How to study everyday life in post-socialist contexts?
Transcription
How to study everyday life in post-socialist contexts?
Institute of Sociology, Macro Sociology, POB 4120, 39016 Magdeburg, GER How to study everyday life in post-socialist contexts? Conceptual remarks on a comparative research project on livelihoods in Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan. Prof. Dr Eckhard Dittrich, eckhard.dittrich@ovgu.de Prof. Dr. Heiko Schrader, heiko.schrader@ovgu.de Dr. Denis Gruber, gruber.denis@web.de A project funded by Volkswagen Foundation under Az.: 84933 General outline The collapse of the Soviet Union caused great changes in the former Eastern bloc. Perestroika and Glasnost aimed at changes not only in the spheres of the economy or of politics. As soon as the changes gained momentum, it became clear to most observers, that the overthrow of the old system meant a profound change of the whole society. Even the former unity of the Soviet Union broke up. For analysts this means a strong interconnectedness of all processes of change. To recognize the ―Gleichzeitigkeit‖ (Offe), simultaneousness, is therefore an important aspect of all analytic endeavors. Questions of nationhood, of economic and political organizations as well as of norms and values that is of cultural orientations and their interwovenness are at stake. For analytic reasons one should keep this in mind even if one analyzes detailed developments. In the sphere of the economy, the reforms taken aimed at a change from a centrally planned economy to a market economy. At least two general approaches can be distinguished concerning the restructuring of the economy, a radical and a reformist one. The radical one favored a shock therapy: a rapid transgression to market economic institutions. It was believed that thus the development of counter powers could be prevented that were able to question the aims. Roughly speaking, success was believed to have been reached if the institutions of a market economy were established. The accomplishment of this was thought of to be reached in a few years. General opinion was that after five to ten years’ transition, the market economy would fully function and the economic sphere would recover. Within this time span, the societies would have to pass a deep valley of sorrows (Dahrendorf). Prototype for this change is believed to be Poland. The opposite approach supported a more gradual change. For most of the politicians and scientific observers, the changes were believed not to be mere economic ones – in a market liberal sense – but had to take the behavioral scripts of the populations involved into account, especially their slow evolution. The process was believed to last much longer. Some observers talked about one generation. They would declare Czech Republic a prototype of this approach. In general, one can say today, that the changes in the emergent independent states followed different strategies and also the scientific camp was divided. From a sociological point of view such a transformation is a complicated and complex process. Traditionally theories of revolutions and of radical social change were applied to explain the developments. In any case they did not just mean implementing market organizations (Dittrich, Schrader and Stojanov 2008), since the functioning of these depends upon market behavior of the actors involved. We therefore distinguish between market economy and market society (Schrader 2004) as the general aims of evolution. Market societies display special features, f.e. the differentiation of a sphere of the economy and a political sphere with the institutions of democracy and elements of civil society. Very soon scientific observers discovered that a disentanglement/differentiation of economic and political spheres had not happened as expected in analogy with the Western development. Aiming at explanations, social scientists typed the evolving new features – the above mentioned being not the only ones - as ―political capitalism‖ (Staniszkis 1991). With this they wanted to develop an explanatory scheme that was supposed to help to understand the new form of capitalism in the post-socialist countries as being distinct from the western type of capitalism. While this new type was initially thought to be transitional, an increasing size of scholars began to believe that a new type had started to be established and they adhered to parallel developments of capitalism in the West. Varieties of capitalism were rediscovered. These varieties were initially researched in order to explain an Anglo-Saxon from a continental European capitalism displaying different institutions like e.g. special subsystems of banking. The idea was that these special features found in research implied different forms of economic behavior such as long term versus short term benefit orientations. To these variations was now added a post-socialist variation. Implicitly this meant to say, that the post socialist variation had established its own regulatory power. The path-dependency argument (North 1991; Stark 1992) of social change became increasingly important. It also helped to discover new variations also between post-socialist economies and their stability. Path dependency arguments imply the rooting of economic behavior in the political, social and cultural web of society. Paths taken are decided on the basis of the distribution of power and wealth and are guided by both formal and informal norms and values that stem from cultural orientations. They are sedimented in traditions and constantly renewed in ongoing formal and informal socializing processes that have to find solutions for correct behavior for the individual in face of the society and its structural impositions on it. Simultaneousness, complexity and culture as necessary categories for analyzes become even more evident if we investigate into everyday economic life. Here scholars empirically will soon discover if and how far implemented organizations of market economy as e.g. private property or money based transactions are really accepted and guide economic transactions by the population or whether these have been constituted as empty facades behind which lay different economic rationales. While basically every citizen participates in economic action, certain transactions, however, are restricted to those people living above the poverty line. For the general understanding of the functioning of special market societies, however, it is very important to take all forms of transactions into account. Only thus it is possible to fully decipher the mix of social actions taken by economic actors in order to organize their economic lives. Furthermore, empirical research shows that people do not plan as pure individuals as assumed by economic theory, but set up strategies as social actors, be they households or families or what so ever. That is we have to reflect on the proper unit of research that might not necessarily be individuals` transactions. These units of action follow their own rationale. It implies muddling through and planning, maximizing profits, and/or minimizing risks. All agents plan into the future, try to build security for times of crises, old age, the next generation, etc. A lot of businesses may be involved: banks, insurance companies, building companies, etc. but also neighbors, one’s own ethnic group, clans, migratory possibilities, households, etc. And, besides market institutions, non-market ones such as subsistence or informal strategies may be important as well (Schrader 1999). However, making a living beyond immediate consumption for survival requires a certain level of stable income. The research project and its theoretical concept After having investigated the changes of economic actions in other post-socialist societies (Russian Federation, Estonia, Bulgaria, Czech Republic; and formerly also in post-colonial societies such as India and Indonesia) we decided to empirically study the research issue in Central Asia. The basic research question is how far people in everyday life have adapted to market economy so that we can indeed speak of a market society. Simply taken, the key element of the investigation is of whether care of the state (―nanny state‖) in state socialism has been substituted by self-responsibility for one’s own destiny in the new capitalism. Here we do not so much refer to a ―muddling through‖ that occurred during the early phase of transformation and still occurs during economic and political crises, but to new forms of planned, rational action of households to combine different household roles to a joint strategy to gain long-term security. That is, our research is guided by the assumption that the first phase of change is over and that post post-socialist societies develop new forms of economic action made possible by the (precarious) stability of the new economic systems. Households may follow strategies of minimization of risks preferred to maximization of chances. A diversification of incomes, formal, informal as well as subsistence incomes, within the same household may spread risks. Among such strategies is also labor migration with which households secure incomes by transfer payments. In the institutionalized market economies these changes may occur through and are mirrored by institutions such as banks (savings and other bank investment), insurance companies (health, old-age, unemployment, etc.), gaining of private property (apartments, houses, business space) but also by relying on personalized networks among relatives and friends to embed one’s own economic behavior in social actions or socially accepted corruption. The stronger the reliance on one of these forms of economic actions and of consecutive benefits, the trust/distrust in market and state institutions occurs and stabilizes the experiences. It is assumed that in rural settings strategies differ immensely from urban settings, in so far that in such subsistence incomes as well as other forms of savings (e.g. in kind by a herd of cattle) play a much more important role. Furthermore, cohort differentiation assumes that younger cohorts are more easily adaptive to the market economy and self-responsibility while older cohorts may more strongly rely on an imagined ―nanny state‖ that existed under state socialist rule (McMann 2007). Theoretically we use the concept of ―Sustainable Livelihoods Approach‖ (SLA) (Chambers 1995) as an analytic guide line. The SLA is less a fully developed theory than a practical analytical framework which was conceptualized for povertyoriented development projects. It is directed towards collecting, systematizing and interpreting complex social structures. It is particularly suitable to consider the reproduction capacity of vulnerable groups in a rapidly changing society. The approach takes a ―bottom-up‖ perspective on a bundle of factors determining risks in making a living, the reproduction of precarious life situations, the societal embeddedness, political factors impinging on vulnerable groups, and the key factors that are responsible for developing strategies for survival. While the approach was initially used in rural contexts of developing societies (e.g. Chambers 1988, 1992; Conroy 1988) it was also implemented in towns and cities (Espling 1999; Evans 2002a; Evans 2002b; Tacoli 1998). For post-socialist countries the approach is particularly interesting because of rapid political and economic changes being implemented by system transfer. Societal norms and codes of conduct have been reversed, and with them everyday-life requires often contrawise action. The SLA combines the micro- with the meso and macro levels. It does so because the life strategies of households are closely connected to their resource basis that bridges the analytic frame of levels. Here Bourdieu’s concept of different forms of capital is helpful for analyses: capital sorts of economic capital, cultural capital such as human capital, and social capital such as personal networks (Bourdieu 1977). But one has to take into account also natural/environmental capital. It seems nearly selfevident that these forms are influenced not only by the individuals`contexts, but also by the macro context (world economy, national economy and policies), by the existence of organizations (e.g. availability of banks and their loans) and the vulnerability context. While the different capital sorts may partly substitute each other (e.g. lack of capital may be compensated by a network of friends who lend oneself capital), it is equally true that certain social strata may lack access to any of these capital sorts and makes them particularly vulnerable (e.g. single-headed households, late migrants with no access to land, etc.). While the SLA gives particular emphasis on vulnerable groups, we take, however, a broader view by particularly referring to households above the poverty line and their strategies to make a living. With some regards, this comes closer to Max Weber’s conception of ―Lebensführung‖ (conduct of life), which was developed further in Germany, however, usually refers to individuals rather than households or families. Therefore we will try to combine the strength of both approaches and try to avoid their weaknesses. Methodology of the empirical research Evaluating the ongoing changes in post socialist countries and deciphering the institutions and processes that drive them, can best be done by a comparative design. Insofar one would classify our research as intercultural: we analyze different national orientations and their possible influence on economic behavior. This implies epistemological problems as usually researchers are only familiar with one’s own culture. Of course, in sociological research, theory served and serves to overcome these restrictions stemming from the cultural bias. Since the development of modern social sciences theory served the overcoming of this bias and allowed for generalizations and thus the possibility ―to transfer results from one context to another‖ (Baur, 2008, 193) the discussion about ―scientific colonialism‖ given, we added to our strictly theory driven research agenda our ―mixed team approach‖. It is an additional helper to avoid cultural biases. In this case, our research brings together cognitive orientations from people from Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan and Germany, not to mention that some also won part of their education and/or working experience in other countries. Thus, we hope to add to the validity of our empirical research. We compare two countries in order to add to the ongoing discussions about varieties of capitalism on the global level as well as in the post-socialist countries. The underlying assumption is that the post-socialist societies go through a lengthy process of changes. To analyze them it is necessary to define temporality. In order to show the new forms of economic behavior after the initial organization building phase, we - so to say - personalize temporality. We argue that the generation being brought up after the 1989 divide and especially having had its first working experience under the new conditions is no longer structurally socialized into a Soviet type of society as were their forerunner generations, so that social change will occur inter-generationally (Inglehart 2003). They still struggle more strongly with the remnants of the past. Of course, there is no clear divide but nevertheless we expect to find different types of economic behavior, maybe even different forms of world views in the different cohorts. This may, of course, sometimes also engender tensions within the same household as different generations may live under the same roof. This is a particular challenge to researchers and can, for example, be solved by group focused interviews. We believe that the basic unit for research in looking at changing economic behavior should be households. Private households are open security networks based on common residence. This common residence for the members may be temporarily or non-temporarily. Households combine the activities of different family members belonging to it. Incomes in these households are pooled. The incomes may take monetary as well as non-monetary forms. Here we roughly follow Bourdieu’s concept of different forms of capital, adding social, cultural and environmental etc. assets to the monetary ones. The entities that will be investigated are private urban and rural households in two strongly diverging post-socialist societies: Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan. This differentiation between rural and urban is grounded on theories of social change arguing that modernization processes initially start from cities and then with time gap - spread to villages. In the countryside resistance to modernization processes normally is much stronger due to a higher degree of subsistence economy that embodies strict adherence to traditional forms of behavior. As most research on transformation is done in the urban centers we hope to broader the view on them (Dittrich, Oswald 2010). Empirical research will take place in two steps: we will start with quantitative data gathering. We will use questionnaires and thus collect data in and around Astana and Almaty, as well as Bishkek urban contexts). These data will be analyzed with statistical methods (SPSS descriptive and analytical statistics to find dependent variables). From the first insight thus gained, we will develop an interview guideline for indepth interviews to gather and later on interpret the qualitative data won. Participating researchers in this project are Prof. Aigul Zabirova (L.N. Gumilev Eurasian National Univ., Astana), Dr. Nazym Shedenova (Al-Farabi Univ., Almaty), Dr. Galina Gorborukova (Univ. of Central Asia, Bishkek), Dr. Markus Kaiser (OSCE Academy Bishkek), Batima Mambetalina, MA, and Nigina Avganova, M.A. both Univ. of Magdeburg. Additionally we involve PhD students from the participating institutions. Literature: Baur, Nina, Taking Perspectivity Seriously. Asuggestion of a Conceptual Framework for Linking Theory and Methods in Longitudinal and Comparative Research, in, Historical Social Research, Vol 33, 2008, No.4: 191 – 213 Bourdieu, P. 1977. Outline of a Theory of Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press. Chambers, Robert. 1995. "Poverty and Livelihoods: Whose Reality Counts." Environment and Urbanization 7(1):173-204. Dittrich, E., Oswald, I., Ed., Jenseits der Staedte. Postsozialistische Lebensweisen in laendlichen Regionen Mittel- und Osteuropas, Berlin: LIT-Verlag Dittrich, E. H. Schrader, and Ch. Stojanov. 2008. "The Development of Small Enterprieses in Bulgaria, Czech Reupublic and Russian Federation." Journal for East European Management Studies (JEEMS) 13(2):129-53. Espling, M. 1999. Women's Livelihood Strategies in Processes of Change: Cases from Urban Mozambique. Göteborg Univ., School of Economics and Commerical Law. Evans, P. 2002a. "Introduction: Looking for Agents of Urban Livability in a Globalized Political Economy." Pp. 1-30 in Livable Cities? Urban Struggles for Livelihood and Sustainability, edited by P. Evans. Berkeley / Los Ageles: University of California Press. —. 2002b. "Political Strategies for More Livable Cities: Lessons from Six Cases of Development and Political Transition." Pp. 222-46 in Livable Cities? Urban Struggles for Livelihood and Sustainability, edited by P. Evans. Berkeley / Los Angeles: University of California Press. Inglehart, R.. 2003. Human values and social change : findings from the values surveys. Leiden: Brill. McMann, K. M..The Shrinking of the Welfare State: Central Asians`Assessments of Soviet and Post-Soviet Governance. In: J. Sahadeo, R. Zanca, Ed., Everyday Life in Central Asia, Bloomington, Indianapolis: Indiana University Press North, D. C. 1991. "Institutions." Journal of Economic Perspectives 5:97-112. Schrader, H. 1999. Ekonomitscheskaya Antropologija. Saint Petersburg: Zentr "St. Peterborgskoje Vostokovedenje". —. 2004. "Social Capital and Social Transformation in Russia." Journal for East European Management Studies (JEEMS) 9(4):391-410. Staniszkis, J. 1991. "'Political Capitalism' in Poland." East European Politics and Societies 5(1):127-41. Stark, D. 1992. "Path-Dependence and Privatization Strategies in East Central Europe." East European Politics and Society 6:17-51. Tacoli, C. 1998. Bridging the Divide: Rural-Urban Interactions and Livelihood Strategies. London: International Institute for Environment and Development.