis: SIPP Sample: All women age 25-54 Married once or twice 1st Marriage 1990 or later Both work and marriage information available Divorce statistics: Fraction of marriages ending in divorce by year 5 = 0.18 Average duration of 1st marriage ending in divorce = 5 years Probability 1st marriage ever ended in divorce = 0.29 Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Wife’s work during marriage and divorce: SIPP Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Wife’s work during marriage and divorce: SIPP Summarizing Wife worked during marriage associated with 5-6 percentage points lower probability of marriage ending by year 5 Similar results hold if year = 7, 10 or hazard model. Strongest effect for women with relatively high educational attainment (>High School degree). Other mechanisms such as age at first marriage, education, children and divorce laws (unilateral, community property) do not seem to drive the results. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical Analysis: MILC MILC follows married couples over 20-year span. National probability sample: 2,034 married men and women under 55 years old. Interviewed by telephone for first time in fall 1980. Re-interviewed five times: 1983, 1988, 1992-1994, 1997 and 2000. 1980 sample nationally representative relative to: age, race, household size, presence of children, region, and female participation to the labor market. Designed to examine causes of marital instability throughout life course of a group of married individuals. Indicators of marital trouble or happiness. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical Analysis: MILC Our Sample: Couples in 1st marriages as of 1980 Excludes marriages ending in widowhood. Age of both spouses >18. 827 marriages: 24% of couples divorced by 2000. High Labor Force Attachment: High Attachment = 1 if wife worked >75% of the time during marriage. Based on work after marriage and between/during surveys. 68% of wives in our sample Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical Analysis: MILC “High Attachment” women more likely to: Have a college degree Earn more Have less variability in their share of household earnings Graph However, their husbands are not statistically different, except for being slightly more likely to have had a working mother while growing up. Some additional stats: Average age at (first) marriage: 20 (women), 22 (men) 89% white Education: 46% (women) and 55% (men) have > high school diploma. 10% women and 8% men change education status post 1980. Wife respondent: 51% Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Wife’s Labor Attachment and Divorce Inequality Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Empirical Analysis: MILC Alternative definitions based on worked before/during marriage. Alternative Definition: Career Woman (Career) “Career” = 1 if respondent said that pretty important or very important reasons for wife working were: Having a career For a sense of accomplishment For contact with other people For financial independence 64% of wives in our sample are “Career” Correlation (High Attachment, Career) = 0.6*** Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Wife’s Work and Divorce: Alternative Definitions Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Wife’s work, household inequality and divorce Dependent variable is Divorce by End of Survey High Attachment (1) (2) -0.0867*** [0.0287] -0.0683** [0.0302] 0.224* [0.119] -0.242** [0.123] 742 0.238 732 0.246 I(40): Wife Contribution >=40% (High Attachment) * I(40) Observations R-squared *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Robust standard errors in brackets. Weighted with weights provided by MILC. Omitted categories: Low Attachment; White; <HS; Protestant. Includes controls for: Years married, husband's and wife's race, husband's and wife's age at marriage, whether wife worked before marriages, average household income during marriage, children, %time husband worked full time. Divorce probability: High Attachment, Low Share = -7% High Attachment, High Share = -9% Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Alternative mechanisms To summarize, high female labor force attachment reduces the probability of divorce by about half, particularly when she earns close to 50% of the family income. Could some form of selection be driving the results? Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Alternative mechanisms To summarize, high female labor force attachment reduces the probability of divorce by about half, particularly when she earns close to 50% of the family income. Could some form of selection be driving the results? Search: “High Attachment” women choosier, marry later and have higher quality matches. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Alternative mechanisms To summarize, high female labor force attachment reduces the probability of divorce by about half, particularly when she earns close to 50% of the family income. Could some form of selection be driving the results? Search: “High Attachment” women choosier, marry later and have higher quality matches. Selection: “High Attachment” women are more ‘stable’ (better at compromising, care more about kids etc.) both in their jobs and in their marriages. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Alternative mechanisms To summarize, high female labor force attachment reduces the probability of divorce by about half, particularly when she earns close to 50% of the family income. Could some form of selection be driving the results? Search: “High Attachment” women choosier, marry later and have higher quality matches. Selection: “High Attachment” women are more ‘stable’ (better at compromising, care more about kids etc.) both in their jobs and in their marriages. Sorting: Egalitarian households might somehow reflect better matching Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Alternative mechanisms To summarize, high female labor force attachment reduces the probability of divorce by about half, particularly when she earns close to 50% of the family income. Could some form of selection be driving the results? Search: “High Attachment” women choosier, marry later and have higher quality matches. Selection: “High Attachment” women are more ‘stable’ (better at compromising, care more about kids etc.) both in their jobs and in their marriages. Sorting: Egalitarian households might somehow reflect better matching All these stories imply that we should observe higher marriage quality in households with high attachment wife. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Alternative mechanisms To summarize, high female labor force attachment reduces the probability of divorce by about half, particularly when she earns close to 50% of the family income. Could some form of selection be driving the results? Search: “High Attachment” women choosier, marry later and have higher quality matches. Selection: “High Attachment” women are more ‘stable’ (better at compromising, care more about kids etc.) both in their jobs and in their marriages. Sorting: Egalitarian households might somehow reflect better matching All these stories imply that we should observe higher marriage quality in households with high attachment wife. Use MILC’s subjective indicators of marital happiness/stability to assess these hypotheses. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage High Attachment and Match Quality Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage High Attachment and Match Quality Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage High Attachment and Match Quality Dependent variable is: (1) (2) (3) (4) Index of Marital Instability Index of Marital Happiness Either Spouse ever suggested divorce Either spouse ever talked counselor, clergy etc. 0.0405* -0.135 0.0468 0.0694 [0.0244] [0.323] [0.0359] [0.0466] 0.0656 -1.768* I(40): Wife Contribution >=40% 0.172 0.248* [0.0643] [1.032] [0.127] [0.144] -0.0518 1.609 (High Attachment) * I(40) -0.140 -0.224 [0.0716] [1.125] [0.135] [0.151] *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Robust standard errors in brackets. Weighted with weights provided by MILC. All regressions control for years married, husband and wife age at marriage, whether wife worked before marriage, percent of time during marriage that husband worked fulltime, number of children under 18 in the household,log average family income during the marriage, and husband and wife's race. High Attachment Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage High Attachment, Match Quality, Divorce Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage High Attachment, Match Quality, Divorce Summarizing: High attachment women do not seem to have better marriages! Putting it all together: Marriages that run into trouble are more likely to end in divorce but: Controlling for marital trouble, high attachment still negatively correlated with divorce. Interaction term between marital trouble and high attachment tends to be negative Interpretation: attached women do not have better marriages, but are better able, via transferability, to keep them together. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion Theory suggests, and the evidence shows, that career women differ from non-career women in ways that are good for their marriages. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion Theory suggests, and the evidence shows, that career women differ from non-career women in ways that are good for their marriages. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion Theory suggests, and the evidence shows, that career women differ from non-career women in ways that are good for their marriages. Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Summary Monetary earnings, particularly permanent ones, facilitate bargaining: Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Summary Monetary earnings, particularly permanent ones, facilitate bargaining: transferability effect Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Summary Monetary earnings, particularly permanent ones, facilitate bargaining: transferability effect We use panel data to discern this effect by distinguishing between career and remedial earners: Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Summary Monetary earnings, particularly permanent ones, facilitate bargaining: transferability effect We use panel data to discern this effect by distinguishing between career and remedial earners: Greatest durability in egalitarian two-career households Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Summary Monetary earnings, particularly permanent ones, facilitate bargaining: transferability effect We use panel data to discern this effect by distinguishing between career and remedial earners: Greatest durability in egalitarian two-career households Quality of marriage questions suggest this result is not due to selection Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Further Implications Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Further Implications Decline in US divorce rate since the mid-1980’s, despite continuing increase in MFLP is easily understood as a consequence of the transferability effect, particularly in the face of Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Further Implications Decline in US divorce rate since the mid-1980’s, despite continuing increase in MFLP is easily understood as a consequence of the transferability effect, particularly in the face of narrowing gender wage gap Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Further Implications Decline in US divorce rate since the mid-1980’s, despite continuing increase in MFLP is easily understood as a consequence of the transferability effect, particularly in the face of narrowing gender wage gap increased “marketization” of many formerly household-produced goods Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Further Implications Decline in US divorce rate since the mid-1980’s, despite continuing increase in MFLP is easily understood as a consequence of the transferability effect, particularly in the face of narrowing gender wage gap increased “marketization” of many formerly household-produced goods Policy implication: a woman’s decision to work has very different ramifications depending on whether she is a career woman or a remedial worker Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Further Implications Decline in US divorce rate since the mid-1980’s, despite continuing increase in MFLP is easily understood as a consequence of the transferability effect, particularly in the face of narrowing gender wage gap increased “marketization” of many formerly household-produced goods Policy implication: a woman’s decision to work has very different ramifications depending on whether she is a career woman or a remedial worker If a married non-career woman asks whether working will threaten her marriage – Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Further Implications Decline in US divorce rate since the mid-1980’s, despite continuing increase in MFLP is easily understood as a consequence of the transferability effect, particularly in the face of narrowing gender wage gap increased “marketization” of many formerly household-produced goods Policy implication: a woman’s decision to work has very different ramifications depending on whether she is a career woman or a remedial worker If a married non-career woman asks whether working will threaten her marriage – It’s likely too late... Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Further Implications Decline in US divorce rate since the mid-1980’s, despite continuing increase in MFLP is easily understood as a consequence of the transferability effect, particularly in the face of narrowing gender wage gap increased “marketization” of many formerly household-produced goods Policy implication: a woman’s decision to work has very different ramifications depending on whether she is a career woman or a remedial worker If a married non-career woman asks whether working will threaten her marriage – It’s likely too late... But if a young woman asks whether investing in a career could later threaten her marriage – Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Conclusion - Further Implications Decline in US divorce rate since the mid-1980’s, despite continuing increase in MFLP is easily understood as a consequence of the transferability effect, particularly in the face of narrowing gender wage gap increased “marketization” of many formerly household-produced goods Policy implication: a woman’s decision to work has very different ramifications depending on whether she is a career woman or a remedial worker If a married non-career woman asks whether working will threaten her marriage – It’s likely too late... But if a young woman asks whether investing in a career could later threaten her marriage – If the alternative is to look for a rich husband, then by all means, go for the career! Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage THE END Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage 0 Z ∞ D (v ) = f ()f (W ( + v ) − u)(W 0 ( + v ) + 1)d, −∞ where u=I-v. Use W 0 (x) + 1 = 0 for x ∈ (φ, φ + I ), make a change of variable and exploit symmetry of W (·) to rewrite this as 0 Z φ D (v ) = [f (x − v )f (W (x) − u) − f (x − u)f (W (x) − v )][W 0 (x) + 1]dx. −∞ Over the domain of integration, W 0 (x) + 1 > 0 a.e., while log-concavity of f ensures that f (x − v )f (W (x) − u) − f (x − u)f (W (x) − v ) ≥ 0 iff v < u (with strict inequality on a non-null set). Thus, D 0 > 0 when v < u and D 0 < 0 when v > u, implying that D is decreasing in inequality of earnings. Back Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage It’s not just equality... Φ Φ Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage It’s not just equality... Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage It’s not just equality... Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage It’s not just equality... Back Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage Distrib of Coef of Variation of Wife Contrib to HH Inc During Marriage as of 2000 0 kdensity coefvar_w_incp .5 1 1.5 Regression Sample as of 2000 0 1 2 3 x Low Attachment High Attachment High Attachment = worked 75% of marriage or more ® Back Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage From: [Name withheld] @brown.edu Subject: Career women and the durability of marriage Date: February 16, 2015 at 6:56 PM To: afnewman@bu.edu Dear Professor Newman, My name is [Name] and I am a senior at Brown University studying Economics and Development Studies. I've just received note from a friend studying economics in Paris that you are leading a seminar on "Career women and the durability of marriage." Although I cannot attend this seminar I would love to hear - as a young woman with career ambitions and Indian grandparents - what you would have to say on the subject. Is there a paper or book of yours that I could read? I hope you enjoy Paris. Best regards, -[Name withheld] Brown University '15 B.A. Development Studies and Economics Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage From: [Name withheld] @brown.edu Subject: Career women and the durability of marriage Date: February 16, 2015 at 6:56 PM To: afnewman@bu.edu Dear Professor Newman, My name is [Name] and I am a senior at Brown University studying Economics and Development Studies. I've just received note from a friend studying economics in Paris that you are leading a seminar on "Career women and the durability of marriage." Although I cannot attend this seminar I would love to hear - as a young woman with career ambitions and Indian grandparents - what you would have to say on the subject. Is there a paper or book of yours that I could read? I hope you enjoy Paris. Best regards, -[Name withheld] Brown University '15 B.A. Development Studies and Economics Back Newman & Olivetti Career Women and the Durability of Marriage