Germany`s new strength? From stimulus to growth
Transcription
Germany`s new strength? From stimulus to growth
Current Issues Germany’s new strength? Germany October 7, 2010 From stimulus to growth “Germany is back.” Its economic rebound and stable government cast Germany in a positive light by international comparison. Buoyant demand from abroad and the stimulus from the government‘s economic policies have dragged German industry out of recession. But clouds on the economic horizon for important trade partners harbour risks. German economic policy is better than its reputation. After the 2009 federal election Germany‘s policymakers got off to a rocky start. An economic stimulus package at the end of 2009 was followed by political attempts at clarification in an effort to make good lost ground amid hefty criticism from the media. But the substance of the government‘s economic policy is considerably better than its outward perception. However, a broad growth agenda is still in its infancy. The relationship between the market and state needs to be recalibrated – and not just since the crisis interventions. The debate over social justice will have to be conducted more intensively, if only for reasons of intergenerational fairness. Fiscal policy must be set on a new track. Above and beyond the austerity package already presented, the top priority is a government spending review focusing on the contribution this expenditure makes to economic growth. Tax breaks and subsidies need serious pruning, accompanied by income tax relief in the medium term. Windfall revenues must be used to reduce deficits more quickly. Social policy financing issues are reducing growth opportunities. Delinking the financing of social protection from wages remains on the agenda. At the same time the risks inherent in the social welfare system must be brought under control. Latent growth potential in the healthcare system should be leveraged. Authors Barbara Böttcher +49 69 910-31787 barbara.boettcher@db.com High levels of employment are a key factor in strengthening domestic demand. Labour policy should continue down the successful path of greater Editor Dieter Bräuninger flexibilisation. Consistent regulation must minimise the problematic interaction between minimum wages, additional earnings regulations and incentives to work. The supply-side prerequisites for consistently higher economic momentum also include a better level of education for the population and sufficient supply of skilled staff. Technical Assistant Judith Runge An integrated energy and climate policy must remain a growth driver. Klaus Günter Deutsch +49 30 3407-3682 klaus.deutsch@db.com Deutsche Bank Research Frankfurt am Main Germany Internet: www.dbresearch.com E-mail: marketing.dbr@db.com Fax: +49 69 910-31877 Managing Director Thomas Mayer To retain a pioneering role in innovation, it is urgently necessary to put down markers in coal-based power generation, grid and storage development and grid regulation, building renovation, goods traffic and the institutional framework. Little stands in the way of the rise of renewables. Current Issues Contents* New government, economic recovery – everything rosy?.........................................................3 Deep in the valley of tears, recovery champion? ................................................................................4 Subdued economic outlook……………… .............................................................................................6 An outline of measures by the German government 2008-2010 .......................................................7 German pragmatism in economic policy…………………………………………………………………...8 A growth agenda……………………………………………………………………….……….…..…………..…8 Modern economic policy – more balanced growth profile and reassessment of the welfare state……………………………………………………………….……...9 Fiscal policy beyond cost-cutting………………………………………………………………….……......11 Challenges remain for labour market policy……………………………………………………………....13 Setting social policy on a sensible track………………………………………………………….………..15 Climate and energy policy ...………………………………………………………………………………….18 Literature……………………………………………………………………………………….………………...…22 * 2 Translation of the study ―Deutschlands neue Blüte? Von der Konjunkturpolitik zur Wachstumsagenda.‖ Published in German on September 29, 2010. Data have not been adjusted since then. October 7, 2010 Germany‟s new strength? From stimulus to growth New government, economic recovery – everything rosy? German Bundestag election results 1990-2009, percentage of second votes 50 40 30 20 10 0 1990 1994 1998 2002 2005 2009 CDU/CSU SPD FDP Alliance 90/The Greens The Left Party - PDS Others Source: Federal Returning Officer, Schmidt (2007) 1 Distribution of seats in the 17th German Bundestag 622 seats in all 68 76 239 146 93 CDU/CSU FDP SPD The Left Party Alliance 90/The Greens Source:Bundestag 2 Distribution of seats in the Bundesrat 69 seats in all 8 9 31 4 3 3 11 CDU/FDP CDU/Greens SPD SPD/The Left Party In its post-war history Germany has gone through cycles of international acclaim and criticism. Germany has alternately been a model, a ‗locomotive‘; then again it has held the red lantern and been the ‗sick man of Europe‘. The situation was no different in the recent economic crisis – first the waterfall drop in economic output and now a powerful recovery. Such strong alternations have equally occurred in the realm of politics. The difficult years of German reunification were followed by the comparatively low-key end to the conservative-liberal coalition government. In Chancellor Schröder‘s SPD-Green Party coalition, periods of friction and weak leadership (1998, 2002, 2005) alternated with periods of strong political governance in which reforms were embraced (2000 tax reform, 2001/02 pensions reform, 2003/2004 labour market reforms). The 1 ―Schröder cycle‖ culminated after seven years in early elections 2 and loss of the chancellorship in 2005. At least the Social Democrats managed to scramble into an unwanted Grand Coalition led by Chancellor Angela Merkel from the CDU. Whilst the audience liked the orchestra and music (sound public finances, more environmental protection, more welfare state, crisis management), polarisation heightened again between the political parties. Following a long drawn-out electoral campaign, in the 2009 federal election voters brought about a change in government to a centreright administration, marking a return to rule by a coherent political camp rather than a tripartite constellation such as the so-called ‗Jamaica alliance‘ referencing the trademark colours of the conservative CDU/CSU (black), liberal Free Democrats (FDP – yellow) and Greens or a ‗traffic light‘ (red/yellow/green) combination 3 of SPD, FDP and Greens. However, opinion polls revealed that most Germans were satisfied with the Grand Coalition‘s performance and that – unlike the situation in 1969, 1982 and 1998 – there was no dominant change of sentiment. At the same time the SPD imploded, while the CDU/CSU turned in a consistently weak performance, which – given the high proportion of second votes captured by the FDP – sufficed for a comfortable CDU/CSU/FDP majority. Ultimately the clear election campaign pledge by the FDP and CDU/CSU to form a ‗black-yellow‘ coalition paid off. During the election campaign promises to cut taxes fuelled expectations of a centre-right change of course. However, following the rapid negotiation of a coalition agreement and the formation of a new government, the CDU/CSU and FDP had to resolve issues over their policy direction in practically all areas, with the result that at first no clear government agenda was apparent. After a moderate tax cut of somewhat more than EUR 8 bn had been rushed through the necessary institutions in late 2009, very little else happened. Loss of the May 2010 state election in North Rhine-Westphalia (NRW) and the centre-right‘s ejection from office then prompted the announcement of another fresh beginning, bringing the CDU/CSU/FDP coalition round to a clear policy of consolidation at the expense of any further tax relief. CDU/SPD CDU/Greens/FDP SPD/Greens 1 Source: Bundesrat 3 2 3 October 7, 2010 Raschke (2010). See Egle, Ostheim, Zohlnhöfer (2003) and Egle, Zohlnhöfer (2007) for a review of the two legislative periods and Egle, Zohlnhöfer (2010) and Dyson (2010) on the Grand Coalition. See the articles in ―Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte‖ (2009). 3 Current Issues State parliament elections 2011 Date Federal state March 20 Saxony-Anhalt March 27 BadenWürttemberg March 27 RhinelandPalatinate May 22 Bremen Sept. 4 Berlin Sept. 4 MecklenburgWestern Pomerania Government* CDU, SPD CDU SPD SPD, Greens SPD, Left Party SPD, CDU * Present majorities Source: DB Research 4 Germany – a “Grand Coalition nation” — Parliamentary system with coalition governments as the norm — Distinct division of power in the federal system with the Bundesrat (the upper chamber of parliament representing the states) sharing decision-making in many policy areas — Different party-political majorities in the Bundestag and Bundesrat ―par for the course‖ — Many veto players in the decision-making process — Delegation of important policy areas to self-governing bodies and semiautonomous administrative units in the social welfare system Source: Schmidt (2007), p. 198. Germany is therefore labouring at present under an interpretation deficit. Economic euphoria and criticism of the government dominate the headlines. Are we gambling away the future, as the Sachverständigenrat, the panel of economic advisors to the German government, pondered last autumn? Or have we emerged older and 4 wiser from the crisis? Are we currently a recovery champion and growth star in Europe or a repeat offender expanding again at other nations‘ expense? Are we belt-tightening too soon and too rigorously, or is it not our duty to consider our ageing society? An economic and political close-up of the situation in Germany in the wake of the deepest recession in the past 60 years reveals an unusually high degree of uncertainty. Economic question marks hang not only over the sustainability of global economic recovery as monetary and fiscal stimuli are gradually wound down, but also over the possibility of inflation-free trend growth thereafter and the state of public finances. Political question marks include the direction of government policy, which has to pick its way through the minefield of limited strategic scope in the tripartite alliance between CDU, CSU and FDP, the potential of the Bundesrat (the upper chamber of parliament representing the states) to block the passage of legislation since the formation of a state government in NRW has left it without a CDU/CSU/FDP majority, and the need to court public opinion. And looming on the horizon in 2011 are elections in important federal states in which the CDU forms part of a coalition government (see sidebar). Calls for a clear political orientation are thus growing more strident. In our opinion Germany is not alone with these uncertainties – quite the contrary. By international standards Germany is in a good position to put the crisis behind it in the coming two to three years. It has an administration with a parliamentary majority, the next federal elections are not until 2013, and the economic situation is comparatively good. It is therefore very likely that in the next few years Germany will still be able to pursue a stability-oriented fiscal policy, an economic and labour market policy creating jobs and a consistent climate and energy policy. And of course there is also considerable scope to get to grips with the growth deficits in education and integration policy and with structural reforms in the healthcare and financial systems and on the goods and services markets. However, no major course corrections are to be expected in the costly welfare state – competition between the political parties for the approximately 40% of voters who depend directly on welfare 5 transfer payments will see to that. Nevertheless, it has usually been the case in the past that, for all the obstacles standing in the way of concrete decisions, reforms were engineered that had a sustained impact on the economy and society. The last two governments at least achieved this with the 2003 labour law reform and the 2009 ‗debt brake‘. Initially, neither project featured prominently in government planning. Viewed in this light, the present administration still stands a good chance of laying down markers. 4 5 4 Sachverständigenrat (2009), Economist (2010). Schmidt (2010), pp. 319-320, estimates the narrowly defined number of German citizens entitled to vote who profit directly from social benefits at 22.4 m (36% of the electorate in 2005); adding temporary recipients of transfer payments to this brings up the number to 27 m or 40% of the electorate. And counting the administrators of these benefits, the grand total comes close to the 50% mark. October 7, 2010 Germany‟s new strength? From stimulus to growth Deep in the valley of tears, recovery champion? Growth contributions To price-adjusted GDP in percentage points, yoy 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Investment Private consumption Foreign balance Government spending Real GDP Sources: Federal Statistical Office, DB Research 5 Imports, exports and industrial production % yoy 40 30 20 10 0 -10 -20 -30 05 06 07 08 09 10 Imports Exports Industrial production Source: Deutsche Bundesbank 6 Unemployment* In % 11 9 7 5 3 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Germany OECD EU Japan The force of the crisis. The global crisis brought Germany‘s 6 temporary economic and political resurgence between 2006 and the summer of 2008 to an abrupt end as the country felt the full 7 force of the slump in world trade. The German banking system also acted as an important channel for the transmission of seriously misguided developments and declines in asset values on the US real estate market. Having racked up far too much exposure to structured US mortgage-backed securities, a number of German banks suffered heavy losses. Some were rescued by other, healthier banks and some bailed out by the state with liquidity guarantees, injections of equity and nationalisation. Within mere weeks, the loss of confidence in the international financial markets triggered by the insolvency of Lehman Brothers on September 15, 2008 caused world trade and investment to collapse. Germany‘s merchandise exports and imports and its manufacturing output plummeted by more than 20% in six months, with order books in some of its industry champions shrinking even more dramatically. Ultimately, overall economic output in 2009 fell by 4.7%. But thanks to resolute political action to stem the tide with economic stimulus packages and further relief legislation, by the second quarter of 2009 gross domestic product was already back in positive territory (quarter-on-quarter). While private consumer spending in Germany was dented only slightly, particularly in comparison to other countries, public-sector consumption and investment expenditure up to autumn 2010 picked up the slack created by sluggish private demand, particularly from abroad. The second quarter of 2010 saw net exports spurring the German economy to its fastest rate of expansion for 20 years with growth of 2.2% quarter-on-quarter (4.1% year-on-year). Flexible labour market, low unemployment. Given such drastic fluctuations in manufacturing output and overall economic activity, developments in the German labour market stand out conspicuously. Many companies entered the crisis with excellent earnings and financial figures, having already coped with their restructuring in the first half of the decade, when business was poor. At the same time corporate Germany had massively improved its competitiveness as trends in unit labour costs diverged within the European Monetary Union. Even in the recession, this ‗buffer zone‘ for corporate cost increases was not entirely exhausted. Furthermore, companies made flexible use of various human resources management tools. Employees scaled back overtime, took time off to balance out their ‗working time accounts‘ and took advantage of the contractually negotiated leeway to reduce their regular weekly working hours. Additionally, given the shortage of skilled staff many companies embraced the instrument of short-time work, which was 8 expanded during the crisis, in order not to lose their core workers. The number of people on short time peaked at more than 1.5 million. However, this figure has already fallen to just over 700,000, and new applications have fallen dramatically. USA 6 *Number of jobless as percentage of civilian labour force; ILO definition Source: OECD October 7, 2010 7 7 8 Böttcher, Deutsch (2007). For a detailed discussion see Gräf, Schneider (2010a, b), Gräf (2010), Heymann, Just (2010). In autumn 2008 the government increased the entitlement periods for short-time working allowances from six to first 18 and subsequently (in January 2009) 24 months. 5 Current Issues Unemployed, labour force and short time workers In millions 6 41 5 40 4 40 3 39 2 39 1 0 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 38 June 2010 Unemployed (lhs) Short time workers (lhs) Labour force (rhs) Sources: Federal Labour Agency, Federal Statistical Office 8 Real GDP Private consumption Government spending Fixed capital formation Machinery and equipment Construction Germany thus achieved the feat of weathering a global recession without its labour market suffering any major harm. Instead of the rise to upwards of 4 million unemployed in 2010 that the Sachverständigenrat, for example, was predicting only a year ago, we can probably expect considerably fewer than 3.5 million on average for 2010 (not quite 3.2 million were registered in August 2010). Whether expiry of the various state measures and sluggish business activity at many trade partners will lead to a renewed rise in 2011 is not yet clear. However, we consider it unlikely that an economic slowdown would entirely wipe out the positive tendencies of rising employment with a decline in the supply of labour and presumably 10 slightly falling unit labour costs in 2010. The Federal Labour Agency is reckoning with not quite 3 million unemployed in 2011. Subdued economic outlook Forecast at a glance % yoy This pattern of adjustment to the recession initially caused the volume of work to contract by 3% in 2009 and labour productivity to decline steeply, not picking up again until spring 2010. As a reflection of this, unit labour costs soared by 5%. The unemployment rate (ILO definition on a seasonally adjusted basis) edged up only marginally and briefly, and in June 2010 it stood at 6.9%. Meanwhile, joblessness in June 2010 hit 10% in the euro area and 9.5% in the US, only slightly below their respective highs. In absolute terms the number of people out of work in Germany on average for 9 2009 climbed by just 155,000 year-on-year to not quite 3.5 million. On the whole, the number of people in work has even increased since 2007 and did not fall in any crisis year. 2009 2010E 2011E -4.7 3.4 1.7 -0.2 0.0 0.5 2.9 2.9 0.7 -10.1 5.2 2.0 -22.6 8.2 4.5 -1.5 2.6 -0.6 Exports -14.3 15.5 7.3 Imports -9.4 13.9 6.2 Sources: Federal Statistical Office, DB Research 9 Germany‘s economic outlook is mixed. This year we are pencilling in growth of around 3.5%, driven by a sharp acceleration in exports (by 12%), chiefly to Asia (there, in turn, with China as the major customer) and in machinery and equipment investment (by 8.2%). Industrial output will also gather steam. Although Germany has not yet returned to the production levels and capacity utilisation rates seen in the summer 2008 boom period, the export-centric capital goods and high-end consumer goods industries are on a rapid upward path with new orders up 20-30% on the previous year. Germany‘s four export industry champions – automotive, mechanical engineering, electrical engineering and chemicals – are doing particularly well: the better the fit between the regional structure of exports in any one sector and the uneven pattern of global economic recovery, the stronger the stimulus. Mechanical engineering could therefore benefit from Asia‘s growth. However, business activity in the US, Japan and the euro area is fragile. Many EU countries running high debt levels and facing critical developments on their sovereign debt markets have launched austerity packages. Germany itself presented a catalogue of measures in July 2010. Although fiscal policy remains expansive in 2010, the debt-reduction drive will start to bite in 2011. At the moment, all the stimulus is coming from buoyant growth in Asia and some emerging markets (Turkey, Brazil). 9 10 6 The statistics were adjusted in 2009; some of the people previously registered as out of work were no longer included. Boss et al. (2010), pp. 39-40. October 7, 2010 Germany‟s new strength? From stimulus to growth An outline of measures by the German government 2008-2010 General — Cut in the unemployment insurance contribution rate (from 4.2% to 3.3% w.e.f. 2008 to 2.8% w.e.f. 2009) and increases in contribution rates for nursing care insurance (0.25 percentage points) and statutory health insurances (0.6 percentage points) w.e.f. January 1, 2009 — Commuter allowance: return to legal situation in 2006 — Abolition of the homeowner subsidy — Increase in truck toll Financial market stabilisation acts (October 2008 / July 2009) — Creation of the Financial Market Stabilisation Fund (SoFFin) under which guarantees can be issued up to a total of EUR 400 bn (EUR 147 bn drawn down), equity injections made up to EUR 80 bn (EUR 28 bn drawn down) and toxic assets acquired from the banks — ―Bad Bank Act‖ on the transfer of toxic structured securities or non-strategic business areas to special purpose vehicles with the SoFFin and the establishment of winding-up agencies First and Second Economic Stimulus Package (Nov. 2008 / Jan. 2009) (EUR 85 bn) — Labour market policy: Extension of the entitlement period for short-time working benefits to 18 (ESP I) and 24 months (ESP II) up to the end of 2010 and subsidisation of short-time working allowances, prolonged until mid-2012; and setting of the unemployment insurance contribution at 2.8% until the end of 2010 and federal subsidy to the Federal Labour Agency (EUR 16 bn) — Cuts in taxes and other levies worth EUR 60 bn: Reduction in income tax scale in two stages, temporary lowering of statutory health insurance contribution rate of by 0.6 percentage points from July 2009 until the end of 2010, reintroduction of declining balance depreciation method and other relief for businesses — Increase in public-sector investment by EUR 20 bn (EUR 6 bn for motorways and railways; EUR 10 bn (Federal government) for education infrastructure and local infrastructure; EUR 3.3 bn (regional governments) for these purposes — Car scrappage bonus scheme: EUR 5 bn in subsidies Loan and credit guarantee programme (March 2009) — Wirtschaftsfonds Deutschland (German Business Fund): EUR 100 bn max. (EUR 75 bn for credit guarantees, EUR 25 bn to provide loans to large SMEs and big business) — Special KfW programme: EUR 15 bn for the provision of loans to SME businesses Citizens Relief Act (June 2009) (EUR 10.6 bn) — Improved tax-deductibility of contributions to health insurance and nursing care insurance (EUR 9.5 bn) — Application of a higher tax threshold to the interest barrier (Zinsschranke) in corporate taxation Act to Accelerate Economic Growth (January 2010) (EUR 8.3 bn) — Tax relief of altogether EUR 8.3 bn p.a. with measures including: relief for families (EUR 4.6 bn) by increasing the tax-free child allowance from EUR 6,024 to 7,008 and increasing child benefits — Relief for businesses (EUR 3.3 bn) by relaxing the existing restrictions on deducting losses and interest, improving write-off possibilities and amending corporation tax — Reduction of VAT to 7% in the hotel trade — Changes to inheritance tax (EUR 420 m) “Austerity package” (July 2010) (EUR 82 bn of budget consolidation*) — Welfare cuts (EUR 29.5 bn): cuts in compulsory benefits in the Social Code Books II + III, improved efficiency inter alia — Burdens on corporate sector (EUR 19.2 bn): tax compensation from the nuclear energy industry, railway dividend, financial market tax and fiscal privilege — Cuts in government administrative expenditure (EUR 13.4 bn) — Reduction in subsidies (EUR 10 bn): reducing tax privileges in the field of ecological taxation and introduction of an air transportation tax — Others (EUR 17.8 bn): interest savings, reform of armed forces, cuts in parenting and housing allowances and lower spending across the board *With budgetary effects in the fiscal years 2010-2014 vs previous budgetary planning Sources: BMWi (2009a, b, 2010), Sachverständigenrat (2010), p. 65; Boss et al. (2010), p. 32; BMF (2010). October 7, 2010 7 Current Issues German pragmatism in economic policy Current account balances As % of GDP 8 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6 2005 2006 2007 2008 Germany OECD EU Japan 2009 USA Source: OECD 10 Rates of growth In % 3 2 1 0 -1 -2 -3 -4 -5 -6 2007 2008 Germany OECD EU Japan 2009 USA Source: OECD 11 Ratios of government activity At the same time the government took steps to prevent a potential corporate credit crunch with a loan and credit guarantee programme worth EUR 115 bn. Moreover, its response to the banking crisis in autumn 2008, which did not come until after the collapse of Lehman Brothers but was then rolled out swiftly with intervention concentrating on two banks, massively defused the macroeconomic risks. These successes notwithstanding, the government intends to remain vigilant in its economic policy with a robust political agenda 13 designed to temper the very likely deterioration in potential growth as a result of the crisis. In its forecast up to 2014 the government is similarly pencilling in average real growth of only 1.5% p.a. – on the assumption that the output gap will have closed again by then and that (without further political reforms) medium-term potential growth 14 will amount to a scant 1% p.a. It is obvious that such meagre growth will make the consolidation of government finances an uphill task and that the public investment so urgently needed in areas such as education would have to be made at the expense of other outlays. Following the moves on economic policy in both directions – first strong expansion and then gradual restriction – it is now therefore only logical to focus greater attention on strengthening the forces driving growth. A growth agenda As % of GDP 2006 2007 2008 2009 Government spending 45.4 43.7 43.7 47.3 Contribution ratio 39.5 39.7 39.6 40.8 - Tax ratio 23.3 24.2 24.3 23.8 - Social contributions ratio Financial balance 16.2 15.5 15.3 17.0 -1.6 0.2 0.0 -3.1 Structural budget balance -1.9 -0.3 -1.0 k.A. Debt-to-GDP ratio 67.6 65.0 65.9 71.8 Sources: Sachverständigenrat (2009), p. 178; for 2009 Boss (2010) Economic and fiscal policy made a very major contribution to this 11 development (see p. 7). There can be no question that the government‘s macroeconomic countermeasures – diffident at first but subsequently comprehensive – prevented the worst. Consumer demand was stabilised and public-sector investment boosted with the aid of three economic stimulus packages (including the December 2009 Act to Accelerate Economic Growth – Wachstumsbeschleunigungsgesetz)) and a Citizens Relief Act (Bürgerentlastungsgesetz) providing total relief of more than EUR 90 bn, equivalent to almost 4% of GDP spread over two years; measures worth EUR 36 bn took effect in 2009 and the remaining EUR 54 bn this year. The fiscal stimulus is estimated at about 1.3% of GDP in 12 2009 and 0.8% in 2010. Stronger alignment of economic policy to the promotion of growth is very difficult to accomplish without reviving the debate on the role of the state versus that of the market. The economic and financial crisis has shifted emphasis away from the market and more towards the state. But extensive crisis intervention by the state is being conducted on top of what is already a high level of public sector activity. In 2007 the government sector in Germany was around 15 44%, and this year it is expected to brush 47%. Whilst there is no ideal level for government spending ratios, the structure and type of state activity do play a crucial part. When performance of (perceived) duties of the state permanently overtaxes its fiscal capacity, it is high time for a fundamental rethink. Irrespective of the fiscal (and political) cycles mentioned, since the 1970s the state sector in 12 11 12 13 14 15 8 See Enderlein (2010), Grasl, König (2010), for a critical overview Sinn (2010), Dullien et al. (2009) and Bofinger (2009), for example. Sachverständigenrat (2009), p. 65, pp. 166-174, Boss et al. (2010a), pp. 31-32. See IMF (2009). BMWi (2010c). On average, the government sector in the EU countries this year will pass the 50% mark, lifting it 5 percentage points above its 2007 pre-crisis level. October 7, 2010 Germany‟s new strength? From stimulus to growth Social market economy and social justice In % 100 200 This paradox is something Germany will presumably find hard to disregard. On the one hand, acceptance of our market-oriented economic regime is bound up closely with the aspect of social justice. On the other, a free market system is least able to provide social services on a scale permanently above its financial means. This is equally true if the funds required ultimately have to be made available by racking up public debt despite the fact that spending, tax and contribution ratios are all tracing an economically and politically acceptable path. Even the sensibly launched process of conversion from a ―welfare to a workfare state‖ (one in which the concept of caring for people in need is replaced by the aim of making provision to prevent people from having to rely on state assistance in the first place) cannot be entirely free from funding considerations. What Germany therefore needs is a fundamental debate not only on how it produces social security but also on what ―social justice‖ actually means and where the suitable means to achieve this – and the present-day limits to social justice – lie. In the context of a convincing growth agenda, we must ask ourselves whether the principle of social justice can be the foremost yardstick by which politics is measured. In most cases the answer to this will more likely be ―no‖ given the growing danger of missing out on growth opportunities, suffering efficiency losses or adopting social 17 benefits today at the expense of generations to come. 150 Modern economic policy – more balanced growth profile and reassessment of the welfare state 80 60 40 20 0 Total popul. Fair Unfair No opinion People who consider the situation in Germany to be… Opinion on social market economy: good negative undecided 13 Source: Allensbacher Archiv Social budget and GDP Rate of change in the decade in % 100 50 0 80* 90 Social budget 00 08 GDP *1980 vs 1970 Source: Own calculations following Sachverständigenrat (2009) Germany has always spent more money than it has collected in revenues. The bulk of public spending has gone on expanding the 16 welfare state. But at the same time – and despite still-high welfare expenditure overall – there is a growing perception in the country that Germany‘s Social Market Economy is out of social kilter. 14 Sensible as ‗pragmatic‘ economic policy may have been in the throes of the crisis, it will not therefore suffice to lead the current economic upsurge onto a sustainable longer-term growth path. Going forward, closer attention must be paid to giving vent to the forces driving domestic growth in order to reduce reliance on trade with other countries and to enable more evenly balanced economic development. This calls for government activity to be reined in and processes unleashed to improve productivity and add value in goods and services markets, and for more business competition. It is also a matter of leveraging the considerable value-adding potential in healthcare, nursing care and education. Market regulation. Unfortunately, since the reform of German crafts legislation and implementation of the Services Directive, market regulation policy, privatisation policy and policies to promote growth have taken rather too much of a back seat. Negative experience with the shelved attempt to take railroad operator Deutsche Bahn public and the failed attempt to privatise Deutsche Flugsicherung (German Air Traffic Control) may have something to do with this. Regulatory policy on the postal services did not exactly go smoothly 18 either. 16 17 18 October 7, 2010 The ratio of social expenditure to GDP has climbed from 24.5% in 1970 to more than 30% today. But back in the SDP-Green coalition period, the government already began stabilising the level of welfare benefits as a whole. A substantial part of the increase is due to integration of the east German states into the welfare system. The 2009 pension guarantee and the rekindled debate on retirement at 67 can be taken as cautionary examples of this. Herweg and Zohlnhöfer (2010). 9 Current Issues Gross value added by sectors Growth p.a. 2000-2007, in % 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 GER OECD Social services Financial and corporate services Transport and communications Wholesale and retail trade, hotels and restaurants Electricity, gas and water supply All sectors 0.5 0.0 USA Source: OECD 2010 15 Bad banks in Germany In December 2009 WestLB established a winding-up agency as a special purpose vehicle to which assets no longer counting as strategically essential, structured securities and toxic assets worth altogether EUR 77 bn have since been transferred. WestLB and its owners have provided the agency with up to EUR 4 bn of equity and guarantees to bear any losses it may incur; they are also liable for losses going beyond this. The Financial Market Stabilisation Fund (SoFFin) further plans to support the remaining core WestLB with EUR 3 bn of equity capital assistance, which still requires approval by the European Commission under European state aid legislation. Hypo Real Estate Bank (HRE) transferred EUR 173 bn of strategically non-essential assets and risk positions to the winding-up agency authorised this July under the aegis of SoFFin. Source: SoFFin But we need to dig deeper here. For more than 15 years now the pattern of growth in Germany has borne the stamp of marked weakness in the service industries. The OECD recently pointed out 19 again that in the period 2000-2007 Germany fell behind the OECD average in terms of gross value added by all major services sectors. Regrettably, no one really seems to know exactly why and what might be done to remedy the situation. But we do already have the odd pointer. Whilst corporate services turned in quite reasonable growth in absolute terms, consumer services – with the exception of social and education services – and services for mixed users showed very sluggish development. Generally, Germany currently lacks resolute liberalisation and competition policies on the banking market, in the crafts sector (despite initial successes under the Schröder government), in the liberal professions and in other industries that would stimulate productivity and output. At least the government has addressed the issue of boosting competition on the electricity and gas markets with the Bundesnetzagentur (Federal Network Agency) – and not a moment too soon, given their oligopolistic position. Restructuring of the Landesbanken, which are jointly owned by the regional state governments and the savings banks, has also slipped out of public sight. The premiers of the states involved had committed to this vis-à-vis the Federal government in 2009 in return for federal legislation‘s embracing a ‗bad bank‘ solution for the winding-up agencies installed by the states. However, the commitment to restructure the Landesbanken by the end of this year was a political one only – an outcome that the then federal finance minister Steinbrück subsequently described as a ―big mistake‖ because at the last moment the federal government surrendered its leverage for consolidation of the sector. His judgement tallies with 20 that of the Sachverständigenrat. Progress has yet to be made. The OECD is not alone with its germane criticism that, besides a cleanup of the Landesbanken balance sheets going easy on the taxpayer and balance sheet shrinkage in compliance with European regulation in the four cases in which state aid has been granted, restructuring should also comprise concentration on a sustainable business model, a merger into one to two companies and the 21 privatisation of bank assets. WestLB is the first to begin shifting toxic or non-strategic assets to SoFFin. An explicit privatisation policy by the Federal and state governments 22 could also create significant leeway in the public budgets. Furthermore, existing impediments to company start-ups and the weaknesses in seed funding for companies through venture and equity capital should be addressed. Important tasks likewise await infrastructure policy, notably in goods traffic and broadband. Additionally, the Federal government‘s otherwise laudable high-tech strategy is still very heavily skewed to industry. At least all its costcutting measures have bypassed the increase in research funding towards the 3% mark, and it should waste no time in including a tax R&D component for companies. 19 20 21 22 10 OECD (2010) and Deutsch, Frank, Gornig (2006). On the services industry in Germany in general see Ehmer (2009) and Schettkat (2010). For a discussion of the pros and cons of banking policy see e.g. Sinn (2009), Enderlein (2010) and Sachverständigenrat (2009), Chapter 4. OECD (2010), pp. 81ff.; Schrooten (2009), SVR (2009), pp. 124-130 and SVR (2008b). In 2008 the Federal Ministry of Finance listed 61 federal shareholdings, 59 of which would in principle be eligible for privatisation. See Herweg and Zohlnhöfer (2010), p. 258. October 7, 2010 Germany‟s new strength? From stimulus to growth Expansion and restriction Since 2000 German fiscal policy has been through two cycles of expansion and restriction – rather a lot in just ten years! While the government‘s income tax reform in 2000 and yawning public deficits featured most prominently in the first half of the decade, legislation passed by the Grand Coalition, notably the hike in the general rate of Value Added Tax from 16% to 19%, ushered in a return to consolidation. This policy achieved its goal of consolidating general government finances in 2008 and would also have worked shortly after at the federal level had the crisis not erupted. The German „debt brake‟ The debt brake adopted in 2009 commits the federal government to presenting a budget close to balance in 2016 with a structural deficit of no more than 0.35% of GDP or roughly EUR 10 bn. That necessitates embarking on this in 2011 in equal stages. Keystones of Federal financial planning Exit strategies. But the top priority is government withdrawal from the crisis intervention measures before both sides become overly accustomed to the situation. Quite correctly, the German economics minister has taken the positive economic data as an opportunity to confirm that the German Economic Support Fund (Wirtschaftsfonds Deutschland ) will expire at the end of the year (although loan and credit guarantee applications received up to December 31, 2010 will still be processed even after official expiry of the programme). That should prevent economic structures from solidifying beyond the crisis due to subsidies keeping companies with (financially) unsustainable business models afloat. Only about one-tenth of the funds available under the programmes had been drawn down anyway, given businesses‘ fairly sound financial structures and consequently slack demand for credit. Measures to shore up other economic sectors must also be rigorously reviewed to ensure that economic agents are not relieved of their own restructuring and consolidation obligations. A counter-example of the political handling of crisis interventions with a limited time frame is the government‘s short-time work scheme, in itself a sensible arrangement. It was, however, extended twice, most recently this April, although its original term until the end of 2010 would have sufficed to tide companies over their demand-driven employment difficulties. The government has embarked on the exit from its expansive, anticyclical fiscal policy – in 2010 a general government deficit 23 equivalent to 4 ½% of GDP is expected – with a consolidation package designed to trim federal budget deficits gradually by around half a percentage point a year. This is expected to cost about a 24 quarter of a point of annual growth from 2011. 65% of the measures, most of which work on the expenditure side, affect the social budget, which makes up 55% of the federal budget. This change of course is decreed not only by considerations of the Stability and Growth Pact and the constitutional requirements of the ‗debt brake‘; it appears equally urgent in view of the higher level of debt in relation to economic output (2010: 78%), which similarly breaches the rule in the stability pact and, judging by economic 25 experience, is anything but sustainable. The debt brake will at least see to it that the debt-to-GDP ratio falls appreciably over the long term. Fiscal policy beyond cost-cutting EUR bn 2010* 2011 2012 2013 2014 Exp. 319.5 307.4 301.0 301.5 301.1 Rev. 239.3 249.9 260.9 269.9 277.0 NB** 65.2 57.5 40.1 31.6 24.1 SD*** 53.2 45.8 39.0 32.1 25.1 SD**** 2.2 1.9 1.6 1.3 1.0 * Finance Ministry forecast summer 2010 ** Net borrowing *** Structural deficit **** Structural deficit as % of GDP Source: Federal Ministery of Finance 16 In the next four to five years the financial balances of all layers of government and the social security funds should be brought down significantly from their present hefty deficits towards zero. This should be accomplished primarily through the central, regional and local authorities setting prudent spending guidelines clearly below the expected level of nominal GDP growth and, to a limited extent, by increasing revenues. For the latter, the possibility of taking the axe to tax subsidies and federal and regional financial aid immediately springs to mind: in this legislative period the government could set itself the goal of making cuts equivalent to at least one percent of GDP (around EUR 25 bn) in subsidies and aid 26 totalling nearly EUR 130 bn. Revenues should not be increased by raising wage, income and corporation tax rates, especially since 23 24 25 26 October 7, 2010 The structural general government deficit in 2009 was 2.1% (SVR 2009, p. 178), but it is likely to rise sharply in 2010. Even so, reducing these fairly small deficits is not an insurmountable problem. See Zipfel (2010) for details of the package of measures. Rogoff, Reinhart (2009). Boss, Rosenschon (2010). 11 Current Issues Money spinner Value Added Tax VAT revenues in EUR bn, share in % 190 180 170 160 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 36 35 34 33 32 31 30 29 28 27 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 Share of VAT in total tax revenues (rhs) VAT revenues (lhs) Sources: BMF, own calculations 17 In %, 2010 target 3.3 Problems are looming in the medium term on the contributions front, mainly in healthcare and social care. On the other hand, and despite the government‘s ―pension guarantee‖, difficulties with funding for the statutory pension insurance scheme are only likely to build up gradually – although the contribution rate will remain high. And it should be possible to keep funding requirements on the labour market fairly low if all the reforms announced are put into practice. Another item still in need of attention is carefully aligned, step-instep conversion of the funding base for ―non-insurance‖ social security benefits, moving preferably to a tax-based instead of a contributions-based system, and reform of the funding for healthcare and nursing care (see below) as a whole. Experience has taught us that it is easier to exercise fiscal control over welfare states funded 31 by taxes than over systems financed chiefly through contributions. 4.8 5.1 11.7 54.2 17.0 Social security General public services (administration, defence, etc.) Interest expenditure Commercial enterprises, assets Education, science & research, cultural affairs Transport and communications Others Sources: BMF, DB Research The Coalition is to be commended for the planned transition to topdown budgeting along a path of politically pre-determined monitoring and for further institutional fiscal policy reinforcements. This kind of approach should smooth the way for projected changes in the context of greater budget policy coordination within the European Union (―European Semester‖) and, conversely, be driven ahead by them. Similarly copious consolidation work faces Germany at regional government level, even if spot-on compliance with the debt brake is 29 not necessary until 2020. Nonetheless, a painful consolidation policy will be necessary very soon. At the same time, the reorganisation of local government finance should succeed at the 30 third attempt, placing finances on a more stable footing. Federal expenditure by functions 3.9 these are now comfortably in the middle range on an OECD comparison. By and large, however, the course adopted in the austerity package with the imposition of extra, sector-specific levies and taxes has not taken this direction; but at least some tax breaks are up for review. Rigorous cuts in tax privileges and more stringent taxation of external environmental effects, and possibly also increasing revenues from property tax, would be suitable mediumterm ways of creating the scope for corrections to the reform of 27 corporate taxation and for significant and fundamentally appropriate relief for the populace in the income tax schedule – the buzzwords being ―getting rid of the middle-class spread‖ and ―cold progression‖, ―integration of the solidarity surcharge‖, ―extending the 28 progressive zone‖ . Estimates on the potential relief range up to EUR 24 bn. The economically inappropriate variety of goods and services to which the reduced rate of value added tax applies also merits strict scrutiny. 18 But fiscal policy should not only set its sights on the broad brush of government activity; instead it should prioritise expenditure in policy areas that make a verifiable and demonstrable contribution to potential growth. Undisputed candidates here are education and research (and hence parts of government consumption), spending on which remains obstinately inadequate; expenditure on public infrastructure in general and on transport infrastructure and local infrastructure in particular; and state incentives to investment in certain areas. The Coalition‘s self-imposed commitment to increase 27 28 29 30 31 12 See e.g. Morawitz, Wiegard (2009) on this complicated issue. OECD (2010). See Kastrop, Sudhof, Meister-Scheufelen (2010) on the debt brake. See Zipfel (2010a) on the situation with local finances and on possible funding models. Wagschal (2006), Becker et al. (2008). October 7, 2010 Germany‟s new strength? From stimulus to growth Social budget As % of GDP 10 8 6 4 2 1970 1980 1990 2000 0 2008 Illness Unemployment Old age * Includes children, maternity and married couples Source: Own illustration following Sachverständigenrat (2009) 19 Contractual minimum wages Number of Minimum workers wage (€) Waste management 130,000 8.02 Construction sector - West 289,100 10.82 - East 92,600 9.25 Roofing trade 58,200 10.60 Industrial cleaning 700,000 - West 8.40 - East 6.83 Care provision sector 800,000 - West 8.50 - East Security services e. g.* 7.50 170,000 8.46 - BadenWürttemberg - North RhineWestphalia - HesseMinimum Challenges remain for labour market policy For all the good news coming out of the labour market, key regulatory issues remain unresolved. One is the role that minimum wages will have to play going forward. For another, satisfying the demand for skilled personnel merits increasing attention. Family* Sector spending on education points in the right direction, although the bar is still set far too low. Nor should policy-makers stop short of a specific review of government spending, for instance on the big welfare budget and most particularly the outgoings on policies for families – all the more so since it is a well-known fact that German welfare policy pays too much account to the interests of old people and jobholders and too little to those of young people and out32 33 siders. This quality agenda for fiscal policy is therefore equally as important as the observation of numerical rules and quantitative management of budget balances required by the Stability Pact and the EU‘s debt rule. 7.82 wages and the 7.50 basic at6.53 odds welfare - East Germany incl. Berlinbenefit * From 01/2011, generally binding character not yet clarified Source: WSI-Tarifarchiv 20 Minimum wages. The government has not adopted a clear position on the subject of minimum wages. Whilst it rejects a uniform statutory minimum wage and has announced an evaluation of the existing minimum wage regulations by October 2011, the conservative-liberal coalition is pursuing the expansion of the controversial wage limits launched by the preceding Grand Coalition. New contractual minimum wages for various sectors have been declared generally binding and a minimum wage ordinance issued for the care provision sector for the first time. Moreover, temporary employment is to be included in the Law on the Posting of Workers. These moves are aimed at labour-intensive sectors in which pressure on wages is also expected from the supply side of the labour market, especially once it is opened up on May 1, 2011 to workers from the Central European EU member states. Social welfare associations, trade unions and the Opposition parties have long been clamouring for nationwide minimum wages to stem further expansion of the low wage sector. However, there is a very serious risk here of protection for jobholders robbing jobseekers of chances to obtain employment, and of 34 legislators thus cementing labour market segmentation. Traditional labour market theory identifies clearly negative effects on employment from minimum wages. It is true that economic theory also admits of conditions, e.g. monopoly job-suppliers, from which other outcomes can be deduced, but these are likely to be exceptional cases of little overall relevance. The many empirical studies and international comparisons are of little help to policy-makers here. As a rule their findings are disputed – which is understandable if only because the institutional framework of relevance to employment varies over time and even more so from country to country. It is, however, evident that the higher the minimum wage the more detrimental it will be to employment. Basically, minimum wages ill fit the basic welfare benefit currently in 35 operation in Germany (Hartz IV). This is geared to placing recipients of state transfers as quickly as possible in employment 32 33 34 35 October 7, 2010 Cf. Schmidt (2010). For greater detail on this see Becker et al. (2008), Kastrop (2008), SVR (2008), pp. 250-256, and SVR (2009). Cf. Ifo Institut (2008) on the minimum wage debate. But what does require regulation is wage-setting behaviour deliberately designed to exploit the welfare system by setting wages so low that they are just about tolerable for the person employed when ―topped up‖ by the minimum basic benefit. 13 Current Issues that will secure their basic livelihood. Taking on low-paid work (temporarily) may be a decisive step in this process, particularly for the long-term unemployed. Here, the job serves primarily as a means of (re)integration (learning by doing), while the basic livelihood is secured in combination with Hartz IV benefits (additional earnings disregard). Minimum wages block this bridge into the jobs market to the extent that they reduce the availability of low-skilled jobs. Given the high number of 2.2 million Hartz IV recipients alone registered as unemployed, this should not be allowed to happen. Alternatives such as subsidies for firms offering jobs of this kind, or even state job creation companies, are expensive and have proved of little use. The problem of the high cost of combi-wages (EUR 11 bn in 2009) should be tackled by reforming the additional earnings disregard arrangement (see below). Shortage of skilled staff becoming acute Skilled labour. Given the strong business upswing in latter months, the shortage of skilled staff has already become an issue for some sectors. But it is in the medium term that the problem threatens to jeopardise potential growth. The Cologne Institute for Economic 36 Research (IW) estimates that German business will need around four million academics by the middle of the coming decade, way above the number of university graduates available. According to the consultancy Prognos, by 2030 Germany could find itself short of altogether 4.5 million skilled workers (with a university degree or 37 professional qualifications). The ever more pressing scarcity of highly qualified staff over time is chiefly a reflection of the demographically-related shortage of fresh talent, but it is also partly due to failings in education. Higher birth rates would take decades at best to alleviate the problem. Germany is therefore heavily reliant on the influx of skilled labour from abroad, but for this it needs to improve the institutional conditions. Germany needs qualified immigrants Immigration. Germany does have concepts for a rational immigration policy like that practised in Canada, for instance; among others, there are the recommendations by the Süssmuth Commission. But the immigration legislation currently in force is still quite a long way behind this, due chiefly to the rejection of a qualification-based selection process (points-based system). Further steps towards immigration regulations geared to longer-term labour market requirements would therefore be welcome. Germany‘s migration balance has been very low in recent years, if not negative. Yet many official projections are based on the assumption of net immigration of 200,000 people a year. Migration balance* 8 6 4 2 0 -2 91 93 95 97 99 01 03 05 07 09 *Difference between in migration from abroad and out migration from Germany Source: Federal Statistical Office 21 Hunderte In 100,000 In parallel to this, the qualification levels of the labour already available should be furthered. In the 12 years up to 2007 the proportion of young people with tertiary education (university and university of applied sciences degrees) was increased from 14% to 25%. Further progress needs to be made here. In tertiary education Germany still falls short of the 38% OECD average, but as a highwage country it should be in the top segment. Greater efforts in respect of qualification and integration must also focus heavily on the growing number of young people from immigrant families. In the short term, measures to improve the transparency of qualifications that migrants have obtained abroad could be helpful here. 36 37 14 Anger, Plünnecke (2010). Prognos (2010). October 7, 2010 Germany‟s new strength? From stimulus to growth Setting social policy on a sensible track The cost of Hartz IV In EUR bn 50 40 30 20 10 0 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Source: Federal Labour Agency 22 Hartz IV is still paradoxically widely viewed as synonymous with cutbacks in the welfare state, even though the costs of basic benefits remain persistently high (around EUR 46 bn in 2009). A unilateral upward adjustment would probably do little to temper this dissatisfaction but could cause expenditure on benefits to soar, given around 6.9 million recipients at last count. Nonetheless there remains broad consensus that support should focus on increases for the not quite 1.8 million children in the Hartz IV system. To ensure that the assistance actually reaches these children, policy-makers are concentrating on encouraging the use of childcare, educational, leisure and sports facilities. Alternative ways being discussed to achieve this include issuing vouchers and electronic solutions (socalled FamilyCards) to prevent potential stigmatisation of the recipients. However, the question that arises here is just how far these objectives justify the additional costs involved. Structure of Hartz IV expenditure* In % 9.3 12.6 49.1 29.0 Long term unemployment benefits (ALG II) Accommodation costs Integration Administration *Excl. authorised local administrative units Source: Federal Labour Agency 23 Recipients of long term unemployment benefits (ALG II) In millions 3 2 1 0 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010* * 1st half-year Source: Federal Labour Agency Difficult tasks await social policy. The Federal Constitutional Court ruling of unconstitutionality on the way in which the standard rate of basic welfare benefit (Hartz IV) is calculated gives cause to review the benefits. It is a matter of balancing considerable cost risks against popular demands for higher payments. But legislators must not loose sight of the primary objective – to get more people in need of assistance back to full-time employment. Conflicts are also looming over how to make funding of the statutory health and longterm care insurance schemes more sustainable. Good solutions offer the prospect of a double dividend here: greater intergenerational fairness and fresh impetus to competition in dynamic areas whose importance (generating 10.5% of GDP) and aboveaverage growth potential could make a big contribution to a more 38 domestically focused growth strategy. 24 It is evident that a blanket increase in the standard rate of basic welfare benefits for the roughly 5 million Hartz IV recipients able to work would cause costs to surge. But more is at stake than just the direct costs. The standard rates form the linchpin of the welfare system, and if they are shifted a lot could be thrown out of kilter. Firstly, they set the benchmark for a reservation wage and hence the minimum wage below which it is financially unattractive to take up work (voluntarily). At roughly EUR 4.50, this minimum wage seems moderate for single persons, but problems arise with people in need of assistance who have unemployed spouses/partners and/or children. Even now, the Lohnabstandsgebot, the principle that benefits should be below the going wage, hardly applies for these 39 groups. A substantial increase in standard rates could make the rapid integration of many recipients of benefits into the labour force even more difficult. Secondly, the standard rates are the fixed point for the additional earnings disregard, in the case of Hartz IV the combi-wage. The Coalition plans to improve this regulation to give recipients of state benefits a greater incentive to take up full-time employment. At present the first EUR 100 of the additional earnings disregard is not counted towards the benefits at all. Welfare payments are reduced 38 39 October 7, 2010 Bräuninger, Rakau (2010) and Blinkert, Gräf (2009). Boss et al. (2010b). In principle, the precept that people in work should receive more than those that do not work has been realised – support to supplement income falling short of the level of basic benefits, such as the child supplement and housing benefits in particular, take care of that. However, the child supplement in turn creates negative (lock-in) effects (professional advancement is not worthwhile), see Mauer (2006). 15 Current Issues Hartz IV as combi-wage* Recipients in 100,000 1,400 97 111 398 335 1,000 197 201 210 800 606 643 2007 2008 68 349 1,200 600 665 400 200 0 2009 up to € 400 more than € 800 € 400 to 800 Others *Number of employed Harzt IV recipients by gross income Source: Federal Labour Agency 25 Needy persons capable of employment 2009, in % 10 44 37 But lowering the currently high benefit withdrawal rates would only partly solve the problem with mini-jobs, and most importantly it 40 would prove relatively expensive. Increasing the Hartz IV standard rates will also automatically lead to rising costs. The higher reservation wage obliges the government to raise the limit for partial offset of earned incomes if it does not wish to weaken incentives to take up work through higher withdrawal rates. The IZA Institute for 41 the Study of Labour calculates that lowering the benefit withdrawal rate to 60% for incomes between EUR 100 and EUR 1,000 would cost an extra EUR 6 bn a year, and this does not even allow for an increase in standard benefit rates. The fiscal sensitivity of the issue should keep a tight rein on well-meaning proposals for higher Hartz IV benefits. Generally speaking, a situation in which fewer than 10% of people in need of support hold down a full-time job, while almost 40% are not available (at least on a temporary basis) to the labour market at all, should not be allowed to persist. Were it possible to reduce this ratio to at least 30% and to halve the number of jobless benefit seekers, employment could be boosted by no less than 1.5 million, or roughly 3 ½%. Even on the assumption that these workers would exhibit below-average productivity the outcome could still be one-off GDP growth of more than 1%. Health policy. In the healthcare sector – a constant reform work in progress – the government is planning a triple jump. Bidding to alleviate immediate and looming funding woes in the statutory health insurance system (SHI), where the 2011 deficit could top the EUR 10 bn mark, the Coalition aims to cut back spending, hike contribution rates and muster the courage to really start rolling out nonincome-related additional premiums. The latter is a bold step whose political success is as yet by no means guaranteed. 10 Employment schemes Others* Employed persons** Unemployed*** *E.g. Caring for relatives, illness, students, bringing up children under 3 years **With a gross income > € 400 ***Incl. mini-jobs Source: Federal Labour Agency by 80% of additional (net) income between EUR 100 und 800, by 90% on income above this and by the full amount of the additional net income once it reaches EUR 1,200. This is presumably a key reason why only 0.34 million of the more than 1.3 million recipients of Hartz IV are in full-time employment. On the other hand, roughly 0.7 million – that is to say more than half – have a 400 euro job. 26 West German SHI contribution rate As % of income liable to insurance contributions 16 15 14 13 12 11 10 9 8 7 6 Cost containment measures worth around EUR 2 ¼ bn have already hit the pharmaceutical industry, which has been obliged inter alia to grant the health insurance funds higher rebates on new drugs. Now – amid recent hefty increases in expenditure – the health insurance funds, hospitals and broad sections of office-based physicians must likewise step up to the plate (with a contribution of altogether EUR 1 ¼ bn in 2011). Applying the brakes to spending is essential, but it is no substitute for further structural improvements to foster competition and efficiency. Government has yet to deliver on this. With the increase in SHI contributions on January 1, 2011 from 14.9% at present to 15.5% (adding around EUR 6.3 bn) the government is approaching its self-imposed cap of 40% on social security contributions (financed equally by employees and employers), especially as the unemployment insurance contribution is to be raised at the same time from 2.8 to 3.0% (with pension insurance contributions remaining at 19.9%). Indeed, factoring in the extra 0.9% employee contribution to the SHI, this limit is clearly 40 70737578818386899194979902050710 Source: Versicherungsnetz 27 41 16 Especially if the incomes above EUR 1,200 are still subsidized, as would be necessary to avoid major discontinuities in the withdrawal of benefits. It is therefore worth considering not exempting the first EUR 100 but counting all or most of it towards benefit withdrawal, as recently proposed by the Cologne Institute for Economic Research (IW), for example (see IW 2010). Pichl (2010). October 7, 2010 Germany‟s new strength? From stimulus to growth New system of additional contributions planned Health expenditure 1992=100 230 210 190 170 150 130 110 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 SHI (statutory health insurance system) PKV (private health insurance) Employers Private* * Private households / private not-for-profit organisations Sources: Destatis, DB Research 28 breached. The higher contribution rates patently contradict the necessity to reduce the burden of contributions for people in the low and middle income range in particular. Arguably the only alternative feasible in the short term, however, would be even higher tax subsidies for the SHI. But already this year the federal government is coming to the aid of the SHI with EUR 11.8 bn (fully EUR 15.7 bn counting the additional subsidy to compensate shortfalls in revenue resulting from the economic crisis). The 2011 shot in the arm will cost almost EUR 14 bn. This makes reform of SHI funding geared to the medium term all the more important. The plans submitted point in the right direction. Essentially, employers‘ contributions are to be frozen at 7.3%, severing the peg to labour costs. Going forward, disproportionate increases in healthcare spending will therefore no longer stand in the way of employment – a step towards strengthening potential growth. The system of additional contributions is also to be reorganised. At present these contributions are capped at 1% of earned income. Future planning sees the health insurance funds being able to set the amount of additional contributions at their own discretion. This would give them sovereignty in this area and turn additional contributions into a potentially significant parameter in competition for members. To prevent people insured under the statutory scheme from being overburdened by additional contributions, the contributions that each individual must bear will be capped at 2% of their income liable to social insurance contributions. Where additional contributions overstep this level, state assistance kicks in. However, the amount of the state refund is calculated not on the basis of the contributions actually levied by the health insurance fund but by the target amounts that the SHI‘s own independent administration sets for a year in advance. If an insurance fund‘s additional contributions are above this target level, its members will have no choice but to pay the excess amounts – irrespective of the 2% additional contribution cap. This gives all contributors, including those subsidised by the state, an incentive to switch to insurance funds with lower contributions. The state aid is to be financed by the Gesundheitsfonds, a centralised health fund. In the medium term its financial resources will be built up through higher subsidies from tax revenues. People insured under private health insurance schemes (PHI) will contribute towards the new social equalization through tax revenues, which should silence at least part of the criticism of the PHI. Of course, the rising transfers required in the longer term (going forward, SHI expenditure will increase faster than labour incomes due partly to demographic trends) will pose a further challenge for the national budget. Even in the short term, the fact that the insured will be able to claim their additional contributions – which will be considerably higher next year already – against tax could give rise to problems. Liberal critics also object to retention of the Gesundheitsfonds and, even more so, the morbidity-based structural risk adjustment that redistributes revenues among the health insurance funds. But remedying this defect would take nothing short of a revolution – the introduction of insurance premiums geared to health risks such as have traditionally been customary in PHI. October 7, 2010 17 Current Issues As a result of the reform SHI members will themselves have to shoulder more of the expected rise in healthcare spending. From a regulative point of view this is fitting. However, legislators should communicate the message clearly to the people, because they are the ones who must prepare for the situation by saving more and/or working until later in life. System becoming increasingly complex With the blueprint as it stands at present the government is moving only partially and gradually towards the model originally favoured – a flat-rate insurance premium or what became known as the ‗Citizens‘ Insurance Scheme‘ – along the lines designed by the Sachverständigenrat. This is due partly to fiscal constraints. It comes not only at the expense of time delays; more importantly financing for the SHI system is made even more complex and opaque and the rather inaccurate redistribution of incomes through premiums remains in operation – even if it will become less relevant over time. Nursing care insurance. The CDU/CSU/FDP coalition agreement provides inter alia for full funding of the nursing care insurance scheme to enhance the present pay-as-you-go system. This is to be made ―compulsory, individualised and intergenerationally fair‖. An interministerial working group is supposed to draw up proposals on this by early 2011. But that is no easy matter. There are very good reasons why fully funded nursing care insurance has been on the social policy agenda for years now. But only this legislative period remains for policy-makers to take the plunge: any later and the target will probably be out of range, given that building up any capital stock of note takes much longer than a decade. Climate and energy policy Greenhouse gas emissions 1990-2009 In m tonnes CO2 equivalent 1,400 1,200 1,000 800 600 400 200 0 90 95 00 05 Total by source categories Energy Industrial processes Agriculture Others Source: Umweltbundesamt 29 Climate policy trailblazer? The past twenty years have already seen big changes in Germany‘s climate and energy policy. Faced with the growing risks of climate change, various federal governments have tightened the reins on climate and environmental policy. This is hitting the electricity industry hardest, because Germany‘s energy production is heavily skewed to coal, making it one of the biggest greenhouse gas emitters in the EU. But by modernising hard coal-fired power plants and the network of power stations in the east of the country, and with the rapid rise of renewables, Germany has 42 made enormous headway in lowering greenhouse gases. Moreover, since the late 1980s it has earned itself a reputation for pursuing an aspirational environmental policy, with national targets for 43 the reduction in greenhouse gas emissions , market incentives, environmental taxes (notably the 1999 Ecotax and the truck toll on heavy goods vehicles), subsidies for renewable energies and pushing through emissions trading in the EU as illustrations. Possibly the most controversial issue was, and remains, the decision in 2002 to phase out nuclear power. The upshot of this relatively challenging environmental policy is that German companies have taken the innovative lead in many environmental goods and technologies. Nonetheless, the conceptual integration of energy and climate policy in the past decade has been a neverending project causing elements of uncertainty, especially with regard to investment in power stations. 42 43 18 See Jänicke (2010), Schmidt (2007) and Kemfert (2007). As early as 1990 the government set itself the target of a 25% reduction by 2005, initially taking 1987 as the reference year and subsequently 1990. October 7, 2010 Germany‟s new strength? From stimulus to growth German climate protection targets Reduction in greenhouse gas emissions (vs 1990): — 40% by 2020 — 55% by 2030 — 70% by 2040 — 80% by 2050 Share of renewable energy in gross consumption of energy by end users: — 18% by 2020 — 30% by 2030 — 45% by 2040 — 60% by 2050 Share of renewables in electricity consumption: — 35% in 2020 — 50% in 2030 — 65% in 2040 — 80% in 2050 Source: BMU 2010 Not that politicians have sat on their hands. Most recently, in 2008 the Grand Coalition rolled out an integrated energy and climate protection programme. This had positive effects on growth and employment and was intended to reduce German emissions by between 34% and 36% (versus 1990) up to 2020. But even the government admitted that this fell short of what was actually required; its self-imposed target was 40%. Among the most prominent components were work on buildings, incentives for the generation of power from renewables, projects referring to the transport sector, financial inducements for combined heat and power systems and a package of measures to boost energy efficiency in general. Additionally the government pushed in both the G8 and the United Nations for ambitious long-term emission reduction targets, advocating that emissions be cut by at least 80% (on 1990) by 2050. Meanwhile studies abound on how to achieve this or indeed to go 44 even further (up to 90 to 95%). Moreover, EU emissions trading is designed to reduce the listed greenhouse gases by 75% up to 2050 with continuation of the pace of linear reduction for emissions beyond the end of the third trading period (2013-2020). Outside of the emission trading scheme, Germany has also committed within the framework of the EU‘s integrated energy and climate package to a 14% reduction in greenhouse gases by 2020 (taking 2005 as the reference year). That total German emissions had already fallen by 22.4% up to 2008 was undoubtedly helpful here. Germany should therefore be able to meet the 21% prescribed in the Kyoto Protocol (2012/2008 on 1990). Transforming the energy industry is a massive task. A calculable efficiency policy reducing energy consumption, an efficient framework for renewables, a consistent institutional environment for coal- and nuclear-based power generation and a grid and storage strategy represent the major long-term parameters for development of the energy mix and compliance with climate targets. At the beginning of September 2010 the centre-right coalition government presented the basic outlines of an integrated energy 45 and climate policy package. The government blueprint consists of setting long-range targets for lowering emissions, for the share of renewable energies in gross demand by end users for energy and in electricity generation, for the reduction of energy consumption and for strengthening the institutional framework in this policy area. Terms of reference are also to be put in place for monitoring and for 46 adjustments if targets are not met. The blueprint does not rely on EU emissions trading alone, presumably because the targets set 47 were not ambitious enough (see sidebar). The price signals alone were not therefore sufficient to trigger the necessary investment; a complementary policy is needed for the promotion of research and innovation, the development of an appropriate grid and storage infrastructure, and specific incentive regulation. Efficiency. Further adjustments also need to be made in the efficiency strategy geared to approximately doubling the pace of 48 energy savings so far (1.5% p.a.). By 2050, for example, it is 44 45 46 47 48 October 7, 2010 See e.g. McKinsey (2007), WWF (2010). BMWi and BMU (2010). See Ecologic (2009), particularly on the complication of interaction between (legally binding) targets at national and EU level. Matthes (2010). According to the Sustainability Report (Federal Statistical Office 2010), energy productivity climbed between 2000 and 2008 by 1.4% p.a. To meet the official 19 Current Issues Is emissions trading alone the road to salvation? Some people consider strict emissions trading alone sufficient to enforce climate targets. However, closer examination of the mechanism shows this to be incorrect because firstly, in political practice emissions trading has not been designed with due rigour for many reasons of political economy; secondly, only about half the emissions in the EU are covered; and thirdly, market imperfections cannot be eliminated either. An important point is the complementarities that exist between the at least partial provision of energy and transport infrastructures by the public sector and private investment, for example — in electromobility, the electricity grid, the storage and recharging infrastructure, — CCS and the transport and storage infrastructure, — transportation infrastructure planning and private transport investment. Another issue is the barriers to market introduction of low-emission technologies competing with high-emission and/or established technologies when external environmental impacts are not correctly factored in. Policy-makers must therefore use a variety of tools, but all the while paying attention to the interrelationships between them. Important instruments in addition to emissions trading are taxes and financial incentives, regulative legislation and grid regulation. Moreover, the toolkit must be coordinated across the relevant EU and national levels. It is thus obvious that when designing emissions trading, for example – and emissions reduction in particular – the promotion of renewable energies must be taken into consideration. For coal-based power generation and CCS technology, too, all the tools available must be analysed together and their mutual impacts coordinated. The same naturally applies to the taxes and energy carriers encompassed by EU emissions trading. planned to reduce electricity consumption by a quarter. It is in buildings that the economically most attractive potential for cutting 49 back on consumption lies. There the pace of refurbishment is to be doubled from 1% p.a. to 2% p.a. in order to slash four-fifths of demand for heating by 2050. But the regulations governing upgrading of the energy efficiency of existing rental property remain the big stumbling block given that there is a user-investor dilemma in rent law and that it is almost impossible at present to share the economies obtained from energy efficiency upgrading. However, amendments to rent regulations are on the agenda. Were regulation successful, substantial investment could be expected over a long period, with a significant impact on growth and employment. The existing KfW programme will not create sufficient pace here: so far a scant 3% of the existing stock of property has been upgraded. A large number of measures are planned, including efficiency programmes for consumers and industry. Renewable energies. The main source of uncertainty over renewables lies less in the technologies involved than in development of the grids and storage capacities. Only if this impediment is successfully removed can demand and supply be brought together. By 2020 the share of renewables is to be ramped up from around 10% to 18% of gross final energy consumption by end users. In August 2010 the Federal government adopted a National Renewable Energy Action Plan complying with the requirements of the EU directive on renewable energies, which provides for an increase in the share of renewables in heating/cooling to 15.5%, in electricity to 38.6% and in transport to 13.2%. But it has at least made some correction in its very generous feed-in tariff rates for photovoltaic. Within just a few years greater use of market mechanisms is to be made with a view to more cost-efficient production. Coal. With the changeover of coal- and gas-based electricity generation to carbon capture and sequestration (CCS), considerable uncertainty surrounds the amounts of investment required, clarification of the storage issue, long-range development in the price of EU emissions trading certificates and other factors (political resistance to storage). The introduction of CCS technology is extremely important in terms of the economic viability of coal-based 50 electricity generation. In July the government adopted the basic parameters for legislation on trialling CCS power stations and plans to finalise its legislative passage by the end of the year. It also intends to have two demonstration power plants built in Germany and to offer incentives for CCS-enabled new-builds when old plant becomes due for replacement. However, this falls well short of the requirements for plannable commercial introduction, leaving the future of coal-based electricity generation shrouded in uncertainty. Nuclear. The major change versus SPD-Greens policy, which was not up for debate in the Grand Coalition, refers to nuclear power. On September 5 the new Coalition government reached agreement on the use of nuclear energy: power reactor run times are to be extended by an average of 12 years per plant (eight years for reactors built before 1980 and 14 for those built in 1980 and thereafter). But owing to specific calculation based on the residual electricity volume they may still produce, individual power plants will 49 50 20 target of doubling between 1990 and 2020, the pace needs to be stepped up to 3.5% p.a. Auer, Heymann and Just (2008). See Auer (2007) and Herold, von Hirschhausen (2010) for a discussion of coal in general. October 7, 2010 Germany‟s new strength? From stimulus to growth Primary energy consumption by energy sources Shares in % -0.4 1.7 8.7 11.0 Grids. Devising a national grid strategy accommodating the requirements of feed-ins of electricity from offshore wind turbines in the North Sea and the Baltic Sea, as well as from biomass and solar panels, is also on the agenda. The development of extra-high voltage grids connecting the new production regions in the north of Germany to the centres of consumption in the south and west is sadly lagging behind demand. Now the government is setting out to address the obstacles to investment in the grid infrastructure. Renewables development also calls for heavy investment in distribution networks and storage facilities capable of decentralised 52 load management, so-called smart grids. Correspondingly comprehensive are the resolutions on these strategy components, which are to flow into a ten-year development plan and a federal grid plan. It is not clear whether the economic incentives to invest in the grid and storage infrastructure have been made strong enough. 34.9 21.9 11.0 11.3 Petroleum Hard coal Lignite Natural gas, petroleum gas Nuclear energy Renewable energies Electricity trage balance Others Source: Arbeitsgemeinschaft Energiebilanzen, status June 2010 30 Power generation by sources, 2009 As % (of altogether 596.8 Twh) 4.8 Beyond electricity. In industry, another very important factor is reducing process heat with new materials and methods, but even in the long term certain emissions will presumably be almost 53 inevitable. Meanwhile, in the transport sector price signals and taxes (such as the truck toll) are being very slow to take effect. Most important here is the gradual switchover of drive systems to low emission technologies and fuels and shifting a substantial amount of goods carriage from road to rail. On the other hand, the regulation of fuel consumption for cars in the EU is already far advanced, arguably going beyond an appropriate abatement cost level. There are still plenty of other more efficient ways to drive climate protection forward. Potential output growth lies not only with energy services themselves but also in the skilled trades and construction, in software development and in small and medium-sized engineering firms. Barbara Böttcher (+49 69 910-31787, barbara.boettcher@db.com) 18.3 14.7 possibly remain online for considerably longer. From 2011 to 2016 a nuclear fuel-rod tax is to be levied, with power plant operators additionally being called upon to contribute large sums towards the promotion of renewable energies. The main impact of this regulatory revamp will be on nuclear plant operation, on the competitive situation for electricity suppliers and on investment in the various 51 segments of electricity generation and grids. Dr. Klaus Günter Deutsch (+49 30 3407-3682, klaus.deutsch@db.com) 24.5 22.6 12.9 Hard coal 2.1 Lignite Petroleum Natural gas Nuclear energy Renewables Others Source: BMWi website 31 51 52 53 October 7, 2010 See the study by the Institute of Energy Economics (EWI) et al. (2010) for the German government. Auer and Nguyen (2010). Röttgen (2010). 21 Current Issues Literature Anger, Christina and Axel Plünnecke (2010). Droht durch den künftigen Akademikermangel eine Abnahme der Konvergenzchancen Ostdeutschlands? In IW-Trends 2/2010. Institut der deutschen Wirtschaft. Cologne. Auer, Josef (2007). Technology to clean up coal for the post-oil era. DB Research. Current Issues, February 2007. Frankfurt am Main. Auer, Josef, Eric Heymann, Tobias Just (2008). Building a cleaner planet. The construction industry will benefit from climate change. DB Research. Current Issues. November 2008. Frankfurt am Main. Auer, Josef und Thu-Lan Nguyen (2010). Revolutionary developments in power industry – expansion of new energies requires massive investment in grid restructuring. DB Research. Talking point. April 1, 2010. Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte (2009). Bundestagswahl 2009. 51/2009, 14.12. Supplement to weekly ―Das Parlament‖. Becker, Werner, Sascha Brok, Klaus Günter Deutsch, Frank Zipfel (2008). Improving the quality of public finances – the road ahead. A workshop report. DB Research. Current Issues, February 2008. Frankfurt am Main. Blinkert, Baldo and Bernhard Gräf (2009). Deutsche Pflegeversicherung vor massiven Herausforderungen. DB Research. Aktuelle Themen 442. Frankfurt am Main. Bofinger, Peter (2009). Ist der Markt noch zu retten? Berlin: Ullstein. Böttcher, Barbara and Klaus Günter Deutsch (2007). Germany cresting the wave – A reform agenda for the Grand Coalition. DB Research. Current Issues. September 2007. Frankfurt am Main. Boss, Alfred et al. (2010a). Deutschland: Konjunkturelle Erholung setzt sich in verlangsamtem Tempo fort – Gefahr eines Rückschlags durch die Schuldenkrise. Institut für Weltwirtschaft, Kiel. Kieler Diskussionsbeiträge 481/482. Boss, Alfred et al. (2010b). Die Hartz IV-Falle: Wenn Arbeit nicht mehr lohnt. Institut für Weltwirtschaft, Kiel. Kieler Diskussionsbeiträge 474/475. Boss, Alfred and Astrid Rosenschon (2010). Subventionen in Deutschland: Der Kieler Subventionsbericht. Institut für Weltwirtschaft, Kiel. Kieler Diskussionsbeiträge 479/480. Bräuninger, Dieter and Oliver Rakau (2010). Gesundheitswirtschaft im Aufwind. DB Research. Aktuelle Themen 481. Frankfurt am Main. Brüderle, Rainer (2010). Die zukünftige Energiepolitik der Bundesregierung. Speech, July 1. Berlin. Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft und Technologie. Bundesministerium für Umwelt, Naturschutz und Reaktorsicherheit (2010). Energiekonzept. September 6, 2010. Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft und Technologie (2010a). Jahreswirtschaftsbericht 2010. BMWi. Berlin. --- (2010b). Projektion der gesamtwirtschaftlichen Entwicklung in Deutschland bis 2014. Schlaglichter der Wirtschaftspolitik. BMWi. June 2010, pp. 38-43. --- (2009a). Die Krise abfedern – Zwischenbilanz zur Konjunktur- und Wachstumspolitik der Bundesregierung. Schlaglichter der Wirtschaftspolitik. BMWi. August 2009, pp. 9-15. --- (2009b). ―Wirtschaftsfonds Deutschland‖ – Perspektiven in der Krise sichern. Schlaglichter der Wirtschaftspolitik. BMWi. August 2009, pp. 16-21. CDU, CSU and FDP (2009). Koalitionsvertrag – 17. Legislaturperiode. Wachstum. Bildung. Zusammenhalt. Deutsch, Klaus Günter, Björn Frank, Martin Gornig (2006). The EU Services Directive: Nightmare or Opportunity? Implications for Transatlantic Business. AICGS Policy Report 25. Washington. American Institute for Contemporary German Studies. Dullien, Sebastian, Hansjörg Herr and Christian Kellermann (2009). Der gute Kapitalismus. Und was sich dafür nach der Krise ändern müsste. Bielefeld: transcript. Dyson, Kenneth (2010). In the Shifting Shadows of Crisis: Pivot Points, Crisis Attribution, and Macroeconomic Policies under the Grand Coalition. German Politics. December 2010 (work in progress). Ecologic (2009). Ein Klimaschutzgesetz für Deutschland. Kurzgutachten für den WWF Deutschland. Economist (2010). Older and wiser. A special report on Germany. March 13, 2010. 22 October 7, 2010 Germany‟s new strength? From stimulus to growth Egle, Christoph and Reimut Zohlnhöfer (Ed.) (2010). Die Zweite Große Koalition. Eine Bilanz der Regierung Merkel 2005-2009. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag. Egle, Christoph and Reimut Zohlnhöfer (Ed.) (2007). Ende des rot-grünen Projektes. Eine Bilanz der Regierung Schröder 2002-2005. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag. Egle, Christoph and Tobias Ostheim, Reimut Zohlnhöfer (Ed.) (2003). Das Rot-Grüne Projekt. Eine Bilanz der Regierung Schröder 1998-2002. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag. Ehmer, Philipp (2009). Services in the throes of structural change. Knowledge-intensive business services on an uptrend. DB Research. Current Issues. September 2009. Frankfurt am Main. Enderlein, Hendrik (2010). Finanzkrise und Große Koalition: Eine Bewertung des Krisenmanagements der Bundesregierung. In Egle/Zohlnhöfer (2010). Die Zweite Große Koalition, pp. 234-253. Grasl, Maximilian and Markus König (2010). Von außen getrieben. Die Finanzpolitik der Großen Koalition 20052009. In Egle/Zohlnhöfer (2010). Die Zweite Große Koalition, pp. 205-233. Gräf, Bernhard (2010). Germany‘s jobs miracle. Short-time work, flexible labour contracts and healthy companies. DB Research. Research Briefing. April 27, 2010. Frankfurt am Main. Gräf, Bernhard and Stefan Schneider (2010a). German economy (still) churning along nicely. DB Research. Research Briefing. June 4, 2010. Frankfurt am Main. --- (2010b). Germany‘s jobs miracle. DB Research. Research Briefing. April 27, 2010. Frankfurt am Main. Herold, Johannes and Christian von Hirschhausen (2010). Hohe Unsicherheiten bei der CO 2-Abscheidung: eine Energiebrücke ins Nichts? In DIW Wochenberichte No. 36. Berlin. Herweg, Nicole and Reimut Zohlnhöfer (2010). Die Große Koalition und das Verhältnis von Markt und Staat: Entstaatlichung in der Ruhe und Verstaatlichung während des Sturms? In Egle und Zohlnhöfer (2010). Die zweite Große Koalition, pp. 254-278. Heymann, Eric and Tobias Just (2010). German industry benefits unevenly from global upswing. DB Research. Research Briefing. June 2, 2010. Frankfurt am Main. Ifo-Institut für Wirtschaftforschung (2008). Mindestlohn: Für und Wider. Ifo-Schnelldienst 6/2008. Institut der deutschen Wirtschaft (2010). Hartz IV. Verdrehte Debatte. Iwd 8/2010. Cologne. International Monetary Fund (2009): Regional Economic Outlook. Europe. Securing Recovery. Washington, DC. October 2009. Kastrop, Christian (2008). Qualität der öffentlichen Finanzen – eine umfassende finanzpolitische Strategie. In Becker et al. (2008). Kastrop, Christian, Gisela Meister-Scheufelen, Margaretha Sudhof (Ed.) (2010 work in progress). Die neue Schuldenregel im Gefüge der Reform der bundesstaatlichen Finanzbeziehungen. Kemfert, Claudia (2007). Ein Zehn-Punkte-Plan für eine nachhaltige Energiepolitik in Deutschland. Gaia 16 (1): 16-21. Mauer, Urban (2006). Kombilohn – Was es für den Erfolg braucht. DB Research. Aktuelle Themen 366. Frankfurt am Main. McKinsey&Company (2007). Kosten und Potenziale der Vermeidung von Treibhausgasemissionen in Deutschland. Study commissioned by ―BDI initiativ – Wirtschaft für Klimaschutz‖. Morawitz, Markus and Wolfgang Wiegard (2009). Steuerpolitischer Handlungsbedarf: Nachjustierung der Unternehmensteuerreform. In Günther G. Schulze (Ed.). Reformen für Deutschland. Die wichtigsten Handlungsfelder aus ökonomischer Sicht. Stuttgart: Schäffer-Poeschel, pp. 207-228. OECD (2010). OECD Economic Surveys: Germany. Paris. Pichl, Andreas et al. (2010). Reform der Hinzuverdienstregeln in der Grundsicherung: Kein Entkommen aus der Transferfalle. IZA Standpunkte No. 26. Bonn. Prognos AG (2010). Arbeitslandschaft 2010. Auswirkungen der Wirtschafts- und Finanzkrise. Study commissioned by vbw. Munich. Raschke, Joachim (2010). Zerfallsphasen des Schröder-Zyklus. Die SPD 2005-2009. In Egle und Zohlnhöfer (2010). Die zweite Große Koalition, pp. 69-98. Rogoff, Kenneth S. and Carmen M. Reinhart (2009). This time is different. Eight Centuries of Financial Follies. Princeton: Princeton University Press. October 7, 2010 23 Current Issues Röttgen, Norbert (2010). Vision 2050. Perspektiven für Stadtwerke im Energiemarkt. Speech, July 6, 2010. Berlin. Sachverständigenrat zur Begutachtung der gesamtwirtschaftlichen Entwicklung (2009). Die Zukunft nicht aufs Spiel setzen. Jahresgutachten 2009/10. Wiesbaden. --- (2008). Die Finanzkrise meistern – Wachstumskräfte stärken. Jahresgutachten 2008/09. Wiesbaden. --- (2008b). Das deutsche Finanzsystem. Effizienz steigern – Stabilität erhöhen. Report commissioned by the Federal Government. Wiesbaden: SVR. June 2008. Schettkat, Ronald (2010). Dienstleistungen zwischen Kostenkrankheit und Marketization. Report commissioned by the Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung. FES. WiSo-Diskurs. August 2010. Schmidt, Manfred G. (2010). Die Sozialpolitik der zweiten Großen Koalition (2005-2009). In Egle und Zohlnhöfer (2010). Die zweite Große Koalition, pp. 302-326. --- (2007). Das politische System Deutschlands. Institutionen, Willensbildung und Politikfelder. Munich: C.H.Beck. Schrooten, Mechthild (2009). Landesbanken. Rettung allein reicht nicht. DIW-Wochenbericht 24. Berlin. DIW. Sinn, Hans-Werner (2009). Kasino-Kapitalismus. Wie es zur Finanzkrise kam, und was jetzt zu tun ist. Berlin: Ullstein. Statistisches Bundesamt (2010). Nachhaltige Entwicklung in Deutschland. Indikatorenbericht. Wiesbaden. Wagschal, Uwe (2006). Erfolgreiche Budgetkonsolidierungen im internationalen Vergleich. Gütersloh: Bertelsmann Stiftung. World Wide Fund for Nature (2010). Modell Deutschland. Klimaschutz bis 2050. Study prepared by Prognos AG, Öko-Institut and Dr. Hans-Joachim Ziesing. Berlin. Zipfel, Frank (2010). Germany‘s austerity package and the federal budget: Growth-compatible. DB Research. Research Briefing. July 21, 2010. Frankfurt am Main. Zipfel, Frank (2010a). Kommunalfinanzen – zukunftssicher aufgestellt? DB Research. Aktuelle Themen 482. Frankfurt am Main. © Copyright 2010. Deutsche Bank AG, DB Research, D-60262 Frankfurt am Main, Germany. All rights reserved. When quoting please cite ―Deutsche Bank Research‖. The above information does not constitute the provision of investment, legal or tax advice. Any views expressed reflect the current views of the author, which do not necessarily correspond to the opinions of Deutsche Bank AG or its affiliates. Opinions expressed may change without notice. Opinions expressed may differ from views set out in other documents, including research, published by Deutsche Bank. The above information is provided for informational purposes only and without any obligation, whether contractual or otherwise. No warranty or representation is made as to the correctness, completeness and accuracy of the information given or the assessments made. In Germany this information is approved and/or communicated by Deutsche Bank AG Frankfurt, authorised by Bundesanstalt für Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht. In the United Kingdom this information is approved and/or communicated by Deutsche Bank AG London, a member of the London Stock Exchange regulated by the Financial Services Authority for the conduct of investment business in the UK. This information is distributed in Hong Kong by Deutsche Bank AG, Hong Kong Branch, in Korea by Deutsche Securities Korea Co. and in Singapore by Deutsche Bank AG, Singapore Branch. In Japan this information is approved and/or distributed by Deutsche Securities Limited, Tokyo Branch. In Australia, retail clients should obtain a copy of a Product Disclosure Statement (PDS) relating to any financial product referred to in this report and consider the PDS before making any decision about whether to acquire the product. Printed by: HST Offsetdruck Schadt & Tetzlaff GbR, Dieburg ISSN Print: 1612-314X / ISSN Internet and e-mail: 1612-3158 24 October 7, 2010