What Is International Financial Contagion? Thomas Moser

Transcription

What Is International Financial Contagion? Thomas Moser
International Finance 6:2, 2003: pp. 157–178
What Is International Financial
Contagion?
Thomas Moser
International Monetary Fund.
Abstract
Despite the growing popularity of blaming ‘contagion’ for international
financial crises, contagion remains an elusive concern. Without a clear
understanding of financial contagion and the mechanisms through which
it works, we can neither assess the problem nor design appropriate policy
measures to control it. This paper organizes and evaluates recent
research on international financial contagion. The main finding is that
the different mechanisms by which a crisis can spread greatly differ from
each other both in their causes and implications. Policy measures that do
not take these differences into account may do more harm than good.
I. Introduction
Blaming financial crises on contagion has proved to be highly contagious
among economists and politicians alike. For each of the international
financial crises of the 1990s, financial contagion has increasingly received
more credit, and some believe this to be an indispensable consequence of
I thank Barbara Do¨beli, Morris Goldstein, Werner Hermann, Maria Rueda Maurer, Jakob
Schaad, Umberto Schwarz, Charles Wyplosz, Fritz Zurbru¨gg and an anonymous referee for
valuable comments and suggestions. The views in this paper are my own and do not
necessarily reflect those of the IMF or IMF policy.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA
158
Thomas Moser
the ‘new global economy’ (IMF 1999, p. 66; Summers 2000, p. 6). This
popularity has led to a flood of research on the topic.1 If it were true that
financial crises can now easily spread across countries like contagious
diseases, the consequences would be serious. It has been claimed that in the
new global economy sound economic policies may not be enough to prevent
financial crises, as ‘the threat of contagion makes even the virtuous
vulnerable to currency runs’ (Feldstein 1999, p. 93). A financial crisis in any
country may be a threat to the stability of the global financial system. The
large international financial rescue packages of the 1990s and the
subsequent call for a new international financial architecture have been
responses to these concerns. To cure or at least mitigate financial contagion
is one of the main aims of the ongoing efforts to reform the international
financial system (Fischer 1999a, p. 557).
Despite the advanced stage of the policy debate, however, and the large
body of research it has generated, financial contagion remains an elusive
concern. Economists do not agree and are often not clear about what they
mean when they refer to it. Without a clear understanding of financial
contagion and the mechanisms through which it works, though, we can
neither seriously assess its importance nor design appropriate policy
measures. This paper organizes and evaluates recent research on the
subject.2 The main finding is that the mechanisms by which a crisis can
spread greatly differ both in their causes and implications. This is of
practical importance: Appropriate policy measures against contagion
depend on the specific contagion mechanism. Otherwise, they may do
more harm than good.
II. What Financial Contagion Does and Does Not Mean
Not only ‘contagion’ but also ‘financial crisis’, the supposedly transmitted
disease itself, is a remarkably imprecise term. The classical view in the
tradition of Thornton ([1802] 1978) and Bagehot ([1873] 1962) restricts the
term to problems in the banking sector (Wood 1999). In this classical view,
crashes in asset markets that do not threaten the stability of the banking
system are not financial crises; see, for example, Bordo et al. (1998). Most
contemporary authors, however, use the term more broadly, even
generically for events grouped into currency, banking and debt crises.
Currency crises are habitually defined as periods of ‘large’ changes in the
exchange rate or some index of market pressure, additionally allowing for
1
See, for example, the conference volume by Claessens and Forbes (2001).
2
For other attempts, see Claessens et al. (2001) and Pritsker (2001).
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
What Is International Financial Contagion?
159
changes in foreign reserves or interest rates to capture both successful as
well as unsuccessful currency attacks (Eichengreen et al. 1996; Kaminsky
and Reinhart 1999). Definitions of banking crises typically employ ratios of
non-performing assets to total assets in the banking system or incidents of
public sector crisis management such as rescue operations, takeovers,
deposit freezes, generalized deposit guarantees or bank holidays (Demirgu¨c¸Kunt and Detragiache 1998; Kaminsky and Reinhart 1999). Debt crises are
identified either by a certain level of arrears or by incidents of default or
debt restructuring agreements (Detragiache and Spilimbergo 2001).
Economists have used the concept of contagion even more widely.
Contagion is a long standing idea in explanations for the spread of bank
runs, but it has also been used to describe the spread of strikes across firms
or industries (Price 1890, p. 425; Mavor 1891, p. 205), the spread of wage
increases secured by labour unions to non-union firms or sectors (Ulman
1955, p. 397), the spread of business fluctuations across economies
(Mack and Zarnowitz 1958, p. 18), the diffusion of technology and
growth convergence across countries (Findlay 1978, p. 3; Baumol 1994),
and the spread of speculative trading across individuals (Murchison 1933,
p. 75; White 1940). In the recent literature, the concept is supposed to
describe incidents in which a (suitably defined) financial crisis in one
country brings about a crisis in another. In its broadest sense, therefore,
financial contagion has to do with the propagation of adverse shocks that
have the potential to trigger financial crises. The crux of the matter is
to identify potential propagation mechanisms and define those that
represent contagion. As a first step it is helpful to understand what
contagion does not mean.
A. Independent Shocks and Common Shocks
Simultaneous crises are not a sufficient condition for contagion. Contagion
requires causal connection. The (near) simultaneous occurrence of financial
crises may instead result from coincidence or common cause rather than
causal links. In the case of coincidence, independent shocks hit countries at
about the same time with no connection between the different crises, and
diagnosing contagion would be a post hoc fallacy. With common cause,
several countries are hit by a common global or regional external shock
(other than a financial crisis). Candidates for such adverse common shocks
with the potential of inflicting balance-of-payment difficulties, particularly
in emerging market economies, are changes in global (US) interest rates,
exchange rates between major currencies, commodity prices, or recessions
in major industrial countries.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
160
Thomas Moser
A rise in US interest rates adversely affects the funding of emerging
market economies not only by increasing their debt servicing costs and
lowering their creditworthiness (Calvo et al. 1996), but also by exacerbating
asymmetric information problems (Mishkin 1997). Similarly, unanticipated
drops in export prices may impair the corporate sectors’ capacity to service
debts in countries that heavily depend on export earnings and deteriorate
financial sector balance sheets. Movements in exchange rates between major
currencies may also inflict deterioration in balance sheets through adverse
effects on price competitiveness and export growth. Overall, such common
external shocks adversely affect economic fundamentals in a number of
countries simultaneously, potentially triggering crises in some of them. In
fact, for each of the major crises over the last two decades one can easily
identify a common shock in the run up to the crisis. The Latin American
debt crisis of 1982 and the Mexican crisis of 1994 were both preceded by a
sharp increase in US interest rates. A significant appreciation of the D-Mark
starting in the mid-1980s paved the way for the ERM crisis of 1992–93. The
Asian crisis of 1997 followed a sharp appreciation of the US dollar against
the yen, persistent economic stagnation in Japan, and a steep decline in
semiconductor prices.
Masson (1999b) proposes the term ‘monsoonal effects’ rather than
contagion for common shocks that result from such economic shifts. Others
tend to generalize the term contagion to any kind of external shock that
includes common shocks (Summers 2000, p. 6). However, this is misleading.
Contagion should be confined to describe situations in which a crisis in one
country causes crises in other countries, or at least makes them more likely.
Though common shocks and contagion are both a source of systemic risk,
they are different phenomena.
B. Interdependence of Fundamentals
Even confined to crises that are causally connected, it is controversial
whether any transmission of country specific shocks should be considered
contagion. In particular, interdependence among countries arises because
their economic fundamentals are linked through the balance of payments. A
crisis in one country can affect another’s fundamentals.
A well-known channel of such shock propagation is international trade. A
crisis in one country, usually associated with economic contraction and
exchange rate devaluation, negatively affects exports of trading partners
through a fall in demand and a loss in price competitiveness. Such trade
related shock propagation does not only work through bilateral trade links,
but also through indirect trade links resulting from common third markets.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
What Is International Financial Contagion?
161
In the recent Argentine crisis, the devaluation of the peso in early 2002
followed by a severe economic contraction had clear repercussions for
Mercosur, the trade bloc including Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay and
Uruguay. It is no coincidence that the other three members approached a
financial crisis in 2002, particularly Uruguay with Argentina its second
largest trading partner. In turn, Brazil’s devaluation in 1999 was an
important reason for the protracted period of contraction that Argentina
and Uruguay suffered in the run up to the crisis.
Kindleberger (1985, p. 227) has argued that such trade propagation
mechanisms are ‘too strung out with lags to explain the near simultaneity of
y crises’, but agents in financial markets respond in anticipation of real
impacts causing immediate corrections in asset prices. However, asset prices
and capital flows do not react only to anticipated trade shocks. Independent
financial linkages can be either bilateral direct cross-border investments, or
indirect through common investors. As an example of a bilateral linkage, the
Argentine crisis of 2002 led many Argentines to withdraw dollar deposits
held in Uruguay, causing banks in Uruguay to withdraw required reserves
and accelerate the decline in central bank reserves, finally leading to the
floating of the peso in June 2002.3
Regarding indirect links, international investors including banks and
institutional investors such as mutual funds, hedge funds and pension
funds, diversify their portfolios over financial assets of numerous
countries. Even if they hold only a small fraction of their portfolio in
emerging markets, these fractions can represent a significant proportion of
the relatively small capital markets in those countries, and portfolio
rebalancing may cause significant capital flows (Kaminsky et al. 2001).
Several authors have pointed out that international investors could
undertake such portfolio rebalancing in response to a crisis in one country,
and thereby put other emerging economies in trouble by selling their assets
or calling loans.
Schinasi and Smith (2001) show how cross-country transmission of
shocks can be explained by basic portfolio theory as an optimal portfolio
rebalancing response to a financial crisis in one country. They show that an
adverse shock to a single asset’s return distribution can lead to a reduction
in other risky asset positions, depending on the portfolio management rule
and the parameterization of the joint distribution of asset returns. In the
presence of leverage, the optimal response to a realized loss on a specific
position is to deleverage and reduce risky asset positions in all markets.
3
However, the withdrawal of deposits by Argentines also contained a significant element of
‘domino effects’. Many Argentines were forced to raise liquidity due to the fact that their
government imposed a freeze on withdrawals from domestic banks, the corralito.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
162
Thomas Moser
Overall, their analysis suggests that, under plausible conditions, a crisis in
one market can generate substantial reductions in the optimal positions in
non-crisis markets in the move to a new equilibrium.
In the literature on financial contagion, there is yet little convergence of
views about whether cross-country propagation of shocks through
fundamentals should be considered contagion. A number of authors call
for discrimination between ‘pure contagion’ and shock propagation through
fundamentals, which they suggest labelling ‘transmission’ (Bordo et al.
1998), ‘spillovers’ (Masson 1999b), ‘interdependence’ (Forbes and Rigobon
2002) or ‘fundamentals-based contagion’ (Kaminsky and Reinhart 2000).
The main reason for discrimination is that shock propagation through
fundamentals is the result of an optimal response to external shocks. As a
crisis in one country upsets the equilibrium in other countries, real and
financial variables adjust to a new equilibrium. Financial market responses
only reflect (anticipated) changes in fundamentals and speed up adjustment
to the new equilibrium, but they do not cause the change in equilibrium. In
other words, rather than causing the crisis, financial market responses bring
the crisis forward.
III. Mechanisms of Pure Contagion
To explain cross-country propagation of shocks not related to or explained
by economic fundamentals, one has to resort to market imperfections. I will
divide the different explanations into information effects and domino
effects. Information effects involve a crisis in one country that triggers a
crisis in others as agents take the crisis as a signal to update information. In
a domino effect, a crisis in one country leads to crises in others because of
financial connectivity.
A. Information Effects
Information imperfections and costs of acquiring and processing information make a correct assessment of fundamentals difficult and a certain
degree of ignorance rational. As a result, market participants are uncertain
about the true state of a country’s fundamentals. A crisis elsewhere might
lead them to reassess the fundamentals of other countries and cause them to
sell assets, to call in loans, or to stop lending to these countries, even if their
fundamentals remain objectively unchanged. The literature offers a number
of reasons why a crisis elsewhere could lead to a reassessment of objectively
unchanged fundamentals.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
What Is International Financial Contagion?
163
Signal extraction failures
One group of explanations follows the framework adopted by King and
Wadhwani (1990). The basic idea is that due to incomplete information,
market participants are uncertain about the relevance of a financial crisis in
one country for the fundamentals of another country. There are two possible
stories of how this could result in contagion. In what could be called
‘fictitious interdependence’, market participants falsely assume interdependence of fundamentals or at least overestimate the extent of interdependence. As a result of the former, a country specific shock that would have no
effect on the other country in the case of full information would nevertheless
be transmitted. As a result of the latter, the propagation would be excessive
relative to a situation with full information (Pritsker 2001). Second, in what
could be called the ‘lump together hypothesis’, market participants assume
that countries considered ‘similar’ to the crisis country face potentially
similar problems. For instance, investors could misinterpret a country
specific shock as a common shock for a number of countries. Alternatively,
lumping several countries together could result from some form of
statistical discrimination, insofar as the problems that cause a crisis in
one country are thought to reveal a characteristic of a wider group of
countries. In both cases of signal extraction failures, fictitious interdependence or lumping together, a crisis in one country leads to an inefficient
revision of fundamentals and a less accurate assessment. This inaccuracy
would give better-informed investors scope for profits. However, one could
argue that the resulting short-run pressures suffice to lead the countries
concerned into trouble.
Wake-up call
A different story as to why a crisis in one country could lead to a
reassessment of objectively unchanged fundamentals in other countries is
what Goldstein (1998, p. 18) calls the ‘wake-up call’ hypothesis. A crisis in
one country may serve as a ‘wake-up call’ for market participants if it causes
them to take a closer look at fundamentals similar to those in the crisis
country. Contagion occurs if this leads them to detect problems or risks they
failed to see before.4 The difference to the former explanation is that, in the
signal extraction story, the initial crisis makes market participants assume
problems that do not exist, whereas, with a wake-up call, it makes them
aware of existing problems. This sort of contagion is the result of an efficient
correction and leads towards a more accurate assessment of fundamentals.
4
See Goldstein (1998, p. 18): ‘I refer to it as a wake-up call because to judge from most
market indicators of risk, private creditors and rating agencies were asleep prior to the
outbreak of the Thai crisis.’
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
164
Thomas Moser
Expectations interaction
This line of argument takes a crowd psychology approach and employs a
form of ‘mental contagion’ in the tradition of the classical financial panic
view, depicting financial crises as self-fulfilling expectations phenomena or
coordination failures among agents in the presence of multiple equilibria.
Contagion arises if a crisis elsewhere serves as the ‘sunspot variable’ that
leads agents to co-ordinate their expectations on crisis equilibria. A crisis in
one country may cause the loss of public confidence in financial markets or
international investments in general, setting off runs in other countries.5
Alternatively, such a story would be consistent with Bayesian updating in
which market participants raise the probability they assign to the
occurrence of a crisis in similar circumstances on the basis of drawing
another favourable observation (Drazen 2000).
There are two frameworks for modelling self-fulfilling financial crises, one
along the lines of the Diamond–Dybvig (1983) model of bank runs, the other
along the lines of the Obstfeld (1986) model of speculative attacks. Chang
and Velasco (2001) and Marshall (1998) apply the Diamond–Dybvig
approach to countries, and the cause for financial crises are simultaneous
liquidity withdrawals, not driven by economic fundamentals, which result in
costly liquidations and asset price collapses. Two equilibria arise when a
country’s financial system has potential short-term obligations in foreign
currency that exceed the amount of foreign currency it can access on short
notice. The crisis equilibrium occurs if international creditors stop lending
and withdraw funds for fear that all other will do so, forcing the financial
system to liquidate potentially profitable investments at a loss. Alternatively,
in the Obstfeld (1986) model, the multiplicity of equilibria arises because
expectations feed back in an adverse way into the fundamentals, eventually
inducing the government to change its policy. For instance, expectations of
devaluation affect aggregate demand, debt servicing costs and bank balance
sheets through higher interest rates. Consequently, a country will abandon
the exchange rate peg if coordinated behaviour of speculators raises the
costs of maintaining the peg sufficiently high.
Common to both approaches is the implication that such crises are apparently unnecessary as they are not determined by underlying fundamentals,
but every agent will find it individually advantageous to participate in an
expected run or attack. Both frameworks, however, require initial fundamentals to be in a range of ‘discomfort’. Consequently, while self-fulfilling
crises seem possible, not just any country can be subject to such a crisis. The
Obstfeld model requires a sufficiently unfavourable initial state of the
5
Note that contagion across different markets or institutions requires more than herding
behaviour with respect to one market or institution, explaining the notion ‘in general’.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
What Is International Financial Contagion?
165
economy to make adverse market sentiment possible and the country
vulnerable to the cost it may cause. In the Diamond–Dybvig approach, the
multiple equilibrium phenomenon is essentially related to liquidity risk, a
risk that is evident for banks due to the unique characteristics of their
balance sheet and deposit contracts, but not imperative for countries.
To construct an international financial contagion story, however, one
could still apply the original Diamond–Dybvig approach confined to the
banking industry. For instance, when in late April 2002 residents in Uruguay
started to join Argentines in withdrawing dollar deposits, some saw this as a
matter of pure contagion across banking institutions. However, considering
the unresolved problems in some banks in Uruguay, the signs of a
deepening recession, the decline in international reserves and the rising
doubts about the government maintaining the exchange rate peg, there was
good reason for demanding immediate withdrawal. More generally, there is
not much evidence that depositor runs have driven solvent banks into
insolvency, not even during the exemplary banking panic of the Great
Depression (Calomiris and Mason 1997).
Moral hazard plays
Dooley (2000) offers an explanation for contagion where a crisis in one
country leads investors to revise their bail-out expectations. This line of
argument links contagion to moral hazard, as expected insurance against
losses is an important factor in generating capital flows in the first place.
Investors overlook weak fundamentals as long as reserves plus the amount of
potential assistance by the international community is thought to be large
enough to insure against losses. Contagion may occur if a crisis elsewhere
leads investors to revise potential international assistance below some critical
level where the expected liquidation value of the investments net of insurance
is less than the value of claims. Such a downward revision could occur
whether or not the crisis country receives official lending. If it does, this will
reduce potential lending available for bail-outs for any other country, as the
overall size of funds available for bail-outs is likely to be limited. Conversely,
if the country is not rescued (e.g., Russia in 1998), investors may interpret
this as a change in the crisis management policy of the international
community and revise downward the expected value of the overall size of
funds available for bail-outs. In either case, contagion would mean that
investors bring their positions closer into line with economic fundamentals.
Membership contagion
Drazen (2000) provides an explanation for contagion in currency crises that
focuses on the actions of policy makers. Countries with fixed exchange rates
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
166
Thomas Moser
can be thought of as members of a ‘no-devaluation club’ with the value of
membership depending positively on who else is a member. Such a club can
be defined explicitly (e.g., the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) of the EU)
or implicitly if politicians attach weight to being ‘lumped together’ with
successful neighbour countries that have fixed exchange rates. Membership
contagion may then result if the devaluation by one ‘club member’ weakens
the membership criterion and makes other members more likely to devalue
because governments assign a lower value to the commitment. One could
also broaden the story and argue that governments, sacrificing domestic
economic goals to maintain a fixed exchange rate, can assume market
participants take a more favourable view of a devaluation if it follows in the
wake of other devaluations, particularly if contagion can be blamed.
Contagion would then result from the lower costs of breaking a commitment
if others do so.
B. Domino Effects
In this group of explanations, a crisis in one country spreads to others
rather mechanically in domino fashion as a result of direct or indirect
financial connections. This story comes in three variations.
Counterparty defaults
The most straightforward version is the one of ‘cascading defaults’ and is a
matter of ordinary credit risk (Marshall 1998). High exposure to troubled
private or sovereign debtors may lead to cross-border transmission of
failures if losses for creditors are large enough. This is particularly likely if
banks are among the major creditors, as they operate with relatively low
capital-to-asset ratios. Accordingly, a country could experience a banking
crisis if major banks suffer large losses from defaults on foreign loans or
cross-border settlements. Concerns over loan defaults were one of the main
motivations for the international rescue operations during the Latin
American debt crisis of 1982, with claims on troubled debtors heavily
concentrated in the hands of few leading banks.6 A famous example for
cross-border settlement failure is the closure of the Herstatt Bank in
Germany in 1974, which occurred during the business day in New York and
led to counterparty losses for banks that had already fulfilled their side of
foreign exchange transactions with Herstatt.
6
See, for example, Fischer (1987, p. 166). In 1982, the nine large US money centre banks had
more than 250% of their capital in loans to less developed countries.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
What Is International Financial Contagion?
167
Portfolio rebalancing due to liquidity constraints
A number of authors have pointed out that liquidity or capital constraints
could impose greater than optimal asset reduction on international
investors affected by a crisis in one market, forcing them to unwind
positions in other markets to raise liquidity. This unwinding could occur if
investors need to meet margin calls or other collateral requirements, or fulfil
investor redemptions in the case of mutual funds. As originally suggested by
Valde´s (1997), liquidity needs could also arise if market liquidity sharply
declines or virtually dries up because a market maker or important market
participant suffers large losses and withdraws funds, or if several
participants unwind similar positions at the same time. If market
participants rely on such a market for funding or hedging, they might be
forced to cover by selling assets in unrelated liquid markets. Such concerns
seem to have been a factor in the Federal Reserve’s intervention to prevent
forced liquidation of the hedge fund Long Term Capital Management
(LTCM) in Autumn 1998 (Greenspan 1998). Anecdotal evidence also
suggests that, in the financial market turbulence following the Russian crisis
during the Autumn of 1998, market liquidity dried up temporarily even in
such deep and mature markets as the US repo market and the yen/dollar
currency market (IMF 1998, p. 51). It has also been reported that, in the
wake of the 1998 Russian crisis, international investors put short positions
in the relatively deep markets for Hungarian and Brazilian debt in place to
hedge against long positions in Russian securities (CGFS 1999).
As pointed out by Masson (1999a), explaining the persistence of such
effects requires explaining why other investors, seeing the fundamentals
unchanged, do not take advantage of the buying opportunity created by a
few institutions in trouble. Calvo (1998) offers that a ‘lemons problem’ could
arise because of information asymmetries. If buyers cannot distinguish
whether sellers sell because of liquidity constraints or because they know
something about the fundamentals, investors in need for liquidity can sell
assets only at firesale prices.
Portfolio rebalancing due to capital constraints
Capital constraints are another factor that could impose greater than
optimal asset reduction on investors affected by a crisis. Particularly, capital
requirements that induce banks to adjust their capital ratios might cause
them to cut back foreign loans or, in the case of ratios to risk-weighted
assets, shift into low-risk assets such as government securities. A bank could
also respond by improving the numerator in the capital–asset ratio, perhaps
by issuing equity or by retaining earnings, although this might be difficult in
times of crisis. Evidence that this channel can be economically significant
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
168
Thomas Moser
even between advanced countries has been provided by Peek and Rosengren
(1997) who show that risk-based capital requirements associated with the
Japanese stock market decline resulted in a significant decrease in lending by
Japanese banks in the USA in the early 1990s. Peek and Rosengren (2000)
further show that this loan supply shock had real effects on economic activity
in the USA in that it was not compensated by lending from other sources.
IV. Does Contagion Matter?
While the above discussion suggests that pure contagion is possible, to be a
matter of political concern it has to be empirically relevant. The empirical
research on contagion seems to arrive at the following conclusion. First,
while common shocks and interdependence of fundamentals, particularly
trade links, explain a large part of the simultaneous occurrence of financial
crises, the empirical role for pure contagion seems to be relatively limited.
Second, regarding this limited role, empirical evidence points to the
existence of portfolio rebalancing effects.
A. Testing for Contagion
Measuring contagion encounters empirical difficulties (Rigobon 2002). One
problem is that financial contagion is associated with high frequency events
while, for most economic fundamentals, high frequency data is not
available, making it difficult to control for fundamentals. A widely used
approach to test for contagion is to study cross-market correlation of
financial variables and to define contagion as a significant increase in
correlation coefficients during the crisis period.7
Several of the initial studies that applied the correlation approach to the
crises of the 1990s found that cross-market correlation did increase
significantly during these crises. However, Forbes and Rigobon (2002)
pointed out that correlation coefficients are biased in the presence of
heteroscedasticity, overstating the magnitude of correlation when market
7
The logic of this approach can be shown in a simple framework following Forbes and
Rigobon (2002). The financial market variable of interest (exchange rate, interest rate, stock
prices) of country i, yi,t, can be described by yi,t 5 aixt1bizt1ei,t, where x is a vector of the
respective variable in countries other than i, z is a variable that captures common shocks,
and e represents country-specific shocks. Vector a measures the impact of country-specific
shocks elsewhere on fundamentals of country i (interdependence) and vector b the effect of
common shocks on country i. Contagion is captured by a change in either ai or bi after a
shock to an other country, as reflected by a change in the correlation between yi,t, and xt.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
What Is International Financial Contagion?
169
volatility increases during a crisis.8 Based on an extensive set of tests, they
find that, if correlation coefficients are adjusted for heteroscedasticity, there
is virtually no evidence for contagion during recent crises. Since they find
considerable cross-market linkages in all periods, their analysis suggests
that most shocks are common or transmitted across markets through
interdependence of fundamentals.
Some recent studies have found somewhat more favourable evidence for
pure contagion even after correcting for the bias described by Forbes and
Rigobon (2002), but they do not establish a strong case for contagion.9 Baig
and Goldfajn (1999) study cross-market correlation during the Asian crisis
with respect to foreign exchange, equity, interest rates and sovereign debt
markets, and find a significant increase in correlation only in foreign debt
markets, whereas the evidence in stock markets is mixed at best. They
further try to distinguish co-movements driven by fundamentals and nonfundamentals by creating a set of daily variables constructed from news
reported by the press that proxy for movements in fundamentals. Testing
for impacts of cross-border news on the markets after controlling for owncountry news and other fundamentals, they find evidence for such impact in
the currency and equity markets. Gelos and Sahay (2001) employ a VAR
framework to study daily stock and exchange market data during the 1997
Czech crisis, the Asian crisis and the 1998 Russian crisis, and find that
Russian stock returns ‘Granger caused’ returns in European transition
economies during the Russian crisis, while this was usually not the case
during tranquil times. They find no evidence for an increase in
heteroscedasticity-adjusted correlations in stock markets, but do so in
exchange markets. Bordo and Murshid (2001) examine cross-country
correlations in bond prices and interests rates during seven international
financial crises from the pre World War I era to the Asian crisis. After
adjusting for heteroscedasticity, they find only a very small number of
isolated cases of pure contagion.
The conclusions of Forbes and Rigobon (2002) coincide with Moreno and
Trehan (2000) who analyse the extent to which common external shocks
alone can explain simultaneous currency crises. Analysing a sample of 121
countries over the 1974–97 period, Moreno and Trehan (2000) find that
common external shocks can explain close to 75% of the variation in the
total number of crisis over time. In fact, according to their findings, changes
8
The intuition behind this is that, due to an increase in the variance of xt, a greater
proportion of the fluctuations in yi,t is explained by xt and, therefore, estimated correlation
between yi,t and xt increases, even if the value of a remains unchanged.
9
For a critical discussion of the Forbes–Rigobon approach, see also Corsetti et al. (2001) who
find the Forbes–Rigobon test to be biased towards the null hypothesis of interdependence.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
170
Thomas Moser
in US interest rates and US inflation alone explain about half of the variation
in the aggregate number of crises over time. Overall, their results suggest
that common shocks are responsible for a large fraction of the simultaneous
occurrence of currency crises.
B. Testing for Specific Propagation Mechanisms
A number of studies attempt to disentangle the different mechanisms
through which shocks are propagated. A general finding is the importance of
trade links for crisis transmission, coinciding with the result that the driving
force is interdependence of fundamentals rather than pure contagion.
Eichengreen et al. (1996) estimate a probit model with a panel of data for
20 industrial countries for the period 1959–93 and define contagion as a
crisis in one country increasing the probability of a crisis occurring in other
countries. After finding evidence of such contagion, they discriminate
between different channels of transmission by weighting crises elsewhere by
the importance of trade and by the similarity of macroeconomic policies and
outcomes. They find the trade weighted measure to be significant and
conclude that trade links rather than revisions of expectations have been the
dominant channel of crisis propagation. This result is confirmed by Glick
and Rose (1999) who estimate a probit equation across countries to test for
the importance of direct and indirect trade links in five episodes of currency
crises from the breakdown of the Bretton Woods system in 1971 to the Asian
crisis in 1997–98. They find that currency crises mainly spread along trade
links. Gelos and Sahay (2001) find that composite indices of exchange
market pressure are moderately correlated across European transition
economies during the 1990s, a correlation that can partly be explained by
direct trade linkages but not measures of other fundamentals. De Gregorio
and Valde´s (2001) examine the performance of alternative crisis indicators
as a function of initial macroeconomic conditions and a weighted average of
crisis indicators. Alternative weighting schemes are used to capture different
channels of propagation. They find that, during the 1982 debt crisis and the
Mexican and Asian crises of the 1990s, trade links were very important,
although they cannot account for the entire regional effect. Forbes (2002)
obtains a similar result by decomposing the trade channel into separate
competitiveness and income effects and utilizing industry level trade data
rather than aggregate trade flows. Examining a sample of 58 countries
during 16 crises from 1994 through 1999, she finds that countries competing
with exports from a crisis country (competitiveness effect) and exporting to
the crisis country (income effect) had significantly lower stock market
returns. However, these trade effects explain only a portion of stock market
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
What Is International Financial Contagion?
171
movements during crises, perhaps pointing to other channels such as
portfolio rebalancing.
These conclusions also hold at the firm level. Forbes (2000) looks at firmlevel data including 46 countries with more than 10,000 companies to test
how the Asian and the Russian crises affected individual company’s stock
market returns. Estimating the effect of different firm characteristics on
stock market returns during the crisis, Forbes confirms the importance of
both direct and indirect trade links as transmission channels. Additionally,
she finds that, during the later part of the Asian crisis, more liquid stocks
had significantly lower returns than the rest of the sample and suggests that
this result points to transmission through portfolio effects.
Some recent studies find evidence for portfolio rebalancing effects,
particularly with regard to bank lending.10 These studies, however, do not
discriminate between shock propagation resulting from an optimal portfolio
response and propagation resulting from liquidity or capital constraints.
Additionally, trade and bank lending linkages tend to be highly correlated,
making it difficult to distinguish between the two.
Kaminsky and Reinhart (2000) estimate conditional probabilities that a
crisis will occur in a given country for 80 currency crises and test for a
common lender channel of shock propagation. First, they group countries in
accordance with their exposure to US banks and Japanese banks respectively
to test for propagation through foreign bank lending. Second, they form two
clusters of countries that exhibit a high degree of historic co-movement in
their asset returns to capture cross-hedging strategies and test for
propagation through globally diversified portfolios. They find that both
types of clusters add information in that a crisis in the respective cohort
significantly increases the conditional probability of a crisis, suggesting
evidence for crisis propagation through portfolio rebalancing. Limited to
bank lending (but also including European banks), Van Rijckeghem and
Weder (2001) test the importance of a ‘common bank lender’ channel of
contagion relative to trade links during the Mexican, Asian and Russian
crises of the 1990s. For each crisis episode, they run regressions with a
number of alternative crisis indicators and trade linkages, competition for
bank funds, and a set of macro fundamentals as independent variables, and
find that contagion through common bank lenders was important.
Caramazza et al. (2003) employ panel probit estimation and construct a
trade-link variable and common creditor variables to examine the
occurrence of currency pressures during the major crisis episodes of the
10
In fact, Froot et al. (2001), exploring data on daily international portfolio flows from 1994
through 1998, find that institutional investors did not abandon emerging equity markets
during the Mexican or the Asian crisis.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
172
Thomas Moser
1990s. They find that financial linkages with the major creditor of the crisis
country appears to substantially raise the probability of a crisis. Rather than
looking at prices, Van Rijckeghem and Weder (2000) test the common
lender effect by looking at volumes, studying panel data on bank flows to a
subset of 30 emerging markets disaggregated by 11 creditor countries. Their
regressions point to the existence of a common lender effect in the Mexican
and Asian crises of the 1990s. For the Russian crisis, they find a more
generalized withdrawal of funds, interpreted as an increase in perceived risk
or a general increase in risk aversion.
V. Policy Implications
While much goes by the name of financial contagion, empirical research
suggests common shocks rather than contagion explain an important part of
the simultaneous occurrence of financial crises. As to the other part, there
are good reasons for discriminating between shock propagation through
fundamentals and shock propagation unrelated to fundamentals (pure
contagion). Although the role of pure contagion seems to be rather limited,
this paper identifies eight potential mechanisms that differ sharply in causes
and implications. For instance, contagion may equally stem from an
inefficient reassessment of fundamentals or from efficient correction toward
a more accurate assessment. Policy makers had better take these differences
into account.
A case in point is the call for an international lender of last resort as a
defence against financial contagion (Fischer 1999b). Some authors have
pointed out that policy implications differ with regard to common shocks
and interdependence of fundamentals versus pure contagion (Chang and
Majnoni 2001; Forbes and Rigobon 2002; Baig and Goldfajn 1999). They
conclude that liquidity assistance is an appropriate response only to pure
contagion, while common shocks and interdependence, matters of economic
fundamentals, have to be dealt with through policy measures that seek to
improve the fundamentals. Otherwise, liquidity support might only delay
necessary adjustment. This paper suggests that, even in the case of pure
contagion, the advisability of short-term liquidity assistance depends on the
specific contagion mechanism.
If contagion is channelled through information effects, liquidity
assistance is an appropriate response only in the case of signal extraction
failures and expectations interactions. With signal extraction failures, if
market participants either misjudge interdependence or falsely lump
apparently similar countries together, it is reasonable to assume such
contagion will only give rise to temporary market pressure either because
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
What Is International Financial Contagion?
173
participants learn about the fundamentals or better-informed participants
take advantage of profit opportunities. In the second case, if expectations
interaction triggers a self-fulfilling crisis, liquidity assistance stands a good
chance of success. If the country is vulnerable to self-fulfilling runs because
of international illiquidity, liquidity assistance is just what the doctor
ordered and the prospect of assistance might even stabilize expectations
sufficiently to eliminate self-fulfilling runs in the first place. If the country is
vulnerable to adverse market sentiment because of its initial state of
fundamentals, the availability of additional foreign reserves at relatively low
cost at least increases the critical size of the attack that is required to be
successful (Disyatat 2001). As to the remaining information effects, liquidity
assistance is less promising. In the case of membership contagion,
availability of additional reserves at low cost does influence the government
decision, but hardly enough to substantially weaken the temptation to take
advantage of the ‘sharing-the-blame’ effect so as to solve a conflict between
the fixed exchange rate and other domestic goals. A case in point is the ERM
crisis of 1992–93, where mutual liquidity assistance was available. Wake-up
calls, where participants detect previously unnoticed problems, and moral
hazard plays, where participants overlook problems as long as insurance is
thought to be large enough, are matters of fundamentals; problems that
temporary liquidity assistance are unable to solve. Liquidity assistance
would even further spur the moral hazard play.
In the case of domino effects, results are just as mixed. With counterparty
defaults, the problem is solvency not liquidity. Accordingly, the problem has
to be dealt with through measures that re-establish solvency. In the case of
portfolio rebalancing effects, the reason for rebalancing matters. If the crosscountry transmission of the shock is due to liquidity constraints, the capital
outflow pressure may be a short-term matter as investors return after
liquidity constraints are lifted and short-term financing could help weather
the storm. If portfolio rebalancing is due to capital constraints, the nature of
the shock is more likely to be longer term as it takes more time to raise
capital than to raise liquidity.
Given that the simultaneous occurrence of financial crises seems to be
mainly a matter of common shocks and interdependence of fundamentals,
and that what is left for pure contagion seems to hint at portfolio
rebalancing, international liquidity assistance alone should not be expected
to cure what is perceived, rightly or wrongly, as international financial
contagion.
Thomas Moser
Advisor to Executive Director
IMF, OEDSZ
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
174
Thomas Moser
700 19th Street, NW,
Washington, D.C. 20431
USA
tmoser@imf.org.
References
Bagehot, Walter ([1873] 1962), Lombard Street: A Description of the Money
Market. Homewood, IL: Irwin.
Baig, Taimur, and Ilan Goldfajn (1999), ‘Financial Market Contagion in the Asian
Crisis’, IMF Staff Papers, 46, 167–95.
Baumol, William J. (1994), ‘Multivariate Growth Patterns: Contagion and Common
Forces as Possible Sources of Convergence’, in W. Baumol, W. Wolff and R. Nelson
(eds), Convergence of Productivity: Cross-National Studies and Historical Evidence,
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 62–85.
Bordo, Michael, and Antu Murshid (2001), ‘Are Financial Crises Becoming
Increasingly More Contagious? What is the Historical Evidence on Contagion?’, in
S. Claessens and K. Forbes (eds), International Financial Contagion, Boston, MA:
Kluwer Academic Publishers, 367–405.
Bordo, Michael, Bruce Mizrach and Anna J. Schwartz (1998), ‘Real versus Pseudointernational Systemic Risk: Some Lessons from History’, Review of Pacific Basin
Financial Markets and Policies, 1, 31–58.
Calomiris, Charles, and Joseph Mason (1997), ‘Contagion and Bank Failures
During the Great Depression: The June 1932 Chicago Banking Panic’, American
Economic Review, 87, 863–83.
Calvo, Guillermo A. (1998), ‘Understanding the Russian Virus, with Special
Reference to Latin America’, Mimeo, University of Maryland.
Calvo, Guillermo A., Leonardo Leiderman and Carmen M. Reinhart (1996),
‘Inflows of Capital to Developing Countries in the 1990s’, Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 10, 123–39.
Caramazza, Francesco, Ricci Luca and Ranil Salgado (2003), ‘International
Financial Contagion in Currency Crises’, Journal of International Money and
Finance, forthcoming.
Chang, Roberto, and Giovanni Majnoni (2001), ‘International Contagion:
Implications for Policy’, in S. Claessens and K. Forbes (eds), International
Financial Contagion, Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Chang, Roberto, and Andre´s Velasco (2001), ‘A Model of Financial Crises in
Emerging Markets’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 489–517.
Claessens Stijn, and Kristin Forbes eds, (2001), International Financial Contagion.
Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
What Is International Financial Contagion?
175
Claessens, Stijn, Rudiger Dornbusch and Yung Chul Park (2001), ‘Contagion: Why
Crises Spread and How This Can Be Stopped’, in S. Claessens and K. Forbes (eds),
International Financial Contagion, Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Committee on the Global Financial System (1999), A Review of Financial Markets
Events in Autumn 1998. Basel: Bank for International Settlements.
Corsetti, G., M. Pericoli and M. Sbracia (2001), ‘Correlation Analysis of Financial
Contagion: What One Should Know before Running a Test’, Discussion Paper 822,
Economic Growth Center, Yale University.
De Gregorio, Jose´, and Rodrigo O. Valde´s (2001), ‘Crisis Transmission: Evidence
from the Debt, Tequila, and Asian Flu Crises’, World Bank Economic Review, 15,
289–314.
Demirgu¨c¸-Kunt, A., and E. Detragiache (1998), ‘The Determinants of Banking
Crises in Developing and Developed Countries’, IMF Staff Papers, 45, 81–109.
Detragiache, E., and A. Spilimbergo (2001), ‘Crises and Liquidity: Evidence and
Interpretation’, IMF Working Paper No. 01/2.
Diamond, Douglas W., and Philip H. Dybvig (1983), ‘Bank Runs, Deposit
Insurance, and Liquidity’, Journal of Political Economy, 91, 401–19.
Disyatat, Piti (2001), ‘Currency Crises and Foreign Reserves: A Simple Model’, IMF
Working Paper No. 01/18.
Dooley, Michael P. (2000), ‘A Model of Crises in Emerging Markets’, Economic
Journal, 110, 256–72.
Drazen, Allen (2000), ‘Political Contagion in Currency Crises’, in P. Krugman
(ed.), Currency Crises, Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press, 47–67.
Eichengreen, Barry, Andrew Rose and Charles Wyplosz (1996), ‘Contagious
Currency Crises’, Scandinavian Economic Review, 98, 463–84.
Feldstein, Martin (1999), ‘A Self-Help Guide for Emerging Markets’, Foreign
Affairs, 78, March/April, 93–109.
Findlay, Ronald (1978), ‘Relative Backwardness, Direct Foreign Investment, and
the Transfer of Technology: A Simple Dynamic Model’, Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 92, 1–16.
Fischer, Stanley (1987), ‘Sharing the Burden of the International Debt Crisis’,
American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 77, 165–70.
Fischer, Stanley (1999a), ‘Reforming the International Financial System’, Economic
Journal, 109, F557–76.
Fischer, Stanley (1999b), ‘On the Need for an International Lender of Last Resort’,
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13, 85–104.
Forbes, Kristin (2000), ‘The Asian Flu and Russian Virus: Firm-level Evidence on
How Crises are Transmitted Internationally’, NBER Working Paper 7807.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
176
Thomas Moser
Forbes, Kristin (2002), ‘Are Trade Linkages Important Determinants of Country
Vulnerability to Crises?’, in S. Edwards and J. A. Frankel (eds), Preventing
Currency Crises in Emerging Markets, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press,
77–124.
Forbes, Kristin, and Roberto Rigobon (2002), ‘No Contagion, Only Interdependence: Measuring Stock Market Comovements’, Journal of Finance, 57, 2223–62.
Froot, Kenneth, Paul O’Connell and Mark Seasholes (2001), ‘The Portfolio Flows of
International Investors’, Journal of Financial Economics, 59, 151–93.
Gelos, Gaston, and Ratna Sahay (2001), ‘Financial Market Spillovers in Transition
Economies’, Economics of Transition, 1, 53–86.
Glick, Reuven, and Andrew K. Rose (1999), ‘Contagion and Trade: Why are
Currency Crises Regional?’, Journal of International Money and Finance, 18, 603–
17.
Goldstein, Morris (1998), The Asian Crisis: Causes, Cures, and Systemic
Implications. Washington: Institute for International Economics.
Greenspan, Alan (1998), ‘Testimony before the Committee on Banking and
Financial Services’, US House of Representatives, 1 October. Available at
www.federalreserve.gov.
International Monetary Fund (1998), World Economic Outlook and International
Capital Markets: Interim Assessment. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
International Monetary Fund (1999), World Economic Outlook: May 1999.
Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Kaminsky, Graciela, and Carmen Reinhart (1999), ‘The Twin Crises: The Causes of
Banking and Balance-of-Payment Problems’, American Economic Review, 89, 473–
500.
Kaminsky, Graciela, and Carmen Reinhart (2000), ‘On Crises, Contagion, and
Confusion’, Journal of International Economics, 51, 145–68.
Kaminsky, Graciela, Richard Lyons and Sergio Schmukler (2001), ‘Mutual Fund
Investment in Emerging Markets: An Overview’, World Bank Economic Review, 15,
315–40.
Kindleberger, Charles (1985), ‘International Propagation of Financial Crises: The
Experience of 1888–93’, in Charles Kindleberger Keynesianism vs. Monetarism and
Other Essays in Financial History, London: Allen and Unwin, 226–39.
King, Mervyn, and Sushil Wadhwani (1990), ‘Transmission of Volatility between
Stock Markets’, Review of Financial Studies, 3, 5–33.
Mack, R. P., and V. Zarnowitz (1958), ‘Causes and Consequences of Changes in
Retailers’ Buying’, American Economic Review, 48, 18–49.
Marshall, David (1998), ‘Understanding the Asian Crisis: Systemic Risk as
Coordination Failure’, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Economic Perspectives, 22,
13–27.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
What Is International Financial Contagion?
177
Masson, Paul (1999a), ‘Multiple Equilibria, Contagion, and the Emerging Market
Crises’, IMF Working Paper No. 99/164.
Masson, Paul (1999b), ‘Contagion: Monsoonal Effects, Spillovers, and Jumps
Between Multiple Equilibria’, in Pierre-Richard Agenor, Marcus Miller, David
Vines and Axel Weber (eds), The Asian Financial Crisis: Causes, Contagion and
Consequence, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 265–80.
Mavor, James (1891), ‘The Scottish Railway Strike’, Economic Journal, 1, 204–19.
Mishkin, Frederic (1997), ‘Understanding Financial Crises: A Developing Country
Perspective’, in M. Bruno and B. Pleskovic (eds), Annual World Bank Conference
on Development Economics, 1996, Washington: World Bank, 29–62.
Moreno, Ramon, and Bharat Trehan (2000), ‘Common Shocks and Currency
Crises’, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper No. 05.
Murchison, C. T. (1933), ‘Requisites of Stabilization in the Cotton Textile
Industry’, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 23, 71–80.
Obstfeld, Maurice (1986), ‘Rational and Self-Fulfilling Balance-of-Payments
Crises’, American Economic Review, 76, 72–81.
Peek, Joe, and Eric Rosengren (1997), ‘The International Transmission of Financial
Shocks: The Case of Japan’, American Economic Review, 87, 495–505.
Peek, Joe, and Eric Rosengren (2000), ‘Collateral Damage: Effects of the Japanese
Bank Crisis on Real Activity in the United States’, American Economic Review, 9,
30–44.
Price, L. L. (1890), ‘The Position and Prospect of Industrial Conciliation’, Journal
of the Royal Statistical Society, 53, 420–59.
Pritsker, Matt (2001), ‘The Channels for Financial Contagion’, in S. Claessens and
K. Forbes (eds), International Financial Contagion, Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic
Publishers, 67–97.
Rigobon, Roberto (2002), ‘Contagion: How to Measure it?’, in S. Edwards and J. A.
Frankel (eds), Preventing Currency Crises in Emerging Markets, Chicago: The
University of Chicago Press, 269–334.
Schinasi, Garry J., and R.Todd Smith (2001), ‘Portfolio Diversification, Leverage,
and Financial Contagion’, in S. Claessens and K. Forbes (eds), International
Financial Contagion, Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 187–223.
Summers, Lawrence (2000), ‘International Financial Crises: Causes, Prevention,
and Cures’, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 90, 1–16.
Thornton, Henry ([1802] 1978), An Enquiry into the Effects of the Paper Credit of
Great Britain. Fairfield: Augustus Kelley.
Ulman, Lloyd (1955), ‘Marshall and Friedman on Union Strength’, Review of
Economics and Statistics, 37, 384–401.
Valde´s, Rodrigo (1997), ‘Emerging Markets Contagion: Evidence and Theory’,
Documento de Trabajo del Banco Central de Chile No.7.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003
178
Thomas Moser
Van Rijckeghem, Caroline, and Beatrice Weder (2000), ‘Spillovers Through
Banking Centers: A Panel Data Analysis’, IMF Working Paper No. 00/88.
Van Rijckeghem, Caroline, and Beatrice Weder (2001), ‘Sources of Contagion: Is It
Finance or Trade?’, Journal of International Economics, 54, 293–308.
White, Horace (1940), ‘Foreign Trading in American Stock-Exchange Securities’,
Journal of Political Economy, 48, 655–702.
Wood, Geoffrey (1999), ‘Great Crashes in History: Have they Lessons for Today?’,
Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 15, 98–109.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2003