Document 6516291
Transcription
Document 6516291
[2007] Comp Law 123 SECTION WHAT IS AN AGREEMENT? Peter Willis and Paul Hughes INTRODUCTION 1 Recent case-law, including Commission v Volkswagen AG (Volkswagen II) and, in the UK, the 2 judgments of the Court of Appeal in Toys and Games and Replica Kit and of the Competition 3 Appeal Tribunal (CAT) in Makers UK Ltd v Office of Fair Trading, has put the spotlight once more on a fundamental point: what is an ‘agreement’ for the purposes of Art 81 of the Treaty of Rome 1957 (EC Treaty) and how does this concept dovetail with its companion term ‘concerted practice’? 4 In Bayer AG v Commission and Bundesverband der Arzneimittel-importeure EV and Commission 5 v Bayer AG, the Court of First Instance (CFI) held that the key issue is to show a concurrence of wills between the parties, with the European Court of Justice (ECJ) indicating that the parties should jointly intend to fulfil a common goal. As the ECJ explained: ’97. ... the Court of First Instance set out from the principle that the concept of an agreement within the meaning of Article [81](1) of the Treaty ... centres around the existence of a concurrence of wills between at least two parties, the form in which it is manifested being unimportant so long as it constitutes the faithful expression of the parties’ intention. The Court further recalled, in paragraph 67 of the same judgment, that for there to be an agreement within the meaning of Article 8[1](1) of the Treaty it is sufficient that the undertakings in question should have expressed their common intention to conduct themselves on the market in a specific way. … 102. For an agreement within the meaning of Article 8[1](1) of the Treaty to be capable of being regarded as having been concluded by tacit acceptance, it is necessary that the manifestation of the wish of one of the contracting parties to achieve an anti-competitive 1 2 3 4 5 Partner and Head of EU & Competition, Dundas & Wilson LLP, and Consultant, Dundas & Wilson LLP and Senior Academic, University of Westminster. This article is based on a paper by the authors delivered at IBC’s EC Advanced Competition Law Conference in London, April 2007. (Case C-74/04) [2006] ECR I-6585. Argos Ltd v Office of Fair Trading; JJB Sports plc v Office of Fair Trading [2006] EWCA Civ 1318, [2006] 42 LS Gaz R 32. [2007] CAT 11, [2007] All ER (D) 49 (Mar). (Case T-41/96) [2000] ECR II-3383. (Cases C-2/01 P and 3/01 P) [2004] ECR I-23. 124 [2007] Comp Law ARTICLES goal constitute an invitation to the other party, whether express or implied, to fulfil that goal jointly ...’ Interestingly, Bayer has been used as authority for a range of propositions on different aspects of the scope of Art 81 EC, including propositions relating to the parties’ subjective intent and to the extent to which liability under Art 81 EC can arise from tacit acquiescence with an instruction. In Toys and Games and Replica Kit, the UK Court of Appeal (at para [141] of its judgment), ruling on the interpretation of the Chapter I prohibition of the Competition Act 1998, used the ECJ’s judgment in Bayer as the basis for the following proposition: ‘… if (i) retailer A discloses to supplier B its future pricing intentions in circumstances where A may be taken to intend that B will make use of that information to influence market conditions by passing that information to other retailers (of whom C is or may be one), (ii) B does, in fact, pass that information to C in circumstances where C may be taken to know the circumstances in which the information was disclosed by A to B and (iii) C does, in fact, use the information in determining its own future pricing intentions,[6] then A, B and C are all to be regarded as parties to a concerted practice having as its object the restriction or distortion of competition. The case is all the stronger where there is reciprocity: in the sense that C discloses to supplier B its future pricing intentions in circumstances where C may be taken to intend that B will make use of that information to influence market conditions by passing that information to (amongst others) A, and B does so.’ Using this formula as inspiration, this article, perhaps somewhat ambitiously, attempts to reduce current Art 81 EC case-law to three similar, and to some extent overlapping, series of propositions. Each of the three series of propositions represents a progression from a set of facts that infringes Art 81 EC to one that does not, as follows: 6 As an aside, it is not clear that (iii) is a necessary element of the infringement. It is not necessary in a concerted practice that the recipient of exchanged information should have acted upon it. It is sufficient that he should have received it. See in this respect European Sugar Cartel, Re, Cooperatieve Vereniging Suiker Unie UA v Commission (Cases 40/73, 41/73, 42/73, 43/73, 44/73, 45/73, 46/73, 47/73, 48/73, 50/73, 54/73, 55/73, 56/73, 111/73, 113/73 and 114/73) [1975] ECR 1633). The ECJ held (at para 174 of that judgment) that Art 81 EC strictly precludes any direct or indirect contact the object or effect of which is to influence the contacted party’s conduct on the market or which discloses the course of conduct the disclosing party intends to or is contemplating adopting. There is no requirement that the disclosure should in fact have had the desired effect. [2007] Comp Law 125 Unilateral instruction or express/tacit bilateral vertical agreement Competitors A and B expressly agree in writing that they will both charge the same price for their products Supplier A instructs reseller B not to resell to customers outside the territory in which B is located, and B expressly agrees A transmits pricing information to its competitor B, and both parties intend that B should act on that information in order to align its prices with A’s and thereby to restrict competition Competitors A and B expressly agree orally that they will both charge the same price for their products Supplier A’s agreement with reseller B provides that A may instruct B not to resell to customers outside the territory in which B is located, or not to sell at less than a specified price, and A issues such instructions A and B exchange pricing information at a trade association meeting. C, who is also present, receives information from B and C, but does not transmit its own pricing information to A or B. It has no intention of aligning its prices with those of A and B, nor that A and B should align their prices with its own Competitors A and B have a gentlemen’s agreement (a morally but not legally binding agreement) that they will both charge the same price for their products Supplier A instructs reseller B not to resell to customers outside the territory in which B is located, or not to sell at less than a specified price, and B complies with that instruction A transmits pricing information to its competitor B, but does not intend that B should pass that information to A’s competitor C A discloses competitively sensitive information on its future prices to its competitor B who either requested it, or accepts it Supplier A instructs reseller B not to resell to customers outside the territory in which B is located. B is reluctant to comply, but does so under duress A discloses competitively sensitive information on its future prices to its competitor B who neither requested it, nor accepts it Supplier A instructs reseller B not to resell to customers outside the territory in which B is located, and B continues to deal with A, but does not otherwise comply with the instruction A becomes aware of and responds to its competitor B’s pricing intentions, in the absence of any communication from B A determines its policy on the market independently, with no knowledge of its competitor B’s intentions From common intent to cross purposes ARTICLES From express written ‘horizontal’ agreement to ‘intelligent adaptation’ 126 [2007] Comp Law ARTICLES FROM EXPRESS WRITTEN (HORIZONTAL) AGREEMENT TO ‘INTELLIGENT ADAPTATION’ This section summarises the progression, well-documented in several decades of case-law of the European courts, from express agreements, via gentlemen’s agreements and concerted practices, to intelligent adaptation to a competitor’s behaviour and thence to entirely independent action. Competitors A and B expressly agree in writing that they will both charge the same price for their products Written agreements, although for obvious reasons less commonly employed as a vehicle for hard-core cartel activity these days, are clearly caught by Art 81(1) EC: Brasserie Nationale SA 7 and Others v Commission. Competitors A and B expressly agree orally that they will both charge the same price for their products These are also caught. It is not necessary that the agreement be established in writing. 8 Competitors A and B have a gentlemen’s agreement (a morally but not legally binding agreement) that they will both charge the same price for their products The term ‘agreement’ has an autonomous meaning under Art 81 EC and catches arrangements 9 that do not constitute agreements for the purposes of contract law. So gentlemen’s agreements – where the parties are not legally bound but consider themselves morally bound – can constitute agreements for the purposes of Art 81 EC. This principle applies in other situations where there is no legally binding agreement in place, so, for example, there is an agreement for the purposes of Art 81 EC where two undertakings are negotiating the terms of an agreement and have not yet reached a consensus, but believe 10 themselves to be morally bound by some of those terms, or where an express agreement has 11 expired but the parties continue to align their behaviour in accordance with the agreement. A discloses competitively sensitive information on its future prices to its competitor B who either requested it, or accepts it In the absence of a legally or morally binding agreement or understanding, there may still be an ‘agreement’ within the autonomous meaning given to the term under Art 81 EC if it can be 7 8 9 10 11 (Joined Cases T-49/02 to T 51/02) [2005] ECR II-3033. Re Italian Flat Glass Industria Vetraria Alfonso Cobelli v Società Italiana Vetro-SIV SpA (EC Commission Decision 89/93) [1990] 4 CMLR 535, on appeal Re Italian Flat Glass: Società Italiano Vetro SpA v Commission (Cases T-68/89, T-77/89 and T-78/89) [1992] ECR II-1403. ACF Chemiefarma NV v Commission (Case 41/69) [1970] ECR 661, at paras 107 and 110–112. See also Commission Decision of 21 October 1998 relating to a proceeding under Article 85 of the EC Treaty 1999/60/EC (Case No IV/35.691/E-4 – Pre-Insulated Pipe Cartel) (1999) OJ L 24/1. Jaeger v Opel Norge AS (Case E-3/97) (1998) OJ C 263/9, [1998] Rep EFTA Ct. Commission Decision of 19 December 1990 relating to a proceeding under Article 85 of the EEC Treaty 91/297/EEC (IV/33.133-A: Soda-ash – Solvay, ICI) (1991) OJ L 152/1. [2007] Comp Law 127 The ECJ has consistently held that independent undertakings must determine their commercial policies independently and without reaching any understanding with competitors as to the commercial policies they intend to adopt on the market. The concept applies to collusive behaviour which falls short of a legally or morally binding agreement. 13 In Hüls AG v Commission (Polypropylene), the ECJ held, at paras 158 and 159: ‘The Court of Justice has consistently held that a concerted practice refers to a form of coordination between undertakings which, without having been taken to the stage where an agreement properly so-called has been concluded, knowingly substitutes for the risks of competition practical cooperation ... The criteria of co-ordination and co-operation must be understood in the light of the concept inherent in the provisions of the Treaty relating to competition, according to which each economic operator must determine independently the policy which he intends to adopt on the market ...’ 14 The court held in Suiker Unie that a concerted practice comprises: ‘174. ... any direct or indirect contact between such operators, the object or effect whereof is either to influence the conduct on the market of an actual or potential competitor or to disclose to such a competitor the course of conduct which they themselves have decided to adopt or contemplate adopting on the market.’ 15 In Apex Asphalt and Paving Co Ltd v Office of Fair Trading the CAT provided a very useful summary of the relevant case-law of the ECJ and CFI in this area. 16 In Cimenteries CBR SA v Commission, the CFI considered to what extent disclosure of future intentions, in the context of an alleged concerted practice, must be reciprocal. One of the alleged cartel members argued that since the disclosure had been in only one direction, the required element of reciprocity had been absent. The CFI disagreed: ‘1849. In that connection, the Court points out that the concept of concerted practice does in fact imply the existence of reciprocal contacts (Opinion of Advocate General Darmon in Woodpulp II, cited at paragraph 697 above, points 170 to 175). That condition is met where 12 13 14 15 16 See n 4, above, at para 67. (Case C-199/92P) [1999] ECR I-4287. See n 6, above. (Case No 1032/1/1/04) [2005] CAT 4, [2005] CompAR 507, at para [206]. (Cases T-10/92, T-11/92, T-12/92 and T-15/92) [1992] ECR II-2667. ARTICLES demonstrated that the parties have ‘expressed their joint intention to conduct themselves on 12 the market in a specific way’. In practice, these arrangements are highly likely to be seen as ‘concerted practices’ and are the target of much of the EC Commission’s enforcement activity. 128 [2007] Comp Law ARTICLES one competitor discloses its future intentions or conduct on the market to another when the latter requests it or, at the very least, accepts it.’ (emphasis added) The interesting point that arises from this is what constitutes ‘acceptance’ for the purposes of Art 81 EC. It is clear that if A requests price information from B, and B supplies that price information in response to the request, there is sufficient concurrence of wills to constitute an agreement. However, where is the concurrence of wills in a situation where A unilaterally communicates price information to B, with no warning? It seems obvious that mere involuntary receipt of an email – or being present at a meeting where a competitor unexpectedly discloses its pricing intentions – cannot of itself be interpreted as acceptance of the communication that it contains. However, the position of the Commission and the European courts is that is not necessary that the recipient of such information should act on the disclosure in order to be taken to have accepted it. It seems to be sufficient not to object to having received the communication. This theme was developed further on appeal to the ECJ, in Aalborg Portland A/S and Others v 17 Commission. The ECJ held that, once an undertaking has participated in cartel meetings, the burden of proof shifts to that undertaking to demonstrate that it was not party to an unlawful agreement, by: ‘81. … demonstrating that it had indicated to its competitors that it was participating in those meetings in a spirit that was different from theirs.’ The reason for this is that: ‘82. ... having participated in the meeting without publicly distancing itself from what was discussed, the undertaking has given the other participants to believe that it subscribed to what was decided there and would comply with it.’ So it is not incumbent on the Commission to establish acceptance of unsolicited communications. Instead, the onus is on the recipient to demonstrate that it did not accept the disclosure, and the way to do that is by expressing clear objections to the disclosing party and to any other competitors to whom that disclosure was also made. A discloses competitively sensitive information on its future prices to its competitor B who neither requested it, nor accepts it The logical consequence of these cases, and of the principle that an agreement requires a concurrence of wills, is that mere passive receipt of information about a competitor’s future pricing intentions does not constitute an agreement for the purposes of Art 81 EC. The difficulty in this case is probably more practical than legal – how to show that the information was not sent in response to solicitation, and also that sufficient steps were taken to distance the recipient from the communication. 17 (Cases C-204/00 P, C-205/00 P, C-211/00 P, C-213/00 P, C-217/00 P and C-219/00 P4) [2004] ECR I-123. [2007] Comp Law 129 The next step towards a complete absence of concurrence of wills is the situation where there is no direct communication between the parties. Although, as we have seen above, the ECJ 18 held in Suiker Unie that competitors are precluded from: ‘... any direct or indirect contact … the object or effect whereof is either to influence the conduct on the market of an actual or potential competitor or to disclose to such a competitor the course of conduct which they themselves have decided to adopt or contemplate adopting on the market.’ they may: ‘174. ... adapt themselves intelligently to the existing and anticipated conduct of their competitors ...’ So parallelism and intelligent adaptation are permissible in the absence of evidence of a concerted practice. 19 In Ahlström Osakeyhtiö and Others v Commission (Woodpulp II) the ECJ stressed that parallel conduct would constitute evidence of a breach of Art 81 EC where it was inexplicable otherwise than as a result of the existence of a concerted practice: ‘71. Parallel conduct cannot be regarded as furnishing proof of concertation unless concertation constitutes the only plausible explanation for such conduct. It is necessary to bear in mind that, although Article [81] of the Treaty prohibits any form of collusion which distorts competition, it does not deprive economic operators of the right to adapt themselves intelligently to the existing and anticipated conduct of their competitors (see the judgment in Suiker Unie, cited above, paragraph 174).’ (emphasis added) ‘72. Accordingly, it is necessary in this case to ascertain whether the parallel conduct alleged by the Commission cannot, taking account of the nature of the products, the size and the number of the undertakings and the volume of the market in question, be explained otherwise than by concertation.’ Could price signalling that falls short of communicating prices directly and specifically to competitors (eg, issuing press releases or publishing price information on a website) give rise to liability under Art 81 EC? In Woodpulp II, Advocate-General Darmon was of the opinion that: 18 19 See n 6, above. (Joined cases C-89/85, C-104/85, C-114/85, C-116/85, C-117/85 and C-125/85 to C-129/85) [1993] ECR I-1307 (Woodpulp II). ARTICLES A becomes aware of and responds to its competitor B’s pricing intentions, in the absence of any communication from B 130 [2007] Comp Law ARTICLES ‘249. ... in no circumstances can the behaviour of undertakings on a market, which comes to the knowledge of their competitors, constitute in itself an exchange of information amounting to concertation ...’ ‘250. ... if they engage in conduct which is justified by commercial needs, I do not see on what grounds it may be challenged.’ However: ‘251. ... practices which do not correspond to rational needs in the light of the characteristics of a given market ... may amount to an exchange of information.’ So where undertakings deliberately communicate information in a market where this behaviour is not explicable by customer need or market conditions, they are running a risk of being considered to be engaged in concertation. Following Woodpulp II, it also remains the case that, where undertakings are engaged in parallelism in a market where this is not economically likely, this parallel behaviour may be seen as explicable only by the existence of a concerted practice. A determines its policy on the market independently, with no knowledge of its competitor B’s intentions There is no infringement of Art 81(1) EC. This behaviour cannot amount to an agreement or concerted practice. UNILATERAL INSTRUCTION OR EXPRESS/TACIT BILATERAL VERTICAL AGREEMENT The next section examines the progression from unilateral instruction to express bilateral agreement. This situation is typified by Bayer. In the context of a vertical agreement, the supplier wishes its resellers to act in a way (in this case, not to resell to customers located in other territories) that, if it constituted the subject matter of an express agreement, would infringe Art 81 EC. However, cases such as Bayer and Volkswagen II have made it clear that where there is no concurrence of wills between the issuer and the recipient of such unilateral instructions, there is no infringement. The progression in this case therefore goes from express bilateral agreement, via unilateral instruction that is accepted tacitly by the recipient, to unilateral instruction that is not accepted. It is probably in this area that there has been the most movement in the case-law. Supplier A instructs reseller B not to resell to customers outside the territory in which B is located, and B expressly agrees As in the case of express horizontal agreements, these arrangements constitute clear infringements of Art 81 EC. [2007] Comp Law 131 In Volkswagen II, the agreements between Volkswagen (VW) and its German dealers allowed VW to require its dealers ‘to comply with all instructions issued for the purposes of the agreement’ by VW. VW had threatened to terminate the agreements of those dealers who offered discounts on new models and had exhorted them to observe ‘strict price discipline’. The ECJ held that what was important was whether the agreement entered into by the parties could authorise VW to issue instructions whose implementation would infringe the competition rules. The CFI had found that while the agreement authorised VW to make non-binding price recommendations, it did not authorise it to make binding recommendations. The instructions had therefore not been the subject of any acceptance by the dealers, and there was therefore no agreement for the purposes of Art 81 EC. Supplier A instructs reseller B not to resell to customers outside the territory in which B is located, or not to sell at less than a specified price, and B complies with that instruction It is relatively uncommon that a formal distribution agreement contains express restrictive terms. What is more common is that the supplier adopts a policy or issues instructions, and there is then a question as to whether the distributors have tacitly accepted that policy or those instructions by complying with them. In Volkswagen II, the ECJ noted that instructions from VW – ie those that were not authorised by a specific provision of the agreement – could subsequently have been accepted by dealers, either expressly or tacitly, by their conduct. However, in this case – as the court pointed out – the Commission had relied entirely on its interpretation of the contract and had not argued that the dealers had tacitly accepted VW’s instructions. This omission from the Commission’s case is somewhat surprising, because the Commission has on a number of occasions successfully argued that an agreement has arisen from the tacit acceptance of apparently unilateral instructions. 20 In Allgemeine Elektricitäts-Gesellschaft AEG-Telefunken AG v Commission, for instance, AEG had a policy of refusing admission to its selective distribution network unless the applicant agreed to adhere to minimum resale prices set by AEG. The court held that the exclusion of candidate distributors on this basis was unlawful and was not unilateral behaviour falling outside Art 81 EC: ‘37. Such a practice must be considered unlawful where the manufacturer, with a view to maintaining a high level of prices ... refuses to approve distributors who satisfy the qualitative criteria of the system. 38. Such an attitude on the part of the manufacturer does not constitute, on the part of the undertaking, unilateral conduct which, as AEG claims, would be exempt from the prohibition contained in Article [81](1) of the Treaty. On the contrary, it forms part of the 20 (Case 107/82) [1983] ECR 3151. ARTICLES Supplier A’s agreement with reseller B provides that A may instruct B not to resell to customers outside the territory in which B is located, or not to sell at less than a specified price, and A issues such instructions 132 [2007] Comp Law ARTICLES contractual relations between the undertaking and resellers. Indeed, in the case of the admission of a distributor, approval is based on the acceptance, tacit or express, by the contracting parties of the policy pursued by AEG which requires inter alia the exclusion from the network of all distributors who are qualified for admission but are not prepared to adhere to that policy.’ The court therefore held that admission was contingent on the distributor’s acceptance, tacitly or expressly, of the policy of RPM. Supplier A instructs reseller B not to resell to customers outside the territory in which B is located. B is reluctant to comply, but does so under duress The fact that a reseller complies with the instructions of its supplier only under duress does 21 not vitiate its consent for the purposes of Art 81 EC. Supplier A instructs reseller B not to resell to customers outside the territory in which B is located, and B continues to deal with A, but does not otherwise comply with the instruction So we have seen that an agreement for the purposes of Art 81 EC can arise where a distributor either expressly accepts a restriction of competition imposed by the supplier, or tacitly accepts it by falling in with the required conduct. A concurrence of wills is established or inferred from that acceptance. What is the situation where there is no evidence that the distributor takes steps to comply with the restriction, but it merely continues to deal with the supplier? Can it be held to have tacitly accepted the restriction? Here the case-law of the European courts has evolved, resulting in a more rigorous approach. 22 In Sandoz Prodotti Farmaceutici SpA v Commission, the ECJ concluded that where dealers continued to trade with Sandoz following its issue of invoices with the words ‘export prohibited’ on them, they were deemed to have accepted that stipulation, giving rise to an agreement for the purposes of Art 81 EC. The export ban did not constitute unilateral conduct but formed part of the general framework of commercial relations and was a term to which the parties adhered. However, Sandoz may no longer be good law in the light of the judgments of the CFI and ECJ in Bayer. In that case, the CFI and ECJ respectively had to consider the Commission decision that Bayer had infringed Art 81(1) EC by seeking to withhold supplies of Adalat to distributors in Spain and France in order to deter sales to the UK where Bayer sold direct. The CFI summarised the law relating to the concept of an agreement as follows: ‘71. ... case-law shows that a distinction should be drawn between cases in which an undertaking has adopted a genuinely unilateral measure, and thus without the express or implied participation of another undertaking, and those in which the unilateral character of 21 22 Cimenteries CBR v Commission (Cases T-25–26, 30–32, 34–39, 42–46, 48, 50–65, 68–71, 87–88 and 103–104/95) [1992] ECR II-491; Solatrenz SA v Commission (Case T-149/89) [1995] ECR II-1127 and Trefileurope Sales SARL v Commission (Case T-141/89) [1995] ECR II-791. (Case C-277/87) [1990] ECR I-45. [2007] Comp Law 133 The CFI concluded that the wholesalers had striven to obtain additional quantities of Adalat and had not acquiesced in Bayer’s policy and that there was no agreement for the purposes of Art 81(1) EC. With reference to the Commission’s argument that the maintenance of commercial relations by the parties sufficed under Art 81 EC, the CFI held that the requirement of a concurrence of wills meant that the Commission had erred: ‘172. … in holding that the continuation of commercial relations with the manufacturer when it adopts a new policy, which it implements unilaterally, amounts to acquiescence by the wholesalers in that policy, although their de facto conduct is clearly contrary to that policy.’ The ECJ upheld the CFI’s decision, concluding that: ‘141. In that respect, it is important to note that this case raises the question of the existence of an agreement prohibited by Article [81](1) of the Treaty. The mere concomitant existence of an agreement which is in itself neutral and a measure restricting competition that has been imposed unilaterally does not amount to an agreement prohibited by that provision. Thus, the mere fact that a measure adopted by a manufacturer, which has the object or effect of restricting competition, falls within the context of continuous business relations between the manufacturer and its wholesalers is not sufficient for a finding that such an agreement exists.’ So ‘mere’ maintenance of commercial relations is not sufficient to found a finding of an agreement in breach of Art 81 EC. However, attempting to control resellers by means of unilateral instructions carries significant risk in practice. The reason is that the supplier is generally unable to control whether or not the reseller expressly or tacitly accepts its instructions. In order to avoid liability under Art 81 EC, the supplier needs its resellers not to agree to its instructions – but this is the exact opposite of the desired commercial result. FROM COMMON INTENT TO CROSS PURPOSES The third progression addresses the extent to which parties must share the same subjective intent in order for there to be an agreement for the purposes of Art 81 EC. In particular, this section addresses the principle elaborated in the UK Court of Appeal judgments in Replica Kit ARTICLES the measure is merely apparent ... in particular ... practices and measures in restraint of competition which, though apparently adopted unilaterally by the manufacturer in the context of its contractual relations with its dealers, nevertheless receive at least the tacit acquiescence of those dealers.’ 134 [2007] Comp Law ARTICLES and Toys and Games, dealing with the extent to which it was necessary that the parties should actually have foreseen the use that would have been made of their disclosures, as opposed to that use being merely foreseeable. The CFI held in Bayer that the necessary ingredient is a concurrence of wills. The CFI remarked that proof of an agreement having been reached must be founded on: ‘173. … the existence of the subjective element that characterizes the very concept of the agreement, that is to say the concurrence of wills between economic operators on the implementation of a policy, the pursuit of an objective, or the adoption of a given line of conduct on the market.’ However, the extent to which the parties share the same subjective intent can vary, and a party to an arrangement will very rarely be aware of its partner’s subjective intentions. So in a case where a distributor tacitly accepts an instruction not to sell outside its territory, its subjective intent may not be the same as that of the supplier. The supplier may intend to prevent parallel trade and price arbitrage. The distributor may be motivated by nothing more than the desire to take whatever steps are required to ensure that it remains on good terms with the supplier and does not have supplies withheld from it. Subjective intent is therefore a fairly imprecise concept, and for that reason courts and competition authorities often prefer to look to the outward manifestation of the parties’ intent. A transmits pricing information to its competitor B, and both parties intend that B should act on that information in order to align its prices with A’s and thereby to restrict competition It is clear that in this situation, the intention is to align prices. The object of the agreement is to restrict competition and there is an infringement of Art 81 EC. A and B exchange pricing information at a trade association meeting. C, who is also present, receives information from B and C, but does not transmit its own pricing information to A or B. It has no intention of aligning its prices with those of A and B, nor that A and B should align their prices with its own Notwithstanding the importance of this concurrence of wills, there are circumstances where liability appears to arise in the absence of concurrence as to subjective intent – or at least in the 23 absence of evidence to that effect. For example, in Aalborg Portland, the ECJ held that the fact that a participant at a meeting which had a clearly anti-competitive object did not intend to be bound by the agreement reached by the other participants at the meeting did not absolve it of liability for the infringement. The ECJ does not appear to be saying that this is a strict liability offence. It is still open to a participant in such a meeting to show that its subjective intent was different from that of the other participants (although the evidence required, in the form of a public distancing from the purpose of the meeting, is highly objective). This seems therefore to be an evidential issue. 23 See n 17, above. [2007] Comp Law 135 A transmits pricing information to its competitor B, but does not intend that B should pass that information to A’s competitor C It is here that the judgment of the Court of Appeal in Replica Kit and Toys and Games comes into play. The OFT had found in two separate cases, relating to replica football kit and toys respectively, that suppliers had acted as a conduit by which retailers had aligned their respective retail prices. The OFT had found not merely bilateral vertical resale price maintenance agreements, but also bilateral or multilateral horizontal agreements between the retailers. The CAT had upheld the OFT’s decisions, and had set out the following proposition: ‘659. … if one retailer A privately discloses to a supplier B its future pricing intentions in circumstances where it is reasonably foreseeable that B might make use of that information to influence market conditions, and B then passes that information on to a competing retailer C, then in our view A, B and C are all to be regarded on those facts as parties to a concerted practice having as its object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition. The prohibition on direct or indirect contact between competitors on prices has been infringed.’ Before the Court of Appeal, the appellants argued that this formulation was too wide: it was not sufficient for an anti-competitive outcome of the transmission of information from reseller to supplier to be foreseeable: it was necessary that the reseller should in fact have foreseen the subsequent transmission of the information to a competing reseller. The Court of Appeal agreed, although it emphasised that in practice, this distinction did not make a significant difference – under the circumstances, the retailers must have intended that their pricing intentions would be transmitted to their competitors via the suppliers. However, it is important to note that this principle appears to apply only where there is a legitimate alternative explanation for the transmission of information to an intermediary. 24 In its judgment in Makers, the CAT considered the application of the Toys and Games and Replica Kit principle, in the context of a bid-rigging arrangement. The OFT had found that figures submitted by Makers as part of its tender were identical to figures in a schedule faxed from Rock, one of the other bidders to Asphaltic, a third bidder. The OFT concluded that this indicated collusion between the parties – either directly or indirectly. Makers argued that based on the Toys and Games and Replica Kit formulation, in order to establish an infringement, the OFT must establish that Makers knew that the figures provided to it by Asphaltic originated from Rock, or that Makers knew that Rock and Asphaltic were colluding. 24 See n 3, above. ARTICLES Subjective intent is still relevant, but because of the difficulty of proving intent from what may be entirely passive participation at a meeting, intent is presumed from that participation. 136 [2007] Comp Law ARTICLES However, the CAT disagreed. It held, at para [100]: ‘This case, by contrast, involves the direct disclosure of pricing information from one competitor to another. We do not consider it necessary therefore for the OFT to prove that, in passing the pricing schedules to Asphaltic, Rock knew that Asphaltic would pass them on to Makers; nor that Makers knew that the figures had come from Rock.’ CONCLUSION The definition of an agreement is a fundamental one. At first sight, it lacks the complexity and interest of questions relating to the restriction of competition. Nevertheless, it has been the subject of some of the most important and interesting judgments and decisions of the past few years. It is clear that an analysis of the parties’ intentions underpins this entire issue. However, precisely because of this, and because the parties’ intentions may not be clear to each other or even to themselves, this is an area where further argument appears inevitable.