THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL
Transcription
THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL
THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL1 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Proceedings from a Farewell Conference in Honor of Stanley Fischer, Governor, Bank of Israel The Israel Museum, Jerusalem June 18, 2013 2 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 3 CONTENTS 7 FOREWORD KARNIT FLUG, Governor, BOI OPENING REMARKS KARNIT FLUG, Deputy Governor, BOI 9 SESSION I: RETHINKING THE LIMITATIONS OF MONETARY POLICY MARIO DRAGHI, President, ECB Introduced by Stanley Fischer MICHAEL WOODFORD, Columbia University Introduced by Karnit Flug ALEX CUKIERMAN, IDC Herzliya, Member, BOI MC Introduced by Karnit Flug 15 23 31 SESSION II: THE ROLE OF THE CENTRAL BANK IN MACROPRUDENTIAL POLICY Chair: BARRY TOPF, Senior Advisor to the Governor, Member, BOI MC 37 CLAUDIO BORIO, Deputy Head, Monetary and Economic Department and Director of Research and Statistics, BIS PATRICK HONOHAN, Governor, Central Bank of Ireland RODRIGO VERGARA, Governor, Central Bank of Chile 39 JACOB A. FRENKEL, Chairman, JPMorgan Chase International, Former Governor of the Bank of Israel Introduced by Stanley Fischer 75 53 61 ADDRESS 4 SESSION III: THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE BANK OF ISRAEL'S CORPORATE GOVERNANCE—INSIGHTS AND LESSONS FROM THE FIRST YEAR THE MONETARY COMMITTEE Chair: 103 NATHAN SUSSMAN, Director, Research Department, BOI PANEL KARNIT FLUG, Deputy Governor, BOI REUBEN GRONAU, Member, BOI MC RAFI MELNICK, Member, BOI MC BARRY TOPF, Member, BOI MC REUBEN GRONAU, Member, BOI MC ALEX CUKIERMAN, Member, BOI MC THE SUPERVISORY COUNCIL DAN PROPPER, Chairman, BOI Supervisory Council STANLEY FISCHER, Governor, BOI KEYNOTE ADDRESS LARRY SUMMERS, Harvard University Introduced by Stanley Fischer 111 119 121 131 REMARKS HEZI (EZEKIEL) KALO, Director General, BOI CONCLUDING ADDRESS STANLEY FISCHER, Governor, BOI 137 139 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 5 6 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL With thanks to Deputy Governor Dr. Nadine Baudot-Trajtenberg for editorial support and guidance, and to Yehudit Golan, Meir Dubitsky, and Zipi Weiss for their coordination, editorial assistance and typesetting efforts. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 7 FOREWORD This volume puts into print the lectures, speeches and dialogues that were presented and conducted at the Bank of Israel’s Farewell Conference honoring Governor Stanley Fischer. The conference was held in Jerusalem on June 18, 2013. The topics portray how the thinking about monetary policy and the central bank’s role have evolved since the onset of the global financial crisis. The conference also looked at the main pillars of the transformation of the Bank of Israel into the "New Bank of Israel" under Stan's leadership, in light of lessons from the global financial crisis and under the new Bank of Israel Law that came into effect in 2010. Stan made Aliyah in May of 2005, becoming an Israeli citizen and the eighth Governor of the Bank of Israel. He brought to his Governorship the experience earned during a distinguished career as a brilliant academic whose textbooks served as the foundations of our understanding of macroeconomics, vast experience in policy making at international organizations, and the perspective of the private financial sector. He navigated the Bank of Israel through turbulent times in the domestic and global environments. During the years of his Governorship, Israel went through the disengagement from the Gaza Strip in 2005, the passing of Prime Minister Sharon and his replacement by Ehud Olmert in 2006 and the Second Lebanon War in 2006, and he served through all these while having to work alongside six different Ministers of Finance over a term of eight years. On the global front, the period of Stan's Governorship was, of course, marked by the global financial crisis and the Great Recession. Stan successfully steered Israel's economy through the rough waters of these domestic and global developments. He brought about revolutionary changes in the Bank’s structure and operations with the long-awaited passage of the new Bank of Israel Law. He led the Bank into a new era—new in its structure, in its corporate governance, in an activist approach to banking supervision, in the scope of its policies, in the way we think about monetary policy and in its national and international standing. When the conference honoring Stan took place, we did not yet know that the experience he gained in leading the Bank of Israel during the previous eight years would turn out to be of great service to the global economy, with his subsequent move to yet another peak in his career, as the Vice Chairman of the of US Federal Reserve Board of Governors. Israel, the Israeli economy and the Bank of Israel were lucky to have Stan's knowledge, experience, and leadership at their disposal during what turned out to be a critical time. In this volume, several of Stan's colleagues, from Israel and from 8 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL around the world, have shared their insights on several topics which are all related, one way or the other, to the work that Stan has done and will be doing in the coming years. I wish to thank all those who took part in the conference, including the speakers, panelists, audience, BOI staff who helped with the program, logistics, arrangements and editorial support. Karnit Flug Governor, Bank of Israel THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 9 OPENING REMARKS KARNIT FLUG Dear Stan, President Draghi, Governor Honohan, Governor Vergara, Professor Summers, Professor Woodford, Jacob Frenkel, Claudio Borio, distinguished guests, ladies and gentlemen. I would like to open this farewell conference honoring our Governor, Prof. Stanley Fischer. During Governor Fischer’s tenure, the Bank of Israel has been profoundly transformed. It has been transformed in the way decisions are made, its internal organization and its corporate governance; it has been transformed in terms of its goals and the targets of its policies; and it has been transformed in terms of the policy tools that are being used. This transformation reflected the adoption and implementation of the new Bank of Israel Law, as well as the evolution of central banking following the experience of, and the lessons from, the "Great Recession". In this conference we will deal with the various elements of this transformation. In the first session, we will discuss the evolution of thinking about monetary policy and its limitations in an environment where issues of systemic financial stability play an important role and when interest rates approach the zero bound. In the second session, we will discuss more specifically the role of central banks in macroprudential policy. In the afternoon session, we will focus on corporate governance, and we hope to draw some lessons and insights from the experience we’ve gained in the first year and a half of operation of our Monetary Committee and Supervisory Council. The new Bank of Israel Law finally came into effect in June 2010 following a very long—13 year—process. The initiative to update and modernize the Bank of Israel Law began in 1995, when Governor Frenkel appointed Prof. Zvi Sussman to head a committee to propose changes in the Bank’s decision-making process and policy objectives, and to enhance the Bank's independence. This committee was followed by the Klein Committee, which was appointed in 1997 to recommend which alternative among those put forward by the Sussman Committee should be advanced. By that time, it had become clear that in order to mobilize the support for, and to overcome the controversies surrounding, the new Bank of Israel Law, an independent public committee was needed. Prime Minister Netanyahu (then in his first term) formed the Levin Committee and its recommendations were presented in December 1998. Incidentally, among the experts who testified before the Levin Committee was the then First Deputy Managing Director of the IMF, Prof. Stanley Fischer. 10 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL However, many disputes along the way prevented the completion of this complex task of legislation until 2010. One benefit of having such a long process was that the law that was eventually adopted was based on the accumulated experience of many countries that had updated their laws much earlier. It also took into account at least some of the initial lessons from the global financial crisis regarding the role that central banks should play, and the tools they should have at their disposal. (However, some work, regarding the coordination and cooperation with other regulators, remains to be completed). Since the adoption of the law, the Monetary Committee has been appointed and has been making monetary policy decisions since October 2011. The Supervisory Council has also been appointed, and has been overseeing the way the Bank is run, including its annual budget and its work program. Focusing on monetary policy: Back in the old days (that is, before the global crisis) the lives of central bankers were relatively simple: they would meet once a month, or every 6–8 weeks, to decide about the interest rate, look at data on inflation and activity, they decided on the rate, and they were done. Now they still meet at the same frequency to decide about the rate, but they also look at the housing market, the growth of credit, capital flows, the exchange rate—and they think about the interest rate, but they may also think about purchasing assets in a quantitative easing program, intervening in the foreign exchange market, and they may think of limiting loan to value ratios or applying some other macroprudential tools to one market or another. In the case of the Bank of Israel, the Governor didn't even have to consult with anyone, he was (formally) the sole decision maker. Since the formation of the Monetary Committee in accordance with the new Law, this is no longer the case. Things have really become more complicated. This conference will deal with some of the challenges faced these days by central bankers. Here is a brief summary of what has changed at the Bank of Israel over the period of the Governorship of Stanley Fischer: We have a new law, which redefined the policy objectives; which expanded the policy tools at our disposal; which expanded the flexibility in our foreign exchange reserves management—we could invest in new assets that we couldn’t beforehand; and a Monetary Committee and Supervisory Council were formed. In terms of the use of various policy tools, we have been intervening once in a while in the foreign exchange market; during the crisis we adopted measures of quantitative easing in the form of purchases of government bonds on the secondary market; we’ve used prudential and macroprudential tools such as, in the housing market, limiting the loan to value ratios and limiting the share of variable interest rate mortgages, among other measures; and we’ve introduced some limitations on short-term capital flows. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 11 In its internal operations, the Bank of Israel has undergone a thorough reorganization, has put in place business continuity plans and practices and has reached a new wage agreement with its employees, following protracted negotiations. Before I call on Governor Fischer to present President Draghi, I would like to take this opportunity to say just a few words on a personal level. This conference is a farewell conference honoring Governor Stanley Fischer, and it is about the transformation of the Bank of Israel, which he has led into a new era—new in its structure, in its corporate governance, in the scope of its policies, in the way we think about monetary policy and in its national and international standing. Although I have been at the Bank of Israel for almost a quarter of a century, most of what I know about conducting monetary policy, especially during rough times, I have learned from Stan. His leadership, which I have witnessed—his recognition that it is worthwhile to listen to everyone in the room, encouraging even the most junior person to speak, recognizing that listening to all helps in making the most informed and best decisions, his steady hand on the steering wheel during very rough times, his ability to make decisions early on, using judgment, before the picture fully clears up (and it never does), and his ability to communicate these decisions in plain language—Hebrew—in a way that can be grasped by the general public, is an inspiration and a lesson for life. Thank you, Stan. 12 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 13 SESSION I: RETHINKING THE LIMITATIONS OF MONETARY POLICY Introduction of Mario Draghi Stanley Fischer Welcome and thanks to all of you, particularly those of you who have come from abroad to discuss issues of central banking – notably those that have arisen during the Great Recession – as well as Israelis, my colleagues from the Bank of Israel and from the wider public. We are fortunate to have as our opening speaker, one of the two leading central bankers in the world, Mario Draghi. Mario earned his Ph.D. at MIT, where he was one of the first of the Italian students who heralded a new generation of Italian economists, those who are among the leaders of the field, whether they work in Italy or elsewhere. I think the change had to do with the growing capacity of Bocconi University, although Mario wasn’t from Bocconi. From MIT, Mario went back to Italy and taught at the Universities of Trento, Padua, Venice and Florence. Not bad places to be if you were a professor who probably sometimes had time to enjoy the scenery. Mario entered the world of public policy in 1984 as Executive Director for Italy at the World Bank and our professional paths crossed there, because while he was there – and I suspect with his support – I became Chief Economist of the World Bank. He then left the World Bank and began a remarkable ten-year period as Director General of the Italian Treasury, a job which he did from 1991 to 2001. The period was remarkable in many respects. Italian governments at that time changed more frequently than the civil servants: it was the civil service that provided the essential elements of stability and continuity in economic policy. And during his period as Director General of the Treasury, Mario was the anchor – a highly respected anchor – of economic stability and continuity of policies. Mario was well respected inside Italy, and well respected internationally. Among his most impressive achievements was his management of Italy’s large-scale privatization program during the 10 years he was Director General of the Treasury. There was not then, nor has there subsequently been, one word in the press or anywhere else about the possibility that there was any corruption in this process. Nothing—which is almost unprecedented in any country, and probably particularly difficult in the context in which Mario was working. That is symptomatic of the high regard and high respect in which he was held. 14 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Ten years is a long time to serve in a position as responsible as Director General of the Italian Treasury. Mario left in 2001, and moved to the private sector, as Vice Chairman of Goldman Sachs, a position he held from 2002 to 2005. Then, in 2006, he became Governor of the Banca d'Italia. The Banca d'Italia is probably the most highly respected institution in Italy, but its reputation had suffered before he arrived. Very rapidly, he restored the reputation of the Bank and began to operate in the international arena. As Governor of the Banca d'Italia, he was obviously one of the people who decided on monetary policy in the ECB. In 2011 he became the president of the European Central Bank, at an extremely difficult moment, when the European crisis was accelerating and deepening. History may well credit him with the record for the most effective open mouth policy in the history of central banking, and possibly the most effective single sentence in the history of central banking, when he said in a three and a half minute speech in London in July 2012 that the ECB will do—I’ll allow you to quote it, Mario, since you do it better than me—“will do everything that is necessary to save the euro”. There were many—I among them—who were certain that he wouldn’t have done that without coordinating with the political level. Now I understand that almost certainly he didn’t coordinate with the political level—and this, if you think about the politics, was an extremely courageous step because he could have been repudiated and that would have made his life as president of the ECB virtually impossible. That sentence restored the credibility of the Euro and of the ECB. The situation is not fully stabilized but it changed dramatically and immediately after that single statement. It is a great pleasure for me to present Mario Draghi as the first speaker in this conference. Mario, we enormously appreciate and thank you for your participation in this event. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 15 MARIO DRAGHI Ladies and gentlemen, The topic for this session – “the limitations of monetary policy” – is one that has attracted a great deal of attention since the beginning of the financial crisis. Circumstances have forced all major central banks to resort to instruments and policies carefully tailored to the unusual situation. Alex Cukierman and Michael Woodford, who will present their views on the issue in a few minutes, are among the prominent academics that have written about it extensively.1 Before handing the floor to them, let me say a few words about the current situation in the euro area, about our perspective at the European Central Bank (ECB) on today’s topic and about longer-term issues for the euro area. In terms of the current situation, the euro area economy is still in a phase of adjustment. Real GDP fell by 0.6% in the fourth quarter of 2012 and by 0.2% in the first quarter of 2013. Output has thus declined for six consecutive quarters, labour market conditions remain weak and public and private sector balance sheet adjustments continue to weigh on economic activity. Unacceptably high levels of unemployment, particularly youth unemployment, are the prime concern of economic policy-makers. Recent survey data suggest some improvement, but from low levels. Export growth should benefit from a recovery in global demand. Domestic demand should be supported by accommodative monetary policy; by the recent real income gains from lower oil prices and lower inflation; and by the confidence and wealth effects stemming from the improvements in financial markets since last summer. The ECB’s Governing Council has stressed that that monetary policy will remain accommodative for as long as necessary. In the period ahead, we will monitor very closely all incoming information on economic and monetary developments and stand ready to act if necessary. In the meantime, it is important to note that economic and financial fragmentation in the euro area has declined significantly since last summer. This has had beneficial effects for the real economies of all euro area countries. Banks in stressed countries have been able to regain access to interbank and capital markets – and they have raised funds as well as capital. Larger corporations have benefited from lower borrowing costs in capital markets. And small and medium-sized enterprises have seen borrowing costs from banks somewhat reduced. All of this should support investment. 1 See, for example, Cukierman, A., 2013, Monetary policy and institutions before, during, and after the global financial crisis, Journal of Financial Stability, in press, and Cúrdia, V. and Woodford, M., 2011, The central-bank balance sheet as an instrument of monetary policy, Journal of Monetary Economics, 58(1), 54-79. 16 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Target balances, which provide a powerful summary indicator of fragmentation, have declined by almost 300 billion euros or 25% from their peak. The costs of protection against risks of deflation have fallen from peaks twice their long-term average last summer to slightly below average now.2 Overall, monetary policy has regained steering capacity, which had become lost for large parts of the euro area in mid-2012. This is an important positive development. Let me turn now to the limitations of monetary policy. Here I see two possible dimensions. The first is positive and refers to the effectiveness of central bank actions at the margin – for example, when interest rates are close to zero. The second is normative and refers to the constraints imposed on us by our mandate and to the fears that boundaries between central bank policies and other policies might become blurred. I will not dwell on the first dimension because I do not think that we are materially challenged in our ability to deliver our objective of price stability by the low level of interest rates. Looking back, despite extraordinarily testing economic circumstances, inflation in the euro area has remained on the whole consistent with the ECB’s objective of below but close to 2%. Looking forward, Eurosystem staff project annual HICP inflation at 1.4% in 2013 and 1.3% in 2014, but medium-term inflation expectations remain anchored in line with our definition of price stability. One reason why inflation expectations have remained broadly stable is that we – and other major central banks around the world – have prevented the materialisation of deflation risk by adopting both standard and non-standard measures as and when necessary. In the euro area, one such non-standard measure was the introduction of the outright monetary transactions (OMT) programme last year, the stabilising effects of which are widely recognised. There are numerous other measures – standard interest rate policy and nonstandard measures – that we can deploy and that we will deploy if circumstances warrant. At the same time, I have also made clear that some of those measures may have unintended consequences. This does not mean that they should not be used, but it does mean that we need to be aware of those consequences and manage them appropriately. We will look with an open mind at these measures that are especially effective in our institutional setup and that fall within our mandate. 2 See P. Praet, Monetary policy in the context of balance sheet adjustments, Speech at Peterson Institute for International Economics, 22 May 2013. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 17 This leads me to the second dimension of discussion of the limitations of monetary policy, namely the risk of a blurring of the boundaries of central bank policy. To approach this question, it is useful to refer to the framework put forward by another prominent scholar in central bank matters. Marvin Goodfriend classifies central bank actions into three categories.3 The first category is what he calls “monetary policy” proper – changes in the size of the monetary base via purchases and sales of government securities. Second comes “credit policy” – changes in the composition of the central bank’s assets between government securities and claims on the private sector of various kinds. Third is “interest on reserves policy” – changes in the opportunity cost for banks to hold reserves or excess reserves. Goodfriend argues that all three categories have fiscal implications. And he states that credit policy and interest on reserve policy involve the use of public funds in a way that may imply an allocative role – and which may therefore blur the respective roles of the monetary and fiscal authorities. In this context, it is worth recalling that the monetary constitution of the ECB is firmly grounded in the principles of ‘ordoliberalism’, particularly two of its central tenets: First, a clear separation of power and objectives between authorities; And second, adherence to the principles of an open market economy with free competition, favouring an efficient allocation of resources. More explicitly, and by reference to another famous framework – the three basic policy functions that Richard Musgrave described as allocation, stabilisation, and distribution, and which aim delivering what Tommaso Padoa-Schioppa later described as efficiency, stability and equity – our policy is concerned only with macroeconomic stabilisation through the pursuit of price stability. We do not and should not play an active role in the functions of allocation and distribution.4 At the same time, our operational framework has always included elements of what Goodfriend qualifies as credit policy. The ECB manages liquidity and steers money market rates by lending to banks in temporary credit operations against a broad range of collateral. Furthermore, we have always remunerated reserves. 3 See Goodfriend, M., 2011, Central banking in the credit turmoil: an assessment of Federal Reserve practice, Journal of Monetary Economics, 58(1), 1-12. 4 Having said that, the objective of monetary policy being stabilisation does not imply that it cannot contribute to efficiency and equity, and indeed stable prices are a precondition of both (see B. Coeuré, Monetary Policy in a fragmented world”, Speech at Oesterreichische Nationalbank, Vienna, 10 June 2013. 18 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Does the fact that our operations entail some credit risk on the balance sheet of the central bank imply a violation of our ordoliberal principles? Does it imply that the ECB policy interferes with credit allocation? My answer is no. The risks we take onto our balance sheet in the context of our operations are controlled, and they are accepted only insofar as they are strictly necessary for the pursuit of price stability. This is entirely consistent with the concept of monetary dominance, which stipulates that fiscal considerations cannot stand in the way of the achievement of price stability. Indeed, ECB credit is backed by adequate collateral, which implies that the amount of residual risk borne by the central bank is buffered. There are two layers of protection. The first is founded on the ECB’s recourse to the borrowing institutions and the full credit and guarantee represented by their balance sheets. The second – when the first is exhausted – is given by the appropriation of the collateral posted as backing of the loan. If a counterparty defaults, the underlying collateral assets allow for the recovery of the amount lent. The use of risk control measures such as valuation haircuts and variable margins further mitigate the exposure to credit risk. The same risk control principle applies in the context of the OMT programme, through limitations on the maturity of eligible securities (one to three years) and through the strict conditionality for a country to be eligible for the programme. Another aspect of our operations is that they are designed precisely with the goal of achieving neutrality in credit allocation. The ECB’s policy framework was designed with a view to allowing the participation of a broad range of counterparties. The framework rests on the fundamental principle of equal treatment of counterparties. Equal treatment is also reflected in the collateral framework, which features a broad range of assets and a set of eligibility criteria that apply to all Eurosystem credit operations without distinction. A further observation is that lending to banks is consistent with an untargeted monetary policy. In the euro area, the majority of credit intermediation is processed via the banking system, as opposed to financial markets. Banks lend to households and to financial and non-financial firms of any size across the credit spectrum. Influencing bank funding conditions amounts to influencing credit conditions across the whole economy. What I have said applies in normal times, but it also largely applies in the specific circumstances of a fragmentation of the financial system – circumstances that we have faced and continue to face, albeit to a diminishing extent. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 19 Financial fragmentation in itself creates a distortion of the allocation of resources. It undermines the concept of a free market economy because it alters the conditions of competition. In this context, the measures that we have implemented through the crisis do not have an allocative or distributive role. On the contrary, by supplementing financial intermediation where it had become dysfunctional, they have contributed to reestablishing the allocative and distributive neutrality of markets. The liquidity measures that we took early in the crisis can be interpreted in this light. At that time, central banks had to substitute for the sudden disappearance of interbank market activity by acting themselves as a money market intermediary when necessary. For the ECB, this task was facilitated by the wide range of counterparties accepted in refinancing operations and by our broad collateral framework. Other central banks had to innovate more through the use of various targeted facilities outside their normal operating framework in order to reach out to the broad economy. The ECB could also mobilise its collateral framework to relieve the liquidity constraints faced by banks. We expanded the list of eligible collateral, so that banks could liquefy their balance sheets and mobilise assets that had become difficult to trade. In addition, the ECB could further contribute to alleviating the banks’ funding uncertainty by providing banks with assurance that they could rely on our refinancing operations for extended periods. The maximum maturity of our operations increased from three months to three years. Through these measures, the ECB decisively addressed the liquidity pressures faced by euro area banks and avoided a genuine credit crunch. What must be clear from what I have said so far is what constitutes the limitations to our actions, consistent both with the letter of our mandate and with the philosophy of the market economy that underpins it. We have been able to regain better control of monetary conditions in the euro area economy, which is very important for providing the appropriate monetary policy impulse to the economy. Part of this achievement is due to the announcement of the OMT programme. But equally important has been the progress in economic reform and adjustment at both the country level and the euro area level. Such reforms need to continue. There is still a rich reform agenda, especially structural, at the country level for many members of the euro area. There is also an important reform agenda at the European level. One key aspect of that is the banking union, which rests on single supervision and single resolution, the latter with an effective backstop if necessary. 20 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Preparations for single supervision at the ECB are advancing, and naturally we are working closely with the relevant national authorities. Five work streams are underway: first, on mapping the euro area banking system to identify systemically important banks; second, on the supervisory model to be adopted, which is most likely to be centred around joint supervisory teams; third, on supervisory data reporting; fourth on legal issues; and fifth, on the asset quality review that we will undertake prior to taking any bank under supervision. Formal adoption of the legal texts by the European Parliament will allow us to formalise the preparations and launch them so that we can be operational one year after adoption. Effective supervision requires effective resolution, which in turn requires establishment of a single resolution mechanism. We count on the European Commission to make a proposal in due course. Once these processes are launched, the banking union will be within operational reach. It should provide an answer to many of the challenges currently facing the euro area, including uneven credit conditions and the fragmentation of financial markets. When observers from outside look at our Economic and Monetary Union, they often emphasise how unfinished it appears compared with fully established unions such as the United States. In so doing, they highlight a number of unresolved issues, for example that in a monetary union of 17 otherwise sovereign states, a credit or transfer across Member States is viewed differently from a credit or transfer within an individual Member State. The equivalent of Target balances, for example, is a non-issue in the United States. However, such observers vastly underestimate the political capital invested in the euro by our leaders, as well as the political significance that such an investment has for the future of Europe. Of course, much work remains to be done for economic policy-makers across Europe. But I am confident that together we can build a stronger economic and monetary union that ultimately delivers jobs, growth and a return to prosperity for the citizens of the euro area. Thank you for your attention. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 21 Intoduction of Michael Woodford Karnit Flug Professor Michael Woodford is the John Bates Clark Professor of Political Economy at Columbia University. He received his undergraduate degree from the University of Chicago, a law degree from Yale Law School, and a PhD in Economics from MIT. Professor Woodford has been a MacArthur and a Guggenheim Fellow, and in 2007 he was awarded the Deutsche Bank Prize in Financial Economics. Prof. Woodford’s primary research interests are macroeconomic theory and monetary policy. He has written extensively on all aspects of monetary theory and policy. His most important work is the award-winning book, "Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy”. It is not an accident that the title of his book is very close to Professor Patinkin’s classic work, “Money, Interest and Prices”. We couldn't have asked for a better qualified academic to speak about the challenges faced today by monetary policy makers. 22 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 23 MICHAEL WOODFORD It’s a great pleasure to be asked to address you all, and particularly at a conference in honor of the career of Stan Fischer. I owe Stan a very great debt. When I came to graduate school at MIT, I knew virtually nothing about monetary economics, indeed I didn’t know much about macroeconomics in general. I had studied a little bit of macroeconomics before, and I imagined that that was what I was going to specialize in, in my graduate study. But in the first semester of the program at MIT, there was room for one elective course in addition to the required courses that we all had to take; and some of my fellow students who were more clued in insisted, “we have to take Fischer’s course”. This was a course that we weren’t supposed to be ready for, because it was a second-year course in monetary economics, and there was a whole first-year sequence in macroeconomics that we were supposed to take first. But it was already known that Stan was going to be on leave during our second year, and therefore my cohort wasn’t going to be able to have him teach this course in our second year, and everyone said that this was a course not to be missed. So I was one of the students who took the course in our first year, and I have to say that it was an outstanding course. I didn’t even fully appreciate how true this was until some years later, when I had to prepare a course in monetary economics myself, and went back to the notes I had from Stan’s course, and discovered how much more there had been in the class than I was able to appreciate at the time. But it did convince me that monetary economics was a deep subject, and of course, an important subject, and that is what I have ended up trying to understand better. For that I have Stan to thank. We have been asked to speak about the role of monetary policy, and in particular, about the limits to what monetary policy can achieve. I think that few people today will argue that monetary policy is not important. Central banks have played an especially prominent role in public policy over the past few years. Indeed, in many countries, the central bank has been the indispensable policy authority in dealing with the problems created by the global financial crisis. Yet this has not in all cases resulted in an increase in the prestige of central banks and the deference shown to them. Instead, in many places, and certainly in the US, public criticism of monetary policy has greatly increased in this period. In some cases, this criticism raises legitimate issues about complex and debatable judgments that have had to be made in conducting policy in a difficult environment. But some of the criticism seems to reflect unreasonable expectations about what monetary policy can be asked to achieve. In particular, the assumption that central banks have god-like power over the economy neglects the importance of real factors that monetary policy is powerless to undo. 24 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL For example, a criticism that is increasingly raised in the US argues that the Federal Reserve’s policy that has kept the federal funds rate near zero for more than 4 years, that promises to keep it there for considerably longer, and that has also sought to lower longer term interest rates through asset purchases, is harmful to savers. It’s argued in particular that retirees who worked hard and saved an amount that was expected to be sufficient to finance their retirement now face hardship if expected to live off the income from bonds in an environment of unexpectedly low interest rates for years on end. This is not, of course, an issue to dismiss lightly. But in asking whether the Fed should raise interest rates, one has to recognize that a higher interest return on savings will have to also mean a higher rate of interest charged to borrowers. And it is unclear whether, on net, increased income for savers would do more to lower hardship associated with unexpectedly tight budget constraints than the increase in hardship on the part of indebted households, who would face unexpectedly tightened budget constraints if interest rates are increased. Thus it is unclear in which direction a consideration of the distributional impact of monetary policy should cut. But more importantly, the supposition that interest rates are simply determined by the fiat of the central bank, and can equally well be higher or lower if the central bank wishes them to be, neglects the role of real factors. In fact, the ultimate reason for the current disappointment of savers in the US is a situation in which fewer households and firms have been willing to spend, at a normal level of interest rates, owing to increased concern to reduce their levels of indebtedness, and increased uncertainty about future conditions. Under these circumstances, the equilibrium real rate of interest is lower than its usual level, for reasons unrelated to Fed policy; and in a world of perfectly flexible wages and prices, the real rate of return received by savers would fall regardless of monetary policy. It would be unfortunate to be a saver intending to live off the return of one’s past savings in such a state of the world; but this would not be the fault of the central bank, nor a problem that monetary policy could solve. It would have to be addressed by some combination of better retirement planning, social insurance programs, and statecontingent fiscal policy. In a world with sticky nominal wages and prices, instead, it’s no longer true that monetary policy can’t affect real rates of return. Still, it is important to recognize how it affects them. Monetary policy can achieve a temporary departure of the market real rate from the natural rate only by causing the level of aggregate real activity also to temporarily depart from the natural rate of output. Specifically, it is possible for the central bank to keep the market real rate of return from falling, when a shock of the kind that I’ve described occurs, only by pursuing a contractionary policy that would keep output below potential for a time. This means that preserving the incomes of savers would require not merely a corresponding reduction in others’ incomes, but a reduction in aggregate income— so that the incomes of others would fall by more than the amount by which the THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 25 incomes of savers would increase, if indeed a net increase in the incomes of savers would even be achieved, given the likely effect on them of the sharper contraction in economic activity. This example illustrates one reason why people demand more from central banks than they can possibly deliver—the simple fact that people have conflicting interests. But this cannot, by itself, explain why the degree of controversy about monetary policy has increased so much recently. I think part of the reason may relate to the way that central banks have responded to the global financial crisis. One source of outsized expectations about what monetary policy should accomplish may be the degree which some central banks have emphasized their power to stimulate the economy despite the unusually difficult circumstances recently faced. Central bankers have sought to assure the public that monetary policy is not impotent, that they have not “run out of ammunition,” even when their traditional policy tools have reached their limits. The reason for this, doubtless, has been a desire to avoid the possibility of self-fulfilling pessimistic expectations. It’s feared that if the central bank were to admit that there were limits to its ability to further stimulate aggregate demand, the result would be deepening gloom about coming deflation, and continuing low incomes, which then would further reduce what the central bank could achieve with its instruments. But exaggerating the power of the available instruments of monetary policy has potential costs as well. One of these is the creation of exaggerated hopes, that can then lead to disillusionment with the central bank, which in turn results in political pressure to limit the central bank’s autonomy. Another cost, I believe, is that excessive confidence in what monetary policy should be able to achieve tends too easily to relieve fiscal authorities of responsibility for the macroeconomic consequences of their decisions. One of the reasons for the slowness of the recovery in the US, and some other countries as well, has been the fact that fiscal policy has lately been focused largely on the problem of maintaining the long-run solvency of the government, with the consequence that the government budgets and public sector employment have been slashed precisely at the time when unemployment was already high and demand already insufficient. Confidence that monetary policy should be able to manage the level of aggregate demand has helped to excuse this emphasis. Indeed, one wonders whether the UK Treasury’s enthusiasm this spring for requesting that the Bank of England review the possible use of additional, more aggressive, easing policies beyond the remarkable steps already taken there may not have been due to this motivation—encouraging the view that monetary policy should be able to do even more provides an excuse for continuing to focus fiscal policy purely on longrun solvency concerns. I would agree that monetary policy can do more, when the zero lower bound for short term interest rates has been reached, as it has been in the US, than to simply point out that interest rates are as low as they can get. In particular, a commitment 26 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL to maintain a more accommodative stance of policy in the future, when conditions would ordinarily justify a policy rate above zero, should be able to increase aggregate demand now, through a variety of channels, and I believe that the Federal Reserve was right to seek to increase current demand through “forward guidance” of this kind. But there are limits to the power of this tool, particularly at a time when many households and firms are reluctant to increase their spending even if interest rates are low, owing to the state of their balance sheets and uncertainty about the future. And it is not a tool without costs: even if promises about future policy can increase demand now, they do so at the cost of constraining the central bank’s ability to achieve its stabilization objectives later. In the case of fiscal policy, it is well understood that spending more now has the cost of reducing the government’s room to maneuver in the future; hence the emphasis at present in the US and many other countries on reducing the amount of debt carried into the future. But the available means of monetary stimulus when the zero lower bound is reached constrain future policies, as well. Hence it seems a mistake to ask for no help from fiscal stimulus, simply on the ground that future policy is thought to be less constrained this way. Another reason for increased pressure on central banks to satisfy an ever longer list of demands is likely an increased perception that monetary policy is being conducted in a discretionary fashion, with few constraints on what the central bank might choose to do, and uncertainty about what is required to justify particular policies. This represents an apparent change with respect to the most important developments of the two decades prior to the crisis, which had instead emphasized greater commitment on the part of central banks to specific but therefore limited goals. The guiding principles behind this new approach to monetary policy in the period before the crisis were very well articulated in a paper by Stanley Fischer called “Modern Central Banking,” written in 1994 for a volume celebrating the tercentennial of the Bank of England. I realize that it is usually considered impolite to remind a public official of things that he has said in the past, and even more so when the lecture in question is from nearly two decades ago, and from a time long before he was invested with his current responsibilities. But in this case, I think that the essay stands up quite well to the passage of time, and I would still recommend it to anyone interested in central banking. Stan’s paper argued for the importance for granting central banks operational independence in setting interest rates. But the case made for this independence was not so that they could exercise the fullest possible degree of discretion. Rather, it was so that the central bank could commit itself to clearly defined targets, pursue them deliberately, and then be held accountable, both for achieving particular outcomes and for explaining how its policies are guided by the pursuit of the announced targets. This required limiting what monetary policy can be expected to deliver, so that it could be held accountable for delivering something. In particular, the paper THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 27 argued for the desirability of an explicit quantitative target, on the order of 1 to 3 percent per year, for the long-run rate of inflation. It also argued for the importance of clarifying that the central bank was not to be responsible for “the financing of the government deficit, or management of the public debt;” and it argued for the desirability of allowing the exchange rate to float, and vesting responsibility for both interest-rate policy and exchange-rate policy in the central bank, so as not to require the central bank to conform to an exchange-rate target set by someone else. Under this view—that was indeed the one adopted around the world in the decade after Stan expounded it—the case for granting the central bank independence from political interference was based on a commitment on its part to pursue definite, pre-specified goals, for which it could be held accountable. A reversion to a more discretionary approach to policy instead makes it more likely that both the public and the political branches of government will ask why central banks have so much apparently unchecked power. But can the kind of framework for the conduct of monetary policy described in Stan’s 1994 essay still be considered viable today, after all that happened since the crisis in 2008? I believe that many of the principles enunciated there remain valid. The analytical case for the desirability of a policy rule, as opposed to unfettered discretion, turns on the importance of expectations of future outcomes as a determinant of current conditions, and also on the idea that central bank commitments can influence these expectations. But the importance of expectations, and also of seeking to influence them through central-bank statements, has only become more prominent in monetary policy since the crisis. Both the use of forward guidance by the Federal Reserve and the Bank of Japan’s most recent policy initiative represent examples of policies intended to affect the economy primarily by influencing expectations. And to the extent that a central bank seeks to change expectations about its future policy, it must be able to commit its future policy in advance, rather than leaving itself full discretion. I believe that the benefits of stabilizing medium-run inflation expectations have also continued to be evident during the crisis. Inflation expectations have remained relatively stable in many countries in the face of large disturbances and dramatic changes in policy. I believe this has been an important stabilizing factor. In countries like the US, a significant disruption of the financial sector didn’t lead to the kind of deflationary spiral seen in the 1930’s; and elsewhere, large increase in commodity prices didn’t lead to the kind of wage-price spiral seen in the 1970s. In both cases, the stability of inflation expectations, relative to what had been true under prior policy regimes, made it easier for current policy to contain the disruptive consequences of these shocks. Some aspects of the theory of inflation targeting as they were understood 20 years ago, however, do need to be modified in the light of more recent developments. Most notably, I think there is a need for greater clarification of how policy should be conducted in the short run so as to be consistent, and also to be seen to be consistent, with the central bank’s medium-run inflation target. A 28 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL formulation proposed in Stan’s 1994 paper is that a central bank should always be able to project that inflation will return to the target rate if things evolve as currently expected, over a definite, fairly short horizon—say, within two years. I don’t think this is a suitable general principle, if one allows for the kind of more serious macroeconomic disturbances encountered recently. There is no reason to think that the time that it should take for convergence back to a long-run steadystate position should be independent of the nature and the size of the economic disturbance. There is also a problem of intertemporal consistency with a criterion that only requires a promise that the target will be reached two years in the future. If, a year from now, one expects the central bank also to be content with an expectation of reaching the target only two years further in the future, then one should not expect now that the target will be actually reached within two years, if things develop as can currently be anticipated.5 A solution, in my view, would be to define acceptable short-run departures from the inflation target, not in terms of the time expected to be required to reach the target, but in terms of the presence of other imbalances that justify not proceeding more rapidly to the target rate of inflation. For example, the appropriate short-run policy stance might be defined to be the one that keeps nominal GDP as close as possible to a pre-announced target path. Such a criterion would allow for temporary departures of the inflation rate from the long-run target rate if they coincide with temporary departures of real GDP growth from the potential growth rate. At the same time, the target path for nominal GDP could be 1.chosen so to guarantee an average rate of inflation equal to the target rate over periods of several years, as long as real GDP can be expected to equal potential on average over sufficiently long periods of time. Defining a desirable criterion for short-term policy decisions, which can clarify the way in which alternative short-term objectives should be balanced, however, is admittedly a more difficult task than simply designing a desirable medium-run inflation target. The answer is more sensitive to specific assumptions about the structure of the economy, and so judgments about it will therefore be more controversial. We will be fortunate indeed if someone with both the analytical capacity and the practical wisdom of a Stanley Fischer will take on the task of synthesizing what’s known about the principals of central banking in the light of more recent experience. I don’t know what Stan’s own plans are after leaving the Bank of Israel, though I was happy to see him say in a recent interview that he doesn’t intend to retire. If he were to take on the challenge of writing an updated essay on modern central banking, I for one would be very eager to read it. 5 This point is developed in further detail in Michael Woodford, “Forward Guidance by Inflation-Targeting Central Banks,” paper presented at the conference “Two Decades of Inflation Targeting,” Sveriges Riksbank, June 2013. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 29 Introduction of Alex Cukierman Karnit Flug Professor Alex Cukierman is a member of the Bank of Israel Monetary Committee and a Professor of Economics at the Interdisciplinary Center in Herzliya. He earned his PhD at MIT, and his BA and MA at the Hebrew University. He has served as visiting professor or research fellow at Princeton, Stanford, the ECB, and the World Bank, among many other institutions. He has served as associate editor of the European Journal of Political Economy, and as an editor of other journals. He has written several books and more than a hundred papers on macroeconomics, monetary economics and monetary policy, monetary institutions and political economy. His most well-known book is "Central Bank Strategy, Credibility and Independence: Theory and Evidence". Professor Cukierman was also a member of the Levin Committee, which was appointed to recommend reform in the Bank of Israel Law. Clearly, Professor Cukierman presents an ideal combination of research on monetary policy and institutions and experience in policy making as a member of our Monetary Committee, and is thus the perfect choice to be the last speaker in this session. 30 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 31 US BANKS’ BEHAVIOR SINCE LEHMAN’S COLLAPSE, BAILOUT UNCERTAINTY AND AMBIGUITY ALEX CUKIERMAN 1. SOME EVIDENCE There has been a dramatic shift in the behavior of the US banking system in terms of both credit growth and demand for reserves since the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008. Between January 1947 and August 2008, total US banking credit expanded at an average yearly rate of 7.15%. From Lehman’s collapse until June 2011, this rate dropped to a mere 0.65% – about one-tenth of its previous normal long-term rate of growth. Figure 1 illustrates this dramatic change in the behavior of US banking credit prior to and after the downfall of Lehman Brothers. Figure 2 shows that, although there was some resumption of credit growth after the summer of 2011 this rate never came close to the rates observed in the pre-Lehman’s collapse era.6 Figure 1: Total US commercial banks' credit (Billions of $): Figure 1: Total US commercial banks' credit (Billions of $): January 1947 – May 2013 January 1947- May 2013 12000 10000 8000 6000 4000 2000 1 January 2013 1 January 2011 1 January 2009 1 January 2007 1 January 2005 1 January 2001 1 January 2003 1 January 1999 1 January 1997 1 January 1995 1 January 1993 1 January 1989 1 January 1991 1 January 1987 1 January 1985 1 January 1983 1 January 1981 1 January 1977 1 January 1979 1 January 1975 1 January 1973 1 January 1971 1 January 1969 1 January 1965 1 January 1967 1 January 1963 1 January 1961 1 January 1959 1 January 1957 1 January 1953 1 January 1955 1 January 1951 1 January 1949 1 January 1947 0 Source: Cukierman A., “Monetary policy and institution before, during and after the global financial crisis, Journal of Financial Stability, 9(3), September 2013, 373-384. 6 Between June 2011 and May 2013 the average yearly rate of credit expansion rose to 4.58%. 32 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Figure 2: Total US commercial banks' credit (Billions of $): Figure 2: Total US commercial January 2008 banks' – Maycredit 2013 (Billions of $): January 2008- May 2013 10200 10000 9800 9600 9400 9200 9000 8800 8600 8400 Source: Same as in figure 1. 1 April 2013 1 October 2012 1 January 2013 1 July 2012 1 April 2012 1 October 2011 1 January 2012 1 July 2011 1 April 2011 1 January 2011 1 July 2010 1 October 2010 1 April 2010 1 January 2010 1 July 2009 1 October 2009 1 April 2009 1 January 2009 1 July 2008 1 October 2008 1 April 2008 1 January 2008 8200 Source: Bloomberg - Ticker: ALCBBKCR Index Table 1: Average growth of US commercial banks' credit by subperiods at annual rates Time period Yearly growth of US Commercial banks' credit January 1947 – August 2008 7.15% August 2008 – June 2011 0.65% June 2011 – May 2013 4.58% Source: Author’s calculations based on Bloomberg – Ticker: ALCBBKCR Index. An even more dramatic break – before and after September 2008 – can be observed in the behavior of total US bank reserves. Their annual long-term normal rate of increase between January 1999 and August 2008 is about half a percent. After the Lehman event and up to April 2011, this annual rate accelerated to 100%. Figure 3 shows the rush to reserves of US banks after September 2008. At the end of August 2008, total banking reserves stood at about $46 billion. A year later they were eighteen times larger!!! They did decline moderately during the second half of 2010, and then increased again by about sixty percent till the end of April 2012. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 33 Figure 3: Total Reserves of US Depository Institutions Figure 3: Total reserves of (Billions US depository institutions (Billions of $) of $) 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 1 1 Ja n 9 Ju 9 1 l9 Ja 9 n 1 00 Ju 1 l0 Ja 0 n 1 01 Ju 1 l0 Ja 1 n 1 02 Ju 1 l0 Ja 2 n 1 03 Ju 1 l0 Ja 3 n 1 04 Ju 1 l0 Ja 4 n 1 05 Ju 1 l0 Ja 5 n 1 06 Ju 1 l0 Ja 6 n 1 07 Ju 1 l0 Ja 7 n 1 08 Ju 1 l0 Ja 8 n 1 09 Ju 1 l0 Ja 9 n 1 10 Ju 1 l1 Ja 0 n 1 11 Ju 1 l1 Ja 1 n 1 12 Ju 1 l1 Ja 2 n 13 0 Source: Same as in figure 1. Another way to appreciate the magnitude of the change in the behavior of US banks prior to and after the Lehman event is to compare the ratio between their total reserves and their total credit before and after this event. Just one month prior to Lehman’s downfall, on August 31, 2008, this reserve ratio was slightly more than half a percent. As can be seen from figure 4, it shot up dramatically immediately after Lehman’s demise reaching 12.62 percent on November 30, 2009 (a twenty-four fold increase in the reserve ratio) and climbing further to almost 20 percent in May 2013. Figure 4: Evolution of average reserve ratio of US banking system: Figure 4: Evolution of average reserve ratio of US banking January 2008 2008– MayMay 2013 system: January 2013 25.00% 20.00% 15.00% 10.00% 5.00% 1 April 2013 1 January 2013 1 July 2012 1 October 2012 1 April 2012 1 October 2011 1 January 2012 1 July 2011 1 April 2011 1 January 2011 1 July 2010 1 October 2010 1 April 2010 1 October 2009 1 January 2010 1 July 2009 1 April 2009 1 January 2009 1 October 2008 1 July 2008 1 April 2008 1 January 2008 0.00% Bloomberg - Ticker: ALCBBKCR Index, Federal Reserve Board Website Source: Author’s Source: calculations based on raw data from Bloomberg – Ticker: ALCBBKCR Index, and from Federal Reserve Board website. 34 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 2. HIGHER BAILOUT UNCERTAINTY AS AN EXPLANATION FOR THE POST LEHMAN BEHAVIOR OF US BANKS The previous evidence suggest that Lehman’s downfall marks a watershed in the behavior of US banks, raising a fundamental conceptual question about the reasons for this shift. I argue here that this change in behavior is due to a change in bailout uncertainty induced by Lehman’s downfall. In view of the Fed’s actions and the general political climate prior to the collapse it is not hard to support the argument that the decision not to bailout Lehman was a surprise that increased bailout uncertainty in the immediate aftermath of the collapse. In conjunction with aversion to bailout uncertainty on the part of banks, this argument can explain the rush of US banks into safe assets during the initial post Lehman period. In particular suppose that bailout risk is captured by a single binomial distribution with a parameter, P, that designates the probability of bailout in the minds of financial market participants. Bailout uncertainty in the Knightian sense means that individuals are not certain about the parameter P. Following Gilboa and Schmeidler this uncertainty can be modeled by postulating that individuals possess multiple priors about P.7 To illustrate, suppose that, prior to Lehman’s collapse, individuals in financial markets entertained the view that all the probabilities of bailout in the range between 0.4 and 0.6 were possible. Following the decision not to bailout Lehman, they became more uncertain about the likelihood of bailout, implying that their set of multiple priors expanded to also include lower probabilities of bailout. For concreteness suppose that their multiple priors set expanded to include all binomial probability distributions with P between 0.1 and 0.6. Using a set of axioms similar to the von Neuman-Morgenstern axioms on which the expected utility criterion is based, Gilboa and Schmeidler (Op. Cit.) show that, in the presence of ambiguity, individuals should behave as if they are maximizing expected utility with respect to the worst probability distribution.8 In the context of binomial multiple priors concerning the probability of bailout, the worst distribution from the point of view of investors in financial markets is the one with the lowest P. Continuing the numerical example above, this implies that, prior to Lehman’s collapse, investors in bonds maximized expected utility under the presumption that P=0.4 and after it under the assumption that it is lower (P = 0.1). Cukierman and Izhakian trace out theoretically the general equilibrium implications of this change in perceptions for banks and investors in the bond 7 See: (1) Knight F. M..Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. Houghton Mifflin, Boston, 1921. (2) Gilboa I. and D. Schmeidler.“Maxmin Expected Utility with Non-unique Prior”. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 18(2):141–153, April 1989. 8 Ambiguity is the term used in modern decision theory for Knightian uncertainty. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 35 market.9 They find that such an increase in bailout uncertainty induces a flight to safety by both banks and investors in the bond market, to a reduction in credit and, depending on parameters, even to a total arrest of financial intermediation. The upshot is that the decrease in the growth of banking credit, and the associated dramatic increase in the demand for reserves following Lehman’s downfall, can be understood in terms of an increase in bailout uncertainty in the aftermath of this event. 9 Cukierman A. and Y. Izhakian, “Bailout Uncertainty in a Microfounded General Equilibrium Model of the Financial System”, April 2013, Manuscript, Interdisciplinary Center and Tel-Aviv University. 36 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 37 SESSION II: THE ROLE OF THE CENTRAL BANK IN MACROPRUDENTIAL POLICY BARRY TOPF Good morning and welcome back. This morning’s first session, on the limitations of monetary policy, leads us directly to the topic of the role of central banks in macroprudential policy. As our first speaker, Claudio Borio, wrote in a recent paper, “before the crisis there was a consensus that monetary policy will take care of price stability while regulation and supervision will ensure financial stability. Unfortunately we have seen that price stability does not ensure macroeconomic stability. An additional objective has been added—financial stability, but that requires additional tools to deal with specific tasks for the economy that can’t be addressed easily or effectively by traditional monetary policy”. And so we have seen increasing interest in the use of macroprudential tools. But what does macroprudential policy actually mean? Macroprudential is very messy. Every discussion of policy quickly runs into difficulties of definition: it does not fit nicely into categories—theoretical, organizational or operational. It is hard to quantify, lacks benchmarks, and cuts across numerous areas of responsibility. Models are hard to come by and frequently unsatisfactory. It is extremely country specific; success is frequently unobservable while failure is painfully obvious. It has few tools which are exclusively its own but borrows them from other areas, and even its name is a hybrid borrowed from more clearly defined aspects of economic policy. The ambiguity is perhaps most succinctly summarized in the question posed in the very beginning of one recent paper on macroprudential policy: “is the goal of macroprudential policy to protect the banks from the economy or to protect the economy from the banks?” We have with us today three speakers who are eminently qualified to help us make sense of this complex field. Claudio Borio is the Deputy Head of the Monetary and Economic Department and Director of Research and Statistics at the Bank for International Settlements. He has written extensively and more notably insightfully on macroprudential policy and central banking. Patrick Honohan was appointed Governor of the Central Bank of Ireland in 2009, and that is a position that certainly makes him well acquainted with the risks and dangers of having a large banking system. Prior to that, he was a professor of international financial economics and development at Trinity College, Dublin. Rodrigo Vergara has been Governor of the Central Bank of Chile since December 2011. Before that he had broad experience not only in that central bank but in various think tanks and as a professor in the Economics Department of Universidad Catolica. Claudio, please. 38 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 39 MACROPRUDENTIAL POLICY AND THE FINANCIAL CYCLE: SOME STYLISED FACTS AND POLICY SUGGESTIONS CLAUDIO BORIO INTRODUCTION10 I would like to thank the organisers for their kind invitation; it is a pleasure and great honour for me to be here in such distinguished company. In the limited time available I would like to provide context. The objective is to explore what I consider as the major source of systemic risk, namely the financial cycle and its link with systemic financial (banking) crises and the far better known business cycle. I would like to highlight a few stylised facts and then turn to the implications for macroprudential policy. By “financial cycle” I shall mean, somewhat loosely, the self-reinforcing interaction between risk perceptions and risk tolerance, on the one hand, and financing constraints, on the other, that, as experience indicates, can lead to serious episodes of financial distress and macroeconomic dislocations. This is what has also come to be known as the “procyclicality” of the financial system. There are three takeaways from my presentation. First, the financial cycle should be at the very core of our understanding of the macroeeconomy. To my mind, macroeconomics without the financial cycle is very much like Hamlet without the Prince. Second, the financial cycle has significant implications for the design and limits of macroprudential policy. And, finally, it also has significant implications for the design and limits of other policies, notably monetary and fiscal. I will address two questions in turn. What are the properties of the financial cycle? I will highlight seven. What are the policy issues it raises? I will highlight four. Let me stress that what I will be presenting is based on research carried out at the BIS over the years. But many of the findings are quite consistent with work carried out elsewhere, including here at the IMF.11 10 This presentation was originally prepared for the IMF conference "Rethinking macro policy" (April 2013) and appears in the corresponding conference volume. The views expressed are my own and not necessarily those of the Bank for International Settlements. 11 Similarly, the references will be almost exclusively to BIS work, especially recent one, although the institution’s support of macroprudential policy goes back a long way (eg, Clement (2010)). That work contains extensive references to the literature. 40 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 1. THE FINANCIAL CYCLE: SEVEN PROPERTIES12 It is useful to think of the financial cycle as having seven properties. First, its most parsimonious description is in terms of the joint behavior of credit and property prices. In some respects, equity prices, while so prominent in finance and macroeconomics, can be a distraction. This, in turn, is related to the next property. Second, the financial cycle has a much lower frequency than the traditional business cycle.13 By traditional business cycle I mean how economists and policymakers think of the business cycle and measure it. This business cycle has a duration of up to eight years. By contrast, the financial cycle that is most relevant for serious macroeconomic dislocations has a duration that, since the early 1980s, has between 16 to 20 years. It is a medium-term process. This, at least, is what we have found in a sample of seven advanced economies for which we had good data (Drehmann et al (2012). The point is illustrated for the United States in Graph 1. The graph plots the traditional business cycle (red line) and the financial cycle (blue line) as measured through band-pass filters as well as peaks and troughs (vertical lines). The financial cycle is identified by combining the behaviour of credit, property prices and the ratio of credit to GDP.14 The difference in duration is obvious. Equities can be a distraction in the sense that their time-series properties are closer to those of GDP in terms of the duration of swings. For example, the stock market crashes of 1987 and 2000 were followed by slowdowns, or outright recessions, in GDP. But the financial cycle as measured by credit and property prices continued to expand, only to turn a few years later (early 1990s and 2007-8, respectively), bringing the economy down with it and causing even greater damage. Seen from this longer-term perspective, one can thus consider the early contraction phases in economic activity “unfinished recessions” (Drehmann et al (2012)). Third, peaks in the financial cycle tend to coincide with systemic banking crises or serious strains. Post-1985 all do in the sample of advanced countries we examined (Drehmann et al (2012)). And those crises that occurred well away from the peak were “imported”, ie they reflected losses on cross-border exposures to financial cycles elsewhere. Think, for instance, of the losses that German and Swiss banks incurred in the most recent financial crisis on their exposures to the 12 This section draws, in particular, on Borio (2012a). The qualification “traditional” is important. The data also reveal longer swings in GDP, which are closer to those for the financial cycle. See Drehmann et al (2012)). 14 While the changes in amplitude over time in the business and financial cycles are meaningful, because the financial cycle combines different series, it is not possible to draw inferences about the relative amplitude of the two cycles from the graph. See Drehmann et al (2012) for a discussion of the technical issues involved. 13 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 41 United States. Not surprisingly, business cycle contractions that coincide with the bust of financial cycles are much deeper. Fourth, thanks to the financial cycle, simple leading indicators can identify risks of banking crises fairly well in real time (ex-ante)15 and with a good lead (between 2 to 4 years, depending on calibration). The indicators we have found most useful at the BIS are based on the positive deviations of the (private sector) credit-to-GDP ratio and of asset prices, especially property prices, jointly exceeding their respective historical trends (eg, Borio and Drehmann (2009), Borio and Lowe (2002)).16 One can think of these indicators as real-time proxies for the build-up of financial imbalances: the deviations of asset prices provide a sense of the likelihood and size of the subsequent reversal; those of the credit-to-GDP ratio, a sense of the loss absorption capacity of the system. These indicators flashed red in the United States in the mid-2000s (Graph 2). There is also growing evidence that cross-border credit often outpaces purely domestic credit during such financial booms (eg, Borio et al (2011), Avdjiev et al (2012)).17 Fifth, and for much the same reasons, the financial cycle also helps construct estimates of sustainable output that, compared with traditional potential output estimates, are much more reliable in real time, as well as statistically more precise (Borio et al (2013)). None of the current methods, ranging from fully-fledged production function approaches to simple statistical filters, spotted that output was above its potential, sustainable level ahead of the Great Financial Crisis. In recent work, we have found that incorporating information about the behaviour of credit and property prices allows us to do just that. Graph 3 illustrates this for the United States, by comparing our estimates of the output gaps (the so-called “finance-neutral” gap) with those from the IMF and OECD, based on more fully fledged model approaches, and with a popular statistical filter (the Hodrick-Prescott filter). The traditional estimates made in real time, during the economic expansion that preceded the crisis, indicated that the economy was running below, or at most close to, potential (red lines in the corresponding panels). Only after the crisis did they recognise, albeit to varying degrees, that output had been above its potential, sustainable level (blue lines). By contrast, the finance-neutral measure sees this all along (bottom right-hand panel, red line). And it hardly gets revised as time unfolds (the red and blue lines are very close to each other). One reason why production function and similar approaches miss the unsustainable expansion is that they draw on the notion that inflation is the only signal of unsustainability. But, as we know, ahead of the crisis it was the 15 Real-time or ex ante refers to an estimate which is based only on information that is available at the time it is made. 16 Not surprisingly, these trends are consistent with the average length of the financial cycle; see.Drehmann et al (2011)). 17 All this casts doubt on the view that current account imbalances were a cause of the financial crisis; for an in-depth discussion of this issue, see Borio and Disyatat (2011). 42 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL behaviour of credit and property prices that signalled that output was on an unsustainable path: inflation remained low and stable. Sixth, and critically, the amplitude and length of the financial cycle are regimedependent: they are not, and cannot be, a kind of cosmological constant. Arguably, three key factors support financial cycles: financial liberalisation, which weakens financing constraints; monetary policy frameworks focused on near-term inflation control, which provide less resistance to the build-up of financial imbalances as long as inflation remains low and stable; and positive supply-side developments (eg, the globalisation of real economy), which fuel the financial boom while at the same time putting downward pressure on inflation. It is not a coincidence, therefore, that financial cycles have doubled in length since financial liberalisation in the early and mid-1980s and that they have become especially virulent since the early 1990s (Graph 1). Finally, busts of financial cycles go hand-in-hand with balance sheet recessions.18 In this case, compared with other recessions, debts and capital stock overhangs are much larger, the damage to the financial sector much greater, and the policy room for manoeuvre much more limited, as policy buffers – prudential, monetary and fiscal – get depleted. Evidence also indicates that balance sheet recessions result in permanent output losses – growth may return to its long-run pre-crisis rate but output does not regain its pre-crisis trajectory – and usher in slow and long recoveries. Why so? I suspect it reflects the legacy of the previous boom and the subsequent financial strains. 2. THE FINANCIAL CYCLE: FOUR OBSERVATIONS ABOUT MACROPRUDENTIAL POLICY How should prudential policy address the financial cycle? The financial cycle requires that prudential policy has a systemic, or macrorpudential, orientation. This means addressing the procyclicality of the financial system head-on – what has come to be known as the time dimension of macroprudential policy: this is the 18 Koo (2003) seems to have been the first to use such a term. He employs it to describe a recession driven by non-financial firms’ seeking to repay their excessive debt burdens, such as those left by the bursting of the bubble in Japan in the early 1990s. Specifically, he argues that the objective of financial firms shifts from maximising profits to minimising debt. The term is used here more generally to denote a recession associated with the financial bust that follows an unsustainable financial boom. But the general characteristics are similar, in particular the debt overhang. That said, we draw different conclusions about the appropriate policy responses, especially with respect to prudential and fiscal policy; see Borio (2012a). THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 43 dimension that relates to how system-wide or systemic risk evolves over time (eg, Crockett (2000), Borio (2011) and Caruana (2012a)).19 The general principle is quite simple to describe, but quite difficult to implement: it is to build up buffers during financial booms so as to draw them down during busts. This has two objectives. It would make the system more resilient, better able to withstand the bust. And, ideally, it would constrain the financial boom in the first place, thereby reducing at source the probability and intensity of the bust. Note that these two objectives are very different; the second is much more ambitious than the first. I will return to this point later. Let me now highlight four observations about macroprudential policy. They are all intended to manage expectations about its effectiveness and to set a realistic benchmark about what it can and cannot do -- and this from someone who has been a strong advocate of the approach for over a decade now and who continues to be one! The reason is that the financial cycle is a hugely powerful force. First observation: beware of macro stress tests as early warning devices in tranquil times (Borio et al (2012)). In fact, to the best of my knowledge, none of them flashed read ahead of the recent crisis.20 Their relentless message was “the system is sound”. There are two reasons for this. The first has to do with our risk measurement technology. Our current models are unable to capture convincingly the fundamental non-linearities and associated feedback effects that are at the core of the dynamics of financial distress. In essence, no matter how hard you shake the box, little falls out. This shifts the burden to the required size of the shocks, which become unreasonably large and, therefore, are discounted by policymakers. The deeper point here is that the essence of financial instability is that normal-sized shocks cause the system to break down. An unstable system is not one that would break down only if hit by a huge shock, such as an outsize recession. An unstable system is fragile. As empirical evidence indicates, crises break out close to the peak of the financial cycle, well before GDP has plunged into a deep recession or asset prices have collapsed. The second reason has to do with the context, or what might be called the “paradox of financial instability” (Borio (2011)). Initial conditions are unusually strong just before financial strains emerge. Credit and asset prices have been surging ahead; leverage measured at market prices is artificially low; profits and asset quality look especially healthy; and risk premia and short-term volatilities are extraordinarily compressed. Taken at face value, these signals point to low risk when, in fact, they are signs of high risk-taking. The system is most fragile when it looks strongest. And this point is reached after years of solid and relentless 19 There is also a cross-sectional dimension, which relates to how risk is distributed in the financial system at a point in time; see eg, Crockett (2000) and Borio (2011). 20 Even the FSAP for Iceland, released in August 2008, concluded that “….stress tests suggest that the system is resilient“. 44 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL expansion, typically alongside widespread financial innovations. Under these conditions, the temptation to believe that this time things are really different is extraordinarily powerful (Reinhart and Rogoff (2009)). Bottom line: at worst, macro stress tests can lull policymakers into a false sense of security. That said, if properly designed, they can be an effective tool for crisis management and resolution -- a tool to promote balance-sheet repair. After all, the crisis has already broken out, non-linearities have revealed themselves and hubris has given way to prudence. “Properly designed” means that the authorities need to have the will to shake the system hard, need to start the tests from very realistic asset valuations, and should put in place the necessary liquidity and solvency backups. Second observation: beware of network analysis as a tool to detect vulnerabilities (Borio et al (2012)). As a source of vulnerabilities, bilateral linkages (counterparty exposures) matter far less than common exposures to the financial cycle. Network analysis views the financial system as a web of connections linking institutions. It then models systemic risk by tracing the knock-on effects of the default of one institution on the rest along those interconnections. The larger the portion of the system that fails, the larger is systemic risk. The main problem is that, as empirical evidence confirms, given the size of the interconnections it is too hard to get large effects. The reason is simple: mechanical exercises abstract from behaviour. A financial crisis is more like a tsunami that sweeps away all that gets in its way than a force knocking down one domino after another. The main force driving it is indiscriminate behavioural responses. This also explains why the failure of small and seemingly innocuous institutions can trigger a major crisis. Small institutions do not matter because of what they are but because of what they signal about the rest: they signal shared vulnerabilities – they are the canary in the coalmine. When the financial cycle turns, the failure of the first institution can shake previously seemingly unshakable convictions and trigger a paradigm shift. That said, this does not imply that information about bilateral exposures has little value. Much like macro stress tests, it can be very valuable in crisis management, as a tool to identify pressure points and understand where and how best to intervene. But for this to be the case, the information has to be quite granular and very up to date (Borio (2013)). Third observation: beware of overestimating the effectiveness of macroprudential policy (Borio (2011), Caruana (2012a)). There are two sets of reasons here as well, which is some ways echo those that explain the limitations of stress tests. The first set is technical. The tools are more effective in strengthening the resilience of the financial system – the first objective mentioned above – than in constraining financial booms – the second, more ambitious objective. To be sure, THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 45 some instruments are more effective than others. For instance, it stands to reason, and it seems to be confirmed by empirical evidence, that ceilings on loan-to-value and debt-to-income ratios have more bite than capital requirements (eg, CGFS (2012)). After all, capital is cheap and plentiful during booms. But for typical calibration of the tools it would be imprudent to expect a strong impact. Moreover, and critically, all such tools are vulnerable to regulatory arbitrage. And the longer they stay in place, the easier arbitrage becomes. The second set of reasons has to do with political economy. Compared with monetary policy, it is even harder to take away the punchbowl when the party gets going. The lags between the build-up of risk and its materialisation are very long, certainly longer than those between excess demand and inflation – recall just how long the financial cycle is compared with the business cycle. For some of the tools the distributional effects are more prominent and concentrated. And while there is a constituency against inflation, there is hardly any against the inebriating feeling of getting richer. All this puts a premium on sound governance arrangements and on a right balance between rules and discretion. Fourth observation: beware of overburdening macroprudential policy (eg, Caruana (2010, 2012b), Borio (2012a,b)). This follows naturally from the previous observation. The financial cycle is simply too powerful to be tackled exclusively through macroprudential policy, or indeed prudential policy more generally, be it micro or macro. Macrorpudential policy needs the active support of other policies. What does this mean in practice? For monetary policy, it means leaning against the build-up of financial imbalances even if near-term inflation remains under control (exercising the “lean option”).21 Monetary policy sets the universal price of leverage in a given currency. In contrast to macroprudential tools, it is not vulnerable to regulatory arbitrage: you can run, but you can’t hide. For fiscal policy, it means being extra prudent, recognising the hugely flattering effect of financial booms on the fiscal accounts. This is because the overestimation of potential output and growth (Graph 3), the revenue-rich nature of financial booms, owing to compositional effects, and the contingent liabilities needed to address the subsequent bust. As an important aside, a big open question is how macroprudential frameworks should address sovereign risk. These frameworks were originally designed with private sector vulnerabilities in mind, linked to the financial cycle. But such cycles leave in their wake seriously damaged sovereigns, which can all too easily sap banks’ strength. Moreover, as history indicates, sovereigns may cause banking crises quite independently of private sector excesses. At a time when the 21 The existence of a “risk-taking” channel of monetary policy, whereby changes in interest rates (and other monetary policy tools) influence risk perceptions and risk tolerance strengthens the case for an active role of monetary policy. It is not, however, a necessary condition for it. See Borio and Zhu (2011)). 46 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL sovereigns’ creditworthiness is increasingly in doubt, much more attention should be devoted to this issue. Against this broad backdrop, is there a risk that adjustments in policy frameworks are falling short? Ostensibly, this was the case before the crisis, but what about since then? My answer is that the risk should not be underestimated. Progress has been uneven across policies (Borio (2012b)). Prudential policy has adjusted most. A major shift from a micro to a macroprudential orientation has taken place in regulation and supervision. Think, for instance, of the adoption of a countercyclical capital buffer in Basel III (BCBS (2010), Drehmann et al (2011)) and, more generally, of the efforts under way to implement fully-fledged macroprudential frameworks around the world (CGFS (2012)). That said, expectations about what these frameworks can deliver are running too high and there is a question of whether enough has been done with respect to instruments, their calibration and governance arrangements. Moreover, more could and should have been done to repair banks’ balance sheets in some jurisdictions. Monetary policy has adjusted less. To be sure, there has been some shift towards adopting the “lean option”. But the will to exercise it in practice has been quite limited. The temptation to rely exclusively on the new macroprudential tools has been very powerful, to avoid disturbing monetary policy. And it is worth asking whether the limitations of monetary policy to tackle financial busts have been fully appreciated. Fiscal policy has adjusted least. There is as yet little recognition of the hugely flattering effects of financial booms on the fiscal accounts and of the big risks that busts pose for the sustainability and even effectiveness of fiscal policy. Bottom line: there is a real risk that policies are not sufficiently mutually supportive. And, critically, they are not sufficiently symmetric as between financial booms and busts. They tighten too little during booms with the serious danger that buffers get depleted during busts. This poses a huge constraint on the room for manoeuvre – one that becomes tighter over successive cycles. Policy horizons are simply too short, not commensurate with the duration of the financial cycle (Borio (2012b)). CONCLUSION There is a need to bring the financial cycle back into macroeconomics. Macroeconomics without the financial cycle is very much like Hamlet without the Prince. This raises huge analytical challenges that the profession is just beginning to tackle. The financial cycle has major implications for macroprudential policy and beyond. I highlighted four observations. Beware of macro stress tests as early warning devices. Beware of network analysis as a tool to identify financial THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 47 vulnerabilities. Beware of the limitations of macroprudential policy. And beware of overburdening it. Has enough been done to adjust policy frarmeworks? Not quite. In the case of macroprudential policy, more and better can be done with respect to the calibration and activation of the instruments. In the case of monetary policy more can be done with respect to the exercise of the “lean option”. And in the case of fiscal policy there is a need to recognise the hugely flattering effect that financial booms have on the fiscal accounts. So much for prevention and how to address the financial boom; what about the question of how to address the bust? If anything, here the questions are even bigger and more controversial, while progress has been more limited (Borio (2012a,b)). There is a serious risk, in particular, that the effectiveness of monetary and fiscal policy is overestimated and of a new, more insidious form of time inconsistency. But this is another story. 48 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL REFERENCES Avdjiev, S, R McCauley and P McGuire (2012), “Rapid credit growth and international credit: Challenges for Asia”, BIS Working Papers, no 377, April. http://www.bis.org/publ/work377.pdf Basel Committee for Banking Supervision (2010), Guidance for national authorities operating the countercyclical capital buffer, December http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs187.htm Borio, C (2011), “Implementing a macroprudential framework: blending boldness and realism”, Capitalism and Society, vol 6(1), Article 1. http://ssrn.com/abstract=2208643 ______ (2012a), “The financial cycle and macroeconomics: what have we learnt?”, BIS Working Papers, no 395, December http://www.bis.org/publ/work395.htm forthcoming in the Journal of Banking & Finance. ______ (2012b), “On time, stocks and flows: understanding the global macroeconomic challenges”, lecture at the Munich Seminar series, CESIfoGroup and Sueddeutsche Zeitung, 15 October, BIS Speeches, www.bis.org/speeches/sp121109a.htm. Forthcoming in the NIESR Review. ——— (2013), “The Global Financial Crisis: setting priorities for new statistics”, BIS Working Papers no 408, April. Forthcoming in the Journal of Banking Regulation. http://www.bis.org/publ/work408.htm Borio, C and P Disyatat (2011), ”Global imbalances and the financial crisis: link or no link?”, BIS Working Papers, no 346, May. http://www.bis.org/publ/work346.htm Borio, C, P Disyatat and M Juselius (2013), “Rethinking potential output: embedding information about the financial cycle”, BIS Working Papers, no 404, February http://www.bis.org/publ/work404.htm Borio, C and M Drehmann (2009), “Assessing the risk of banking crises – revisited”, BIS Quarterly Review, March, pp 29–46 http://www.bis.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qt0903e.pdf Borio, C, M Drehmann and K Tsatsaronis (2012), “Stress-testing macro stress tests: does it live up to expectations?”, BIS Working Papers, no 369, January. Forthcoming in the Journal of Financial Stability. http://www.bis.org/publ/work369.htm Borio, C and P Lowe (2002), “Assessing the risk of banking crises”, BIS Quarterly Review, December, pp 43-54 http://www.bis.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qt0212e.pdf Borio, C, R McCauley and P McGuire (2011), “Global credit and domestic credit booms” BIS Quarterly Review, September, pp 43-57 http://www.bis.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qt1109f.pdf Borio, C and H Zhu (2011), “Capital regulation, risk-taking and monetary policy: a missing link in the transmission mechanism?”, Journal of Financial Stability, December. Also available as BIS Working Papers, no 268, December 2008. http://www.bis.org/publ/work268.htm THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 49 Caruana, J (2010), “Monetary policy in a world with macroprudential policy”, speech delivered at the SAARCFINANCE Governors' Symposium 2011, Kerala, 11 June http://www.bis.org/speeches/sp110610.htm ______ (2012a), “Dealing with financial systemic risk: the contribution of macroprudential policies”, panel remarks at Central Bank of Turkey/G20 Conference on "Financial systemic risk", Istanbul, 27-28 September http://www.bis.org/speeches/sp121002.htm ______ (2012b), ”International monetary policy interactions: challenges and prospects”, Speech at the CEMLA-SEACEN conference on "The role of central banks in macroeconomic and financial stability: the challenges in an uncertain and volatile world", Punta del Este, Uruguay, 16 November. http://www.bis.org/speeches/sp121116.htm?ql=1 Crockett, A (2000), “Marrying the micro- and macroprudential dimensions of financial stability”, BIS Speeches, 21 September. http://www.bis.org/review/r000922b.pdf CGFS (2012), Operationalising the selection and application of macroprudential instruments, no 48, December http://www.bis.org/publ/cgfs48.htm Clement, P (2010), “The term "macroprudential": origins and evolution”, BIS Quarterly Review, March, pp 59-67. http://www.bis.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qt1003h.htm Drehmann, M, C Borio and K Tsatsaronis (2011), “Anchoring countercyclical capital buffers: the role of credit aggregates”, International Journal of Central Banking, vol 7(4), pp 189-239. Also available as BIS Working Papers, no 355, November http://www.bis.org/publ/work355.htm ______ (2012), “Characterising the financial cycle: don’t lose sight of the medium term!”, BIS Working Papers, no 380, November http://www.bis.org/publ/work380.htm Koo, R (2003), Balance sheet recession, Singapore: John Wiley & sons. Reinhart, C and K Rogoff (2009), This time is different: Eight centuries of financial folly, Princeton University Press: Princeton. 50 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL The financial and business cycles in the United States Graph 1 Note: Brown and green bars indicate peaks and troughs of the combined cycle using the turning-point method. The frequency-based cycle (blue line) is the average of the medium-term cycle in credit, the credit to GDP ratio and house prices (frequency based filters). The short term GDP cycle (red line) is the cycle identified by the traditional shortterm frequency filter used to measure the business cycle. NOTE: The amplitudes of the blue and red lines are not directly comparable. Source: Drehmann et al. (2012). Leading indicators of banking crises: credit and property price gaps for the United States Credit-to-GDP gap Real property price gap1 Percentage points Graph 2 Percent THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 51 The shaded areas refer to the threshold values for the indicators: 2–6 percentage points for credit-to-GDP gap; 15–25% for real property price gap. The estimates for 2008 are based on partial data (up to the third quarter). 1 Weighted average of residential and commercial property prices with weights corresponding to estimates of their share in overall property wealth. The legend refers to the residential property price component. Source: Borio and Drehmann (2009). US output gaps: full-sample (ex post) and realtime (ex ante) estimates. In percentage points of potential output IMF OECD HP Graph 3 Finance neutral Linear estimates; the non-linear ones for the finance-neutral, which should better capture the forces at work, show an output gap that is considerably larger in the boom and smaller in the bust. Source: Borio et al. (2013). 52 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 53 SMALL COUNTRY, BIG BANKING SYSTEM: WHAT MACROPRUDENTIAL IMPLICATIONS FOR THE CENTRAL BANK? PATRICK HONOHAN Knowing that Claudio would give a terrific overview of the whole area of macroprudential policy, I had to decide what specific area to home in on in the limited time I have here today, in particular reflecting on the fact that this is Stan’s day. I recall that my own first encounter with Stan was when he was Chief Economist at the World Bank, at the start of that huge contribution he has made in international public service at the World Bank and later at the IMF. Much of what he did then falls into the category of “international economics”, but even more would be better categorized as “comparative economics”, i.e., analysis of the similarities and contrasts between the problems of different countries. Thus, I decided to present a bit of comparative economics today, looking at a few countries, whose recent experience is particularly relevant to the topic of today’s conference. A few of the countries are close to you here in the Eastern Mediterranean – thus, hot and dry (Cyprus, Lebanon and Malta); a few of them are damp and cool and close to where I come from in North-Western Europe (Iceland and Ireland). But the unifying factor is that they are all small countries with big banking systems. The problems of small countries with large banking systems have been quite significant factors in the current financial crisis, and I would like to talk about the macroprudential issues from the central bank perspective in these situations. One of the things we were studying in the World Bank back in the 1980s and later was the role of financial systems, and in particular the way in which the size and development of financial systems could contribute to economic growth. I suppose it’s still the conclusion of the academic literature today that having a small and undeveloped financial system will constrain a country’s economic growth. But what is increasingly clear is that, beyond a certain size, a large financial system becomes a risk factor. Nevertheless, industrial policy in governments in several countries encourages international banking and international finance as an export sector. (That has happened in all five of these countries to some extent.) What should the macroprudential policy of central banks do about that? The first thing to note is that this is not a question of doubting the absolute importance of internationalization per se as a powerful positive force for efficiency. What is questioned is the net effect of having a financial system that is very large relative to the size of the economy. 54 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL It’s worth looking at this problem from three different perspectives: lending, funding and the exchange rate. Thus, the first aspect relates to the contribution of the international sector to lending and the well-known domestic bubble problem. The second aspect relates to funding, and in particular to what I call the “domestic financial shield”, sought by foreign providers of funds. This is less studied. Sometimes the shield proves to be effective, sometimes not. The third aspect, which I will not have time to develop, relates to the way that exchange rate policy can become locked-in or constrained if the country has opted to have a large financial system. My main take away will be that it’s safer if domestic and international banking in small economies are not too closely intertwined. Thus, if the government insists on policies that result in a large banking system, then macroprudential policy should try and keep the domestic and international components somewhat separate. It was Mervyn King who said he found that banks were international in life and national in death. That has been found to be true in many cases, but it’s not necessarily true, and in the tradition of offshore centers it really wasn’t true. In practice, governments have not been inclined to bail-out an international bank in an international financial center that does little lending onshore and doesn’t fund locally. Such banks come and go and they are part of something that is quite offshore. But in several of the countries that we are looking at, international banks got involved in the local economy and created macroprudential risk. The lending challenge is the most obvious one. Claudio has talked about this— the funds that are drawn within from abroad pump up the property market. I guess Chile was the first classic example that we also talked about in the early 1980s; there was an example of this kind of boom and bust financed by funds coming in through the banking system. And then we can talk as Claudio did about the macroprudential policies to restrain such activity, and the fashion nowadays to talk about exchange controls against inward flows, that seems to be a big fashion going against the trend of earlier years. The second dimension is funding. Nowadays banking systems are often not readily partitioned on the funding side—between banks that are sourcing their funds in the local economy and banks funded elsewhere. The local banks start to fund internationally in this kind of environment, and the international banks start to fund also locally. Now why would international banks want to do that? One reason is to benefit from what I call the domestic financial shield. The fact that the international bank has domestic funds providers creates a kind of protective shield, inasmuch as they may benefit from the reluctance of the local government to tolerate losses being imposed on domestic depositors, in the event that the bank fails. National fiscal authorities often decide that domestic depositors should be bailed out especially because transaction balances, and the payment system, are involved. In the event of failure then, it is as if the local depositors are taken THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 55 hostage, because it is often not easy in law to discriminate against the foreign funders. Either all or none must be paid. By interlinking their funding sources, local and foreign, the banks are— wittingly or not—tying themselves in eliciting a future potential bail out from the national authorities. This can present a big risk to the fiscal authority and is something that has caused major problems in this crisis. I don’t have time to say much about the third element, exchange rate policy. In many countries with large international banking systems, local borrowers from the banks are tempted to denominate their borrowing in foreign currency because of lower foreign exchange interest rates. Knowing this exchange risk overhang in turn induces the central bank to be very cautious about exchange rate adjustments. After all, a devaluation will then not just improve price and wage competitiveness; it will impose large capital losses on some of the domestic borrowers. Now let me turn to each of the five country cases. Chart 1 shows the size of the total banking system as a percentage of GDP in 2008 and today. Cyprus around 800 percent, Iceland is the winner, with almost 1,000 percent, though now down considerably lower. The other countries also appear very high—Lebanon not quite as high, but included as an interesting and long-standing international banking center which is in our immediate geographical locality today—as indeed is the very topical case of Cyprus. Chart 1 What can we take away from Iceland? Chart 2 shows bank deposits (measured in Icelandic Krona) from 2003 right up to the present day. The chart distinguishes 56 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL between deposits of residents and the rest. The dramatic events of mid-decade are clearly visible. Somewhere in 2005, 2006 the two lines become disengaged as the Icelandic banks start to fund extensively from abroad. When the crash comes, look what happened—the foreign creditors are wiped out but the domestic creditors are not. Iceland managed to create a situation where the system was sufficiently separable. Domestic funders were carved out and protected. The “domestic financial shield” for foreign funders turned out to be weak. Accordingly, the macroprudential risks were somewhat constrained. If Iceland had not had and seized that possibility, the economy would have been in an even worse situation. Chart 2 Turning to the case of Ireland, there’s a lot I could say, but I just want to highlight one point, which is that the domestic financial shield did apply, albeit to only part of the system, but this was sufficient to cripple the public finances. The total banking system got to about 9 times GDP, but I would invite you to dig a little deeper, because within this total are several distinct segments as seen in Chart 3, which shows separately (i) Irish-controlled banks dealing mainly with the domestic economy; (ii) Other domestic banks (they are foreign-owned but almost all of very long standing, and mainly concerned with the domestic economy) (iii) and (iv) the international financial services center – distinguishing between those firms, mostly household names, that have been doing fine, and others that got into trouble in the crisis. The important point here is that (iii) and (iv) represent segments that are not implicitly guaranteed by the Irish Government as we have seen from the fact that THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 57 the banks in (iv) were bailed-out, but by external governments. So in Ireland the domestic financial shield did protect the creditors of the banks in segment (i) accounting for only 44 percent of the system. The Irish government did guaranty all of those and bailed them all out so the domestic financial shield did work for the foreign creditors. The government didn’t want to cause devastation to the domestic holders of claims on Irish banks, so they bailed everybody out. And, by the way, in segment (ii) the British government bailed out the creditors of the British owned banks. Thus the domestic financial shield did work for creditors of banks in Ireland, but only for part of the system. Chart 3 Chart 4 does not do full justice to the complexity of the situation in our third country, Cyprus. It distinguishes between depositors from Cyprus itself; depositors from other parts of the euro area; and depositors from the rest of the world. The declines in the past few weeks and months as the Cyprus crisis evolved are evident. In Cyprus they had an entangled system (as far as domestic and foreign funding is concerned). The two big banks had a lot of foreign funding and a lot of foreign lending. They were very much entangled; macroprudential risks were large in that case. The financial shield did not protect the foreign depositors of those banks because the problem was too big for the fiscal authority to solve. There was a very costly disruption to the domestic economy when the failure occurred, because the domestic shield wasn’t there so the domestic depositors lost as well. This may the clearest example teaching the lesson: “try to disentangle”. 58 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Chart 4 What I’m about to say about the Lebanese banking system could have been said in 1988 or 2012. Chart 5 is in trillions of Lebanese pounds. Lebanon has had a fixed exchange rate against the dollar throughout this long period. Indeed, they have skillfully maintained an equilibrium and contained several interesting complicating features. There is an exchange rate peg throughout; there is large government borrowing from the banking system throughout; there is a domestic financial shield which has enabled the banking system to attract those large external deposits because it’s credible and it has held. So this is really an interesting case. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 59 Chart 5 Finally, two charts on Malta. If I understand in properly, it seems that Malta has achieved the desired separation. Depositors from Malta represent only a quarter of the system as shown in Chart 6. Malta’s “core domestic banks”—they are the ones in the top left hand side of Chart 7—are almost 100 percent domestically funded, and they deal almost 100 percent with the local economy. In contrast, you have the international banks (on the bottom right hand side of the chart), which have very little domestic funding and almost zero systemic relevance in the sense that they don’t do substantial lending in the local economy. The policy conclusion: international banking can be a valuable export sector for a small economy, but beware of it becoming entangled in the local financial system. 60 Chart 6 Chart 7 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 61 BEING PRUDENT ABOUT MACROPRUDENTIAL RODRIGO VERGARA Good morning. I would like to thank the Bank of Israel and the organizers for inviting me to participate in this farewell conference in honor of Governor Stanley Fischer. I have been asked to talk about macroprudential policy. I would like to take this opportunity to share with you some of the questions I have on this topic, my views on some of them, and the way in which we, at the Central Bank of Chile, have gone ahead in balancing the need for more answers with the need for policy action on this front. 1. THE RISE OF MACROPRUDENTIAL Since the financial crisis of 2008, the term “macroprudential” has become the new darling of academic and policy circles. After surviving at the fringes of policy discussion and being outside mainstream academia for decades, hundreds of research papers, policy notes and press reports have been written around this concept since 2008.22 The rise of macroprudential is closely related to the criticisms to the prevailing framework of macro stabilization before the crisis. They have crystallized in an emerging consensus that achieving financial stability requires having it as an explicit goal and adding macroprudential policies to the traditional monetary policy and regulatory framework. This view also reflects the shift in the lean versus clean debate produced by the financial crisis, whose depth and persistence convinced many that the cleaning approach is unable to fully dampen the consequences of a crisis. 23 2. WHAT ACTUALLY IS MACROPRUDENTIAL? Regrettably, while becoming increasingly accepted, this “new consensus” has not fully crystallized in a broadly shared view about what constitutes macroprudential policy. There is currently more consensus on the broad goals of macroprudential policy than on its tools and institutional arrangements.24 This is not surprising 22 See Hanson, et al. (2011), Hahm, et al. (2012), and Galati and Moessner (2011) among others. See also Clement (2010) for historical review of the term “macroprudential”. 23 See Hahm et al. (2012) for a summary of the lean-versus-clean debate and the changes in the monetary policy paradigm after the crisis. 24 For a recent discussion on the meaning, scope, and implementation of macroprudential policies see Bank of England (2009), Borio (2011), Galati and Moessner (2011), and Group of Thirty (2010). 62 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL considering the fluid discussion around a relatively new approach to economic policy, but it could lead to a situation where an extremely broad range of policy actions is justified on “macroprudential” grounds. This concern is not academic. The real risk is that it becomes confusing for the public and costly for policymakers.25 At a broad level, there is consensus that the goal of macroprudential policy is to ensure financial stability. But there is less agreement on whether the pursuance of financial stability should focus on avoiding crises or on smoothing the financial cycle.26 These two views have many similarities but also subtle differences. A financial system without crises would be more stable than one with, and a less volatile financial system should experience no crises. But in contrast to crisis avoidance, smoothing the financial cycle explicitly includes the dampening of booms regardless of whether this reduces the probability of crises. For instance, one may worry about financial booms if they lead to resource misallocation – even if no crisis is looming at the end of this misallocation. Of course, from a practical perspective the distinction becomes blurred if booms are typically followed by crises. Another small difference between these two views is that, while neither provides an immediate operational target for gauging success, the financial cycle view comes a bit closer. The success of crisis avoidance is based on a discrete counterfactual—the occurrence of a crisis, which cannot constitute an immediate or operational target. In turn, smoothing the financial cycle could more easily be cast as an operational target as long as there is agreement on how to measure the state of such cycle. Regrettably, this is not easy task. Since avoiding crises is too discrete a goal to be a useful measure of success, it typically translates into an operational goal focused on limiting risk taking by financial institutions. This requires the definition of risk-taking indicators, and immediately begs the question of what risks should be monitored and what indicators should be used. There are many forms of risk taking and various types of financial sector agents, each with several potentially related indicators. The combination of all of these aspects usually ends up in multidimensional targets. Smoothing the financial cycle, in turn, requires a measurement of the state of such cycle. Some recently proposed measures include the growth rate of credit or some interest rate spreads. However, these indicators typically focus on bank behavior. Since other forms of credit extension are harder to monitor, they have not been considered in the existing analyses of leading indicators of financial stress. Additionally, the available evidence on this front comes from a period where the candidates for leading indicators were not being actively monitored by regulators. 25 See Born et al. (2012) on the challenges involved in communicating macroprudential policies for Central Banks. 26 The Bank for International Settlements (2011) lists five operational definitions of financial stability, but they can be grouped along these two dimensions. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 63 Tracking these indicators with regulatory purposes may simply result in risk shifting behavior that renders the indicators useless. The issues I just highlighted have resulted in an abundance of macroprudential policy tools. Most regulatory tools currently used for banking supervision can be given a macroprudential twist by relating them to an aggregate indicator of risk or of state of the cycle. Other tools that have not been heavily used in the past, such as minimum levels of core funding, have also been proposed as macroprudential. Even tools typically used for liquidity management, such as the reserve requirement rate, have been considered as macroprudential because they can tame domestic credit growth. The toolkit has also been extended to include capital controls and exchange rate interventions. The case for using these tools with macroprudential purposes is that they may help deal with episodes of excessive growth of external borrowing and misalignment of some key relative prices. Finally, some also propose using the policy interest rate with macroprudential purposes. This leads me to the discussion about the institution or institutional setting that should be in charge of implementing macroprudential policies, and how should these policies coordinate with other aspects of economic policymaking, such as monetary and fiscal policy. There is broad debate around these issues. The role of a country’s central bank in the implementation of macroprudential policy has been widely discussed. While there is consensus that central banks should care about financial stability, there is less agreement on whether they should be exclusively in charge of macroprudential policy. The main tradeoff is that while they have a systemic view of the financial system and its interactions with the real economy, the interactions between macroprudential and monetary policy tools and goals may send confusing signals to the public. At the end of the day, the existing institutional frameworks have evolved in a pragmatic manner partly determined by the institutional designs existing before crisis, and therefore varying from one country to the next. 3. BEING PRUDENT ABOUT MACROPRUDENTIAL The difficulties in identifying what actually constitute macroprudential policy means that there is still an important degree of discretion in their setting and pursuance. Many targets and policy combinations may fall under the macroprudential umbrella. There is, therefore, the risk that, for the time being, this situation may become a license to kill for policymakers, justifying the discretionary implementation of a large number of policy measures with little transparency or 64 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL accountability. This is especially dangerous for independent central banks, whose reputation and credibility rely heavily on both.27 In addition to these risks, we cannot forget that macroprudential measures have costs. The crisis has taught us that mopping after a bust is difficult and costly, but we still know little about the costs of preventing the bubble from building. The debate seems to assume that such costs are small. But if these policies constitute insurance against a ”once in a century credit tsunami”, it is crucial to know if the insurance is actuarially fairly priced. 28 These considerations are behind our current approach to macroprudential policies, which I would like to define as being prudent about macroprudential. This prudence does not mean that we believe the macroprudential approach to financial regulation is not useful. On the contrary, we think that close monitoring and understanding of systemic risk is crucial, and that if the need arises we have to act decisively in order to face those risks. We also think that it is crucial to advance in reaching a consensus on best practices in the implementation of macroprudential policies that incorporate the need for transparency and accountability, as well as advance in establishing the costs of different macroprudential policy combinations. We are indeed working on several of these fronts. But while we are busy at work on them, we need to set a high bar for engaging in policies whose impact we still do not fully understand and whose overly enthusiastic pursuance may send confusing signals to the public and markets. 4. MACROPRUDENTIAL POLICIES IN CHILE As I just mentioned, being prudent about macroprudential does not mean that we do not engage in policies that have an either explicit or implicit macroprudential nature. Indeed, our central bank has a mandate to preserve the integrity of the payment system, both domestic and international, and a regulatory role over some financial operations. We are also part of the Chilean Financial Stability Committee (CEF) that brings us together with the other financial regulators: the Superintendency of Banks (SBIF), the Superintendency of Securities and Insurance (SVS), the Superintendency of Pensions (SP), and the Ministry of Finance. As I will explain next, many of the actions we have implemented following this mandate, even before the onset of the crisis, can be seen as falling under the macroprudential umbrella previously described. Since 2004 the Central Bank of Chile publishes a semi-annual financial stability report that tracks and informs the markets of the state of our financial system, and of the main risks that have developed since the previous report. Given our special 27 For a thorough discussion of the challenges involved in the implementation of financial stability goals in central banks see Bank of International Settlements (2011) 28 Former Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, Alan Greenspan coined this term to refer to the financial crisis in testimony given to the US Congress in October 23, 2008. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 65 interest in the payment system, the report focuses naturally, but not exclusively, on the banking sector. As the banks are at the core of our financial system, they interact with many other financial agents, such as pension and mutual funds. Thus, we also monitor and report the main developments and risks faced by these market players. We also track the behavior of key prices, including not only various liquidity and lending spreads, but also equity and, recently, real estate prices. As our financial system has become increasingly complex, we have placed our efforts on keeping track of this increasing complexity and bringing new market segments, agents and prices into our analysis. We complement this analysis of the supply side of financial services with a household financial survey that tracks the financial position and leverage of Chilean households. Giving information to market participants about the state of the Chilean financial system and our perception of the potential buildup of risks in some of its segments has a macroprudential role. The credibility we have been able to build over the years in the conduct of monetary policy means that market participants pay special attention to our reading of the economic conditions, especially in times of uncertainty. Through our close interaction with regulators, our warnings have teeth, even though we do not have a direct regulatory role over many financial institutions. For instance, in our financial stability report of December 2012, we raised our concern with the evolution of housing prices in Chile and clearly let market participants know that the trends that had been recently observed should not be extrapolated into the future. Following this warning we have observed some tightening of credit conditions in the mortgage market. In recent years, we have also sporadically intervened in exchange-rate markets through pre-announced interventions with a fixed amount and a daily schedule of purchases. We have done so when we have judged our real exchange rate to be significantly misaligned from its fundamental level and with the goal of accumulating reserves and dampening exchange rate volatility. Such reserves can later be used to provide foreign exchange liquidity in times of financial stress. Thus, the main goal of our interventions in foreign exchange markets may be interpreted as macroprudential in nature. In the more distant past we have also intervened using capital controls aimed to put some “sand in the wheels” of capital inflows, especially on short-term ones.29 Under some of the definitions previously discussed, this measure also has a macroprudential interpretation. It aims to reduce our exposure to volatile forms of capital inflows that may end up in a sudden stop, with costly consequences for the financial and real sectors of our economy. We have not engaged in this type of controls since 1999, but we are not closed to the option of using them if we consider that the situation requires it. However, what we learned from our previous experience is that this type of measure needs to be temporary. The incentives to 29 For a review of Chile’s experience with capital controls see Cowan and De Gregorio (2005). 66 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL outmaneuver them are large and eventually the creativity of financial engineers finds a way around them. The implementation of policies of macroprudential nature in our country is not exclusive to the central bank. In the past, the banking regulator has expressed concern about systemic issues on several occasions. For instance, in the 1990s, the Chilean banking regulator (SBIF) issued a directive instructing banks to build provisions for consumer loans based on the payment behavior of the whole banking system instead of that of each single institution. In the 2000s, the same agency issued a directive instructing banks to carefully consider the foreign exchange mismatch of their borrowers in their risk assessments and provisions.30 5. CONCLUSION We are living in exciting times where a new paradigm for economic policymaking is rising. In this new paradigm, there are areas of broad consensus, such as the importance of financial stability and the need for a systemic approach to financial regulation. But these broad consensuses have yet to translate into shared views about the goals, operational targets, and preferred tools of macroprudential policy that may eventually turn into best practices. The scope spanned by all possible combinations of these elements risks turning macroprudential policy into a catchall that may be used to justify almost any kind of policy, with the consequent risks to the reputation and accountability of policymakers. Independent central banks should be especially wary of these risks. This does not mean that we should maintain business as usual and not derive any lesson from the painful experiences of the recent crisis. We should clearly strengthen our understanding of the linkage among financial system players and properly assess the importance of systemic risk. Neither should we hesitate to undertake measures to tackle the buildup of risks based on our best judgment and the knowledge derived from our improved analysis. Nonetheless, despite the current diversity of views about macroprudential policy, I have no doubt that eventually a consensus on best practices in the conduct of macroprudential policy will emerge. I also believe that we should work hard and push for discovering and reaching such consensus. But in the meantime we should be prudent. As much as waiting for certainty in undertaking policies usually leads to acting too late, acting too early and too broadly has its costs, some of which we do not fully understand yet. While the evidence is still being collected, it is very likely that among the diverse views on the concept and implementation of macroprudential policies, some are likely to be found mistaken and to carry costs that may outweigh their likely benefits. 30 See Marshall (2012). THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 67 REFERENCES Bank for International Settlements (2011), “Central Bank Governance and Financial Stability”. Available at http://www.bis.org/publ/othp14.htm Bank of England (2009), “The Role of Macroprudential Policy”. Bank of England Discussion Paper. Available at http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/other/financialstabili ty/roleofmacroprudentialpolicy091121.pdf Borio, C. (2011), “Implementing a Macroprudential Framework: Blending Boldness and Realism”. Capitalism and Society, 6 (1). Born, B., Ehrmann, M., and M. Fratzscher (2012), “Communicating About MacroPrudential Supervision- A New Challenge for Central Banks”. International Finance, 15(2), 179-203. Cowan K., and De Gregorio, J. (2007), “International Borrowing, Capital Controls, and the Exchange Rate: Lessons from Chile.” In “Capital Controls and Capital Flows in Emerging Economies: Policies, Practices and Consequences”, 241296. National Bureau of Economic Research. Galati, G. and R. Moessner. (2011), “Macroprudential Policy – A Literature Review”. Bank for International Settlements, Working Paper 337. Group of Thirty. (2010), Enhancing Financial Stability and Resilience: Macroprudential Policy, Tools, and Systems for the Future. Available online at http://www.group30.org/images/PDF/Macroprudential_Report_Final.pdf Hahm, J., Mishkin, F., Shin, H-S., and K. Shin (2012), “Macroprudential Policies in Open Emerging Economies”. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 17780. Hanson, S., Kashyap, A., and J. Stein (2011), “A Macroprudential Approach to Financial Regulation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(1): 3-28. Marshall, E. (2012), “Implementación de Políticas Macroprudenciales en Chile”. Documentos de Política Económica 44. Banco Central de Chile. 68 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 69 BARRY TOPF I sometimes wonder if conferences of this sort actually contribute anything to concrete policy making, and I can certainly state that in this case they have, because I intend to take these cards with me to the next Monetary Committee meeting—especially this one, and use them liberally (referring to a large card informing speakers that "time is up" –ed.) The late Andrew Crockett was superb in summing up sessions, even the ones that were very difficult. Once he was asked how he did it. He said it was very easy—he didn’t say what they said; he said what they should have said. Well, our speakers saved me from that task. All I have to do is review what they said so well, and put some of it together and add a few remarks of my own very briefly. Claudio Borio presented important evidence on the role of the financial cycle in macroprudential policy. Governor Honohan focused on the risks of banking systems which are large in relation to their home country, and also mentioned that beyond a certain point, financial system growth becomes a risk factor in and of itself. And Governor Vergara used the Chilean framework to explain to us some of the risks involved in macroprudential policy. As we have seen, macroprudential policy is important but also complex—but it’s this very complexity and crucial importance which make macroprudential policy so challenging. Success requires integrating areas and operations within the central bank and outside of it in order to meet common goals effectively. In short: putting it all together. I would suggest that in a sense it is one of the toughest tests policy makers would face, a sort of comprehensive exam for central bankers. To succeed, the central bank must meet multiple goals, using multiple tools, in a dynamic and risky environment. Now since the precedent has been established to say a few words personally, I’ll use that. We are talking about success in the central bank; Karnit spoke about the role of the governor, and we have an expression in Hebrew, “anyone who tries to add only subtracts”, so I will leave that where it is, but there are two other points I would like to make when we are talking about success in the central bank. One is so obvious that it’s often overlooked but I think it deserves a mention here, and that is having a staff which is up for the tasks. Be it macroprudential policy, be it monetary policy, supervision, research or anything else, we here in the Bank of Israel were extremely lucky in having a staff which was up for the challenges and was great in helping us go through the previous period so successfully. The other thing that I would recommend, as we have seen in the first session, we spoke about the limitations of monetary policy and we heard it again in this session, is that a good degree of modesty is highly recommended. Not necessarily rewarded but certainly highly recommended in central banking as in other areas of our lives, and I think we should take this lesson away from everything we’ve heard today. One thing is certain: we will be tested. Let us hope we succeed. I would like to thank our speakers and wish everybody an enjoyable continuation of today’s conference. Thank you very much. 70 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 71 Introduction of Jacob Frenkel Stanley Fischer Jacob has had a remarkable career. I am sure that most of you know a lot about his role as Governor of the Bank of Israel, but he had significant achievements well before that. Jacob and I first met in 1969, at the University of Chicago, when I was a post-doctoral fellow freshly arrived from MIT, and he was already well advanced on his thesis. There was a remarkably good class at Chicago when I arrived, with students primarily in international economics, under the leadership of Robert Mundell and Harry Johnson. The three students who later became best-known were Jacob, Rudi Dornbusch and Michael Mussa, who was Jacob’s successor as Economic Counselor and Head of Research at the IMF. Jacob and I wrote a few papers together during that period. Jacob earned his PhD from Chicago, and then returned to Tel Aviv University to join the faculty there. Nineteen seventy-three was a point of some difficulty between Jacob and me: he was invited back to the University of Chicago as a member of the faculty, and precisely after he was invited back, I received an offer from MIT and I left Chicago. There was no causal connection between his arriving and my leaving, but he keeps asserting that he was what forced me to go to MIT. I deny that, but confess that later there were two similar coincidences in other institutions, so my record in his book is not as good as it should be. Jacob was on the faculty at the University of Chicago for 14 years. He ended up as the David Rockefeller Professor of International Economics, a very prestigious chair, and as one of the editors of the Journal of Political Economy, a very prestigious journal of the University of Chicago, and the editorship is a great honor for anyone to have held. In 1987 he was invited to join the IMF to serve as Economic Counselor—which means chief economist but it sounds much better—and Head of Research at the IMF, and we overlapped there during the time I was chief economist at the World Bank. Jacob, I apologize, but I can’t avoid telling this story. We used to fly together to Paris for meetings of the OECD. It’s about a six hour flight, and we would start talking. On one flight, somewhere around three hours into the six hour flight, Jacob says, “We’ve got a great new sleeping tablet at the IMF. You should take one of them, and you’ll be able to go to sleep and wake up not feeling tired at all.” I said, “Jacob, you take the sleeping tablet, and I’ll be able to go to sleep.” Jacob served at the IMF with distinction, and then after nearly five years there he was invited back to Israel as Governor of the Bank of Israel, following Michael Bruno who had had such a critical role first in the 72 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL stabilization program and then later, as Governor of the Bank of Israel. Michael was the person who was most responsible for stabilizing the stabilization. Jacob inherited the economy as it was then, and served as Governor for eight and a half years, from 1991 to 2000. Many important things happened in the economy during that period. Larry Summers has a word which he uses frequently, which is “consequential”. Jacob was a consequential Governor, which is to say that there were major consequences of his being Governor. By the end of his governorship, the inflation rate, which had been somewhere just below 20 percent when he took office, had declined to the low single digit range. The crawling-band exchange rate that had been in place when he took office had been opened in a way that is still worthy of study. As a result of the crawling band, the Bank had lost control of the money supply because the exchange rate was pushing on the lower – appreciated – limit of the band, and the Bank kept having to intervene to maintain the band. They had no way at that time of sterilizing, and in any case, did not want to intervene. They opened the band more at its top – the depreciated level – than at the bottom, the appreciated level. But from that day on they hardly ever had to intervene again during Jacob’s governorship: the Israeli exchange rate became flexible, and the Bank after one intervention in 1998 didn’t have to intervene again until 2008. Further, capital controls were significantly liberalized, the inflation targeting approach to monetary policy was set up, and the Israeli capital markets became much more like the capital markets, particularly the exchange markets, of more advanced countries. This was a much more modern economy in its institutional structure and in other respects as a result of Jacob’s service as Governor of the Bank of Israel – and I know for sure that much of what we have been able to do in the Bank of Israel in the last few years has been a result of our ability to work within a framework behind which, while many contributed to it, Jacob was the driving force. Then he left to work in a series of private sector financial institutions, first Merrill Lynch as chairman of Merrill Lynch International, then AIG, currently JP Morgan Chase, and in each one he has been a highly valued member of those private sector organizations. In addition, he has played a leading role in this mysterious group, the G30, which sounds like a compromise between the G77 and the G20, but it isn’t. It’s a private sector group, while all the other G’s are public sector groups, but it has almost the same prestige as those public sector groups. It’s a group of formers, and some currents—former Governors, former finance ministers, and so forth—which meets to discuss the situation in the global economy 2 or 3 times a year. Its meetings are among the most interesting and important I have the privilege of attending each year. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Jacob became Chairman and CEO of the G30 in 2001. Previous Chairmen and CEOs of the G30 were Gordon Richardson, the former Governor of the Bank of England, Paul Volcker, and then Jacob. Jacob filled that role for 10 years, made sure that the G30 remained a vibrant and interesting institution, and has now graduated to become Chairman of the Board of Trustees of the G30. Jean-Claude Trichet has taken the job that Jacob had as Chairman and CEO, which is a measure of the prestige Jacob has in the international economy. Throughout all these activities abroad, he has been in Israel a significant part of the time, he has never cut his ties with Israel, never lost his interest in, and willingness to help, the State of Israel in a variety of ways, and he has done that also in an exemplary way. Most recently he has accepted to become Chair of the Board of Governors of Tel Aviv University, an important position in an important university in Israel, which has had a difficult time during the difficult financial times everybody’s gone through. Jacob will have a big role which I am sure he will fulfill extremely well in helping maintain and strengthen that important Israeli institution of higher learning. Jacob, for everything you’ve done, and for a very long friendship, I thank you, and I’m very happy to present you as one of our three keynote speakers of the day. 73 74 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 75 INFLATION TARGETING, DISINFLATION AND EXCHANGE RATE POLICY: THE ISRAELI EXPERIENCE JACOB A. FRENKEL INTRODUCTION This is a very special event commemorating the New Bank of Israel. During the past eight years, under the skillful leadership of Professor Stanley Fischer, the Bank of Israel has played a central role in navigating the Israeli economy and in contributing to its outstanding performance. Now, as we get close to the end of Professor Fischer’s term as Governor of the Bank of Israel, it is very appropriate to celebrate the great achievements of the Bank and take stock of its contributions. It is difficult to exaggerate the extraordinary contribution that was made by Professor Fischer. The new Law of the Bank of Israel, the modern internal governance of the Bank, its domestic and international prestige, the intellectual leadership of the Bank, and of course, the outstanding performance of the Israeli economy, all reflect Professor Fischer’s dedicated stewardship, and for that we all owe him an immense debt. As a former Governor of the Bank of Israel and as a very close friend and colleague of Professor Fischer for forty-four years, I feel especially privileged to take part in this special conference. Over the years, the Bank of Israel has established a great tradition anchored in high professionalism and commitment. It was able to continuously modernize and rejuvenate itself so as to keep up with the frontiers of the “art of central banking”. For maintaining this great tradition and for lifting the Bank to new heights, Professor Fischer deserves great credit and deep gratitude and appreciation. The organizers of this Conference have suggested that I provide an overview of the experience of the first ten years of inflation targeting in Israel, and draw some of the general lessons. I am delighted to do so, and to share with the audience some of my own experience with the introduction and implementation of inflation targeting in Israel during the decade 1991-2000. My presentation of the Israeli experience aims at drawing some general analytical and practical principles that can be applicable to other experiences and that are relevant for the subject of inflation targeting, disinflation, and exchange rate policy. By doing so I would also like to pay tribute to the Bank of Israel and its Governor, Professor Stanley Fischer. STABILIZATION AND THE ROAD TO DISINFLATION As background, it would be worthwhile to discuss the situation prevailing in the Israeli economy almost 30 years ago. At that time, in the mid-1980s, Israel suffered from very high inflation, which reached about 450 percent per year. During that Chairman, JPMorgan Chase International, Former Governor of the Bank of Israel. 76 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL period, Brazil and Argentina also suffered from hyperinflation, and these three countries launched a very similar stabilization program that was based initially on the nominal exchange rate as a key nominal anchor. The success of the Israeli stabilization program reflected the fact that, in addition to relying on the nominal exchange-rate anchor, Israel adopted fundamental macroeconomic adjustments, which included, in particular, a drastic cut in the budget. The lack of such drastic budget correction in other stabilization programs resulted in their demise. As a result, the rate of inflation declined very rapidly from about 450 percent in 1984 to 20 percent in 1986. Following this initial success, the annual rate of inflation remained (or was “stuck”) at around 18 percent until 1991 (Figure 1). While this achievement was hailed at the time as a great success, it still left Israel with an inflation rate that exceeded significantly the rates of inflation prevailing in much of the industrialized world. As a result, given the fixity of the exchange rate, this inflation differential between Israel and the rest of the world resulted in a continuous loss of Israel’s international competitiveness. Obviously, that reality created a non-sustainable situation. It became clear that in order to arrest the continuous erosion of competitiveness and restore a more sustainable situation, Israel’s rate of inflation had to be reduced to international levels, or alternatively the exchange rate would have had to be adjusted continuously in order to reflect inflationary differentials. Thus, a policy adjustment had to take place. Figure 1: The rate of inflation (percent) 445 450 400 350 300 250 191 200 150 133 185 132 102 9 11 15 8 11 7 9 1.3 0 1.4 1999 2000 2001 18 1998 18 1997 21 1996 17 1995 16 1994 20 1993 50 1992 100 Note: Data for 2001 refers to November. Source: Bank of Israel. 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 1982 1981 1980 0 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 77 The reference made earlier to the role that was played by the dramatic cut in the budget during the stabilization program highlights the fact that a successful stabilization and disinflation program must be framed within the broad context of macroeconomic policy. A narrower framework that focuses only on the role of monetary policy without paying due regards to other policy instruments is bound to yield unsatisfactory results. Indeed, the non-sustainability that resulted from attempting to maintain a fixed exchange rate in the presence of a significant gap between domestic and foreign inflation, manifested itself in other parts of the macroeconomic system. For example, by the mid-1990s the deficit in the current account of the balance of payments (as a percent of Gross Domestic Product, GDP) rose to non-sustainable levels, reaching 5.9 percent in 1995 (Figure 2). Normally, a country suffering from the inconsistencies associated with the combination of high inflation, fixed exchange rate, and large current account deficit, in penalized by the international capital markets that make the continuation of such inconsistencies nonfeasible. During that period, however, Israel was able to maintain these inconsistencies since it kept the capital account of the balance of payments practically closed. At the time, Israel had strict foreign exchange controls, the foreign exchange market was underdeveloped and, as a result, the discipline, which is normally exerted through world capital markets, was absent. Thus, during the first half of the 1990s, Israel’s “success” in escaping the discipline exerted by the international capital markets was achieved at the cost of not having the full benefits Figure 2: Current account deficit (as a percent of GDP) 7 5.9 6 5.6 5 4.5 4 3.6 3.6 3 2.1 1.9 2 1.3 1.3 1.0 1 0 -0.3 Source: Bank of Israel. 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 -1 78 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL that could have been obtained through a deeper and a more complete integration into the ever growing world capital markets. This situation changed in the second half of the 1990s. Figure 3 shows the composition of Israel’s international transactions. As may be seen, until the middle of the decade, practically all of the international transactions took place in the current account of the balance of payments. In contrast, during the second half of the 1990s, Israel implemented a more comprehensive program of liberalization of its international capital transactions: the capital account of the balance of payments was opened up and liberalized, and foreign exchange controls were removed. As a result, along with the increased international convertibility of the Israeli currency, the composition of the international transactions changed dramatically and most of the transactions shifted to the capital account of the balance of payments. In other words, the capital account has become more and more active and, thereby, the judgment of the markets has become much more prominent and immediate. The dictum that “capital markets carry a continuous referendum on the conduct of policies” has become a reality. With this new reality, the tolerance of the markets for excessively large current account deficits and for excessively high inflation has diminished. As a result, markets have regained their usefulness in exerting a more effective disciplinary role. This development has served as a potent catalyst for directing attention to, and increasing urgency of, exerting a more vigorous disinflation effort aimed at reducing inflation to world levels. The strategy that was chosen to bring about the disinflation process has been the inflation targeting strategy. Figure 3: Foreign exchange transactions: capital versus trade flows* (percent of total) 120 $4 billion dollars $9 billion dollars 100 38 80 60 104 40 62 20 0 -4 Capital transaction Trade transaction -20 January/1989-March/1995 March/1995-March/2000 * The sum above the columns indicates average cumulative change in transactions p.a. including unilateral transfers. Source: Bank of Israel. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 79 EXCHANGE RATE POLICY The fixed exchange rate This section addresses the role played by the exchange rate in the early stages of the stabilization program. Figure 4 illustrates the role of the nominal exchange rate. Initially, for about the first 18 months, the U.S. dollar served as the nominal anchor. During that period, the U.S. dollar depreciated with respect to other major currencies while the Israeli currency was pegged to the U.S. dollar. As a result, Israel’s “trade weighted basket” has gained competitiveness in spite of the fact that Israel’s inflation rate exceeded the corresponding inflation rate of Israel’s trading partners. As illustrated in Figure 4, in 1987 Israel shifted from pegging its currency to the U.S. dollar towards pegging it to the trade–weighted basket of currencies. That situation held for a while but, before long, it became evident that the fixity of the exchange rate coupled with the significant differentials that prevailed between domestic and international rates of inflation continued to erode competitiveness. Thus, the non-sustainability of the situation re-emerged and the search for a new exchange-rate regime got underway. Figure 4: Shekel exchange rate versus basket & USD (July 1985 - May 1989, NIS per unit of basket & USD) 2.1 Band 2.0 3% Adjustment of 8% in the basket 1.9 3% 1.8 1.7 10% 1.6 1.5 1.4 Shekels vs U.S. dollar Shekels vs basket 1.3 1.2 III IV I II 1985 Source: Bank of Israel. III 1986 IV I II 1987 III IV I II 1988 III IV I II 1989 80 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL The horizontal exchange-rate band The search for the new exchange-rate system led to the adoption of a new exchange rate regime that was based on a band. Within the band, the exchange rate was allowed to fluctuate, though the boundaries of the band set a strict limit to the permissible degree of flexibility. These efforts of introducing some degree of flexibility into the determination of the exchange rate reflected the belief that the very introduction of potential exchange-rate flexibility would mitigate the intrinsic inconsistency associated with the maintenance of a fixed exchange rate under circumstances in which the domestic rate of inflation exceeds the foreign rate. However, the new exchange-rate band has not solved the problem and the challenge of non-sustainability prevailed. For, as long as the domestic rate of inflation exceeds the corresponding foreign rate, the mere existence of an exchange-rate band does not remove the basic difficulty. Within the band, the exchange rate is subject to continuous market pressures for depreciation and, as a result, it tends to move towards the top of the permissible band. In order to prevent depreciation to levels beyond the permissible band, the authorities need to intervene in the market for foreign exchange, and non-sustainability of the fixed exchange-rate system reemerges. This phenomenon is illustrated in Figures 5 and 6, which describe the actual experience. The figures reveal how, due to market pressures, the exchange rate band had to be shifted upwards repeatedly reflecting the ongoing mounting pressure for a depreciation of the currency. The pressure for depreciation was the natural and the inevitable consequence of the continuous gap between domestic and foreign inflation. As long as the magnitudes of the two boundaries (and especially of the upper boundary) of the exchange-rate band remain fixed, and as long as domestic inflation exceeds the foreign one, the mere existence of the band does not alleviate the basic difficulty characterizing the fixed exchange-rate regime. The policy of allowing an occasional upward displacement of the exchange-rate band, which was aimed at restoring sustainability, did not achieve its objective. In fact, the repeated upward displacement of the exchange-rate band induced speculation and uncertainty as to the timing and magnitude of the next adjustment of the band. Everyone realized that as long as there was a gap between domestic and foreign inflation, the exchange-rate band could not last for too long, and the nominal exchange rate was expected to depreciate continuously and move towards the upper boundary of the band. Towards the end of 1991 the nonsustainability became more and more evident. With it started the renewed search for an alternative exchange-rate system that would be more sustainable while at the same time would accompany and support the disinflation process. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 81 Figure 5: Shekel exchange rate versus basket (January 1989 - December 1990, NIS per unit of basket) Shift in band 10% mid-point: 2.4 Band 2.3 Shift in band mid-point: 6% 2.2 Shift in band mid-point: Band -5% +3% 6% 2.1 +5% Band -3% 2.0 +3% -3% 1.9 1.8 I II III IV I II 1989 III IV 1990 Source: Bank of Israel. Figure 6: Shekel exchange rate versus basket (March 1990 - June 1992, NIS per unit of basket) 2.8 2.7 Band 2.6 Shift in band mid-point: 10% 2.5 2.4 Band Shift in band mid-point: 5% +5% -5% +5% -5% 2.3 +5% 2.2 -5% 2.1 2.0 1.9 1.8 II III 1990 Source: Bank of Israel. IV I II III 1991 IV I II 1992 82 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL The sloped exchange-rate band At the end of 1991, Israel adapted a new exchange-rate regime: the sloped exchange-rate band, also referred to as the “diagonal exchange-rate regime”. Accordingly, the exchange rate band, which up to that point in time was horizontal, became upward slopping. The idea behind the design of the sloped exchange-rate band was to allow for a continuous rise in the boundaries within which the actual exchange rate can vary. The slope of the band embodied the newly adopted inflation targets. The slope was designed to reflect the expected inflation differential between Israel and the rest of the world that is implied by the inflation target. For example, during 1991 the rate of inflation was 18 percent; the targeted inflation for 1992 was 14 percent while foreign inflation was projected to be 5 percent. With these data the slope of the exchange-rate band was set to equal 9 percent. The logic of this determination was that an exchange-rate band that exhibits an upwards slope of 9 percent, reflects the gap between the target rate of domestic inflation (14 percent) and the projected foreign rate of inflation (5 percent). This construction removed the non-sustainability that was associated with the horizontal exchange-rate band as the latter ignored the projected gap between domestic and foreign inflation. Thus, a slope of 9 percent corresponds to the difference between projected domestic inflation (14 percent) and the projected foreign rate (5 percent). The idea in the design of the sloped exchange-rate band was that after each period of time (say one year), a new and a more ambitious inflation target would be set and, with it, the projected gap between domestic and foreign inflation would diminish. Associated with such a narrowing of the projected inflation gap would be a less slopped exchange-rate band. The important point to note is that in the Israeli context the slope of the exchange rate band was set with a forward-looking perspective. This unique perspective contrasts with the design of the Chilean exchange rate band whose slope was set with a backward looking perspective (so as to compensate for a past differential between the rate of inflation in Chile and the corresponding rate abroad). The forward-looking perspective governing the slope of the exchange-rate band in Israel, contributed significantly to the formation of the inflation-targets strategy. It transformed the policy debate from focusing on the exchange rate towards focusing on reducing inflation. Thus, the subject of exchange-rate policy left the center stage and gave way to the subject of inflationtarget policy. At that stage of the evolution of the policy debate the exchange-rate band still played a prominent role, but the slope of the band was set to be consistent with the inflation target. From that point onward, the focus of monetary policy shifted from being guided by exchange-rate objectives towards being guided by inflation objectives. Figures 7 and 8 describe the evolution of the sloped exchange-rate band throughout the decade of the 1990s. As may be seen, over time, the slope of the band got flatter and flatter, reflecting the progress that was made in the disinflation process. Throughout that period the actual exchange rate moved within the THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 83 widened band. From time to time when a new slope was announced the band itself was allowed to be adjusted upwards. Such upward displacements of the entire band typically accompanied once-and-for-all policy measures which removed distortions, or reduced protectionist measures, or advanced one more step in the direction of opening up the capital account. Figure 7: Shekel exchange rate versus the basket (Early 1992 - June 1994, NIS per unit of basket) 3.6 3.5 6% slope 3.4 +5% 3.3 -5% 3.2 8% slope 3.1 +5% Band with 9% slope 3.0 -5% 2.9 +5% 2.8 -5% 2.7 2.6 2.5 2.4 I II III IV I 1992 II III IV I 1993 II 1994 Source: Bank of Israel. Figure 8: Shekel exchange rate versus basket (July 1994 - January 2001, NIS per unit of basket) 5.4 6% slope 4.9 4.4 6% slope 3.9 2% slope +7% 4% slope 3.4 +5% -7% -5% 2.9 III IV 1994 I II III IV I II III IV I II III IV I II III IV 1995 Source: Bank of Israel. 1996 1997 1998 I II III IV 1999 I II III IV 2000 I 84 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL The natural consequence of adopting the policy which allowed for an everwidening exchange-rate band was the reduced relevance of the formal exchangerate band. As the band got wider, its relevance for the daily determination of the rate of exchange diminished while, at the same time, the degree of exchange-rate flexibility increased. In fact, from 1998 onwards, foreign exchange controls have been eliminated, foreign exchange intervention vanished, and the exchange-rate system has played practically no role in the operation of the inflation-targets strategy. The events in 1998 have stimulated this outcome. As is well known, no country can adopt an exchange-rate policy and a monetary policy that are independent of each other. This constraint on the degrees of freedom that policy makers have, becomes more and pronounced, the more open the capital account of the balance of payment is. Accordingly, by the mid-1990s, with the gradual opening of the capital account and with the gradual removal of foreign exchange control, the conflict between exchange-rate target (as imbedded in the exchange-rate band) and the inflation target has become more and more pronounced. It became clear that at some point in time the choice would need to be made between having an exchange rate objective and having an inflation target. The moment of truth occurred in the summer of 1998. At that time, emerging markets all over the world faced unprecedented challenges. Russia declared a unilateral default on its debt, the large hedge fund LTCM (Long Term Capital) went under, and world capital markets exhibited a high degree of stress. Investors attempted to unload their holdings of emerging market assets and return to their “safe haven”. As a result, the currencies of practically all emerging markets underwent a very sharp and rapid depreciation. Monetary authorities all over the world faced a critical choice: should they attempt to intervene in the foreign exchange market in order to prevent the sharp depreciation of their currency or should they allow the depreciation of the currency to take place and risk the danger of accelerated inflation. The choice was not simple. On the one hand, history is littered with examples of failed foreign exchange interventions which resulted in the monetary authorities suffering huge losses of foreign exchange reserves and with lost credibility. On the other hand, if the monetary authority decides not to intervene in the foreign-exchange market, the challenge that it faces in combating the inflationary consequences of a large depreciation of the currency is also not simple as it may require a very significant rise in rate of interest. In the wake of the emerging markets crisis of the summer of 1998, the Bank of Israel faced a very similar dilemma. In that context the Bank’s decision was clear cut. We reached the conclusion that foreign exchange intervention would be futile and ineffective. As a result we decided to allow the exchange rate to find its own equilibrium in the market place. At the same time, we decided to raise interest rates very dramatically in order to offset the inflationary consequences of the currency depreciation. It is important to emphasize that the rise in the rate of interest was not designed to prevent the depreciation of the currency; rather, it was designed to THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 85 prevent the inflationary consequences of the currency depreciation. This episode is shown in figure 9. Figure 9: Shekel exchange rate versus basket (January 1997 - January 2002, NIS per unit of basket) 5.5 44.0% Slope 6% 5.0 4.5 Slope 6% +7% 4.0 Slope 2% -7% Slope 0% Slope 4% Slope 6% 3.5 I II III IV I 1997 II III 1998 IV I II III 1999 IV I II III 2000 IV I II III 2001 IV I 2002 Source: Bank of Israel. The decision not to intervene in the foreign exchange market laid the foundation for the rapid development of that market. Up to that point in time, the Bank of Israel was expected to be one of the key players in the foreign exchange market. As a result, one of the most important roles of that market—the pricing of foreign exchange-rate risk—was distorted. The continuous presence of the Bank of Israel in the foreign-exchange market reduced the incentives of market participants to develop sophisticated financial instruments designed to deal with foreign exchange risk. As a result, the volume of transactions in the forward and futures market as well as in the market for foreign exchange options was very low. Market participants assumed, at least implicitly, that when the need arises the Central Bank would step in and mitigate sharp changes in the exchange rate; thus, the exchangerate risk, as perceived by the private sector, was deemed to be relatively low. All this was changed dramatically following the Bank of Israel’s decision on intervention in the foreign exchange market during the emerging markets crisis of 1998. Once it became clear that the Bank of Israel was not going to step in and assume the exchange-rate risk, the incentives for developing the appropriate financial instruments required to help the private sector deal with foreign exchange risk were in place. The developments of such instruments improved the efficient functioning of the market and, thereby, facilitated the functioning of the flexible exchange-rate regime. Figure 10 shows the resulting growth in trade in options and 86 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL futures as a share of total foreign exchange transactions. With the passage of time this share has increased further, and by now a very significant proportion of foreign exchange transactions is conducted in the options and futures market. Figure 10: Trade in options and futures as a share of total foreign exchange transactions 25% 20% Exponential trend 15% 10% 5% Moving average 0% Jul - 94 Jan - 95 Jul - 95 Jan - 96 Jul - 96 Jan - 97 Jul - 97 Jan - 98 Jul - 98 Jan - 99 Jul - 99 Note: Incl. TA Stock Exchange. Source: Bank of Israel. We conclude this section by recalling the evolving role that exchange rates have played in the disinflation process. Initially, the nominal exchange rate has served as the nominal anchor for stabilization. The pegged exchange rate was first set in terms of the U.S. dollar and later in terms of a basket of currencies. Subsequently, the exchange rate was allowed to vary within a horizontal band. In the next phase, with the adoption of inflation targeting, the exchange rate was allowed to vary within an upward sloping band, the slope of which reflected the inflation target. The gradual opening up of the capital account of the balance of payments necessitated an ever widening of the exchange-rate band, while the continuous progress in reducing inflation resulted in a diminished slope of the band. Finally, as the capital account was opened, foreign exchange intervention ceased, the exchange-rate band was abolished and the exchange-rate system was transformed into a flexible exchange rate régime. This process was accompanied by a systematic development of a wellfunctioning foreign exchange market which, over time, became wider and deeper. The determination of the exchange rate was left entirely to the market place, and the maturity and depth of the foreign exchange market enabled the private sector to THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 87 deal appropriately with the foreign exchange risk while efficiently employing the appropriate financial instruments. These developments enabled monetary policy to sharpen its focus on reducing inflation and, subsequently, on achieving and maintaining price stability. MONETARY POLICY AND INFLATION TARGETING This section presents some of the conceptual and technical issues associated with the conduct of monetary policy under inflation targeting during the process of disinflation. As background, it is relevant to note the special role that inflationary expectations play in the conduct of monetary policy. Inflationary expectations Prior to adopting the disinflation policy, Israel suffered for many years from high inflation. As a result, both the government and the private sector developed numerous indexation schemes, and many indexed financial instruments got developed. A large proportion of government borrowing was conducted by using indexed bonds, and a large proportion of wage contracts were also indexed. Typically, this indexation used the consumer price index (CPI) as the benchmark. With the passage of time, especially as the disinflation process progressed, two types of government bonds were traded side by side: indexed and non-indexed bonds. Market participants as well as the Bank of Israel have viewed the yield differential between indexed and non-indexed bonds as a proxy for inflationary expectations. This market measure of inflationary expectations is determined every day, and is widely accessible and widely known to market participants. The Bank of Israel has employed this market measure (and a few variations thereof) as a gauge for assessing market expectations about the future course of inflation and about the future course of policy. To gain insight into the characteristics of this inflation expectations indicator, Figure 11 describes its evolution in the later part of the 1990s; also shown is another measure of expectations constructed as an average of various forecasts. It is instructive to focus on the later part of 1998, the period around the emerging markets crisis. Recall that during that period the currency depreciated significantly (Figure 9). Associated with this sharp currency depreciation there was a record rise in inflationary expectations. As seen in Figure 11, inflationary expectations rose by more than 4 percentage points (from 4.3 percent to 8.6 percent in one measure of expectations and from 3.3 percent to 7.7 percent in another measure of expectations). This sharp rise in inflationary expectations posed a real danger to stability, as it threatened to derail and damage the credibility of the entire disinflation strategy. 88 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Figure 11: Inflation expectations indicators (percent) 10 8.6 8.4 8 7.7 6 4.3 3.7 4 3.5 3.3 2.5 2.7 2 Capital markets 1.6 1.5 Average forecasters Oct-01 Jun-01 Feb-01 Oct-00 Jun-00 Feb-00 Oct-99 Jun-99 Feb-99 Oct-98 Jun-98 Feb-98 Oct-97 Jun-97 0 Source: Bank of Israel. The sharp rise in inflationary expectations reflected the fact that the legacy of the past high inflation was still deeply rooted in the psychology of market participants. Against this background, the Bank of Israel reached the conclusion that a dramatic move was necessary in order to arrest this deterioration. Accordingly, the Bank raised its interest rate by 400 basis points—an unprecedented magnitude. We explained to the public that the purpose of the sharp rise in interest rate was to prevent the adverse inflationary consequences of the sharp depreciation of the currency. We also indicated that this rise in interest rates could be gradually reversed once inflation returns to the target range, and once the rise in inflationary expectations is reversed so as to indicate that future inflation is likely to return to its target range. The results of this policy measure were dramatic. Immediately, as seen in Figure 11, inflationary expectations reversed their course and started to decline. At the same time, as seen in Figure 9, the sharp depreciation of the currency also reversed its course and the currency started to appreciate. The crisis was averted, the creditability of the inflation targeting strategy was reestablished and the stage was set for a further decline in inflation. Monetary policy, inflation targets and the rate of inflation The extraordinarily rapid transmission mechanism of monetary policy is exhibited in Figure 12 which shows the monthly inflation rates prevailing during that episode. As may be seen, during the period of July 1997 through August of 1998, the average monthly rate of inflation was 0.3 percent, reflecting a very significant THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 89 progress of the disinflation process. The sharp depreciation of the currency during the emerging markets crisis translated itself into a very sharp rise in the monthly price index. The price index rose in one month by 1.4 percent and rose by a further 3.0 percent in the subsequent month. There was a real danger that these steep rises in the price index, which in principle should be once-and-for-all rises, would feed themselves into rising inflationary expectations, which, in turn, would be transformed into a more permanent rise in the rate of inflation. Figure 12: Change in the monthly CPI (percent) 3.5 3.0 3.0 Ave. 7/97 to 8/98: 0.3% 2.5 Ave. 12/98 to 11/01: 0.1% 2.0 1.4 1.5 1.4 1.2 1.3 1.0 0.9 1.0 0.5 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.7 0.5 0.5 0.3 0.3 0.5 0.9 0.6 0.5 0.40.4 0.3 0.1 0.3 0.1 0.0 0.0 -0.1 -0.3 -0.4 -0.5 -0.1 -0.2 -0.2 -0.2 -0.1 -0.2 -0.5 -0.5 -0.6 -0.6 -0.6 Jan-01 Oct-00 Jul-00 Apr-00 Jan-00 Oct-99 Jul-99 Apr-99 Oct-98 Jul-98 Apr-98 Jan-98 Oct-97 Jul-97 Jan-99 -0.8 -1.0 Source: Bank of Israel. The sharp policy response of raising interest rates by 400 basis points paid off very rapidly. As seen in Figure 12, the monthly price index responded immediately. During the first few months following the rise in interest rates, the monthly rates of inflation were negative and, thereafter, from December 1998 onwards, the average monthly rate of inflation converged to 0.1 percent. In retrospect, it seems that this episode was the turning point. The decisive monetary policy response broke the back of inflation and paved the way to achieving price stability. In fact, from 1999 onwards, the rate of inflation in Israel has not exceeded 3 percent per year. Accordingly, in 1999, the disinflation process reached its successful conclusion and the economy started to enjoy the benefits of price stability. From that point onwards, the objective of reducing inflation with the aid of inflation targets was replaced by the objective of maintaining stability. 90 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Figure 13 presents the summary evolution of the rate of inflation for the entire disinflation period. As may be seen, during the five years (1986–1991) following the stabilization program of 1985, the average annual rate of inflation was 18.1 percent. At that stage, the inflation targeting strategy was adopted. During the 1990s, with the inflation targeting strategy in place, the average rate of inflation declined and, by the end of the decade, price stability was achieved. Figure 13: Change in the annual CPI (percent) 20 18.1 18 16 14 12 10.8 10 7.8 8 6 4 1.4 1.3 2 0.0 0 1986-1991 1992- 1996 1997- 1998 1999 2000 2001 * Note: Data for 2001 refers to November 2001. Source: Bank of Israel. The evolution of the rate of inflation is shown in Figure 14. Also included in the figure are the ranges of the inflation targets corresponding to the various years. As seen, the path of the rate of inflation exhibits a downward trend which is generally consistent with the downward trend of the inflation targets. It is noteworthy, however, that the close association between these two trends did not always hold on a year by year basis. In some years actual inflation missed the target range, but this deviation was then corrected during the subsequent year. The lessons to be drawn from this experience are that it is better to set the inflation target as a range, rather than setting it as a precise numerical value. This reflects the reality that, generally, monetary policy cannot determine with absolute certainty the exact numerical value of future inflation, and it makes little sense to pretend otherwise by setting targets that are likely to be missed. Furthermore, it is preferable to set the inflation target within a multi-year framework, rather than setting it separately for each year. The multi-year setting enables policy makers to correct deviations over time and thereby smooth the relevant adjustments. In contrast, having a single year target may require correcting deviations within a very THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 91 short period of time and thereby may necessitate too sharp and too costly adjustments. In addition, the multi-year setting reflects the lags that are known to exist between the timing of policy actions and the timing of their results. Multiyear frameworks also provide incentives to market participants to view and consider monetary policy within a medium-term perspective, which is the more appropriate time frame. Figure 14: Inflation rate* and the inflation target (percent) 25 20 Inflation rate Upper target Lower target 14.5 15 11.0 10.0 10 10.0 10.0 8.0 7.0 5 4.0 4.0 3.5 3.0 3.0 3.0 2.5 0 1991 2.0 1.0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 * Previous 12 months. Source: Bank of Israel. Monetary policy and inflationary expectations Earlier, we highlighted the role that inflationary expectations play in the conduct of monetary policy. This link between monetary policy and expectations is a two-way link. On the one hand, changes in expectations influence the conduct of policies and, on the other hand, changes in policies influence expectations. Figure 15 demonstrates the interaction between expectations and monetary policy. As may be seen, until 1998 inflationary expectations followed a downward trend, reaching the level of 4.2 percent in mid-1998. At the same time, the path of the nominal rate of interest also followed a downward trend. In comparing these two paths, it is important to emphasize that the path of the rate of interest lagged behind the path of expectations rather than led it. The sharp jump in inflationary expectations that occurred in the later part of 1998 (from 4.2 percent to 8.6 percent) induced the Bank of Israel to respond by a sharp rise in the nominal rate of interest from (9.5 percent to 13 percent). As is seen in Figure 15, this sharp policy response brought about a reversal in the path of inflationary expectations which have now resumed their downward trend. That reduction in inflationary expectations enabled the Bank of Israel to lower gradually the nominal rate of interest. 92 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Figure 15: The Bank of Israel monthly interest rate and inflation expectations (percent) 18 17.0 Bank of Israel interest rate Inflation expectatitions 16 13.5 13.4 14 12.6 11.5 12 9.9 10 9.3 9.5 8.7 7.7 8 6.3 6.0 6 3.8 4.2 4 3.5 2.9 2 1.6 0.8 0 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Source: Bank of Israel. In considering the reduction in the nominal rate of interest, it is important to emphasize that the pace and magnitude of this reduction were slower and smaller than the pace and magnitude of the reduction in inflationary expectations. As a result, the level of real interest rates remained relatively high. The Bank of Israel allowed for a gradual reduction in the real rate of interest only after a significant period of time, when it became clear that the fight against inflation succeeds and that the levels of inflationary expectations reflect the belief that the reduction in inflation is likely to stay. The interaction between the rate of interest and inflationary expectations is illustrated in Figure 16. It shows that following the emerging markets crisis of 1998, the real rates of interest were kept at levels which were relatively stable and relatively high. At the same time, throughout that period, the Bank of Israel lowered the levels of the nominal rates of interest in view of the progress achieved in the disinflation process. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 93 Figure 16: Bank of Israel interest rate - in nominal and expected real terms (percent) 18 17.0 Bank of Israel nominal interest rate 16 Expected real interest rate * 14.0 13.4 14 13.5 11.5 12 9.3 10 9.5 8.5 8 7.0 6.3 6.0 6 6.0 3.8 4 2 3.2 2.5 2.9 2.2 1.3 0 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 * Expected real interest rate = effective Bank of Israel interest rate adjusted for inflation expectations. Source: Bank of Israel. One of the benefits obtained by the successful disinflation process has been the enhanced credibility of monetary policy. Market participants have taken the inflation targets seriously because they knew that the monetary authority takes these targets seriously. As a result, the announced inflation targets which gained credibility started to be incorporated by the business sector into their pricing strategies and wage contracts. The enhanced credibility of the inflation targets impacted on the relationship between changes in the nominal exchange rate and the associated changes in domestic prices, and resulted in a significant departure from the past. In the past, during the high inflation period, every nominal depreciation of the currency was immediately transformed into a corresponding rise in the price level and, as a result, nominal depreciations have not been translated into real depreciations. Consequently, the exchange rate could not be relied upon to influence international competitiveness. With the reduction of the rate of inflation and with the enhanced credibility of the inflation target, a nominal depreciation of the currency was no longer expected to result automatically in higher prices and cost. For market participants knew that if they attempted to mark up prices according to changes of the exchange rate, the monetary authority would respond by altering interest rates so as to insure that inflation stays within the inflation target range. As a result, the path of the nominal exchange rate and the path of inflation got disconnected. In other words, the pass-through from exchange rate 94 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL changes to domestic inflation has been broken. This phenomenon is illustrated in Figure 17 which shows the disconnect between the path of the exchange rate changes and the path of the differential between domestic and foreign inflation. Thus, during that period the nominal depreciation of the currency transformed itself into a real depreciation and was not eroded by an accelerated inflation. Figure 17: NIS depreciation & CPI differential with US (cumulative since January 1997) 135 129.7 129.2 130 130.1 127.8 125 122.0 120 Depreciation Inflation differential 115 112.1 110 108.5 107.1 109.7 108.0 105.7 105 100 1997 105.4 1998 1999 2000 2001 Source: Bank of Israel. The success of the inflation targeting strategy in reducing inflation and in bringing about price stability has also paid off in terms of the rating of the Israeli economy by the international rating agencies. The improved rating that was associated with the successful disinflation process improved the positioning of Israel in the international capital markets. Figure 18 shows the continuous improvement in the rating of the Israeli economy that occurred during the relevant period. In general, the level of international rating has been inversely related to the rate of inflation. Namely, a lower rate of inflation was typically associated with an improved rating. This phenomenon is shown in Figure 19. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 95 Figure 18: Israel’s international credit ratings Source: Bank of Israel. Figure 19: International credit rating and inflation (1986 to 1999) 1.6 Israel's rating / sample average 1.5 1.4 1999 1997 1.3 1998 1996 1994 1995 1.2 1993 1.1 1992 1 1991 1990 1989 1988 0.9 1987 0.8 1986 0.7 1 6 11 Inflation Increase = improvement relative to sample (about 100 countries). Source: Institutional Investor, semi-annual survey. 16 21 96 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL The output cost of disinflation The Israeli disinflation process under the inflation targeting regime spanned the entire decade of the 1990’s. Questions concerning the feasibility and desirability of a vigorous application of the disinflation effort were the subject of heated debate. This debate involved politicians, business leaders, academics, journalists and ordinary citizens. One of the important questions was whether the effort to reduce inflation would exert a significant cost on the Israeli economy and, in particular, whether it would entail a significant recession that is associated with a rise in unemployment. In retrospect, it seems that the cost in terms of economic growth has been limited and confined to a relatively brief period. Figure 20 describes the rate of growth of GDP during the decade. As can be seen, the slowdown was mostly pronounced during the years 1998-1999 but it was short-lived. Once price stability was achieved by the end of the decade, economic growth resumed and reached 6 percent during the year 2000. Figure 20: Growth rate of GDP (percent) 8 7.1 7 6.4 6.5 6 2.6 2.7 5 4 4.3 5.0 6.0 3.7 2.5 3 2.4 2.7 2 1 2.4 3.3 4.5 3.8 2.5 2.1 2.3 2.5 1.0 2.4 2.4 0.0 -0.1 2.6 0.8 0 GDP per capita Population -1 1990-1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Source: Bank of Israel. In retrospect, it seems that the output cost of the disinflation policy was smaller than feared. In fact, even the slowdown of the years 1998-99 should not be attributed only to the anti-inflation policy since this was also the period of the emerging markets crisis and its aftermath. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 97 CHECKLIST OF PRACTICAL ISSUES This section discusses some practical and technical issues that need to be addressed in the context of a disinflation process that employs the inflation targets strategy. Characteristics of the exchange rate band As should be obvious from the analysis from previous sections, the exchange rate system that facilitates the most effective application of the inflation target is the flexible exchange rate regime. However, in some cases (like the Israeli case), the economic system is not ripe for the adoption of flexible exchange rate during the early phases of the disinflation process. Frequently, disinflation starts when the foreign exchange market is still undeveloped and the capital account of the balance of payments is relatively closed. During this transitional phase, the authorities may wish to adopt an exchange rate system that corresponds to the sloped exchange rate band. The practical issues that need to be specifically addressed are: 1. What should the widths of the exchange rate band be? The key principle in answering this question is that the width of the band should increase over time, in parallel with the degree of development of the foreign exchange market. 2. What should the slope of the band be? The main determinant of the slope should be the gap between the level of the inflation target and the corresponding level of projected inflation abroad. Foreign inflation can be measured in terms of the level prevailing in the economy’s trading partners. Over time, with the progress that is being made in reducing inflation, the inflation targets should be more ambitious, and the slope of the band should correspondingly diminish. 3. Who sets the band? It would highly desirable that the band be set by government in close consultation with the central bank. The participation of the central bank is justified on the grounds that it will need to implement the monetary policy in accordance with the exchange rate policy implied by the band. 4. What should the frequency of changes in the band be? It is highly desirable that the band is set at the same time along with the setting of other key macroeconomic targets, like the budget. 98 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL The relevance of these issues diminishes over time as the degree of exchange rate flexibility increases. By the end of the process the system converges towards a flexible exchange rate regime, and the exchange rate band is abolished. Operational issues for inflation targets In implementing the inflation target strategy several operational questions must be addressed. 1. What price index should be targeted? The choice of the relevant price index is critical. For example, should the target be the wholesale price index, the consumer price index or any other index? Likewise, should the target be stated in terms of headline inflation or core inflation? The answers to these questions depend on the specific circumstances, such as the historical relationship between the indices and the role that each index plays in the economic and financial systems. In the Israeli context, the inflation target was set in terms of the consumer price index; furthermore, it was decided to focus on the measure of headline inflation. One of the main reasons for these policy choices has been the fact that many financial instruments and contracts in the economy, including government indexed bonds and wage contracts, employ the consumer price index as their benchmark. 2. Should the inflation target be set as a numerical point or as a range? It seems that a range would be preferable since it is very unlikely that the monetary authorities can aim with absolute precision to achieve a specific numerical target at a specific period of time. In fact, if such a numerical target was set, the likelihood that the target would be missed would be very high. Missing the target would hurt the creditability of the monetary authority and is likely to damage the inflation target strategy. It would, therefore, be preferable to set the target in terms of a range. The monetary authority would be expected to aim to achieve an inflation rate in the middle of the range but would tolerate the deviations within the range. 3. Should the target be a single year or a multi-year target? There are great advantages in adopting a multi-year inflation target. A multi-year framework would enable the authorities to correct deviations over time so that the adjustment would be smooth. In the absence of a multi-year framework, all deviations would have to be corrected within the year, thereby necessitating sharp and costly adjustments. Furthermore, since monetary policy impacts on the economic system with lags, a multi-year approach recognizes the presence of such lags. In addition, a multi-year focus is consistent with the general principle that monetary policy should be conducted within a medium-term framework. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 99 4. Who should set the target? It would be advantageous for the inflation targets be set jointly by the government and the central bank. The objective of achieving price stability and the responsibility for implementing the disinflation strategy should not be viewed as an esoteric objective of the central bank. Rather, this objective should be “owned” jointly by the government and the central bank. Thus, a joint determination of the inflation targets would be appropriate. 5. When should the inflation target be set? The disinflation policy should be cast within the general framework of the overall macroeconomic policy. Since one of the important components of macroeconomic policy is the budget, it would be highly desirable that the inflation targets are set at the same time and together with the budget decisions. This would also ensure that the various objectives of the government are consistent with each other. IMPORTANT “BACKGROUND MUSIC” A successful implementation of the inflation target strategy does not depend only on monetary policy. The rest of the macroeconomic system must be supportive. This section lists some of the essential key institutional requirements that would contribute to the success of the inflation target strategy. 1. A solid fiscal system An important ingredient of a stable macroeconomic system is a sound fiscal system. Among the key characteristics of such a system are relatively small budget deficits and relatively small public debt. 2. A flexible exchange-rate regime The flexibility of the exchange rate frees the monetary authority to focus on its main objective—the attainment of price stability. Furthermore, during some phases of the disinflation process an appreciation of the currency contributes to reducing the inflation rate. In the absence of exchange rate flexibility, such an appreciation would not be possible. Since exchange rates (like other financial variables) tend to respond rapidly to new information, their flexibility speeds up the transmission mechanism and, thereby, shortens the adjustment process. 3. A functioning foreign-exchange market The well-functioning market for foreign exchange reduces the cost of exchange rate flexibility, and contributes to the appropriate pricing of foreign exchange risk. 100 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Furthermore, an efficient market provides market participants with the appropriate financial instruments that can provide protection from excess exchange rate variability. 4. Availability of instruments of monetary policy In order to conduct effective monetary policy, the monetary authorities must be provided with the range of monetary and financial instruments which enable them to carry out the policy tasks. For example, in order to conduct open market operations, the central bank must have access to a sufficiently large stock of government bonds. 5. Central bank independence The requirement of central bank independence is critical. The central bank must be granted the full legal and practical authority and ability to implement monetary policy according to its best and independent judgment. 6. Strong banking system It is important that when the central bank decides on a course of monetary policy, it is not burdened by considerations of the strength of the banking sector. For example, the central bank might decide that it is appropriate to raise interest rates by a significant amount; such a rise in rates might adversely influence banks that have weak balance sheets. In some circumstances the central bank might delay the rise in interest rates in order to prevent damaging the weak banks. This would have negative inflationary consequences. In order to assure that the central bank does not compromise its monetary policy by such considerations, it is imperative that the banking system be strong and sound. 7. A functioning capital market The success of the disinflation strategy would be enhanced if the economy has capital markets that are deep and wide. It is through the well-functioning capital markets that the effects of monetary policy are transmitted throughout the economic system. In order to insure that this transmission is effective, the capital market must be functioning well. Furthermore, when the capital account of the balance of payments is opened, the efficient absorption of international capital flows requires a well-functioning domestic capital market. 8. A flexible economic system The disinflation process may induce short-term cost. Such cost typically arises from rigidities of wages, contracts, and the like. In the presence of such rigidities, THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 101 nominal changes (like a contraction in the quantity of money), induce real changes, which in turn may adversely affect output and employment. In the absence of such rigidities, the cost of disinflation would be reduced. The typical policy instruments that contribute to enhanced flexibility of the economic system are structural policies that remove distortions and enhance competition. CONCLUSIONS This paper dealt with inflation targeting and exchange rate policy. The analysis drew on the experience from the Israeli disinflation process. The lessons, however, are more general and should be applicable to other experiences of disinflation especially for countries that have had a history of high inflation. In recent years, several countries have used the inflation targeting strategy in order to bring down inflation and achieve price stability. It is noteworthy that every country that has implemented the inflation targeting strategy has not regretted that choice. This observation by itself serves as the best testimony to the usefulness of the inflation target strategy. 102 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 103 SESSION III: THE BANK OF ISRAEL'S CORPORATE GOVERNANCE— INSIGHTS AND LESSONS FROM THE FIRST YEAR THE MONETARY COMMITTEE PANEL NATHAN SUSSMAN: Good afternoon. This morning, Karnit told us about the new Bank of Israel Law, and one of the major changes in the Law was the institution of the Monetary Committee that replaced the sole decision making of the Governor. What we would like to do in this short panel is to look a little bit into the inside of the operation of the Monetary Committee—we are not going to reveal what our interest rate decision on Sunday will be. Some of you probably would have liked to be flies on the wall when these committees are sitting, and we will give you a little bit of a glimpse into the operation of the Monetary Committee. We have four members of the Committee here, two internals and two externals, so I’ll start with Barry Topf, who is the Senior Advisor to the Governor, formerly Director of the Market Operations Department at the Bank; Professor Rafi Melnick who is an external member of the Committee and the Vice President for Academic Affairs in the IDC; we have Professor Reuben Gronau, who is also an external in the Committee and is a Professor Emeritus at the Hebrew University, and we have Dr. Karnit Flug, who is the Deputy Governor and my predecessor as Director of the Research Department until recently. Actually, my experience in the Bank starts with the Committee so I will learn here a bit as well about the things that happened before. So the way we will do this will be a short question and answer session, and I’d like each one of the participants to be brief so we can cover more ground. I guess this is one occasion—usually in the Committee, Andrew, who is the Director of the Market Operations, and I are on the hot seat—now we get the rare chance to put these guys on the hot seat. So we’ll start with the veterans of monetary policy decision making, and I’ll ask you a question: what has changed, before and after? BARRY TOPF: First of all, despite what Nathan said, for those of you who regret not being a fly on the wall, you might not be missing all that much, so you don’t have to regret it all that much. We have three external members, so of course we’d be hard put to add three external members, let alone members of the quality we have, without improving the quality of the discussion, without adding additional points of view, without adding additional factors, especially the fact that they are outside the Bank of Israel and they can bring new viewpoints—I must say, in some cases certainly, new viewpoints which we might not have been able to generate within the Bank, so that has been a great advantage. The very fact that there is a discussion I think is very positive, and I must say one of the motivations of having a Committee instead 104 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL of a sole decision maker is primarily, or to a great extent, to limit the downside risk—in other words, the risk of having a very bad decision being made. We have seen that in the Bank of Israel in the past, we have seen that in other places, so that risk, I think, was greatly reduced because the members, both the three internal members and the three external members of the type that we have, will make it very unlikely for us to stumble very badly. KARNIT FLUG: Just to add to what Barry said, I think that one of the things that have changed since we’ve had a Committee is that there are many more questions asked about the analysis. So the downside is that meetings are much longer, but I think it really improves the quality of the analysis. The staff is being put on its toes, and a lot of the underlying assumptions of the models and the analyses are being questioned and reviewed and discussed, and it really improves the quality of the analysis. There is also more diversity in the preferences regarding the different weights that people put on different considerations, there are different views about the likelihood of certain risks materializing and it certainly enriches the discussion. NATHAN SUSSMAN: Thank you. So that leads me directly to the second question, and I’ll start on this side now. Do you think there is any fundamental difference between the considerations made by the internals of the Bank verses the externals? So you can continue on that line. KARNIT FLUG: There was an expectation that there might be a division between external and internal members. That is certainly not the case, and that is not how it played out. In terms of voting, as an indication, we have seen diverse votes, and many times there was one external member, one internal member voting on one side, and four others on the other—this is the clearest indication that there is really no division according to that line. Obviously there are different members on the Committee who put different weights on the different considerations, but it is certainly not divided by the division between externals and internals. REUBEN GRONAU: I can only add that whenever the minority vote consisted of two votes, they came from different "camps". Somebody has thought of the seating arrangement around the table so that each "insider" is flanked by two "outsiders", (and vice versa), and THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 105 judging from the discussion you cannot tell whether the speaker is an "insider" or an "outsider". NATHAN SUSSMAN: Rafi, before you answer, can you clarify a little bit not only about the voting preferences but also on the considerations, how people weight things. Do you see a difference? RAFI MELNICK: It’s very hard to make a judgment about how people on the Committee weight things, because it’s been a very short period of time since we started making decisions. However, from a long term perspective, if we look at the Taylor rule to reveal preferences of decision making on interest rates, we can clearly identify, historically speaking, a change in the Taylor rule when Stanley Fischer started to be the Governor of the Bank. The Bank moved from a very strict Taylor-type policy rule to a flexible inflation-targeting regime, considering output and employment as well. One thing that I can say about the Committee and the way it operates is that it is a very active Committee. Out of 21 decisions we have made since the Committee was formed, on seven occasions we changed the interest rate, which is a ratio of a very active type of committee. Each time we changed the interest rate we had the impression that this is something that will stick for a longer period of time. But then new information arrived, the evaluation changed, and we took new decisions. So it’s a very active Committee. We get a lot of very interesting and very comprehensive information from the different divisions of the Bank and the decisions are taken not according to who is inside the Bank and who is outside. BARRY TOPF: I’ll just add one point which should be fairly obvious, but nevertheless should be remarked. As an internal member, one difference I do see is that in addition to monetary policy there also have to be considerations of monetary operations—it is an operating central bank, and naturally I believe the inside members of the Bank will have a bit more weight on operational considerations as opposed to pure policy concerns, but that might be also a part of a learning curve for the external members. 106 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL NATHAN SUSSMAN: Thank you. So moving on to the publication of the minutes of the meetings—those minutes reveal the considerations and also reveal the pattern of the vote. In the recent Annual Report of the Bank of Israel we had a little box on the pattern of voting, and it seems that one can infer something from these votes, based on the outcomes of the votes and on the decision. What we have shown there, and again it’s not 100 percent and we didn’t test for any statistical significance, but we could show that if there is a dissenting vote during a vote, then in the following meeting the likelihood that that vote will prevail is higher than otherwise. I’m asking you as members, when you’re thinking about casting your votes and speaking to the minutes, the protocols we call them, do you take into account these considerations about the impact of the vote, the impacts of the minutes? BARRY TOPF: OK, I know that puts me with odds with major trends in the profession, but I happen to be much of a skeptic when it comes to transparency. I think it’s a much overplayed attribute, and that will color what I’m about to say, which is that I think consciously or unconsciously everybody takes into consideration the minutes and what will be revealed, and I think we are very bad in anticipating how to actually be understood by the public. I’ve heard also from other central banks that efforts for transparency often are counterproductive and backfire. This might be one of the occasions where less is more. I think there is still value to the old fashioned tradition of, I won’t say secretive central banking, but let’s say very discrete central banking. RAFI MELNICK: OK, here we start with the first difference between one inside and one outside member. I certainly believe that transparency is a very important element in our decision making. The minutes play an important role of interacting with the public, with the financial sector, with industry and with households. In my opinion, their understanding of what we are doing plays an enormous role in achieving the policy goals. And in fact, when I recall all the decisions we made, except for one, in most cases the financial markets actually expected our policy in advance. When you follow over time different interest rates and different indicators of market expectations, it becomes evident that policy is clear and therefore much more effective. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 107 REUBEN GRONAU: The market and the Committee receive the same signals concerning the state of the economy, but the signals are often murky. As a result, the interpretation of these signals may differ between different members of the Committee, and between the Committee and outside analysts. The strength of the signal determines the timing of the vote for change. In the last 20 months, since the Committee was established, we have been living in a period of weakening growth. The disagreement in the Committee never concerned the direction of change, but focused on the timing. Given the side effects of the lower interest rates on the capital and housing markets, it is not surprising that some members advocated a more active interest rate policy and others preferred a more conservative one. But with the exception of one vote, I never had the feeling that the members voted with the minutes in their mind. KARNIT FLUG: Here I happen to disagree with the other internal member on the Committee, and I agree with Rafi. I think that actually transparency and the minutes have been extremely useful in conveying what we really meant in our policy, what the reasoning behind it was, and it helped shape the expectations for the near future. We put a lot of effort into trying to be very clear about what we mean, maybe we are not always successful, but we do put quite a lot of effort into the precise wording of the minutes in an attempt to be really clear about what the arguments behind our decision are. One thing we learned from our experience is not to try and give hints as to our next move, because in our experience, when we did that in the past, by the time the information came and another month passed, we ended up not doing what we thought or hinted that we will do. So we are more careful about that, and it’s not because we don’t want to shape expectations in a certain direction, but just because, as it turns out, things are too dynamic to predict what our next move will be. NATHAN SUSSMAN: Thank you. In one of our recent decisions, in May, we actually had a draw and for the first time, the double vote of the Governor was used. I’d like to ask you, does the special role that the Governor has on the Committee, chairing the Committee and having the double vote, does that impact the decision, does that impact your considerations in voting? 108 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL KARNIT FLUG: Generally I would say that the discussion has a strong effect on the voting. Many times we come to the meeting where presentations are being made with a certain view as to where the decision should go. Then we get into what we call the “narrow discussion”, the discussion of the Committee, and the arguments can really affect our views. When the votes are split, actually, in many cases in some way the vote is split within each of us. The arguments are convincing on each side, and the vote reflects the weights each of us puts on the different arguments, and the probability we assign to different scenarios. Naturally, when our Governor, who is extremely experienced in monetary policy making, expresses his views, Committee members listen very carefully. So to sum up, in many cases it’s the discussion that shapes Committee members’ views as to the policy decision that should be taken. REUBEN GRONAU: I don’t have much to add. It is only natural that the Governor's views, given his past experience, carry more weight than other members of the Committee. Every member of the Committee comes to the meeting with his priors on how to act given his beliefs concerning the state of the economy. These beliefs may change through the discussion. This is true for me, and I believe it is true also for the Governor. Trying to outguess him is therefore a futile exercise. RAFI MELNICK: I second Karnit. I think that the process of analyzing the information, which we get in a very professional way from the people of the Bank, and the discussion that takes place at the Monetary Committee, play an important role, at least in my decisions. I don’t come with a prefixed idea although I certainly have a strategy. The decision is made based on the information we get and the discussion that follows. There is an important lesson I have learned in this process of decision making. As you know, at the end of the day there is a decision to take and it’s not like an academic paper you can end with a question or doubts—you have to decide: the interest rate is going up, down or is not changed. And there is a phenomenon connected to what Reuben said before, related to the question of timing. You always think that when you get the next piece of information the picture will become clear. I have news for you—the picture is never clear. Even when the new piece of information arrives, the horizon is not clear, so it’s always a decision made under uncertainty with things that are not known for sure. Given that, we have adopted Stan's approach—that the Committee or monetary policy should be proactive, in the sense that we should always try to be ahead of the curve and not follow events. It is a real challenge. It seems that making a policy mistake is THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 109 probably less harmful than not making a decision when necessary. A decision can always be corrected; I have learned that from Stan in the last year and a half that we have been working together. Combining the necessity of making a decision, with the picture unclear, in a model that doesn’t exist, at this point, is very challenging. Therefore the discussion and the ideas that we hear from the professionals of the Bank, from the members of the Committee is an important way of taking the decision. BARRY TOPF: I’ll extend something that Reuben said. I would like to think that the influence and weight of any particular position is determined by the arguments marshalled in its favor, and the facts that can be presented in the force of the argument, regardless of whether it’s an external member, an internal member, the Governor or not the Governor. I would even venture to say that staff members can be allowed to influence the decision should their arguments be persuasive enough, and I think that is as it should be. That being said, I think one has to take into consideration that there are also considerations, and should be considerations, of the credibility of the Bank’s policy, continuity of the Bank’s policy, and so on, which can influence people’s decision to vote, but those kind of considerations should be granted the weight they deserve and not more than that. NATHAN SUSSMAN: OK, thank you. I would like to end this short panel by, I guess, addressing the new members, and I will start with Rafi. Summing up the year and a half or so you’ve been on the Committee, what have you learned? RAFI MELNICK: I have learned quite a lot. It’s been quite an experience and a privilege to be among the founders of the Monetary Committee of the Bank of Israel. Obviously the big challenge has been to make the right decisions—but not only that. This is a new era for Israel, it’s a new era for monetary policy making in Israel, and we had to confront the challenge of translating the new Law into an operational way of working within the Bank. This is a tremendous change. In the past, the governor was a sole decision maker, so he could assign any weights he wanted, but now it’s different and there are many things within the law that we have had to consider, on how to implement and how to translate what the legislature wants for us. The goals are very clear and we take them very seriously in the process of decision making. I think that in translating the law into an operational thing we encounter many wise things that the legislature put there in the process. It took a long gestation period to finally produce a law but I think the law is a good law. There are some minor 110 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL things that should be probably corrected in the future but these are not fundamental things. One aspect that the legislature didn’t pay a lot of attention to is the big difference between the process of nominating the members of the Monetary Committee—there are a lot of specifications, there is a procedure and everything is taken care of—but the law doesn’t say anything on how the Governor should be nominated. I think that this is a problem, we are living with that problem these days because less than two weeks before Stan ends his term we still don’t know who is going to enter into his shoes, which are very big shoes. I think that a process of overlap before transferring command should be an important aspect in the nomination of the Governor. NATHAN SUSSMAN: Thank you. I’d like to invite Reuben now to make a short presentation. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 111 MONETARY POLICY 2009-2013 –AN OUTSIDER'S VIEW REUBEN GRONAU Philipp Maier, in his analysis of the performance of monetary committees, points out the importance of the diversity of backgrounds of the committee members. Stan must have read this paper carefully when he chose me to serve as the oddball on the Committee. My specialization is in Labor Economics, and my monetary economics background is confined to two courses on the subject: one by Don Patinkin in the early 60's, and one by Stanley Fischer in the early 80's. Given my empirical background, I thought it is only fitting that in this conference I present an analysis of the impact of the new Monetary Committee on monetary policy, employing a "before and after" comparison based on the change in regime in September 2011—the date when the new Committee first convened. Unfortunately, with only 17 observations on the new era, I realized there is not enough variability in the data to reach any substantive conclusions at this date. I decided, therefore, to expand the period of study to the period beginning in January 2009, one quarter after the beginning of the Crisis. In his lecture to the Israel Economic Association, Stan Fischer lamented, "I long for the days before the crisis when we used to meet once a month to set the interest rate, and thus finishing our work for that month. These days we find ourselves running around throughout the month looking for the holes we have to plug to prevent the floodwater from entering.” Stan is known as an enthusiastic runner. How hard did he run? Figure 1 describes the interest rates at the beginning and the end of the period, and the number of interest changes in between, in a selected sample of OECD and emerging market economies. Judging by the point of departure and the point of arrival very little has been "achieved": Early in 2009, the Bank of Israel rate was 1.75%, and the current rate is 1.50%. But the small differential disguises the amount of effort that was required to stabilize the boat. Given the stormy winds, keeping the boat on track required constant tacking. In the 53 months between January 2009 and May 2013, the Bank of Israel changed its interest rates 21 times—nearly a world record, if we are to judge from the sample of Figure 1. 112 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 6.00 25 5.00 20 % 4.00 15 3.00 10 2.00 5 0.00 0 Eu ro De UK nm No a r rw k Sw Sw e ay it z d en er C h la n d e P o ko s la Ru nd ss ia C a US n M a da ex ic Ch o B r i le a Ja z il pa Ko n Ta rea Th iw a a n Au i lan Ne s t d w rali Si Zel a ng a n ap d o I re S. n di a Af r Isr ic a ae l 1.00 No. o f cha ng es Figure 1:Central Bank Interest Rates and the Number of Interest Changes During the Period Jan. 2009 - May 2013 I.2009 V.2013 # changes Figure 2 provides a schematic view of the path taken by interest rates in a selected sample of economies during the period. It seems that only very few central bankers enjoyed the “tranquility” described by Stan in his speech. Two central banks (the US and Japan) did not change their interest rates throughout the period, one bank (the UK31) adjusted interest downward and stayed there, and one central bank (Canada) adjusted its rates downward only to return to its original position. For the rest of the economies, the interest rate policy, reacting to the dual crises, resembled a rollercoaster—down, up and down again. 31 Switzerland, not in the graph, followed a similar course. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 113 Figure2: The Path of Central Bank Rates, Selected Economies, January 2009 - May 2013 6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 I.2009 Is ra el K or ea Ta iw an Th ai la nd A us tra lia C hi le D en m ar k N or w ay Sw ed en Eu ro C an ad a U K Ja pa n U S 0.00 V.2013 Chile championed in this race, cutting its rate from 7.25% to 0.50% in a sixmonth period, climbing back to 5.25% and settling on 5.00%. Israel was not far behind. With a small open economy, the Bank of Israel reacted immediately to the sign of crisis. It started its travel in September 2008 when the rate was 4.25%, by January 2009 it was already down to 1.75%, continuing downwards to 0.50%; in September of that year it changed course and by June 2011 it reached the level of 3.25%, only to start four months later its way down to the current level of 1.50%. Were these just symptoms of hyperactivity—"Much Ado about Nothing", or were they the traces of fine-tuning as the scenario of the dual crises evolved? The answer is contained in Figure 3, which describes the quarterly rate of growth of the economies that appear in Figure 1. The figure presents both the mean rate and its standard deviation. Israel ranks among the fastest growing economies in this period, surpassed only by Chile and Korea. However, what is unique about Israel’s growth path, though perhaps less known, is the steadiness of this path. Israel’s average growth rate was 3.56%, and the quarterly standard deviation was 2.15%. Chile, which enjoyed an average rate that was one-third higher, went through fluctuations in growth (as measured by the quarterly standard deviation) that were 2.7 times as large. The US economy in that period went through similar fluctuations, but its average growth was only less than one-half the Israeli growth rate. 114 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Figure 3: GDP Quarterly Growth Rates, Mean and Fluctuation, 2009 - 2013 5.0% 4.0% 3.0% 2.0% 1.0% O OE ECD CD T - E o ta Un Eu u ro l i te r o a p e Sw d St r ea itz at e e s Swr lan d Ne N ed e w o rw n Ne Zea ay th l a er nd la n Ko d s Ge re r a De m an nm y a C rk C a hile n Au ada Au str st r i a al Isr i a ae l 0.0% GMEAN % (in annual terms) 6.0% -1.0% STDEV Has there been a unique consistent pattern describing Israeli monetary policy throughout the period? Bank of Israel researchers set out to detect this rule (Bank of Israel 2012 Annual Report, Ch. 3). They applied the Taylor rule to the data, adding a variable measuring the state of the foreign currency market. The equation they estimated related the rate change to the difference between the current rate it and the long run rate, the deviation of the inflation rate πt from its target, the output gap and the depreciation of the Israeli shekel ∆St, (1) it- it-1=ρ ρ *[(iLR - it-1)+α α*( πt-π πT)+ β * GAPt + δ* ∆St]. The parameters estimated were ρ=0.2, α= 2.5, β= 0.8, and δ=0.1. Figure 4 describes the fit of the estimated equation. The estimated rule gives an almost perfect fit to the interest rate path prior to 2007, but, systematically, overestimates the path thereafter. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 115 Figure 4: Applying the Taylor Rule to the Bank of Israel Interest Rates, 1999–2012 Source: The Bank of Israel 2012 Annual Report, Ch. 3, p. 102. The report concludes that “it appears therefore that during the period of the global economic crisis, monetary policy was conducted differently, affected by factors that are not included in the interest rate equation—in particular, risk factors originating in the global economy and expectations of their future moderating effect on the Israeli economy led to a lower rate of interest than that dictated by the equation”. Thus, for example, foreseeing the crisis looming on the horizon, the Bank’s leaders preferred to keep the rate stable in 2007–2008, though the rule called for raising it, and then lowered the rate when the crisis hit.32 The report hypothesizes that it seems that the Bank adopted a forward looking pre-emptive strategy (Stan would call it “being in front of the curve”). A crude test of this hypothesis calls for the replacement of the current values of inflation rates, the output gap and the foreign currency depreciation by future ones (the values of two quarters removed)33 (2) 32 it- it-1=ρ ρ *[(iLR - it-1)+α α*( πt+2-π πT)+ β * GAPt+2 + δ* ∆St+2] In the period December 2006–August 2008 the rate fluctuated in the range of 5.00% to 3.25%. 33 Assuming perfect foresight and that future variables are not affected by current policy. 116 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL the parameters being identical to those in Equation 1. Figure 5 describes the new equation, and it is hard to see where the new “forward looking" equation improves the fit. Figure 5: The BOI Interest Rates, The Taylor Rule And a Forward Looking Monetary Policy 14 12 10 % 8 6 4 2 0 BOI Interest Rates The Taylor Rule A Forward Looking Policy It seems that the Bank of Israel interest rate policy in this period is a classic case of a “two-regime” equation. I tried to disentangle the secret of the second period equation but it evaded me. In despair I concluded that in the second period, as of 2008 onwards, the rule can be summarized by the naïve model it = it-1, or alternatively ρ = 0. The results of this two-regime equation are presented in Figure 6. The new equation outperforms by far the previous ones, leaving us to wonder whether interest rate setting is a science or just art. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 117 Table 6: One or Two Regime Taylor Rule 1999- 2007 vs. 2008-2012 14 12 10 % 8 6 4 2 0 BOI rates One regime Two regime REFERENCES The Bank of Israel Annual Report 2012. Maier, P. (2010), “How Central Banks Take Decisions: An Analysis of Monetary Policy Meetings”, in Siklos, P.L., M.T. Bohl, and M.E. Wohar (eds), Challenges in Central Banking: The Current Institutional Environment and Forces Affecting Monetary Policy, Cambridge University Press, 320-356. 118 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 119 THE TRADEOFF BETWEEN BEING AHEAD OF THE CURVE AND ACCURATE FORECASTING ALEX CUKIERMAN I would like to better highlight a basic tradeoff of monetary policy decision making that is partially implicit in remarks made by some of the previous speakers. On one hand, due to lags in the impact of monetary policy, efficient policy has to be geared to the state of the economy in the future. As a consequence, inflation targeting is really inflation forecast targeting.34 During committee meetings, Stan occasionally referred to this as “making decisions ahead of the curve”. On the other hand, since the future state of the economy is uncertain and even data about the current state of the economy arrives with a lag, monetary policy committees have to make decisions on the basis of current forecasts about the future. Inevitably those forecasts rely on data availability at decision time. Broadly speaking this data consists of the past history and of recent indicators. To minimize future forecast errors policymakers need to determine how much weight to give to recent indicators in comparison to past history. This is an important inference problem in which they have to decide (paraphrasing an old Hebrew proverb) whether one swallow signals the arrival of spring or not. More generally they have to decide how much of recent changes will persist into the future. But learning about the persistence of economic variables is more accurate the more one waits in order to observe how long a given change persists into the future.35 The upshot is that policymakers face a tradeoff between making decisions “ahead of the curve” and waiting in order to obtain a better evaluation of changing economic conditions. The more a monetary policy committee waits before making a decision the better are its forecasts of the economy for a given time period in the future. But waiting also raises the likelihood that policy will be “behind the curve”. Thus, monetary policy committees face the difficult task of finding the optimal balance between those two factors. 34 See Svensson, L.E.O., 1997, “Inflation Forecast Targeting: Implementing and Monitoring Inflation Targets”. European Economic Review 41, 1111–1146. 35 See Muth J.F., 1960, “Optimal Properties of Exponentially Weighted Forecasts”, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 55, June, 299-306, and Brunner K., Cukierman A. and Meltzer A., 1980, “Stagflation, Persistent Unemployment and the Permanence of Economic Shocks”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 6: 467-492. 120 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 121 THE SUPERVISORY COUNCIL STANLEY FISCHER: Before I introduce Dan Propper, the Chairman of the Bank of Israel’s Supervisory Council, I would like to say a word on the issue of academic economists on the Monetary Committee. It would have been useful to have on the Committee an economist who had practical experience in business or in the government, and we suggested that to the Winograd Committee – the Committee appointed to propose people for the Monetary Committee and Supervisory Council. They tried very hard, but found no-one suitable for the Monetary Committee who did not have a conflict of interest between service on the Committee and some aspect of their current activities. The Monetary Committee does not pay its members enough to persuade a potential member to give up on his or her particular conflict of interest in favor of joining the Committee, so it is a real problem. However, we do have a significant range of opinions among the academic members of the Monetary Committee, and that to some extent compensates for the absence of members from different backgrounds. I would like also to mention that we are fortunate to have with us today the Governor of the Palestinian Monetary Authority, Jihad Al-Wazir. The Palestinians use the shekel as one of their currencies, and that requires interaction and cooperation between the two monetary authorities. I believe that cooperation is good, and thank Jihad and the PMA for that. We turn now to a discussion with Dan Propper, the Chairman of our Supervisory Council, which acts essentially as a Board of Directors. As you know, a new Bank of Israel law was passed in April 2010. There had been a lot of work on formulating a new law already in the 1990s, when Jacob Frenkel was Governor. The main difference between the 1990s proposals and the current law is that we added a Supervisory Council to the structure that had been proposed earlier. Under the 1954 law, the Bank of Israel had an Advisory Committee and Advisory Council, with the Advisory Committee’s membership being a subset of the membership of the Advisory Council. Private sector bankers played a major role in each. Dr. Arie Krampf from Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, wrote a thesis on the governance of the Bank of Israel in its early years. A major conclusion of his, based on the protocols of the meetings of the two committees, was that the Bank of Israel in its early years was in practice managed by two people: one was the Governor, David Horowitz, and the other was Ernst Yefet, a prominent private sector banker. That sort of model of central bank management, including private sector bankers who are interested parties in what the central bank does, has dropped out of favor. Why did we add a Supervisory Council to the structure of the governance of the Bank of Israel? When I arrived, I discovered that I was responsible for every decision of the Bank, both the monetary policy decisions and all the managerial 122 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL decisions, including the budget, which was not approved by anybody but me. I thought that was not an appropriate way of running an important public sector organization with a big budget. In addition, I felt uneasy with the responsibility this implied. So we suggested the Supervisory Council largely on the model – as is much of this law – of the Bank of England, which has had a management body, the Court, since 1694. The Court sits in a wonderful room. It has on the wall an instrument that tells the times of the tides of the Thames, because in the early days of the Bank of England, the times when the ships came in was part of what drove the level of activity in the city. The Bank of Israel does not have a tide measurer in the room where the Supervisory Council meets. The Council has seven members, five external and two internal, the internals being the Governor and the Deputy Governor. Neither the Governor nor the Deputy Governor is Chairman of the Supervisory Council; the Chairman is from outside the Bank – and clearly he or she was bound to be a key figure in the running of the Bank. Everyone who was following the process of implementation of the new law asked who we were going to get to be Chairman of the Supervisory Council. We had a general description: someone who is independent – totally independent of the government, independent of the Bank, with his own reputation and the authority that would bring to the Supervisory Council from the start, somebody who has demonstrated powers of management and persuasion, and more. Then Justice Winograd was named as Chairman of the Selection Committee for members of both committees—the Monetary Committee and the Supervisory Council. I was told immediately that I could relax – that there would not be any politics in the choice of members of the committees, that we would get the best people possible. I relaxed and in due course the Winograd Committee found the perfect candidate to be Chairman of the Supervisory Council, Dan Propper. I wasn’t extremely surprised by their choice, because in the meantime I had been asking lots of people who it was that we needed to chair the Council. Dan, we didn’t have an official list, but you were atop the unofficial list, and everything that has happened in the Supervisory Council since has justified that opinion and the choice of the Winograd Commitee. Dan knows how to run a meeting. He doesn’t like to meet too often, so we meet once a month for 5 hours, which, believe me, is a long time to discuss managerial problems, even though we are permitted one coffee break. He listens patiently as the members of the Council speak, occasionally asking a question. At the appropriate moment, he suggests a decision. Occasionally the members of the Council disagree, and discussion then focuses on what the decision should be – and in the end, Dan knows how to formulate the right decision, and how to take the group with him. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 123 But he is much more than the perfect Chairman, because he also acts as a trusted adviser to the Bank on other issues. From time to time he raises concerns with the management of the Bank, issues which are not directly the responsibility of the Supervisory Council, but are essential to the way the Bank is viewed in the community and in society. He plays a far more active and important role as a wise advisor to the management than I would have imagined beforehand. The Council would not have been anywhere near as effective as it is without him – so, Dan, we are extremely grateful to you. DAN PROPPER: Let me interject here on two counts: First, I want to stress that all this praise goes to all the members of the Supervisory Council. Second, after hearing these flattering words from you and from Yankele Frenkel, perhaps I should make a quick exit before anyone has time to get in a critical word. STANLEY FISCHER: I’d like to introduce Dan. He is of Czech origin, that is to say, his parents are Czech, and were born in Czechoslovakia. He was born in Israel, educated in the Technion, with a degree in chemistry and food technology, and after his army service joined a company which eventually became a key component of the wellknown Israeli company, Osem — a food processing company, which is the industry in which his father owned a factory in Czechoslovakia before coming to what was then Palestine. It was Dan who understood that the quality of the firm’s products would be improved significantly if it could form a partnership with a high-quality foreign firm in the same industry. Osem formed such a partnership with Nestle. Osem is now 58 percent owned by Nestle, and was run by Dan as CEO between 1981 and 2006; now he is Chairman of Osem. From 1993 to 1999, he was the president of the Manufacturers Association, and in this context, as Jacob Frenkel mentioned earlier, there were some serious conflicts between Dan and the Governor of the Bank of Israel, possibly over the refusal by the Bank of Israel to intervene in the foreign exchange market. Dan was named Chairman of the Supervisory Council in September 2011, and as I have said, we couldn’t have had a better choice and a better chairman. So Dan, if I can start by asking you a question about your experience as Chairman: what has impressed you most in the Bank – either positively or negatively? 124 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL DAN PROPPER: I came into an entity—the Bank of Israel—with which I had no prior managerial experience. In addition, my acquaintance with public or quasi-public sector entities came from my experience as a chair of NGOs, which of course are much simpler in nature—there is basically no operation to run, the focus is on attracting funds from outside and redistributing them. For most of my life I was heavily involved in private sector businesses, where the emphasis is on profits, for which you establish specific targets, and which are run very differently. Here, I came to a huge entity which is neither a business nor an NGO. It has to generate results like a business, but its goal is not to maximize profits; and it’s not an NGO, which gets donations from the outside—so it’s a very different creature. I admit pondering the question of how such an entity can be run, because all my life I believed that you need simple targets, such as a bottom line and a top line, translating them into many operational targets for managers and employees to focus on, and motivating them accordingly, to ensure that your ultimate goal is reached. So I was surprised to find that there are other ways to motivate. In fact, I found a wonderful team headed by you, of course, Stan, and I saw talented and dedicated people at the top—but I also found people at lower echelons in the Bank to be outstanding. It is not just their qualifications that are impressive, but how they operate even in the small details, such as the way they prepare and present their presentations—there is no doubt in my mind that their overall performance is first class. A second point I would like to mention is that I must say that this experience is a fascinating one for me. It is exciting, because this newly established Supervisory Council must develop and design the managerial framework in which the Bank will operate in the future. So though we are not busy designing policies as the Monetary Committee does, we are putting procedures in place and monitoring their effectiveness. We have also needed to create methodologies for reviewing the financial situation of the Bank, and yes, we’ve had to shake up some mindsets in order to introduce useful elements from the business sector. If I were to take a snapshot of the Bank when I first came, and compare it to what there is today, I think one would find that the Bank has improved considerably in the way it operates, in its corporate governance. It now functions according to quite precise lines and boundaries. There is still a lot of work to do, we still have a long way to go, but I think that the Bank of Israel Law which took effect in 2011—and here again you were one of the people, if not the man, who pushed it forward—is starting to bear fruit. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 125 STANLEY FISCHER: Thanks very much. I think that the improvement of the management of the Bank is a very large contribution and that it comes from the outside members of the Supervisory Council, of which three other members are here—Prof. Nina Zaltzman, a law professor from Tel Aviv University, Yitzhak Edelman, an accountant, and next to him Uri Galili, a former banker — each from a different profession. Nina had helped us before we changed the law. Tzvika Eckstein had suggested that we form an Audit Committee with external members, which we did, and Nina was a member of that Committee. We are lucky that Nina is also a member of the current Audit Committee. The one person on the Supervisory Council who isn’t here at the moment is Maxine Fassberg, who was here this morning. Maxine is the CEO of Intel Israel, and brings her intelligence and business experience to our work in a highly constructive way. There is no question that more discipline is being asserted in the way the Bank is run. There is great value in having a majority of outsiders on the Supervisory Council. A fundamental problem in managing the Bank is that almost everyone has tenure. That means that the management is far more constrained in managing personnel than is private sector management in companies without strong unions. The tendency of most – but not all – departmental heads when asked to take on an additional task (X) is to ask for more workers. It has very rarely been – “if I do X, I will have to reallocate workers and stop doing Y.” In reply to the demand for more workers, one says “No – tell me how to reallocate workers at minimum cost to the work program.” But, you need to keep your managers and workers enthusiastic and motivated, so to keep saying no is not pleasant. Having the backing of the Supervisory Council for standing by the budget is extremely valuable. One of the things that surprised me, and I think also my colleagues in the management of the Bank, is that the Audit Committee has been more active, more important than I thought it would be. The Audit Committee consists of the four outside members of the Supervisory Council; neither the Chairman of the Council, nor the two Bank members of the Council, are members. It is acting somewhat in parallel to and complementary to the internal auditor. Its very active role sometimes creates difficulties with the people who are being audited, but I think its activities contribute to improving the management of the Bank. DAN PROPPER: Although I’m not a member of the Audit Committee—by law I cannot be—I can tell you that I am most impressed by the work of the Committee, comprised of the other representatives of the public on the Supervisory Council, I think it is truly outstanding. First and foremost, the Audit Committee members are bolstering the internal audit process of the Bank, which is very important. An additional point is 126 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL that when they look at issues, they bring with them the much needed perspective of outsiders, with a wealth of experience coming from various corners of the economy, from the private sector as well as from academia. We on the Supervisory Council benefit from the fruits of their labor, fruits born of this combination of well-grounded theoretical knowledge and practical experience that fuse together with the very good work done by the Internal Audit. The truth is, this Committee is one of key tools of the Council, and I am sure it will remain so. STANLEY FISCHER: Would any of the members of the Audit Committee like to say something? No. Like Dan Propper, I am struck by the important role your committee plays. And as he said, you look at our work with very different eyes than we would look at things, and those different eyes are extremely important. The amount of work you put in is also impressive. Sometimes, when Maxine Fassberg wants to tease me, she reminds me that I said the Council would have about six meetings a year of two hours each. In practice, we have several Council meetings, and together with the meetings of the Audit Committee, you must hold two or three meetings a month, and not of two hours each. Dan, last question: We have a lot of changes, none of them large, that we probably would like to make in the Bank of Israel law, when circumstances are ripe. That will be after my time, because we need enough changes to make it worth the effort of going to the Knesset. Further, you know the problem with going to the Knesset is, as the Chairman of the Knesset’s Finance Committee said when we brought the current law to him, “You have to know that no law leaves here as it enters”. That means that if you want to make ten changes, you will probably have 12, at least two of which you don’t want – and you have to weigh that balance all the time. But Dan, if we were to change the system, and certainly if we ever go to the government and Knesset Finance Committee, that is, to the Treasury and the Knesset Finance Committee, would there be changes that should be made in the structure of the Supervisory Council? DAN PROPPER: Given that we haven’t discussed the issue in the Supervisory Council, I can’t speak in the other members’ names. I want to emphasize that the Councils’ decisions are reached through a true democratic process. So when I summarize as Chairman of the Supervisory Council, I review the points made by each one of our members in order to make clear that the decision taken is not mine, but truly the Council’s. I cannot recall having a vote in the Council, and I don’t think we ever should, because so far we have always succeeded in reaching a consensus through open and frank discussions. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 127 However, your question was about a theoretical change of the law, and here I have to admit that in my view there is one thing that is missing—I am not sure whether it should be a separate law or part of the Bank of Israel Law—and that is that the law does not touch on the issue of labor relations. It doesn’t refer to the status of employees of the Bank, in fact, it doesn’t refer to anything having to do with the employees. I feel that there is a need to address that and to do it in a serious way. Government employees are regulated by certain laws and regulations, while employees in private enterprises are regulated by different agreements between the employers and the employees, unions, etc. I think that the Bank needs better defined and appropriate rules regulating the roles and contribution of each and every employee—the best way to design such a set of rules would of course be by way of agreement with the employees, but if that proves too difficult to do, we should still lead for a change, and I am all for it. Finally, I would like to say a few things about you personally. First, Stan, don’t worry I’m not going to praise you here after all the things you heard. My prose is not as good as the prose of many of the other speakers. However, I join everyone who said that you are, first of all, what we call in Hebrew a “mensch”, which translated—it comes from German—says you are a human being, a human being with a heart. Second, you are also a gentleman, a quality that is related to the first one, but it adds some manners. And third, you are also a very wise person who knows when to talk and what to say, and when to listen. Most Israelis think they know it all and thus they rarely listen, so this characteristic of yours, the ability to truly listen, is something very special, and I really appreciate and value it. Last but not least, Stan, I think that the many achievements of Israel’s economy of these last years are in large part your contribution—and I should say your personal contribution—to us. Looking ahead, I want to wish for you that in the future, in all other positions you’ll have, and I’m sure there will be many more, that you will succeed in creating the same environment that you crafted here, and with the same rate of success. One final note: I must say that I would have expected that with such a fine audience as this one, we could also have welcomed the new Governor. Unfortunately, this did not happen, and as a citizen of this country, and as a person involved in the economy of this country, I feel that damage is done to the economy by not announcing who the next Governor will be. This uncertainty creates instability, and instability is enemy number one of success. With these words, I will thank you again, and since we don’t say goodbye, and I know you will come to Israel many times, we’ll just say farewell. Thank you. 128 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 129 Introduction of Larry Summers Stanley Fischer We’re now going to have the pleasure of listening to Larry Summers. Larry almost needs no introduction, but he has had such an impressive and varied career that it is worth reminding ourselves of his many jobs and achievements. Larry was an undergraduate at MIT and then moved to Harvard for his PhD. He came back to MIT as an assistant professor, and then returned to Harvard. Harvard and MIT are only about three miles apart, so these moves were logistically very easy. But MIT was extremely sorry to lose Larry, because he is one of the most creative, and one of the most fertile, thinkers in economics – and not only that, he also throws off more interesting ideas per hour than anyone else I have met. Larry, the wunderkind, became the youngest tenured professor at Harvard, and later the recipient of the John Bates Clark Medal for the best American economist under the age of 40. It was clear early on that Larry was interested in economics primarily as a way of understanding and influencing the real world. He is a great conversationalist, and having a conversation with Larry is one of the pleasures of life, particularly if it starts at around 11 pm and continues for a couple of hours. It’s always fun, and always interesting – and usually you not only enjoy the conversation, you also learn a lot from it. In 1991, he went to the World Bank as Chief Economist, replacing me in that job. In 1993, at the beginning of the first Clinton administration, he was named Undersecretary of the US Treasury. The Undersecretary of the Treasury for International Affairs is probably the most important official in the Treasury with respect to the international economy – and Larry was a very active and very important Undersecretary of the Treasury. Larry believed, and I also believe, that if the US doesn’t lead, nothing much good happens in the international economy. By 1994, I was in the Fund, which meant that he and I spoke often. Sometimes we disagreed – and when that would happen and I was recalcitrant, Larry would unleash the final arrow in his quiver and say to me, “You’re also disagreeing with Bob Rubin and Alan Greenspan.” At that point I was supposed to surrender, and sometimes I did. Larry was remarkably persuasive and remarkably active, including in leading the G7 deputies, and he duly rose through the ranks. He became Deputy Secretary of the Treasury when Bob Rubin became Secretary of the Treasury—that was in 1995. In 1999, Larry was named Secretary of the Treasury. I remember asking him at the time if he was the youngest Secretary of the Treasury since Alexander Hamilton, and he said possibly, 130 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL and I never remembered to follow up so perhaps, Larry, you’ll clarify on this point when you speak. Following the end of the Clinton administration, Larry became president of Harvard University. He was a controversial and courageous president of the university. People in this audience should know that inter alia he was courageous in making his support for Israel quite clear, and that he rejected the almost reflexive hostility to Israel of some student groups. More than once, he took on the students on issues which most presidents would have ducked. After he left the presidency of Harvard, he became a university professor at Harvard, and then in 2009, at the beginning of the Obama administration, he become head of the National Economic Council, which is the group within the White House that coordinates economic policy within the administration. This is a difficult but necessary job because views on economic policies come from the Treasury, from the Council of Economic Advisors, the State Department, the Department of Commerce, and others. The director of the National Economic Council, the first of whom was Bob Rubin, has a very important role to play. Larry left that job at the end of 2010 and President Obama said, “I will always be grateful that at a time of great peril for our country”—remember he took this job after Lehman Brothers and during the worst times of the Great Recession—“a man of Larry’s brilliance, experience and judgment was willing to answer the call and lead our economic team”. He went back to Harvard in 2011, and he is now at the Kennedy School, writes columns for the Financial Times, Washington Post and others, and is frequently seen on television and conferences all over the world – and he is listened to intently. Larry used to be a wunderkind, but we cannot any longer call him a “kind”. However, we certainly should continue to call him a “wunder” – as you are about to discover. Larry, please come and talk to the audience. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 131 LARRY SUMMERS Stan, thank you very much for those generous words. You have it right in essentially every respect save one. The students were easy at Harvard. It was the faculty that was the problem. I have known Stan for thirty-five years. The first serious course, first any course, really, in monetary economics I took was Econ 462 from Stan Fischer, in the fall of 1978. There were several things that struck me in that course: the crystalline clarity of everything that Stan Fischer said; the complete lucidity with which he explained and commented on the latest works in the literature; his dedication to his students; and his habit, which I am going to reciprocate in a few minutes, of posing important questions which would be very valuable for students to figure out how to answer. It was a remarkable experience that had a great deal to do with my decision to focus my efforts as an economist on macroeconomics. I was privileged to be Stan’s colleague, but then years later, after Stan had done a remarkable job as Chief Economist of the World Bank and decided to return to MIT, he was bold enough, perhaps kind enough, perhaps wise enough, to push the idea that I should be his successor. Stan prevailed upon the then-President of the Bank, and I had the honor of succeeding him as Chief Economist. It was not easy to be his successor, as I suspect it will not be easy for whoever succeeds him at the Bank of Israel. He was universally liked, universally admired, universally trusted, and universally revered—and I was the new guy on the street. And when I say all these things I’m not only talking about his colleagues at the Bank, I’m talking about finance ministers around the world who had come to depend on his advice and his wisdom. As Stan mentioned, I moved from the Bank to the US Treasury in 1993. At the end of 1993, the position of Deputy Managing Director of the IMF, a position traditionally filled by an American, came open, and our advice was sought as to who should fill it. My first strategy was very bureaucratically clever. I said the United States is prepared to renounce, temporarily, American leadership in this position, if we could have a Rhodesian Israeli—and if we had a Rhodesian Israeli maybe he could give us some other positions as well. That stratagem was rejected, but my higher purpose was enthusiastically accepted. Michel Camdessus and the IMF Board appointed Stan as the Deputy Managing Director, and I shudder to think what would have happened in Mexico, what would have happened in Thailand, Indonesia, Korea, much of Asia, what would have happened in Brazil and Russia, if Stan Fischer had not been there. He brought the combination he brings to everything – of total analytic skill, unimpeachable integrity, and the ability to connect – and that made him the most influential Deputy Managing Director that the IMF has ever had and I suspect ever will have. I remember a few years later sitting at a dinner in Philadelphia at the American Economic Association meetings and learning that Stan had been approached and was likely to accept the position of Governor of the Bank of Israel. I remember 132 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL having the view that that was fantastic for Israel, that I thought it was very good for Stan, and that I was a little less certain how good it was for my friend Rhoda, but that it would come in time to be wonderful for my friend Rhoda (which I think is the view my friend Rhoda has come to), and that it would be a very good thing for the international financial system, and so it has been. I’m not going to presume to tell this audience the difference that Stan Fischer has made for Israel in this period. What I can say is that in international and economic and financial dialogue on the global response to the financial crisis, if you weighed every country by the ratio of its influence on those discussions to the scale of its GDP, there is no country that had more weight than Israel, and that is not a tribute to Israel’s superb geopolitical positioning. That is instead a tribute to one man, Stan Fischer, and the difference that he has made. So, we are celebrating a remarkable man here today. You know, there has been a tremendous change in the role of economists in the economic system in the forty years since I entered graduate school. When I entered graduate school, it was well known that economists were influential. They wrote books that had a profound impact on economic thinking, some of them whispered in the ears of Presidents or Prime Ministers, some of them advised in other ways, some of them wrote newspaper columns that changed the public debate, but it would be fair to say to that point that, as Churchill put it, “brains were on tap rather than on top.” Few, if any, economists were in a position of ultimate authority over key areas of economic policy to that point. That has changed over the last forty years, and Stan is an exemplar of that change. Stan is an exemplar of that change, as is his student Ben Bernanke, as is his student Mario Draghi, as is our mutual friend Mervyn King, and as is my student Rodrigo Vergara. Of course, Israel was one of the very first in this trend when it appointed Jacob Frenkel to be the Governor of the Bank of Israel in the early 1990s. And so now Ph.D. students in economics can look to model themselves after others like them, others that started in academic careers and now hold positions of high authority with respect to the economy, and no one is more an embodiment of that through the life he has led, and the creator of that through the students he has taught, than Stan Fischer. This trend has created a dynamic in which a professional life cycle is a kind of arc, an arc that begins in reflection as one writes a Ph.D. thesis, as one writes a variety of articles; then, moves into a phase of action when one holds responsibility for actions that affect the lives of millions and millions of people; and then, since no one holds one of these positions forever, cycles back, providing more opportunities for reflection and for instruction. When I was a student, Stan was kind enough to tell me what the most important question would be for me to figure out the answer to—and what comes around goes around, and as Stan prepares to leave the Bank of Israel, but very emphatically not to retire, it occurs to me that I might pose questions that a man of his extraordinary wisdom and experience can usefully answer for all of us. Let me suggest five that go in various ways to the practice of central banking. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 133 First, can one meaningfully operate with two instruments, or is central banking ultimately a brake and accelerator operation? Classic central banking, forget classic, central banking as it came to be understood in the 80s and 90s is basically a brake and accelerator operation. You judged the strength of your economy, you judged the risks of inflation (whether it was an inflation targeting framework or some other framework), and sometimes it was time to put your foot on the gas and sometimes was time to put your foot on the brake. Basically, if the vehicle moved as smoothly as possible that meant that you had succeeded, and enormous intellectual energy has gone in to doing that as well as was possible. Now, we find ourselves living in a more complex world. No one really supposes that inflation was breaking out in a massive way in the mid-2000s; yet, one does somehow suppose that if financial excess had been more effectively curbed less bad things would have happened after 2007. Today there are discussions and concerns around financial excess running substantially ahead of the degree of concerns about demand outstripping capacity or product price inflation accelerating. We can use the word macro-prudential, but can we meaningfully operate with multiple different instruments that allow acceleration on some dimensions with restraint on others, or is that a chimera, an unrealistic aspiration in a world of increasingly open and competitive financial markets? Much about the practice of central banking over the next twenty years will depend on how this question is answered and the world is today without a well-resolved answer to this question. The second question, rather a different type of question—in a sense, Stan has provided his answer to in its Israeli context, but it seems to me it exists more broadly: how should a central bank be structured and how should it communicate? Monetary policy is truly important, so is war and peace; yet, almost every country manages with one Secretary of Defense and not a committee of Secretaries of Defense, and almost every country turns to a committee to make monetary policy. In some cases it is a committee that is very symmetric; in other cases it is a committee that is very asymmetric. A committee provides for the pooling of wisdom; but, a leader seeking advice also provides for the pooling of wisdom. Ken Arrow taught us that an individual can reliably be expected to have consistent preferences, and that a committee can less reliably be expected to have consistent preferences. An individual can perhaps communicate with more clarity than a committee; yet, a committee has the huge advantage of providing broader representation, providing for greater input, providing for greater dissemination of knowledge. What is the optimal way to structure decision-making in this sphere? Perhaps the question is too abstract, but when you think about it, even a small probability of reducing the risk of some of the more unfortunate monetary events we’ve seen over the last fifty years has enormous stakes for human betterment. So, second question: with all the experience, with all one has seen, what is the right structure of central banks – how should they communicate and how frequently? Third question: what is the appropriate role of public liquidity? It is surely right to say that too big to fail is a besetting problem of financial regulation. It is surely 134 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL the case that moral hazard is central to any set of reflections on financial crisis and its prevention, and it is surely the case that transparency and clarity are great virtues. And yet I will also suggest to you that no government, not even the government of Israel, lays down with complete clarity its policy as to how it will response to kidnappings in advance. It provides for a certain ambiguity in how it will respond, perhaps in the interest of preserving credibility, perhaps in the interest of maximizing incentives. And I would ask another question that bears on this very much. It is surely a fact that because there are guardrails on highways people drive a little bit faster than they otherwise would. Is that a good feature of guardrails on highways, or is that a bad feature of guardrails on highways? I would argue it is a good feature of guardrails on highways, it permits people to drive in reasonable safety to where they want to go more quickly than they otherwise would. So then what is the right policy, what is the right way to ultimately understand the role of the discount window, the role of lending in times of crisis? It is easy to say that one should lend only against absolutely good collateral, but of course if collateral is absolute, categorically, certainly good and universally perceived to be good, there is not likely to be any need for the public sector to lend against it, and if it is not those things, then there is a measure of risk involved. These questions go back to Bagehot at least, but they have not been decisively answered. A younger Stan Fischer pushed for the frontier of the notions that I am raising by suggesting a world lender of last resort. Nowadays people wonder whether central banks should or should not be in a position to be able to provide support to institutions that are in extremes. What is the right doctrine that should carry us forward? Fourth question: what about extraordinarily low real interest rates? We say, so it must be right, that interest rates need to find their level, need to be set by the market, need to be responsive to economic conditions. And yet, if one thinks about it, it is a remarkable thing that the safe interest rate as measured by indexed bonds in most of the industrial world and as projected by the market out for periods close to a generation is essentially zero. On at least a simple kind of economic reasoning, that would indicate that the certain equivalent marginal product of capital was zero, which suggests very little impatience on the part of consumers. I first learned this in Stan Fischer’s monetary theory course, and at the time I regarded as a complete theoretical curiosity, finding it interesting how wrong my preconceptions were. But Stan’s course developed to some detail the idea that all kinds of funny things happen when the interest of a country was less than its growth rate: that, for example, it was possible to pay for things without ever really paying for them because one could roll over the debt and still have a declining ratio of debt to GDP. One learned that such an environment was an environment that would create and make possible in every sense a variety of kinds of financial bubbles, and in such cases various government actions that would normally be seen as quite inefficient became quite efficient. And yet, the normal state over the last several decades has been of interest rates less than growth rates in many parts of the world. Should we draw the implications for economic theory from that reality? That would seem a bold and probably rash course. Should we revise economic theory to understand THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 135 these low real interest rates in a way different than we do? Should we be seeking to pursue macroeconomic policies in a way that will create a world in which the interest rate is higher than the interest rates that we have observed? I do not know the answer, but I think it is a question that requires more reflection than it receives, because I think if you describe every feature of modern industrialized economics to most people that are well-trained in economics who have never observed anything in the world, and then ask them what do they think the real interest rates will be, their answer will be nothing like zero. This is a question that I think receives less attention than it should. My final question is what is the broad political compact that will surround 21st century central banking? The world in the wake of the 1970s came to a quite clear doctrine. It was a combination of empirical evidence, theory and argument. It went something like this: inflation always tempts, and it always tempts because in the short run it brings good things with it, and in the long run it brings nothing good with it, and some substantial cost; thus, democracy in its most pure forms lends itself to yielding to short term temptation. Therefore, independent central banks who preserve their independence and are led by figures of extraordinary rectitude can be society’s bulwark against the inflation temptations, leading to lower inflation, the same or better output performance, and a better world. And so, around the world, central banks have become much more independent, in a way that would have been inconceivable to me as a student. When I studied with Stan, and particularly a few years after I studied with Stan, if you took a course in monetary economics, hyperinflation was a big topic, not because it was a really interesting theoretical curiosity where things were taken to their extremes, but because there were hyperinflations on most continents, and a big task of economists was to give advice on how to stop hyperinflation. Today, hyperinflation is like measles: a really bad thing that used to happen often and happens now in very few places. And that is because of the independence of central banks. The independence of central banks now means that there is much more acceptance, though this acceptance is always fragile, of the idea that inflation needs to be contained and controlled, so inflation tempts much less than it once did. To be sure, there needs to be vigilance, there needs to be continued determination, there needs to be continued strong figures of rectitude, but the threat of inflation seems much less pressing than it did in 1979. There are new major concerns for more and more countries: the exchange rate is of central importance for economic performance, questions about the functioning of the banking system are pivotal to every economic objective that a society has, questions of the ways in which monetary policy is carried out matter fundamentally for issues of fairness and equity, deflation has emerged as a major issue in many places. What will be the formula in democratic society for preserving the virtues of independent central banks while at the same time allowing for the cooperation of these central banks with elected officials on matters of fundamental import to democracy? That, too, is a question that will have to be answered in this generation. 136 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL And so, Stan, it is my fervent hope and it is my great conviction that your contributions to monetary economics and monetary practice are no more than half over as you leave the Bank of Israel, and it is my hope that freed from the daily preoccupation, among the many things that you would do, along with the great rest, relaxation and time with your family that you deserve, that you will provide us answers to these questions and the even better questions that you could pose. On behalf of all of us, thank you for a job extraordinarily well done. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 137 HEZI (EZEKIEL) KALO Distinguished guests, Good afternoon. I am very moved, and I consider myself fortunate to chair the final part of this Farewell Conference honoring Governor Fischer. However, before I invite Governor Fischer to present the concluding address, I would like—with your permission, Stan—to say a few personal words of farewell at this prestigious forum. I first met Stanley when I was a candidate for the post of Director General of the Bank of Israel. This was five years ago, the first days of the global financial crisis and the collapse of Lehman Brothers. What struck me then, and still does, was that Stanley found time during the crisis to discuss my role, and internal problems faced by the Bank of Israel. Over the course of my career, I have worked with many managers in different sectors of the country. You, Stan, are the first, and the only, one that I can call a powerhouse. Stan, you are a rare and special blend of unique professional abilities and charming personality—a real "mensch". We have developed a special relationship, based on immense mutual trust. We heard earlier about the reform at the Bank of Israel, with the establishment of the Supervisory Council and the Monetary Committee. There is no doubt that this historic process, led by Governor Fischer, could not have taken place if not for his vision and his willingness to sacrifice parts of his authority in order to allow us to set corporate governance at the Bank of Israel. Stan, you have transformed the Bank of Israel into a leading central bank in the world. In accordance with the vision of the Riksbank, the Swedish central bank, we are really now “among the best”. It is not for me to comment now on Stanley’s economic leadership, but I can definitely say that during Stan’s terms of service, our technological infrastructure was improved very impressively. Governor Fischer has promoted and made a priority of business continuity and disaster recovery planning, including countering cyber threats. And now a special word for you, Rhoda. I will conclude with expressing my warmest appreciation and gratitude to Rhoda, who took part so remarkably in life in Israel, and contributed significantly, through her volunteer work and devoted efforts, to promoting numerous social causes. Thank you, Rhoda. Rhoda and Stan, I wish you much success in the future and all the best. It is now my honor and pleasure to call upon Stanley Fischer for the concluding address. Thank you, Stan. 138 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 139 CONCLUDING ADDRESS STANLEY FISCHER36 It is a pleasure and an honor for me to deliver this concluding speech. It is also difficult, for three reasons. First, I am about to leave the Bank of Israel, after eight wonderful years – wonderful not in the sense that every minute was a pleasure, but rather that we in the Bank had the opportunity over these past eight years to contribute to the economy and to the wellbeing of the people of Israel – and I believe we did that successfully and in a positive spirit that made our work fulfilling and rewarding. That means that I will leave the Bank with the most mixed of feelings. Second, I have been sitting here for a whole day listening to visitors and Bank members speaking well of the Bank and of me. I am grateful to all of you for agreeing to take part in this conference, for your excellent papers and speeches, and for your kind words. But – now I have to return to the real world. And third, there are so many people that I want to thank, that if I thanked them all, I would not have time enough to talk about the main focus of this speech – which is the topic of the conference, “The New Bank of Israel”. So I shall not mention by name almost all the people to whom I am extremely grateful for their advice, assistance, and support. Let me start by saying that whatever successes the Bank of Israel has achieved in the period I have had the honor of being Governor, were built on the foundation of a strong professional staff. That staff was seen at its best during the global crisis. During the crisis we had to do a lot of things we hadn’t done before. We had thought about some of them, we had prepared for crises, as is essential, but still you never fully anticipate what will happen in practice. The management and top professionals of the Bank worked in an exemplary way in dealing with the very difficult issues we had to confront. I would like to thank them and all the workers of the Bank for their work during the crisis and in more normal times. No institution is an island unto itself, especially in Israel, and we owe thanks also to colleagues in other institutions – starting with the Prime Minister’s office under Ariel Sharon, Ehud Olmert, and Benjamin Netanyahu respectively. In addition we generally cooperated closely with the Treasury and the six or seven Ministers of Finance with whom we worked over the past eight years.37 In working on the new Bank of Israel law and on other laws we interacted closely with the Ministry of Justice. We appeared frequently in the Knesset, and met often with members of the Knesset. And we were in continual contact with the private sector, 36 This is an edited version of the concluding speech that I presented at the Bank of Israel Conference “The New Bank of Israel” held on June 18, 2013. In editing the speech, I have tried to retain the tone of the original, while making the text more linear and less discursive. 37 I say “six or seven” because one Finance Minister (Ehud Olmert) served as Finance Minister twice. 140 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL with the hi-tech and the traditional sectors, with the Arab and ultra-Orthodox sectors, with charities and schools and universities, and with members of the armed forces. From them we learned the depth of the talent and dedication of so many people in this amazing country. I am grateful to them for showing me aspects of Israel that I had never seen before – and Rhoda and I are grateful to the public for the warmth with which we were treated from the very beginning to today, from May 2005 through June 2013. I turn now to the new Bank of Israel law. 1. Getting the new law passed The Bank of Israel was set up in 1954, and operated for over fifty years under the law of 1954, in which the Governor made all the policy and administrative decisions, with the advice – but not necessarily the consent – of an advisory council in each area. In 1997, after the then-Governor, Jacob Frenkel, had strongly made the case for modernizing the Bank of Israel law, the then Prime Minister, Benjamin Netanyahu, set up a committee headed by a retired judge, Judge Levin, to recommend a new law. This was the period during which the inflation targeting approach to monetary policy was being developed and implemented in a number of advanced economies. The Levin Committee consulted widely, in Israel and abroad, and presented its report in 1998. The report proposed setting up a Monetary Council, with stable prices as its main goal, and with the subsidiary goal of supporting the other goals of government policy. The report was well received, but despite continuing pressure from Governor Frenkel, the old law remained in place. Before accepting the job of Governor in January 2005, I received assurances from the then Prime Minister (Ariel Sharon) and the then Finance Minister (Benjamin Netanyahu) that they would support the passage of a new Bank of Israel law, broadly along the lines set out in the Levin Report. I took office in May 2005, expecting that it would take two to three years to pass the new law. The negotiations turned out to be far more arduous and perilous than I had anticipated – especially in light of the assurances I had received – and the new law was passed only in March 2010, a month before the end of my first term. Many people – some of them present today – helped to pass the Bank of Israel Law. The Chairman of the Knesset Finance Committee, Rabbi Moshe Gafni, playing a key role in passing the law through the Knesset. The law would not have been passed without the support of the legal team in the Bank of Israel; it would not have passed without the Bank staff who spent countless hours negotiating with Treasury officials and others; it would not have passed without the support of at least two Prime Ministers, Prime Minister Olmert and Prime Minister Netanyahu, and one critical contribution by Prime Minister Sharon in the short period that I had the privilege of working with him. There was an inherent problem in persuading the Treasury to support a law designed among other things to make the Bank of Israel more independent. The THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 141 problem was that the Treasury officials naturally found it difficult to agree to a variety of changes that would take power away from the Treasury. So I would particularly like to recognize the contribution to the new Bank of Israel law made by the then-Director General of the Treasury, Yossi Bachar, who is here today. I had come to Israel with a naïve notion that I could manage a monetary policy committee on which there would be a minority of central bank members. Several people told me: “Listen, you are not in New Zealand, you are in Israel: forget about having a majority of outside members, it’s not going to work.” But that proposal was in the first draft, which included a proposed monetary policy committee with five members, two insiders and three outsiders. One day Yossi took me aside – Yossi, the Director General of the Treasury, supposed to be leading the charge against us – and said, “Stan, you can’t let that happen. You won’t be able to run the central bank that way”, and we, together with colleagues in the Bank, came up with the current structure of three members from within the Bank and three external members, with a double vote for the Chairman. Yossi, the new law wouldn’t have worked without your violating the code of the mafia or the Treasury as you did – and for that, the Bank of Israel and the economy of Israel are very grateful to you. In addition, it took the cooperation of Ministers of Finance, and Directors General of the Treasury, and the Ministry of Justice and many others to pass the new law. 2. Features of the Law The new Bank of Israel Law is not so new anymore; it was passed in 2010 and came into operation at the end of 2011. As mentioned earlier, the law drew heavily on the report of the Levin Committee, which was formed in 1997 and reported in 1998. That report recommended setting up a Monetary Committee with a structure and goals close to that adopted in 2010. The 2010 version added a Supervisory Council, to supervise the non-policy aspects of the work of the Bank, particularly the budget of the Bank of Israel. The Supervisory Council has seven members, five – including the chairman – from outside the Bank plus the Governor and Deputy Governor. Its audit committee consists of the four outside members who are not the Chairman – the key feature being that there is no member of Bank management on the audit committee. As must be clear from the discussion earlier today with the first Chairman of the Supervisory Council, Dan Propper, I believe that the Supervisory Council is an important addition. It has improved the overall governance of the Bank, and in particular has significantly strengthened budgetary discipline in the central bank. I believe further that the structure of the law is basically sound. We have operated in its framework for 17 months, and while there are aspects we would like to change, there are no major problems with the structure. Consider first the way the members of the Monetary Committee and the Supervisory Council are chosen. The mechanism is by now traditional in Israel: if something non-political has to be done, you set up a committee with a retired judge at its head, either to do it or to 142 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL propose how to do it. This is also the method the new law prescribes for choosing members of the Monetary Committee and the Supervisory Council. The appointments committee has only three members. In addition to the retired (and highly respected) judge at its head, the current committee includes a person from the business sector and an economist. The law sets out criteria the members of the Monetary Committee and the Supervisory Council respectively are required to meet. The committee is expected to consult widely in searching for candidates; in addition people can apply for membership. The committee is required to consult with the Governor, but the Governor does not have a veto on its recommendations. The cabinet either approves or disapproves the slates proposed by the committee; it approved the committee’s recommendations made in 2011 for both the new bodies. The delay of nearly a year and a half between the passing of the law and its provisions going into effect in the Bank of Israel was a result of the length of time it took for the appointments committee to identify and choose candidates for the two committees. In his comments earlier today, Dan Propper, the chair of the Supervisory Council, commended the law for setting out clear criteria for membership of the two new committees, but pointed out that it does not specify criteria for an individual to be qualified to become governor, nor does it specify the process by which the governor is to be chosen. That is a lacuna that needs to be filled. 3. The Monetary Committee The Monetary Committee is the change in the new law that is most visible to markets and to the public. I think it works very well. As everybody in the Bank who took part in the previous interest rate discussions said earlier today, the Monetary Committee works better than the informal consultative committee we used to have. In his presentation, Larry Summers asked some questions about committees. I don’t think the issue is whether someone consults. I consulted in my first five years on the job as governor, when I was in effect an absolute monarch. The issue is whether there is a formal committee, including some outside members who do not report to the governor and are thus likely to be more independent of his views, whose procedures are set out, and whose decisions and the reasons for taking them are presented and explained to the markets and the public. Much of the discussion in the negotiations over the new law focussed on the mandate of the Monetary Committee. The policy mandate is lexicographic on the inflation issue. The law says that the central goal of monetary policy is to maintain the stability of prices, as defined by the government. In writing the law, we had lengthy discussions of whether price stability should be the main or the central or the primary goal of monetary policy. Since my Hebrew wasn’t good enough to detect the critical difference in meaning between these adjectives, I would have been content with any of them. The goal is defined as a range, which for all the THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 143 time I was governor, and also before that, was set by the government at between one and three percent per annum. The second goal, provided the inflation goal is being met, is to support the other goals of government policy, particularly growth and employment. In addition, the Bank of Israel is charged with reducing social gaps, a goal which I think is desirable in Israel, but for which the central bank does not have policy tools. Let me explain how it nonetheless made it into the Bank’s mandate. The procedure in the Knesset Finance Committee was that there was a full discussion of all the clauses of the law, and then after the extensive discussion was done, the Committee was set to vote on each clause of the law. The day of the vote the Chairman of the Finance Committee called me into his office and said “You need to know that no law leaves this committee exactly in the form it arrived”. We discussed the various suggestions that had been made by Committee members, and he concluded by telling me I could choose – either we would be given the goal of reducing social gaps, or the Knesset Finance Committee would insert a clause requiring their approval of the central bank budget. I chose to reduce social gaps, and that was acceptable especially because the Member of the Knesset who pushed for it was talking mainly about the Research Department and its research on poverty, labor markets, education, and other topics relevant to social gaps. The lexicographic ordering could be a problem, if the committee interpreted the inflation target as being one that has to be met at every moment of time. In the profession, that problem was solved by the introduction of flexible inflation targeting, the approach under which if, for whatever reason, the inflation rate is outside the target range, the committee has the flexibility to return inflation gradually to within the range. The law specifies that “gradually” means that the policy chosen by the committee should be expected to return inflation to within the target inflation range within two years. The third part of the mandate is to support the stability of the financial system, a topic to which I will return later. Larry Summers discussed the transparency issue, which is both important and complicated. The problem relates to the publication of minutes. From time to time, particularly in a crisis, the committee may want to discuss ideas which might be very novel or unorthodox. However, if you say something novel or unorthodox in discussion within the Monetary Committee, it will be reflected in the minutes and you are going to start creating problems in the markets – so full transparency in practice constrains discussion and may limit the range of decisions that can be considered. A friend who is on the board of the Fed said that when they discovered they would have to make transcripts of their discussions public within five years, the quality of the discussion changed. He said people showed up with written speeches which they read to their colleagues, and the quality of discussion was reduced because people were worried about what they are going to see in print thereafter. I don’t know what to do about this. One wishes there was a way of 144 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL saying “OK, this is all off the record”, but that is against the principle of transparency. I’m not persuaded that it is optimal to require us to publish everything that we talk about, but that is what was said to us in the Knesset Finance Committee when we raised the issue – “We publish transcripts of everything that we say here, you can publish transcripts of everything you say”. I’d like to mention two incidents in which Meir Sokoler, former Deputy Governor, who is among those present today, was involved. The first is a story from over seven years ago. In those days, even before we had a Monetary Committee, we used to publish an announcement which explained the interest rate decision. I usually worked on that explanation with the then-spokesman of the Bank, Gabi Fiszman, who is also present today. That month I made a decision, and Gabi and I started working on the announcement. The more we thought about it and tried to explain it to each other, the less sense the decision made. I was in charge in those days, so we changed the decision. But we were up against the wire, to get the decision written in time to be announced at the regular time of 6:30 p.m. at which we then announced the monetary policy decision. We did not have enough time to inform the informal advisory committee with which I then worked of the change in the decision. The rumor I heard, Meir, was that you were less than pleased to be surprised at the interest rate decision while you were driving home after helping make the opposite decision. I apologize. The point is not primarily that I’m apologizing, but that having to write down your decision and the reasons for it is a very valuable discipline on decision making. We are subject to that discipline now that we have a Monetary Committee. We discuss the decision on the first day of the meeting, and usually reach a preliminary decision by the end of that day. On the second day the Bank spokesman brings a draft of the decision, or sometimes drafts of two possible decisions, and the committee sits down and gets to work on rethinking the decision, on its explanation, and on the wording of the explanation. A lot of work goes into getting the wording right. That is appropriate, for we have to explain ourselves to market participants and the public, and in so doing we try to make sure that what we are doing makes sense, and that it will make sense to those who read or listen to it. Now for the second story. I frequently think of what we are doing in our lengthy discussions of the state of the economy before making an interest rate decision as being like looking at a pointillist painting, and trying to figure out what is going on in it. At one of my first meetings, I said this is an unusually uncertain situation, and a very hard decision, let’s wait a month for the situation to clarify, and then decide. Meir responded with this Anna Karenina-like statement: “there will not be less uncertainty next time; it will just be uncertainty about something else, so make the decision”. That was absolutely right, not only because there would be some other uncertainties a month later, but also because there are lags between making a policy decision and the effects of the decision on the economy. This was a topic on which I wrote some of my earliest papers, under titles like “Stabilization Policy and Lags”. Because these lags exist, and may be long, I believe that policy decisions THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 145 need to be made earlier than our natural tendencies suggest, which means that it may occasionally be necessary to reverse a recent decision. 4. Open Issues I want first to raise the issue of whether the Governor can afford occasionally to be in the minority in the Monetary Committee. There are two traditions. When Paul Volcker lost a vote in the Federal Reserve Board, he was weakened. He managed to reverse the vote on the same day, but he was nonetheless weakened. Further, Chairmen of the Open Market Committee of the Federal Reserve System do not lose votes. In the Bank of England, Mervyn King said he wanted sometime to be in the minority in the Monetary Policy Committee, and he proceeded to lose more than one vote – in fact, he was in a minority a few times – and he said he was quite happy to be in the minority. This is a difficult issue. I don’t see how you can frequently be in the minority on the key decision of the Bank and continue to represent and recommend the policy of the Bank to the public. I decided that I was prepared to lose very occasionally, but I didn’t want to make a habit of it. We’ve had only 17 decisions since the committee was set up, and I haven’t yet been on the losing side. There was one tie vote where I had the casting vote, and there is one more coming up on Sunday (June 23, 2013). I don’t know whether to make an effort to be in the minority, just so that the precedent is there for other people to feel better about, or not. But I’m sure I’ll vote without worrying about whether to set a precedent of being on the losing side that could be useful to a future governor.38 Second, central bank independence: the new law gives the Bank of Israel a significant degree of independence. But I don’t think that independence is absolute for any central bank. The Bank of Israel law is not in Israeli terms a basic law – a law which has quasi-constitutional standing. Rather, it is a regular law, which the Knesset can change through its normal procedures. As I have frequently told my colleagues, we are one bad decision away from losing our independence. Well, maybe one bad decision would be acceptable, a series of bad decisions would not be. The government would either find a way to fire the Governor, or would change the law. In practice, I have not had a problem over the independence of the central bank. I think I’ve twice received calls in advance advising me what to do on the interest rate. I said that’s very interesting, thank you for calling, and that was the end of the pressure. I have had two or three calls telling me I made a bad decision – possibly that may even have been true.39 38 In the event, I was in the majority in the final vote of my period as Governor of the Bank of Israel. 39 The Bank of Israel does not have independence in the setting of salaries of its employees. The system is inflexible and I tried in the negotiations over the law to get more flexibility into the wage-setting process. The Bank is subject to the decisions of the 146 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Third, the financial stability issue. Although the Bank of Israel law includes supporting financial stability as the third goal of central bank policy, we did not in 2010 work out in detail how the financial stability function should be dealt with by the Bank. We are fortunate that bank supervision is in the central bank, and therefore when the Bank Supervisor is concerned about the stability of the banking system, which is one of the goals set out in the law governing his office, he can take action. Those who have been following closely the Bank of Israel’s measures directed at strengthening financial stability know that everything we have done in the way of macroprudential supervision has been done by the Bank Supervisor. That is a power we have in the central bank, but there are other supervisors over other parts of the financial system, and Israel has not yet succeeded in setting up a system to coordinate their actions. The country needs to do a better job of coordinating regulation and supervision among the three authorities who operate in this area – the Supervisor of Banks (Bank of Israel), the Head of the Capital Markets, Insurance and Savings Department (Ministry of Finance), and the Chairman of the Israel Securities Authority. There have been many different attempts around the world to figure out the best organizational structure for dealing with financial stability and its coordination among regulators. The most radical approach is that of the United Kingdom, which has set up a Financial Policy Committee (FPC) in the Bank of England, chaired by the Governor, but with a membership that is not identical to that of the Monetary Policy Committee. The FPC can instruct the regulators on the actions they are to take. The external membership of the two committees differ, and in addition, the Treasury has a non-voting representative on the Financial Policy Committee. In the United States, the FSOC (Financial Stability Oversight Council) has a coordinating role, but it cannot instruct a regulatory authority on actions it is required to take – for the regulators are formally independent institutions. I’d like to add one more thing on macroprudential. I don’t think we should continue to use the term “macroprudential”, because the word covers up a host of sins. In the 1960s and 1970s central banks used to intervene in particular markets, sometimes with different interest rates for credit provided to one industry rather than another, and they had a host of regulations applied to different forms of credit – for instance in the United States, Reg Q, Reg W, and other Regs. Gradually those sectoral rules and regulations dropped away until only the short-term interest rate was left. In part, the recently introduced measures in Israel and elsewhere that have been called “macroprudential” – such as maximum loan-to-value ratios, changes in the capital requirements against mortgages, constraints on the share of a mortgage that can be indexed to very short-term interest rates – are a return to the past. government wage supervisor, a Treasury employee. I did not think that was a good arrangement for two agencies which are in Israel, as in many other countries, sometimes in conflict. I believe the Bank needs more flexibility in this area than it currently has – but that is a major topic, not a subject for a speech like this one. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 147 We’ve introduced measures that deal with some unwanted consequences of monetary policy via regulation and supervision and called them “macroprudential”. I believe we should call these measures “financial stability” measures, because our concern is with stability of the financial system, whose importance has once again been driven home to us as a result of what happened with Lehman Brothers. It is sometimes said that the consequences of the failure of Lehman Brothers are unprecedented. However, accounts of the financial crisis associated with the Great Depression often begin “The bank, Creditanstalt, failed in Austria, …” As a student I asked myself, how does the failure of a medium size bank in a small country lead to a global financial crisis. Well, now you can ask how does the failure of a medium size bank in a large country lead to a global recession. The questions are the same. While we may not have the precise mechanisms worked out, we do know that the loss of confidence in financial institutions can be contagious, and devastating. That is something every central banker has to remember, especially when the good times begin to roll again. Fourth, the role of the Governor as the economic advisor to the government: I was concerned before coming to Israel that the Governor’s role as economic adviser to the government could create a conflict of interest – possibly that in seeking to get close to the Prime Minister, the governor might open a path for too much government influence on monetary policy. I discussed this problem with a few friends in different countries and one of them said to me, “Stop being a purist. The question is will it be useful – will you be helping the country if you and future governors are defined as the economic advisor to the government?” He thought it would be useful, and on the whole, I thought he was right. Another argument in favor of keeping the governor-as-economic-adviser role came from a committee we set up to examine the Research Department of the Bank. The committee was headed by Larry Meyer, with Marty Eichenbaum, Elhanan Helpman and Philip Lane of Trinity College, Dublin as the other members. They came here opposed to the economic advisor role. They ended up supporting it for a reason I hadn’t thought about at all. They said they were surprised by how this particular role motivated the Research Department; they said that researchers felt their work was more important and more worth doing because it was part of the public discourse on economic policy. The committee said that this didn’t cause any difficulty and was a good motivator of the Research Department and of the Bank of Israel. I don’t know whether this function will survive forever, but it certainly has outlived my expectations, and I guess it will continue to be part of the law of the Bank of Israel. Finally: do we have a reasonable central bank law? What changes would we make if we could completely rewrite the law?40 Fundamentally, the law of the 40 As is inevitable with any law, some details of the law need changing after we have seen how they have worked in practice. I am not here discussing those technical and relatively small changes, rather I am talking about the general approach of the new law. 148 THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL Bank of Israel provides a framework for a sensible flexible inflation targeting approach to monetary policy. The flexible part is essential, for I do not believe that any central bank ever was a pure inflation targeter – and I include the Bundesbank in that. I do not think any central bank ever believed that it doesn’t matter to me what happens to the level of output, so long as inflation stays on target. Nor did they behave that way. That issue was formally addressed by the invention of flexible inflation targeting. I think the framework we have is a reasonable one, I’m not sure whether lexicographic preferences will survive but I think they should, provided you understand that you may want to be away from the inflation target for some time. Our law says two years, but I’m sure a succession of negative disturbances to output would justify more than two years. I believe flexible inflation targeting will survive, but there is no question that it is among the issues that we are going to have to contend with in the years ahead. We also have to work on getting the right organizational framework for dealing with financial stability. We have to understand systemic interactions among financial institutions, and among the different classes of financial institutions, and that is work which my successor certainly is going to have to take on. 5. Farewell I don’t want to conclude by saying goodbye to everybody right now. I do want to conclude by saying again that it was a privilege to be given this job, an unexpected privilege. There was no point in my adult life when I expected I would be Governor of the Bank of Israel. Then one day the offer came up, when, on a quiet Caribbean evening, I received a phone call from the then finance minister, the current Prime Minister, Benjamin Netanyahu. Rhoda and I had always wanted to do something positive for Israel, and this unique opportunity was offered to us. I knew it was unique: finance ministers don’t call you every day to suggest becoming the Governor of their central bank. So we said yes, opening the way to a wonderful experience. I said at the beginning that I could not thank everyone by name and so would not start doing that. But I do want to thank those members of management and staff with whom I worked most closely over the last few years: Karnit Flug, Deputy Governor, quiet, intellectually tough, never afraid to state her views, always willing to take on critical tasks; Hezi Kalo, the Director General, a man whom I and everyone trusts, a prodigious worker, whose work and presence have stabilized the Bank; Eddy Azoulay, my Chief of Staff, who is a miracle of quiet efficiency and effectiveness; and the office team, Ronit Cohen, Sharona Cooperman, and Metzada Shamir, with whom it has been a pleasure to work. Every one of these people works with remarkable efficiency and remarkable pleasantness. To them, to my other colleagues in management, to everyone with whom we worked: thank you for everything you have done for your colleagues and for the Bank of Israel. THE NEW BANK OF ISRAEL 149 Finally, I want to thank Rhoda, without whose steadfast support I would not have been able to do this job. This was sometimes not easy for her, but like me, she would not have missed this experience for the world. Thank you for everything you have done, and for everything we mean to each other. Thank you all.