Benefit-Cost Analysis
Transcription
Benefit-Cost Analysis
Benefit-Cost Analysis Downeaster Service Optimization Project FY2014 TIGER Discretionary Grant Program April 25, 2014 Northern New England Passenger Rail Authority Patricia Quinn, Executive Director 75 West Commercial Street Suite 104 Portland, Maine 04101-4631 Tel 207.780.1000 x105 pat ricia@nnepra.com Northern New England Passenger Rail Authority Downeaster Optimization Project 1 Downeaster Service Optimization Project Benefit-Cost Analysis Prepared for the Northern New England Passenger Rail Authority May 31, 2013 1 Contents Executive Summary ................................................................................................................................. 4 Introduction ............................................................................................................................................ 7 Analytical Assumptions............................................................................................................................ 7 Discount Rates ..................................................................................................................................... 7 Evaluation Period ................................................................................................................................ 7 Annualizing Factor Assumptions .......................................................................................................... 8 Project Region ..................................................................................................................................... 8 Travel Demand Sources and Forecast Years for Highway Benefits ........................................................ 8 PRISMTM .................................................................................................................................................. 9 Economic Benefits Included ..................................................................................................................... 9 Economic Competitiveness .................................................................................................................. 9 Travel Time Savings ......................................................................................................................... 9 Induced Ridership Benefits ............................................................................................................ 11 Reductions in Vehicle Operating Costs ........................................................................................... 13 Oil Import Costs ............................................................................................................................. 15 Safety ................................................................................................................................................ 15 Accident Cost Savings .................................................................................................................... 15 Sustainability ..................................................................................................................................... 18 Emissions....................................................................................................................................... 18 Noise Pollution .............................................................................................................................. 20 State of Good Repair ......................................................................................................................... 21 Economic Costs Included and Assumptions............................................................................................ 22 Capital Costs ...................................................................................................................................... 22 Annual Operating and Maintenance Costs ......................................................................................... 22 Residual Value ................................................................................................................................... 22 Key Benefit-Cost Evaluation Measures................................................................................................... 23 Sensitivity Analysis............................................................................................................................. 23 Benefit-Cost Analysis Results ................................................................................................................. 23 Results in Brief................................................................................................................................... 23 Benefits by Category.......................................................................................................................... 24 2 Costs over Time ................................................................................................................................. 25 Cumulative Benefits and Costs ........................................................................................................... 26 APPENDIX A - PRISMTM Sensitivity Analysis ............................................................................................ 28 APPENDIX B - Benefit-Cost Model Detail Tables ..................................................................................... 33 APPENDIX C – Monetization Values and Ranges Used in PRISM™ Sensitivity Analysis ............................ 38 3 Executive Summary A benefit-cost analysis (BCA) was conducted for the Downeaster Service Optimization Project (“Project”) for submission to the U.S. Department of Transportation (U.S. DOT) as a requirement of a discretionary grant application for the TIGER V program. The analysis was conducted in accordance with the benefitcost methodology as recommended by the U.S. DOT in the Federal Register (77 Fed. Reg. 4863) and conducted for a 30-year analysis period after operations begin in 2016. The Downeaster Service Optimization Project includes three elements which will collectively enhance the performance of Downeaster service between Brunswick, Maine and Boston, Massachusetts. The major elements of the project are: A layover facility to improve servicing of trains which will overnight in Brunswick. A siding to provide capacity to support the operation of five round trips daily between Brunswick and Boston. A connecting “wye” track to eliminate back-up movement for trains traveling between Portland and Brunswick. The overall cost of the project is expected to be $29.5 million in undiscounted 2012 dollars (Table 1). At a 7 percent discount rate, the total costs are $26.4 million. While at a 3 percent discount rate, the total costs are $28.1 million in total. Table 1 Downeaster Service Optimization Project Capital Costs Capital Cost Costs (2012 $) Costs (2012 $ discounted at 7 %) Costs (2012 $ discounted at 3 %) Total $29,500,000 $26,367,659 $28,084,646 Source: Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 Operations and maintenance costs are projected to total an average of $1.16 million per year. Over the entire 30-year analysis period these costs accumulate to $34.9 million in undiscounted 2012 dollars; $11.6 million when discounted at 7 percent; or $20.86 million when discounted at 3 percent. In real 2012 dollars, the Project creates $58.9 million in present value benefits when discounted at 7 percent or $120.8 million when discounted at 3 percent. It does so, generally by decreasing travel times and shifting intercity trips previously taken by automobile to train. The overall project benefit matrix can be seen in Table 2. 4 Table 2: Downeaster Service Optimization Project Impact and Benefits Matrix Population Affected by Impact Economic Benefit Summary of Results (at 7% discount rate) Railroad ‘Wye’ Track, Layover Facility & Siding Auto drivers who switch modes Fuel Savings $4.9 million $9.7 million pg 13 Railroad ‘Wye’ Track, Layover Facility & Siding Auto drivers who switch modes Travel Time Savings $37.3 million $76.1 million pg 9 Railroad ‘Wye’ Track, Layover Facility & Siding Society Oil import Savings $448,100 $892,800 pg 15 Railroad ‘Wye’ Track, Layover Facility & Siding Auto drivers who switch modes Non-Fuel O&M Savings $6.0 million $12.6 million pg 13 Railroad ‘Wye’ Track, Layover Facility & Siding New induced riders Consumer Surplus $5.6 million $11.1 million pg 11 Railroad ‘Wye’ Track, Layover Facility & Siding Society and surrounding communities Reductions in Emissions $551,100 $1.2 million pg 18 Railroad ‘Wye’ Track, Layover Facility & Siding All drivers in study region and society Reductions in Accidents $4.0 million $8.4 million pg 15 Railroad ‘Wye’ Track, Layover Facility & Siding Surrounding communities Reductions in Noise $51,800 $108,700 pg 20 Railroad ‘Wye’ Track, Layover Facility & Siding Government and society Reductions in Pavement Damages $51,800 $108,700 pg 21 Type of Impact Source: Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 The overall Project impacts can be seen in 5 Summary of Results (at 3% discount rate) Page Reference in BCA Table 3, which shows the magnitude of change and direction of the various impact categories. There are reductions in both VHT and VMT, as well as in fuel consumption, oil imports, emissions, and safety incidents. Table 3: Project Impacts for Downeaster Service Optimization Project Cumulative 2016-2044 Category Quantity Vehicle-miles traveled (VMT) 159.2 million Vehicle-hours traveled (VHT) 5.4million Induced Ridership Benefits (2012 $ undiscounted) $22.3 million Fuel consumed (gal.) 5.1 million Oil imported (gal.) 4.9 million Fatalities (number) 1.7 Injury accidents (number) 1.2 Property damage only accidents (number) 1.0 CO2 Emissions (tons) 59,400 NOX emissions (tons) 15 PM 10 7.5 (tons) 0.6 SOX (tons) 13.5 VOC (tons) Source: Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 Table 4 below shows the overall results of the BCA. At a 7 percent discount rate, the Project yields a benefit-cost ratio of 1.55 over a 30 year analysis period; and using a 3 percent discount rate the benefitcost ratio is 2.47. Table 4: Benefit Cost Analysis Summary Results Scenario Net Present Value (2012 $ millions disc.) Benefit Cost Ratio Case A (7 percent discount rate) $20.8 1.55 Case B (3 percent discount rate) $71.9 2.47 Source: Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 Sensitivity tests were conducted utilizing a range of valuations for benefit categories and impacts using the Parsons Brinckerhoff Regional Impact Scenario Model, PRISM™ (described on page 3). While the results displayed are the baseline and most likely numbers, further statistical analysis was conducted to meet U.S. DOT’s recommendations of a thorough sensitivity analysis. Using PRISM™ sensitivity analysis, it was found that there is over a 99 percent probability of the benefitcost ratio exceeding 1.0 at a either a 7 or 3 percent discount rate. 6 Introduction In accordance with the benefit-cost methodology as recommended by the U.S. DOT in the Guide to Preparing Benefit-Cost Analyses for TIGER Grants and the Notice of funding availability (77 Fed. Reg. 4863) 1 a BCA was conducted for the Downeaster Service Optimization Project. This BCA was done for submission to the U.S. Department of Transportation (U.S. DOT) as a requirement of a discretionary grant application for the TIGER V program. The analysis was conducted using a 30-year analysis period after operations begin in 2016. Analytical Assumptions Discount Rates For project investments, dollar figures in this analysis are expressed in constant 2012 dollars. In instances where certain cost estimates or benefit valuations were expressed in dollar values in other (historical) years, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics’ Consumer Price Index for Urban Consumers (CPI-U) was used to adjust them to 2012 dollars. 2 The real discount rates used for this analysis were 3.0 and 7.0 percent, consistent with U.S. DOT guidance for TIGER V grants 3 and OMB Circular A-4.4. Evaluation Period For the Downeaster Service Optimization Project, the evaluation period includes the relevant (postdesign) construction period during which capital expenditures are undertaken, plus 30 years of operations beyond the project completion within which to accrue benefits. For the purposes of this study, it has been assumed that construction of the project began as early as 2013, and finish in 2016. The analysis period, therefore, begins with the first expenditures in 2013 and continues through 30-years of operations from 2017 to 2044. All benefits and costs are assumed to occur at the end of each year, and benefits begin in the calendar year immediately following the final construction year. 1 TIGER 2013 NOFA: Benefit-Cost Analysis Guidance, Updated May 3, 2013; http://www.dot.gov/policyinitiatives/tiger/tiger-2013-nofa-benefit-cost-analysis-guidance 2 U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Consumer Price Index, All Urban Consumers, U.S. City Average, Motor Fuel. Series CUUR0000SETB. 1982-1984=100 3 TIGER 2013 NOFA: Benefit-Cost Analysis Guidance, Updated May 3, 2013; http://www.dot.gov/policyinitiatives/tiger/tiger-2013-nofa-benefit-cost-analysis-guidance 4 White House Office of Management and Budget, Circular A-94, Guidelines and Discount Rates for Benefit-Cost Analysis of Federal Programs (October 29, 1992). (http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/circulars_a094). 7 Annualizing Factor Assumptions Travel demand models produce outputs on daily or sub-daily basis. An annualization factor is thus necessary to convert the travel demand outputs into to yearly values. The travel demand model indicates an annualizing factor of 300. Project Region The geographic coverage of this analysis is the Downeaster corridor of 146 miles which runs from Boston, Massachusetts to Brunswick, Maine. While most impacts are within this study corridor, the scope of this BCA is at the national level, incorporating benefits and costs to all of society regardless of geographic location. Travel Demand Sources and Forecast Years for Highway Benefits The layover facility in Brunswick will eliminate the need for deadhead moves between Portland and Brunswick, and along with the Royal Siding junction, will provide the support necessary to increase Downeaster service between Brunswick and Boston to five round trips daily. The “wye” track will eliminate unproductive back-up movement for trains traveling between Portland and Brunswick, and will decrease trip times by 10 minutes. The Layover facility is expected to contribute to nearly 22,000 new riders in its first year of operations. The Royal Junction contributes over 40,000 new annual riders in its first year of operations, while the Wye contributes an additional 8,000 new riders. The following table shows the total projected ridership levels for the project. The existing ridership base is the ridership that would exist under a “no build” scenario. Additional ridership comes from those who shift modes from automobile, as well as new trips that are induced. Table 5: Ridership Forecasts for the Downeaster Service Optimization Project Total Ridership (annual riders) Existing Ridership Base Ridership from Auto Shift Other Induced Ridership 2016 587,384 599,188 19,147 14,444 2020 823,957 694,623 73,720 55,614 2030 1,219,657 1,028,212 109,124 82,322 2040 1,805,391 1,522,004 161,530 121,856 Source: NNEPRA, 2013; (Extrapolation done by Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 based on NNEPRA ridership estimates) Northern New England Passenger Rail Authority (NNEPRA) estimates that of the new ridership, 57 percent will have shifted from autos and the remaining 43 percent are newly induced riders. NNEPRA also provided forecasts of ridership through year 2020, with growth ranging around 4 percent per year through 2020. This same 4 percent figure was utilized for forecasts beyond 2020. The average trip length along this route is 82 miles. In addition to the assumptions about travel demand data listed above, this analysis utilizes PRISM™ sensitivity analysis to test a +/- 10 percent sensitivity on all travel demand figures. 8 PRISMTM This benefit cost analysis was done using PRISMTM (http://prism.pbworld.net/), a benefit cost analysis tool that uses a methodology consistent with the most recent guidelines developed by U.S. DOT. The tool determined benefits according to the following five categories: State of Good Repair; Economic Competitiveness; Livability; Sustainability; and Safety. In addition, PRISM’s risk analysis capabilities (using Monte Carlo simulations) provided statistically derived ‘high’ and ‘low’ scenarios for the benefit cost ratio – e.g., 95% confident that the benefit cost ratio will fall between X and Y. PRISMTM is designed to take into account the difficulty in determining the “true value” of a given impact by allowing for a range of per unit values: low likely and high. The range established by the low, likely and high values allow PRISMTM to run Monte Carlo simulations, which create a probability distribution function. The probability distribution functions are created according to the function described in the Beta distribution.5 Details of the distribution as it is employed in PRISM™ are found in the betaPert (Open Pert) documentation, which uses the modified PERT distribution, a type of Beta distribution. 6 Economic Benefits Included The following identifies and groups the benefits that are included in the BCA for the Downeaster Service Optimization Project. This section discusses the valuations used for each benefit category. More detailed summary of all valuations as used in PRISM™ sensitivity analysis, with statistical details, are available in Appendix C. Economic Competitiveness Travel Time Savings Travel time savings includes in-vehicle travel time savings for auto drivers and passengers. Travel time is considered a cost to users, and its value depends on the disutility that travelers attribute to time spent traveling. A reduction in travel time would translate into more time available for work, leisure, or other activities. Value of Time Assumptions Travel time savings must be converted from hours to dollars in order for benefits to be aggregated and compared against costs. This is performed by assuming that travel time is valued as a percentage of the average wage rate, with different percentages assigned to different trip purposes (Table 6). Because the Downeaster Service Optimization Project consists of Amtrak ridership with an average passenger trip length of over 82 miles, the values for intercity surface travel are used. 5 http://www.itl.nist.gov/div898/handbook/eda/section3/eda366h.htm 6 http://code.google.com/p/openpert/downloads/detail?name=openpert_reference_guide.pdf 9 Values are broken down as low, medium and high for use in PRISMTM sensitivity analysis based on the percentages in Table 7, as recommended by U.S. DOT. 7 Table 6: U.S. DOT Recommended Values of Time, 2012; (per person-hour as a percentage of total earnings) Surface Modes (Except High-Speed Rail) Low Likely High Category Local Travel Personal Business 35% 80% 50% 100% 60% 120% Source: Office of the Secretary of Transportation, 2011. Values of time used for 2012 are as follows: Table 7: U.S. DOT Recommended Values of Time, 2012 Values of time (2012 U.S $ per person-hour) Low Category Surface (except High-Speed Rail) Intercity Travel Personal Business All Purposes $21.20 $26.97 $22.44 Values of time (2012 U.S $ per person-hour) Likely Values of time (2012 U.S $ per person-hour) High $24.73 $33.71 $26.66 $31.80 $40.46 $33.65 Source: Office of the Secretary of Transportation, 2011. Because the exact division between personal and business travel is not known for trips potentially impacted by this project, the values of time for “all purposes” are used; these represent a weighted average of the personal and business values of time according to national proportions of personal and business as calculated by the U.S. DOT.8 Additionally, U.S. DOT guidance accepts the use of a real growth rate of 1.6 percent a year for the value of time.9 This real growth rate was thus applied for values of time in the years after 2012. To account for real wage growth, the value of time used in this analysis is the average value, in real 2012 dollars, 7 Office of the Secretary of Transportation. (2011). Revised Departmental Guidance: Valuation of Travel Time in Economic Analysis, p. 11-12. (http://ostpxweb.dot.gov/policy/reports/vot_guidance_092811c.pdf) 8 Ibid. 9 Office of the Secretary of Transportation. (2011). Revised Departmental Guidance: Valuation of Travel Time in Economic Analysis, p. 14. (http://ostpxweb.dot.gov/policy/reports/vot_guidance_092811c.pdf) 10 across the time period of the analysis, from 2017-2036. This will overestimate the cost in the short term but will underestimate it in the long term balancing this effect out. Average Vehicle Occupancy Since some passengers who ride the new rail service would come off of the roadway network, thus switching from auto to rail, it is necessary to estimate how many automobiles those riders would otherwise represent. This analysis assumes an average vehicle occupancy (AVO) rate of 1.71 persons per vehicle for all trips. This AVO rate is consistent with the one from the National Household Travel Survey 2009’s data for Maine for all trips.10 Induced Ridership Benefits Not all the new passengers will be shifting from automobiles. (See Table 5) Some (approximately 43 percent) will be individuals who were not making the trip previously, but because of the improvements to the Downeaster line, are now choosing to travel. While the nominal cost of the trip or the fare has not changed, the ‘generalized cost’ of the trip has been lowered through the reduction in travel times, increased frequency, and other possible intangibles. These induced riders receive benefits that are not captured in travel time calculations or reductions in costs due to mode shift. (See Figure 1 below) 10 Federal Highway Administration. (2009). National Household Travel Survey (Online Database). From U.S. Department of Transportation. (http://nhts.ornl.gov/tools.shtml) 11 Figure 1 Induced Ridership Benefits Due to Reduction in Generalized Costs Costs Previous Consumer Surplus/Benefits Travel Time Savings for Existing Riders C1 C2 Existing Ridership Increased Ridership Ridership Benefits to new Riders (includes induced riders) Source: Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 Figure 1 above illustrates a general demand curve for ridership given a generalized cost model. Generalized costs refer to all costs a rider incurs, including his or her fare, travel time, wait time, comfort, convenience, and other intangibles. This project is expected to reduce generalized costs in three ways: reducing overall travel times, increasing frequencies of service, and providing more convenience for passengers. This reduction in generalized cost can be seen as moving down from the original generalized cost, C1, to the new generalized cost, C2. In doing so, there are travel time savings to existing users, which have already been captured. The additional benefits are captured in the small triangle (indicated as benefits to new riders). Some of the new riders come from auto, and those benefits are captured in this BCA as reductions in fuel and auto O&M costs. The induced riders that are captured in this triangle are those riders that, but for the reduction in generalized costs (including reduced time, more comfort and convenience, and increased service frequency and access) as a result of the project, otherwise would not have made the trip. It is assumed that the reduction in generalized cost (the average per trip benefit) is only minimally reflected in the travel time savings. 12 Other cost savings (i.e., benefits) associated with the improved service, such as convenience and comfort, as well as easy access to rail service due to increased train frequencies, are less tangible and less easily monetized than the rail travel time reduction. Those costs, in addition to line haul travel time, are assumed to have strongly influenced induced riders’ decision not to utilize the current rail system. By also reducing wait times through reduced headways, and increasing rider convenience and comfort, induced ridership gains are substantial, and the per trip benefit is minimally measured by their fare payment. In total, the induced ridership benefit was assumed to be indicative of a change in generalized cost equal to 4 times the average travel time savings of passengers. This value is intended to serve as a proxy for all the benefits that new riders receive as discussed in this section. Finally, induced ridership benefits were monetized using the same value of time assumptions for travel time savings previously discussed. Reductions in Vehicle Operating Costs Vehicles have operating costs beyond fuel costs that will be addressed in this report. These costs include maintenance and repair, replacement of tires, and the depreciation of the vehicle over time. The per VMT factors of these costs were estimated by a Minnesota DOT study, 11 and used in this analysis (see Table 8 below). Since the original study estimated the likely range for these values in 2003 dollars, the values for this analysis have been updated to 2012 dollars using a CPI adjustment.12 Table 8: Non-Fuel Vehicle O&M Costs Automobile Cost Category Maintenance / Repair Tires Depreciation Total Automobile (2012 $ / VMT) Low 0.0399 0.0112 0.0774 0.1285 Automobile (2012 $ / VMT) Likely 0.0474 0.0112 0.0923 0.1509 Automobile (2012 $ / VMT) High 0.0499 0.0137 0.0973 0.1609 Source: Minnesota Department of Transportation, 2003; Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 Vehicle Operating Costs Fuel Fuel Prices Fuel efficiency values were derived from the U.S. Energy Information Administration (EIA), which provides estimates for the of fuel efficiency through 2035. The values used to calculate fuel efficiency 11 Minnesota Department of Transportation. (2003). The Per-mile Costs of Operating Automobiles and Trucks. (MN/RC 2003-19), p.22, Table 4.2. (http://www.lrrb.org/pdf/200319.pdf). 12 Bureau of Labor Statistics, Consumer Price Index, All Urban Consumers, US City Average, All Items, Series CUSR0000SA0. 13 can be found in the table published by EIA titled “Transportation Sector Key Indicators and Delivered Energy Consumption.”13 The following fuel efficiency values were used for the different vehicle classes: “Light Duty Stock” energy efficiency (mpg) for passenger vehicles. Table 9: Fuel Efficiency (miles per gallon) EIA reference Case Fuel Type Automobiles (Light Duty stock) 2012 20.89 2020 24.08 2030 31.33 2040 35.10 2050 42.37 Source: U.S. Energy Information Administration, 2013; Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 Because fuel taxes are considered a pecuniary benefit, or transfer payment, they cannot be accurately included in benefit calculations of a BCA. Thus, the federal and state taxes estimated by the EIA are subtracted out of the end user fuel prices. The EIA provides of low, likely, and high estimates of fuel prices through 2040; however the analysis period relevant for this project stretches beyond this timeframe and thus estimated fuel prices in those future years are also necessary. In order to do estimate fuel prices that extend beyond 2040, the compound annual growth rate (CAGR) for 2011-2040 was calculated and then used to continue the series through the end of the analysis period. All dollars were reported in real 2011 dollars by the EIA. These dollar amounts were subsequently converted to real 2012 dollars using the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Consumer Price Index adjustment for “motor fuel” between 2011 and 2012.14 The following table provides the range of fuel prices, in real 2012 dollars, and a breakdown of values used for PRISMTM sensitivity analysis, for selected years. Table 10: Fuel Prices (real 2012 $ / gallon) Fuel Type Motor Gasoline Low Motor Gasoline Likely Motor Gasoline High 2012 $3.16 $3.16 $3.16 2020 $2.29 $3.02 $4.01 2030 $2.29 $3.40 $4.66 2040 $2.37 $4.09 $5.66 2050 $2.23 $4.32 $6.45 Source: U.S. Energy Information Administration, 2013; Parsons Brinckerhoff,2013 13 Energy Information Administration. (2012). Annual Energy Outlook 2012 Early Release. Components of Selected Petroleum Product Prices, United States, Reference case. [Microsoft Excel] (http://www.eia.gov/oiaf/aeo/tablebrowser/) 14 U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Consumer Price Index, All Urban Consumers, U.S. City Average, Motor Fuel. Series CUUR0000SETB. 1982-1984=100, 2010=240.724; 2011=301.448 14 To account for change in the cost of fuel overtime, this analysis used the average fuel cost across the time period of the analysis, from 2017-2036, for each fuel type. This will overestimate the cost in the short term but will underestimate it in the long term balancing this effect out. Oil Import Costs Fuel consumption has a cost beyond the actual operating costs and environmental costs of the consumption, and this additional cost is expressed as the economic cost of oil imports. This concept reflects two ideas: a monopsony component and a price shock component. The monopsony component derives from the following logic; because the U.S. is such a large consumer of oil an increase in U.S. demand for oil will lead to higher fuel prices (based on supply and demand relationships). The price shock component comes from the fact that when there is a reduction in oil supplies this leads to higher oil prices which in turn reduce the level of U.S. economic output. As a consequence, reducing oil imports by consuming less fuel reduces the impact of these costs on the U.S. economy. The National Highway Traffic and Safety Administration discusses this concept, and estimates that each gallon of fuel saved reduces total U.S. imports of refined fuel or crude oil by 0.95 gallons. 15 The likely value for NHTSA’s estimate of the per-gallon cost of oil imports (both the monopsony and price shock components combined) is $0.285 per gallon (2005 $). When converted to 2012 dollars using the CPI adjustment,16 this value is $0.328 per gallon (2012 $). For the range of values estimated by NHTSA as adjusted to 2012 dollars, see Table 11. Table 11: Cost of Oil Imports Cost of Oil Imports (2012 $) Low Likely High $0.134 $0.328 $0.562 Source: NHSTA 2009, Parsons Brinckerhoff 2013 Safety Accident Cost Savings The BCA assumes constant accident rates for the “build” and “no build” scenarios. As a result, any changes in the number of accidents will be a result of changes in VMT, not of structural changes to the safety conditions on the roadway network. 15 National Highway Traffic and Safety Administration. (2009). Corporate Average Fuel Economy for MY 2011 Passenger Cars and Light Trucks, Final Regulatory Impact Analysis, p.viii-22 – viii-27. 16 Bureau of Labor Statistics, Consumer Price Index, All Urban Consumers, US City Average, All Items, Series CUSR0000SA0. 15 The cost savings that could arise from a reduction in the number of accidents include direct savings (e.g., reduced personal medical expenses, lost wages, and lower individual insurance premiums), as well as significant avoided costs to society (e.g., second party medical and litigation fees, emergency response costs, incident congestion costs, and litigation costs). The value of all such benefits – both direct and societal – could also be approximated by the cost of service disruptions to other travelers, emergency response costs to the region, medical costs, litigation costs, vehicle damages, and economic productivity loss due to workers’ inactivity. However, should the number of accidents increase, this category is no longer cost savings but costs incurred by individuals and society. This BCA estimates the benefits associated with accident cost savings using the most recently available 2009 statewide Maine accident data reported by the National Highway Traffic and Safety Administration.17 The accident figures are statewide averages and represent accidents on interstate highways, state highways, county roads, and arterials. Table 12: Accident Rate Assumptions Category Fatalities Injuries Property Damage Only Accident Rate (per million VMT) 0.0110 0.0079 0.0063 Source: National Highway Traffic and Safety Administration Fatality Analysis Reporting System In order to convert these accident rates into the appropriate AIS scale for calculating benefits, national statistics from the National Highway Traffic and Safety Administration were used. 18 By using the national statistics, it was possible to derive the distribution of total injuries into their respective AIS categories, as indicated in the following table which lists each AIS category as a proportion of all possible injuries Table 13: U.S. AIS Categories as Proportion of All Non-fatal Injuries. Injury Type AIS 5 AIS 4 AIS 3 AIS 2 AIS 1 All Injuries Proportion 0.18% 0.69% 2.39% 8.28% 88.46% 100% Source: NHTSA, Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 17 National Highway Traffic and Safety Administration (2009), Fatality Analysis Reporting System (FARS), Maine, (http://www.nhtsa.gov/FARS). 18 National Highway Traffic Safety Administration (2002), The Economic Impact of Motor Vehicle Crashes, 2000, p. 9, Table 3 “Incidence Summary – 2000 Total Reported and Unreported Injuries.” 16 The following table lists all accident rates as reported for Maine in the NHTSA FARS database, as converted into AIS standards: Table 14: Accident Rates per million VMT in Maine, 2012 Accident Type Fatality AIS 5 AIS 4 AIS 3 AIS 2 AIS 1 Property Damage Only Accident Rate (per 100 million VMT) 0.0110 0.0000 0.0001 0.0002 0.0007 0.0070 0.0063 Source: NHTSA, 2009; Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2012 Monetized values for fatalities, and accidents categorized on the AIS scale are reported in the U.S. DOT’s guidance for “Treatment of the Economic value of a Statistical Life”19 – this includes low and high ranges used for PRISM™ sensitivity analysis. Values pertaining to property damage only accidents were reported by the National Highway Traffic and Safety Administration,20 and have subsequently been updated to 2012 dollars by the U.S. DOT. 21 The following table lists the range of values used for PRISMTM sensitivity analysis for each accident type: Table 15: Monetized Accident Values Accident Type Fatality AIS 5 AIS 4 AIS 3 AIS 2 AIS 1 Property Damage Only Unit Value (2012 $) Low $5,200,000 $3,083,600 $1,383,200 $546,000 $244,400 $15,600 $3,038 Unit Value (2012 $) Likely $9,100,000 $5,396,300 $2,420,600 $955,500 $427,700 $27,300 $3,376 Unit Value (2012 $) High $12,900,000 $7,649,700 $3,341,400 $1,354,500 $606,300 $38,700 $3,713 Source: U.S. DOT, 2008, 2011 and, 2013 update; NHTSA, 2002 19 Office of the Secretary of Transportation, Guidance on Treatment of the Economic Value of a Statistical Life in U.S. Department of Transportation Analyses (2013 update), Guidance on Treatment of the Economic Value of a Statistical Life in U.S. Department of Transportation Analyses. 20 National Highway Traffic Safety Administration (2002), The Economic Impact of Motor Vehicle Crashes, 2000, p. 62, Table 3. 21 U.S. Department of Transportation (2011), Tiger Benefit-Cost Analysis (BCA) Resource Guide, p.3. (http://www.dot.gov/tiger/docs/tiger-12_bca-resourceGuide.pdf). 17 Sustainability Emissions The Downeaster Service Optimization Project will create environmental and sustainability impacts relating to air pollution associated with automobile and commercial truck travel. Five forms of emissions were identified, measured and monetized, including: nitrous oxide, particulate matter, sulfur dioxide, volatile organic compounds, and carbon dioxide. Emission Rates Per-mile emissions rates were derived from the California Department of Transportation’s California Lifecycle Benefit-Cost Analysis Tool (CAL B/C).22 This tool provides emissions rates for exactly two different years: 2011 and 2031. In order to develop emissions rates for years within this interval as well as beyond 2031, it was necessary to use certain growth rate assumptions. Per mile emissions factors differ depending on vehicle, fuel efficiency, average speed, and driving conditions. This BCA used the California Department of Transportation’s emissions factors from the California Life-Cycle Benefit-Cost Analysis Model (Cal B/C)23 which provides emissions factors for automobiles, trucks, and buses at varying speeds, and applies a dynamic model. In general, at slower speeds vehicles emit pollutants at a greater rate. However, since this project does not impact average travel speeds on the highway network, this analysis assumes the emissions rates for automobiles at an average speed of 35 miles per hour. The CAL B/C documentation24 indicates that growth rates for CO, NOX, PM10, and VOC are exponential, so the 2011 to 2031 compound annual growth rate (CAGR) was used to interpolate and extrapolate as necessary. Growth for SOX and CO2 were shown by CAL B/C to exhibit linear growth. Thus, a linear rate is used for these two emissions categories. Finally, after 2031, emissions rates are assumed “flat-line.” The flat-line represents both a leveling out of emissions rates, as well as a prudent observation of the uncertainty in estimating rates that far into the future. The following tables show per-mile emissions rates at 35 mph for select years: 22 California Department of Transportation (2010) California Life-cycle Benefit/Cost Analysis Model v4.1 [Microsoft Excel]. http://www.dot.ca.gov/hq/tpp/offices/eab/benefit_files/Cal-BCv4-1.xls 23 California Department of Transportation (2010). California Life-Cycle Benefit-Cost Analysis Mode.. Cal-BCv41.xls. [Microsoft Excel] (http://www.dot.ca.gov/hq/tpp/offices/ote/benefit_files/Cal-BCv4-1.xls). Tab “Parameters”, Cells BG7:CA250. 24 California Department of Transportation. (2009). California Life-cycle Benefit/Cost Analysis Model, Technical Supplement to User's Guide (Vol. 3). Sacramento: California Department of Transportation. 18 Table 16: Auto Emissions Rates (grams per vehicle-mile traveled), assuming 35 mph Emissions Type 2011 0.2672 0.0481 0.0037 0.2231 351.97 NOX PM SOX VOC CO2 2031 0.0767 0.0468 0.0037 0.0701 344.48 Source: California Department of Transportation, 2011; Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 Value of Non-CO2 Emissions Costs The values of PM10 emissions are derived from a report published by the National Cooperative Highway Research Program25. The likely values for NOx, SOx, and VOC were derived from a National Highway Traffic and Safety Administration’s CAFE standards for MY2012-MY2016 26. These are consistent with U.S. DOT guidelines. The remaining low and high values used in PRISMTM sensitivity analysis for non-GHG emissions come from Technical Supplement to the CAL B/C tool27. The resulting values are shown in the Table 17 below. Table 17: Non-CO2 Emissions Costs (2012 $ / metric ton) Emissions Type NOX PM SOX VOC Emissions Costs Low $2,427 $1,635 $14,666 $236 Emissions Costs Likely $ 5,777 $3,584 $ 33,791 $ 1,417 Emissions Costs High $35,737 $8,530 $139,071 $2,427 Source: NHTSA, 2010, Cal-B/C, 2013 Value CO2 Emissions Costs The per-ton costs of carbon emissions were derived from the Interagency Working Group on the Social Cost of Carbon28 as well as the analysis conducted by the U.S. DOT in the Tiger Benefit –Cost Analysis 25 NCHRP Project 08-36, Task 61: Monetary Valuation per Dollar of Investment in Different Performance Measures (2007) http://onlinepubs.trb.org/onlinepubs/nchrp/docs/NCHRP08-36%2861%29_FR.pdf 26 National Highway Traffic and Safety Administration (March 2010), Corporate Average Fuel Economy for MY2012MY2016 Passenger Cars and Light Trucks, page 403, Table VIII-8, “Economic Values for Benefits Computations (2007 Dollars)”, http://www.nhtsa.gov/staticfiles/rulemaking/pdf/cafe/CAFE_2012-2016_FRIA_04012010.pdf 27 California Life-Cycle Benefit/Cost Analysis Model (Cal-B/C) Technical Supplement to the User’s Guide, Chapter 5. http://www.dot.ca.gov/hq/tpp/offices/eab/benefit_files/tech_supp.pdf 19 Resource Guide.29 The values used for this analysis were discounted at a 3 percent rate as recommended by the U.S. DOT. Next the social cost of carbon was converted from 2007 dollars to 2012 dollars using a CPI adjustment.30 Finally, values beyond year 2050 were extrapolated using the compound annual growth rate (CAGR) from 2040 to 2050. The Table 18 below shows the low likely and high social costs of carbon for selected years as used for PRISMTM sensitivity analysis. Low and high values are derived from the same Interagency Working Group study, which reports a range for the social cost of carbon. Table 18: Social Cost of Carbon at 3 percent Discounting (2012 $) Social Cost of CO2 Low Social Cost of CO2 Likely Social Cost of CO2 High 2012 $5.65 $24.80 $40.31 2020 $7.53 $29.12 $46.18 2030 $10.74 $36.32 $55.37 2040 $14.06 $43.41 $63.67 2050 $17.38 $49.72 $71.98 Source: U.S. EPA, 2010; Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 For present value calculations, the social cost of carbon was discounted at a 3 percent discount rate, consistent with the U.S. DOT’s guidance.31 To account for change in the social cost of carbon overtime the average cost across the time period of the analysis, from 2017-2036, for each case. This will overestimate the cost in the short term but will underestimate it in the long term balancing this effect out. Noise Pollution Reducing VMT creates environmental benefits to society in the form of noise reduction. On a per-VMT basis, these values were estimated based on a Federal Highway Administration cost allocation study report.32 For PRISM™ sensitivity analysis, the high and low values for the cost of urban automobile noise are calculated as +/- 10 percent of the likely case. As the likely cost of rural automobile noise is so low (one 28 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Interagency Working Group on Social Cost of Carbon (2010), Social Cost of Carbon for Regulatory Impact Analysis Under Executive Order 12866, p.2., Table 19, (http://www.epa.gov/oms/climate/regulations/scc-tsd.pdf). 29 U.S. Department of Transportation, Tiger Benefit-Cost Analysis (BCA) Resource Guide, p.6. (http://www.dot.gov/tiger/docs/tiger-12_bca-resourceGuide.pdf) 30 U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Consumer Price Index, All Urban Consumers, U.S. City Average, Motor Fuel. Series CUUR0000SETB. 1982-1984=100, 2010=239.178; 2011=302.619. 31 U.S. Department of Transportation (2011), Tiger Benefit-Cost Analysis (BCA) Resource Guide, p.7-9. (http://www.dot.gov/tiger/docs/tiger-12_bca-resourceGuide.pdf) 32 Federal Highway Administration, Addendum to the 1007 Federal Highway Cost Allocation Study, Table 13. (http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/policy/hcas/addendum.htm). 20 one hundredth of a cent), reducing it to arrive at a low value would not yield a meaningful figure. Therefore, in this case the low and likely values are the same. Similarly a 10 percent increase of such a small number would not be significant and the likely value was doubled to create a conservative high value. An urban/rural split of 0 percent to 100 percent was used to create a weighted average of the FHWA values for those environments. All values were adjusted from the study’s 2000 values to 2012 dollars using a CPI adjustment.33 See Table 19 for the range of values used in the PRISMTM sensitivity analysis Table 19: Noise Costs, Auto and Truck, 0-100 Urban-Rural Split, 2012 $ Auto Noise Costs per VMT Low 0.00012 Noise Costs per VMT Likely 0.00013 Noise Costs per VMT High 0.00027 Source: FHWA, Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 State of Good Repair As with noise pollution, reductions in VMT lead to societal benefits in the form of reduced costs of pavement damage. Fewer vehicle-miles in turn lead to a lower need of maintenance on roads. The permile costs of these values were estimated based on the same Federal Highway Administration cost allocation study report that reported estimations of the cost of noise pollution. 34 For PRISM™ sensitivity analysis, the high and low values for the cost of urban automobile pavement maintenance effects are calculated as +/- 10 percent of the likely case. The same urban/rural split used in the noise pollution calculations of 100 percent to 0 percent were used to create a weighted average of the FHWA values. All values were adjusted from the FHWA study’s 2000 values to 2012 dollars using a CPI adjustment.35 See Table 20 for the range of values used in the PRISMTM sensitivity analysis. Table 20: State of Good Repair Values, Auto and Truck, 0-100 Urban-Rural Split, 2012 $ Auto Pavement Damage Cost per VMT Low 0.00012 Pavement Damage Cost per VMT Likely 0.00013 Pavement Damage Cost per VMT High 0.00027 Source: FHWA, Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 33 Bureau of Labor Statistics, Consumer Price Index, All Urban Consumers, US City Average, All Items, Series CUSR0000SA0. 34 Federal Highway Administration, Addendum to the 1007 Federal Highway Cost Allocation Study, Table 13. (http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/policy/hcas/addendum.htm). 35 Bureau of Labor Statistics, Consumer Price Index, All Urban Consumers, US City Average, All Items, Series CUSR0000SA0. 21 Economic Costs Included and Assumptions In the benefit-cost analysis, the term “cost” refers to the additional resource costs or expenditures required to implement, and maintain the investments associated with the Downeaster Service Optimization project. The BCA uses project costs that have been estimated for the Downeaster Service Optimization Project on an annual basis. Operations and maintenance costs and rehabilitation costs were initially expressed in 2011 dollars while the capital costs were initially expressed in real 2012 dollars. All costs were converted to real 2012 dollars based on CPI-U adjustments. 36 Capital Costs Initial project investment costs include engineering and design, construction, real estate services, vehicles, other capital investments, and contingency factors. These costs were reported by NNEPRA and included costs beginning in 2013 and ending in 2014. In undiscounted terms, the costs totaled to $29.5 million (2012 $), which at a 7 percent discount rate translates to $26.4 million (2012 $) and at a 3 percent discount rate translates to $28.1 million (2012 $). The facility is expected to be operational in 2016. Annual Operating and Maintenance Costs The annual costs of operating and maintaining the proposed Downeaster Service Optimization projects are included in the analysis. Operations and maintenance activities apply to several assets and are assumed to begin in 2016 which is year one of the Project. The O&M costs reported are the marginal operating costs, or the costs above and beyond those expected in the “no build” scenario. On average the undiscounted O&M costs are estimated to be $1.2 million (2012 $) per year, at a 7 percent discount rate that is $0.4 million (2012 $) per year and at a 3 percent discount rate $0.7 million (2012 $) annually. Residual Value This BCA ends in 2044; however, at the end of the analysis period, infrastructure that has been put in place will not have been completely worn out, and will continue to provide benefits into the future. These future benefits are captured in the Residual value, also known referred to as “Remaining Capital Value,” or RCV. Due to the extended nature of expected life-cycle of the infrastructure put in place by this project, up to 50 years, the decision was made not to include RCV to provide a more conservative benefit cost estimate. 36 Bureau of Labor Statistics, Consumer Price Index, All Urban Consumers, U.S. City Average, All Items, Series CUSR0000SA0. 22 Key Benefit-Cost Evaluation Measures The benefit-cost analysis converts potential gains (benefits) and losses (costs) from the Project into monetary units and compares them. The following three common benefit-cost evaluation measures are included in this BCA. Net Present Value (NPV): NPV compares the net benefits (benefits minus costs) after being discounted to present values using the real discount rate assumption. The NPV provides a perspective on the overall dollar magnitude of cash flows over time in today’s dollar terms. Benefit Cost (B/C) Ratio: The evaluation also estimates the benefit-cost ratio; the present value of incremental benefits is divided by the present value of incremental costs to yield the benefit-cost ratio. The B/C ratio expresses the relation of discounted benefits to discounted costs as a measure of the extent to which a project’s benefits either exceed or fall short of their associated costs. Sensitivity Analysis To test the robustness of the estimated NPV, and B/C ratio, the economic analysis runs PRISMTM sensitivity analysis simulations using the ranges of valuations already discussed, as well as sensitivity on impact and physical units to the degree of +/- 10 percent. For example, tons of carbon emissions were evaluated with PRISM™ sensitivity at a low value of 10 percent less than baseline estimates, and a high value of 10 percent above baseline estimates. Benefit-Cost Analysis Results Results in Brief There were two “Cases” conducted for this analysis. Case A assumes a 7.0 percent discount rate, and Case B assumes a 3.0 percent discount rate, as prescribed by the U.S. DOT. For the Case A at a 7 percent discount rate, the proposed Downeaster Service Optimization investments yield a net present value of $20.8 million, and a benefit-cost ratio of 1.55. For the Case B at a 3 percent discount rate, the proposed Downeaster Service Optimization investments yield a net present value of $71.9 million, and a benefit-cost ratio of 2.47. Table 21 presents the evaluation results for the two cases. All benefits and costs were estimated in constant 2012 dollars over an evaluation period extending 30 years beyond system completion in 2014. Table 21: Benefit Cost Analysis Summary Results Scenario Net Present Value (2012 $ millions disc.) Benefit Cost Ratio Case A (7 percent discount rate) $20.8 1.55 Case B (3 percent discount rate) $71.9 2.47 23 Benefits by Category Over the entire analysis period, Downeaster Service Optimization exhibits decreases in VMT and decreases in VHT. Table 22 below outlines the changes in some of the impact categories. Some categories increased, while others decreased. Overall, the savings in many categories like travel time savings, fuel, and safety provided significant benefits. Table 22: Project Impacts for Downeaster Service Optimization, Cumulative 2016-44 Category Quantity Vehicle-miles traveled (VMT) 159.2 million Vehicle-hours traveled (VHT) 5.4million Induced Ridership Benefits (2012 $ undiscounted) $22.3 million Fuel consumed (gal.) 5.1 million Oil imported (gal.) 4.9 million Fatalities (number) 1.7 Injury accidents (number) 1.2 Property damage only accidents (number) 1.0 CO2 Emissions (tons) 59,400 NOX emissions (tons) 15 PM 10 7.5 (tons) SOX (tons) 0.6 VOC (tons) 13.5 Source: Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 Over the 30-year analysis period, there are $58.9 million in benefits (in 7 percent discounted 2012 dollars) and $120.8 million in benefits (in 3 percent discounted 2012 dollars). In present value dollars, of the positive benefits, travel time savings constitute approximately $37.3 million, induced rider benefits are $5.6 million vehicle O&M savings $6.0 million, user fuel savings are $4.8 million; oil import savings are $0.4 million; and emissions savings are $550,000 (discounted at 7 percent). Most of the benefits occurred in the travel time savings (63 percent), while fuel consumption savings were 8 percent of total benefits, vehicle O&M savings were 10 percent and induced user benefits 10 percent. Thus, the vast majority of benefits (91 percent) were in the economic competitiveness category, with some additional benefits (9.2 percent) in the social category. 24 Figure 2: Cumulative Benefits by Category Vehicle O&M Fuel Savings 10% 8% Emissions 1% Induced User Benefits 10% Other 9% Other 1% Travel Time Savings 63% Safety 7% Source: Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 Costs over Time Figure 3 presents the capital expenditures over time, expressed in constant 2012 dollars before discounting. The capital investments ($29.5 million) were assumed to begin in 2013 and conclude by the end of 2014. These capital costs translate to $26.4million when discounted at 7 percent and $28.1 when discounted at 3 percent Annual O&M costs over the economic evaluation period (2016-2044) are also expressed in constant 2012 dollars before discounting. In real dollars, NNEPRA predicts that these costs will remain generally constant through 2044. O&M costs total $34.9 million over 30 years, or $1.2 million per year in undiscounted dollars. This is an average of $388,800 per year on a 7 percent discounted basis and $695,500 per year on a 3 percent discounted basis. 25 Figure 3: Capital and O&M Expenditures in 2012 Dollars Before Present Value Discounting 25 2012 $ (millions) 20 15 10 5 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 2031 2032 2033 2034 2035 2036 2037 2038 2039 2040 2041 2042 2043 2044 - Capital Costs O&M Costs Source: Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 Cumulative Benefits and Costs Figure 4 and Figure 5 compare the cumulative present value of benefits with the cumulative present value of costs over time for both cases. The figure shows that the cumulative discounted benefits exceed the cumulative discounted costs by mid 2027 with a 7 percent discount rate, and mid 2023 using 3 percent discount rate. 26 Figure 4: Cumulative Benefits and Costs in 2012 Dollars (Discounted at 7 percent) 70 Discounted 2012 $ (millions) 60 50 40 30 20 10 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 2031 2032 2033 2034 2035 2036 2037 2038 2039 2040 2041 2042 2043 2044 - Calendar Years Cumulative Costs Cumulative Benefits Source: Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 Figure 5: Cumulative Benefits and Costs in 2012 Dollars (Discounted at 3 percent) 140 100 80 60 40 20 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 2031 2032 2033 2034 2035 2036 2037 2038 2039 2040 2041 2042 2043 2044 Discounted 2012 $ (millions) 120 Calendar Years Cumulative Costs Cumulative Benefits Source: Parsons Brinckerhoff, 2013 27 APPENDIX PRISMTM Sensitivity Analysis By using PRISMTM sensitivity analysis simulations on both the valuations and impacts it is able to create a 95% confidence interval for both the NPV and B/C ratio. Table 23 reports these ranges at the 7 percent and 3 percent discount rates. Table 23: NPV (2012 $ millions) and B/C ratio, 95% confidence interval, 7% and 3% discount rates Case Case A (7 percent discount rate) B/C-Ratio Net Present Value Case B (3 percent discount rate) B/C Ratio Net Present Value Low Likely High 1.43 $16.1 1.55 $20.8 1.73 $28.2 2.27 $62.5 2.47 $71.9 2.74 $87.8 Furthermore, according to PRISM™ sensitivity analysis, there is over a 99 percent chance that the B/C ratio is above 1.0 at a 7 percent or 3 percent discount rate. 28 Figure 6: PRISM™ Histogram for Benefit-Cost Ratio at 7 percent Discount Rate 29 Figure 7: PRISM™ Histogram for Benefit-Cost Ratio at 3 Percent Discount Rate 30 Figure 8: PRISM™ Histogram for Net Present Value at 7 Percent Discount Rate 31 Figure 9: PRISM™ Histogram for Net Present Value at 3 Percent Discount Rate 32 APPENDIX Benefit-Cost Model Detail Tables Table 24: Detailed Travel Demand and Travel Time Savings VMT Change (Network) Total VHT Change (hours) (99,865) (102,861) (105,946) (109,125) (112,399) (115,770) (120,401) (125,217) (130,226) (135,435) (140,852) (146,487) (152,346) (158,440) (164,778) (171,369) (178,223) (185,352) (192,766) (200,477) $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ Induced Ridership Benefits 128,360.91 308,978.91 373,210.10 409,654.53 450,744.36 494,218.88 513,987.64 534,547.14 555,929.03 578,166.19 601,292.84 625,344.55 650,358.33 676,372.67 703,427.57 731,564.68 760,827.26 791,260.35 822,910.77 855,827.20 Value of Induced Ridership Benefits & VHT Change (2012 $ 3% Discount) $ $ $ 2,407,327 $ 2,555,367 $ 2,600,056 $ 2,619,987 $ 2,642,060 $ 2,664,347 $ 2,690,215 $ 2,716,334 $ 2,742,706 $ 2,769,334 $ 2,796,221 $ 2,823,368 $ 2,850,779 $ 2,878,457 $ 2,906,403 $ 2,934,621 $ 2,963,112 $ 2,991,880 $ 3,020,928 $ 3,050,257 Value of Induced Ridership Benefits & VHT Change (2012 $ 7% Discount) $ $ $ 2,278,482 $ 2,678,393 $ 2,714,774 $ 2,668,868 $ 2,627,850 $ 2,585,642 $ 2,506,902 $ 2,430,377 $ 2,355,740 $ 2,283,331 $ 2,212,967 $ 2,145,180 $ 2,079,875 $ 2,016,941 $ 1,956,287 $ 1,897,787 $ 1,841,375 $ 1,786,978 $ 1,734,482 $ 1,683,785 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 2031 2032 2033 2034 (918,159) (2,210,111) (2,669,554) (2,930,239) (3,224,152) (3,535,123) (3,676,528) (3,823,590) (3,976,533) (4,135,594) (4,301,018) (4,473,059) (4,651,981) (4,838,061) (5,031,583) (5,232,846) (5,442,160) (5,659,847) (5,886,240) (6,121,690) 2035 (6,366,558) (208,496) $ 890,060.29 $ 3,079,872 $ 1,634,777 2036 (6,621,220) (216,836) $ 925,662.70 $ 3,109,773 $ 1,587,419 2037 (6,886,069) (225,509) $ 962,689.21 $ 3,139,965 $ 1,541,607 2038 (7,161,511) (234,530) $ 1,001,196.77 $ 3,170,450 $ 1,497,271 2039 (7,447,972) (243,911) $ 1,041,244.65 $ 3,201,231 $ 1,454,362 2040 (7,745,891) (253,667) $ 1,082,894.43 $ 3,232,311 $ 1,412,802 2041 (8,055,726) (263,814) $ 1,126,210.21 $ 3,263,693 $ 1,371,206 2042 (8,377,956) (274,367) $ 1,171,258.62 $ 3,295,379 $ 1,330,868 2043 2044 (8,713,074) (9,061,597) (159,175,643) (285,341) $ 1,218,108.96 $ (296,755) $ 1,266,833.32 $ (5,351,562) 22,253,143 $ 3,327,373 $ 3,359,678 $ 87,803,484 $ 1,291,749 1,253,808 58,861,885 33 Table 25: Detailed Non-Travel Savings and Benefits at 3 percent 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 2031 2032 2033 2034 O&M Savings Fuel $ $ $ 124,970 $ 287,264 $ 331,067 $ 346,941 $ 363,868 $ 379,527 $ 374,656 $ 369,410 $ 363,360 $ 357,081 $ 350,373 $ 344,210 $ 338,625 $ 333,607 $ 329,182 $ 325,303 $ 322,014 $ 319,272 $ 317,109 $ 315,464 O&M Savings Non-Fuel $ $ $ 119,580 $ 279,459 $ 327,722 $ 349,247 $ 373,086 $ 397,155 $ 401,011 $ 404,905 $ 408,836 $ 412,805 $ 416,813 $ 420,859 $ 424,945 $ 429,071 $ 433,237 $ 437,443 $ 441,690 $ 445,978 $ 450,308 $ 454,680 $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ Safety 79,766 186,411 218,606 232,964 248,865 264,919 267,492 270,088 272,712 275,360 278,032 280,731 283,458 286,209 288,988 291,794 294,627 297,486 300,376 303,293 Emissions $ $ $ 11,434 $ 26,569 $ 30,990 $ 32,860 $ 34,935 $ 37,023 $ 37,226 $ 37,438 $ 37,661 $ 37,894 $ 38,138 $ 38,391 $ 38,653 $ 38,922 $ 39,202 $ 39,489 $ 39,786 $ 40,172 $ 40,562 $ 40,956 Oil Import $ $ $ 11,495 $ 26,422 $ 30,451 $ 31,912 $ 33,469 $ 34,909 $ 34,461 $ 33,978 $ 33,422 $ 32,844 $ 32,227 $ 31,660 $ 31,147 $ 30,685 $ 30,278 $ 29,921 $ 29,619 $ 29,367 $ 29,168 $ 29,016 Noise Reduction $ $ $ 1,030 $ 2,406 $ 2,822 $ 3,007 $ 3,212 $ 3,420 $ 3,453 $ 3,486 $ 3,520 $ 3,554 $ 3,589 $ 3,624 $ 3,659 $ 3,694 $ 3,730 $ 3,766 $ 3,803 $ 3,840 $ 3,877 $ 3,915 Pavement Damage $ $ $ 1,030 $ 2,406 $ 2,822 $ 3,007 $ 3,212 $ 3,420 $ 3,453 $ 3,486 $ 3,520 $ 3,554 $ 3,589 $ 3,624 $ 3,659 $ 3,694 $ 3,730 $ 3,766 $ 3,803 $ 3,840 $ 3,877 $ 3,915 2035 $ 314,255 $ 459,095 $ 306,236 $ 41,353 $ 28,905 $ 3,953 $ 3,953 2036 $ 313,553 $ 463,552 $ 309,209 $ 41,755 $ 28,841 $ 3,991 $ 3,991 2037 $ 313,248 $ 468,052 $ 312,211 $ 42,161 $ 28,812 $ 4,030 $ 4,030 2038 $ 313,338 $ 472,596 $ 315,243 $ 42,569 $ 28,821 $ 4,069 $ 4,069 2039 $ 313,800 $ 477,185 $ 318,304 $ 42,982 $ 28,863 $ 4,109 $ 4,109 2040 $ 314,601 $ 481,818 $ 321,394 $ 43,400 $ 28,937 $ 4,149 $ 4,149 2041 $ 311,732 $ 486,495 $ 324,514 $ 43,822 $ 28,673 $ 4,189 $ 4,189 2042 $ 308,890 $ 491,219 $ 327,665 $ 44,248 $ 28,412 $ 4,230 $ 4,230 2045 $ 306,074 $ 495,988 $ 330,845 $ 44,677 $ 2046 $ 303,283 $ 500,803 $ 334,058 $ 45,111 $ Total $ 9,706,077 $ 12,625,633 $ 8,421,856 $ 1,150,379 $ 28,153 $ 27,896 $ 892,764 $ 4,271 $ 4,271 4,312 $ 4,312 108,710 $108,710 34 Table 26: Detailed Non-Travel Savings and Benefits at 7 percent 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 2031 2032 2033 2034 O&M Savings Fuel $ $ $ 103,293 $ 228,561 $ 253,566 $ 255,789 $ 258,241 $ 259,285 $ 246,389 $ 233,857 $ 221,428 $ 209,466 $ 197,848 $ 187,102 $ 177,185 $ 168,034 $ 159,607 $ 151,830 $ 144,676 $ 138,082 $ 132,020 $ 126,425 O&M Savings Non-Fuel $ $ $ 98,839 $ 222,351 $ 251,004 $ 257,490 $ 264,783 $ 271,328 $ 263,721 $ 256,327 $ 249,140 $ 242,155 $ 235,365 $ 228,766 $ 222,352 $ 216,118 $ 210,059 $ 204,169 $ 198,445 $ 192,881 $ 187,473 $ 182,217 $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ Safety 65,929 148,318 167,431 171,758 176,622 180,988 175,914 170,981 166,188 161,528 157,000 152,598 148,319 144,160 140,119 136,190 132,371 128,660 125,054 121,547 Emissions $ $ $ 9,450 $ 21,140 $ 23,736 $ 24,227 $ 24,794 $ 25,294 $ 24,481 $ 23,700 $ 22,951 $ 22,230 $ 21,535 $ 20,867 $ 20,224 $ 19,605 $ 19,007 $ 18,431 $ 17,874 $ 17,374 $ 16,886 $ 16,413 Oil Import $ $ $ 9,501 $ 21,023 $ 23,323 $ 23,527 $ 23,753 $ 23,849 $ 22,663 $ 21,510 $ 20,367 $ 19,267 $ 18,198 $ 17,210 $ 16,297 $ 15,456 $ 14,681 $ 13,965 $ 13,307 $ 12,701 $ 12,143 $ 11,629 Noise Reduction $ $ $ 851 $ 1,914 $ 2,161 $ 2,217 $ 2,280 $ 2,336 $ 2,271 $ 2,207 $ 2,145 $ 2,085 $ 2,027 $ 1,970 $ 1,915 $ 1,861 $ 1,809 $ 1,758 $ 1,709 $ 1,661 $ 1,614 $ 1,569 Pavement Damage $ $ $ 851 $ 1,914 $ 2,161 $ 2,217 $ 2,280 $ 2,336 $ 2,271 $ 2,207 $ 2,145 $ 2,085 $ 2,027 $ 1,970 $ 1,915 $ 1,861 $ 1,809 $ 1,758 $ 1,709 $ 1,661 $ 1,614 $ 1,569 2035 $ 121,232 $ 177,108 $ 118,139 $ 15,954 $ 11,151 $ 1,525 $ 1,525 2036 $ 116,439 $ 172,142 $ 114,827 $ 15,506 $ 10,710 $ 1,482 $ 1,482 2037 $ 111,978 $ 167,316 $ 111,607 $ 15,072 $ 10,300 $ 1,441 $ 1,441 2038 $ 107,822 $ 162,625 $ 108,477 $ 14,649 $ 9,917 $ 1,400 $ 1,400 2039 $ 103,945 $ 158,065 $ 105,437 $ 14,239 $ 9,561 $ 1,361 $ 1,361 2040 $ 100,314 $ 153,634 $ 102,479 $ 13,839 $ 9,227 $ 1,323 $ 1,323 2041 $ 95,684 $ 149,326 $ 99,607 $ 13,451 $ 8,801 $ 1,286 $ 1,286 2042 $ 91,267 $ 145,139 $ 96,814 $ 13,074 $ 8,395 $ 1,250 $ 1,250 2045 $ 87,054 $ 141,070 $ 94,100 $ 12,708 $ 8,007 $ 2046 $ 83,036 $ 137,115 $ 91,462 $ 12,350 $ 7,638 $ Total $ 4,871,455 $ 6,018,523 $ 4,014,624 $ 551,061 $ 448,077 $ 1,215 $ 1,215 1,181 $ 1,181 51,824 $ 51,824 35 Table 27: Detailed Cost 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 2031 2032 2033 2034 Capital Costs Less ROW Undiscounted 2012 $ $ 9,833,333 $ 19,666,667 $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ - Net O&M Costs Undiscounted 2012 $ $ $ $ 207,569 $ 29,076 $ 1,231,450 $ 1,325,198 $ 1,169,447 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 Rehabilitation Costs Undiscounted 2012 $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ - Total Costs Undiscounted 2012 $ $ 9,833,333 $ 19,666,667 $ 207,569 $ 29,076 $ 1,231,450 $ 1,325,198 $ 1,169,447 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 Total Costs Discounted 3% 2012 $ $ 9,546,926 $ 18,537,720 $ 189,955 $ 25,833 $ 1,062,260 $ 1,109,833 $ 950,868 $ 977,160 $ 948,699 $ 921,067 $ 894,240 $ 868,194 $ 842,907 $ 818,356 $ 794,521 $ 771,379 $ 748,912 $ 727,099 $ 705,922 $ 685,361 $ 665,399 $ 646,018 Total Costs Discounted 7% 2012 $ $ 9,190,031 $ 17,177,628 $ 169,438 $ 22,182 $ 878,007 $ 883,035 $ 728,273 $ 720,433 $ 673,302 $ 629,254 $ 588,088 $ 549,615 $ 513,659 $ 480,055 $ 448,649 $ 419,298 $ 391,868 $ 366,231 $ 342,272 $ 319,881 $ 298,954 $ 279,396 2035 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ 627,202 $ 261,118 2036 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ 608,934 $ 244,036 2037 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ 591,198 $ 228,071 2038 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ 573,979 $ 213,150 2039 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ 557,261 $ 199,206 2040 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ 541,030 $ 186,174 2041 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ 525,272 $ 173,994 2042 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ - $ 1,237,838 $ 509,973 $ 162,611 $ $ 29,500,000 $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 34,908,681 $ - $ $ $ 1,237,838 $ 1,237,838 $ 64,408,681 $ 495,119 $ 480,698 $ 48,949,295 $ 151,973 142,031 38,031,913 2045 $ 2046 $ Total $ 36 Table 28: Detailed Benefit/Cost Summary 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 2031 2032 2033 2034 Total Costs Discounted 3% 2012 $ $ 9,546,926 $ 18,537,720 $ 189,955 $ 25,833 $ 1,062,260 $ 1,109,833 $ 950,868 $ 977,160 $ 948,699 $ 921,067 $ 894,240 $ 868,194 $ 842,907 $ 818,356 $ 794,521 $ 771,379 $ 748,912 $ 727,099 $ 705,922 $ 685,361 $ 665,399 $ 646,018 Total Costs Discounted 7% 2012 $ $ 9,190,031 $ 17,177,628 $ 169,438 $ 22,182 $ 878,007 $ 883,035 $ 728,273 $ 720,433 $ 673,302 $ 629,254 $ 588,088 $ 549,615 $ 513,659 $ 480,055 $ 448,649 $ 419,298 $ 391,868 $ 366,231 $ 342,272 $ 319,881 $ 298,954 $ 279,396 Total Benefits Discounted 3% 2012 $ $ $ $ 2,756,632 $ 3,366,304 $ 3,544,536 $ 3,619,925 $ 3,702,707 $ 3,784,720 $ 3,811,967 $ 3,839,125 $ 3,865,737 $ 3,892,426 $ 3,918,982 $ 3,946,467 $ 3,974,925 $ 4,004,339 $ 4,034,750 $ 4,066,103 $ 4,098,454 $ 4,131,835 $ 4,166,205 $ 4,201,496 Total Benefits Discounted 7% 2012 $ $ $ $ 2,278,482 $ 2,678,393 $ 2,714,774 $ 2,668,868 $ 2,627,850 $ 2,585,642 $ 2,506,902 $ 2,430,377 $ 2,355,740 $ 2,283,331 $ 2,212,967 $ 2,145,180 $ 2,079,875 $ 2,016,941 $ 1,956,287 $ 1,897,787 $ 1,841,375 $ 1,786,978 $ 1,734,482 $ 1,683,785 Net Benefits Discounted 3% 2012 $ $ (9,546,926) $ (18,537,720) $ 2,566,677 $ 3,340,471 $ 2,482,276 $ 2,510,092 $ 2,751,839 $ 2,807,560 $ 2,863,268 $ 2,918,058 $ 2,971,497 $ 3,024,232 $ 3,076,075 $ 3,128,111 $ 3,180,404 $ 3,232,960 $ 3,285,838 $ 3,339,004 $ 3,392,532 $ 3,446,474 $ 3,500,806 $ 3,555,478 Net Benefits Discounted 7% 2012 $ $ (9,190,031) $ (17,177,628) $ 2,109,044 $ 2,656,211 $ 1,836,767 $ 1,785,833 $ 1,899,577 $ 1,865,209 $ 1,833,600 $ 1,801,123 $ 1,767,652 $ 1,733,716 $ 1,699,308 $ 1,665,125 $ 1,631,226 $ 1,597,643 $ 1,564,419 $ 1,531,556 $ 1,499,103 $ 1,467,097 $ 1,435,528 $ 1,404,389 2035 $ 627,202 $ 261,118 $ 4,237,622 $ 1,634,777 $ 3,610,420 $ 1,373,659 2036 $ 608,934 $ 244,036 $ 4,274,665 $ 1,587,419 $ 3,665,731 $ 1,343,383 2037 $ 591,198 $ 228,071 $ 4,312,509 $ 1,541,607 $ 3,721,311 $ 1,313,536 2038 $ 573,979 $ 213,150 $ 4,351,155 $ 1,497,271 $ 3,777,176 $ 1,284,121 2039 $ 557,261 $ 199,206 $ 4,390,583 $ 1,454,362 $ 3,833,322 $ 1,255,156 2040 $ 541,030 $ 186,174 $ 4,430,759 $ 1,412,802 $ 3,889,729 $ 1,226,628 2041 $ 525,272 $ 173,994 $ 4,467,307 $ 1,371,206 $ 3,942,035 $ 1,197,212 2042 $ 509,973 $ 162,611 $ 4,504,273 $ 1,330,868 $ 3,994,300 $ 1,168,257 2045 $ 2046 $ Total $ 495,119 $ 480,698 $ 48,949,295 $ 151,973 $ 142,031 $ 38,031,913 $ 4,541,652 $ 4,579,453 $ 120,817,613 $ 1,291,749 $ 1,253,808 $ 58,861,885 $ 4,046,533 $ 4,098,755 $ 71,868,318 $ 1,139,776 1,111,777 20,829,972 37 APPENDIX Monetization Values and Ranges Used in PRISM™ Sensitivity Analysis Figure 10: Environmental Values Emissions CO2 Figure 11: Environmental Values Emissions NOX 38 Figure 12: Environmental Values Emissions PM Figure 13: Environmental Values Emissions SOX 39 Figure 14: Environmental Values Emissions VOC Figure 15: Environmental Values Emissions Noise 40 Figure 16: Economic Values Travel Time Savings – Auto Figure 17: Economic Values – Induced Ridership 41 Figure 18: Economic Values Fuel Savings – Auto Figure 19: Economic Values Oil Imports 42 Figure 20: Economic Values Vehicle O&M Costs – Auto Figure 21: Economic Values Pavement Damage – Auto 43 Figure 22: Social Values Fatalities Figure 23: Social Values MAIS 5 Incidents 44 Figure 24: Social Values MAIS 4 Incidents Figure 25: Social Values MAIS 3 Incidents 45 Figure 26: Social Values MAIS 2 Incidents Figure 27: Social Values MAIS 1 Incidents 46 Figure 28: Social Values Property Damage Only Incidents 47