Exploring the Nature of “Trader Intuition”
Transcription
Exploring the Nature of “Trader Intuition”
Exploring the Nature of “Trader Intuition” Antoine J Bruguier, Steven R Quartz and Peter Bossaerts∗ ABSTRACT Experimental evidence has consistently confirmed the ability of uninformed traders, even novices, to infer information from the trading process. We hypothesized that ToM was involved after contrasting brain activation in subjects watching markets with and without insiders. ToM refers to the innate human capacity to discern malicious or benevolent intent. We find that skill in predicting price changes in markets with insiders correlates with scores on two ToM tests. We document GARCH‐ like persistence in transaction price changes that may help with reading markets when there are insiders. California Institute of Technology, Pasadena, CA 91125, USA (Bruguier; Quartz; Bossaerts) and Ecole Polytechnique Fédérale Lausanne, Switzerland (Bossaerts). This work was supported by the NSF through grant SES‐0527491 to Caltech and by the Swiss Finance Institute. Comments from Ralph Adolphs, Colin Camerer, Fulvia Castelli, John Dickhaut, John Ledyard, Charles Plott, Tania Singer, the Editor, an Associate Editor and four referees, and seminar participants at BI (Oslo), EPFL, HEC (Paris), Northwestern University (Kellogg), the National University of Singapore, Okinawa Institute of Science and Technology, Rice University, the University of Zurich, University of Louvain, University of Texas‐Austin and Dallas, the 2007 Caltech‐Tamagawa Neuroscience Symposium, the 2007 Japan Neuroscience Society meetings, the 2008 meetings of the Swiss Finance Institute, the 2008 Western Finance Association meetings (especially the discussant, Heather Tookes), and the 2008 International Meetings of the Economic Science Association, are gratefully acknowledged. ∗ 1 This paper reports results from experiments meant to explore how uninformed traders manage to read information from transaction prices and order flow in financial markets with insiders. Since the seminal experiments of Charles Plott and Shyam Sunder in the early 1980s [Plott and Sunder (1988)], it has been repeatedly confirmed (and we will do so here too) that uniformed traders are quite capable of quickly inferring the signals that informed traders (insiders) have about future dividends, despite the anonymity of the trading process, despite lack of structural knowledge of the situation, and despite the absence of long histories of past occurrences of the same situation from which they could have learned the statistical regularities. It is striking that so little is understood about the ability of the uninformed to infer the signals of others. This ability constitutes the basis of the efficient markets hypothesis EMH [Fama (1991)], which states that prices fully reflect all available information. Underlying EMH is the idea that the uninformed will trade on the signals they manage to infer, and that, through the orders of the uninformed, these signals are effectively amplified in the price formation. In the extreme, prices will fully reflect all available information. Without a better understanding of how the uninformed practically manage to read information in prices, EMH remains a hypothesis without a well‐understood foundation. The feedback from trading based on inferred information to price formation has been formalized in the concept of the rational expectations equilibrium (REE) [Green (1973), Radner (1979)]. For economists, REE forms the theoretical 2 justification of EMH. But again, REE takes the ability of the uninformed to correctly read information from prices as given, rather than explaining it. As such, like EMH, REE lacks a well‐articulated foundation. The goal of the experiments that we report on here can be expressed in a more mundane way, as an attempt to better define what is meant by “trader intuition,” and to understand why some traders are better than others. Books have been written to elucidate trading intuition [Fenton‐O'Creevy, Nicholson, Soane and Willman (2005)], and correlations with specific biological markers have been discovered [testosterone level: Coates and Herbert (2008); the relative size of index and ring finger, an indication of a particular genetic polymorphism: Coates, Gurnell and Rustichini (2009)]. But attempts at formalizing the phenomenon have so far failed. In contrast, our approach was methodic. After collecting the necessary trading data from purposely controlled experimental markets with and without insiders, we ran a brain imaging experiment to explore human thinking during exposure to risk from insiders. The resulting data made us formulate a specific hypothesis about what may be at work, namely, Theory of Mind (to be defined below). Armed with this hypothesis, we designed a behavioral experiment to probe whether performance in predicting prices in markets with insiders was correlated with Theory of Mind skill (and uncorrelated with other skill, in particular, mathematical and logical reasoning). 3 Here, we report the results from the markets experiments that generated the data we used in the subsequent analysis, and of the behavioral experiments that confirmed the role of Theory of Mind in markets with insiders. The brain imaging experiment and its results are discussed in the Internet Appendix. While they constituted an important step towards a methodic analysis of trading intuition, in that, without it, our hypothesis would have amounted to pure speculation,1 the technicalities involved distract from the main purpose of this paper, which is to show that trading intuition and Theory of Mind skill are strongly related. With hindsight, it makes intuitive sense that Theory of Mind is important in markets with insiders. Let us elaborate. Theory of Mind (ToM in short) is the ability to read benevolence or malevolence in patterns in one’s surroundings. ToM thus is the capacity to read intention or goal‐directness, through, among others, mere observation of eye expression [Baron‐Cohen, Jolliffe, Mortimore and Robertson (1997)], movement of geometric objects [Heider and Simmel (1944)], the moves of an opponent in strategic play [McCabe, Houser, Ryan, Smith and Trouard (2001), Gallagher, Jack, Roepstorff and Frith (2002), Hampton, Bossaerts and O'Doherty (2008)], or actions that embarrass others (“faux‐pas”) [Stone, Baron‐Cohen and Knight (1998)]. See Gallagher and Frith (2003) for further discussion. What distinguishes markets with insiders is the presence of a winner’s curse: sales are often successful only because prices happen to be too low (relative to the information of the insiders), while purchases may occur only at inflated prices. 4 Either way, the uninformed trader is hurt. While the winner’s curse is usually associated with strategic, single‐sided auctions, it also applies to competitive, double‐sided markets, and indeed, the winners’ curse is not only implicit in the theory of REE but also very much of concern in real‐world stock markets [Biais, Bossaerts and Spatt (2009)]. From the point of view of the uninformed trader, the winner’s curse conjures up an image of potential malevolence in the trading process. Detecting this potential malevolence, then, becomes a Theory of Mind task. Whence the link. Humans are actually uniquely endowed with the capacity to recognize malevolence as well as benevolence in their environment. Theory of Mind is human (or shared only with higher nonhuman primates); it engages brain structures that have undergone recent evolutionary expansion and reorganization, such as the paracingulate cortex, the most frontal and medial part of the cortex. In our brain imaging experiment, distinct activation in this and other ToM related regions helped us narrow down hypotheses about trading intuition to ToM. The fact that markets with insiders may be exploiting a skill that (most) humans are very good at should provide a biological foundation to the plausibility of EMH. It could also explain why experiments on information aggregation in financial markets ever since Plott and Sunder (1988) have been relatively successful. The success of information aggregation experiments is in sharp contrast with, e.g., simple experiments on multi‐period asset pricing, such as the infamous bubble experiments [first studied in Smith, Suchanek and Arlington (1988)]. In theory, 5 these two types of experiments should give rise to the same type of equilibrium – the rational expectations equilibrium REE – yet experimentally equilibrium emerges robustly only in the context of information aggregation. ToM is about pattern recognition, something that recently has been confirmed formally, but so far only for play in strategic games [Hampton, Bossaerts and O'Doherty (2008)]. That is, humans detect malevolence or benevolence by online tracking of changes in their environment (rather than, say, logical deduction about the situation at hand). For markets, however, it is not even known whether there are any patterns at all in the order and trade flow that would allow one to merely identify the presence of insiders (let alone their intentions). Proof that such patterns exist is an important foundation for the proposition that ToM may underlie trading intuition. Therefore, we were curious whether we ourselves could find features that distinguished insider trading from normal trading in our own markets experiment. We discovered that GARCH‐like features [Engle (1982)] emerged when there are insiders. Specifically, autocorrelation coefficients of absolute transaction price changes in calendar time were significantly more sizeable in the presence of insiders. The analysis in this paper is limited to thinking about and prediction in markets when there are insiders. These constitute only two of the three steps towards successful investment. We leave for future research the third step, namely, conversion of analysis and prediction into successful positions, i.e., the trading itself. Indeed, superior forecasting performance does not necessarily translate into 6 superior investments. Still, if the latter is lacking, the trading can be delegated to others who are better at it. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section I describes the markets and behavioral experiments, while briefly discussing the imaging results that identified ToM as a viable hypothesis. Section II presents the results, first of the markets experiment, followed by those of the behavioral experiment. In Section III, we turn back to the markets experiment and attempt to identify whether there are patterns in the trade flow that would allow one to recognize that there are insiders, and hence, on which ToM thinking could build. Section IV finishes with concluding remarks. I. Description Of The Experiments Here, we provide descriptions of the experiments. We first ran a markets experiment, for the purpose of generating order and trade flow in a controlled setting. Next, we ran a brain imaging experiment, to discern how subjects judge the data, by localizing areas of the brain that were active during re‐play of the markets. This led us to identify ToM as a viable theory about the nature of trading intuition. With the ToM hypothesis in hand, we subsequently organized a behavioral experiment, where we tested for correlation between subjects’ ability to predict transaction prices and their generic ToM skills (we also tested for correlation with mathematics and logic skills, for comparison). 7 We will not discuss the imaging experiment in much detail, as it originally provided the foundation for our hypothesis about ToM. Still, the imaging data do also constitute confirmatory neurobiological evidence of the behavioral findings, and without them, the ToM hypothesis would have been mere speculation. But the technicalities involved in proper description of the imaging results would distract from the main point of the paper. The interested reader will find a full discussion of the imaging experiment in the Internet Appendix. A. The Markets Experiment Twenty (20) subjects (undergraduate and graduate students at Caltech) participated in the markets experiment. The following situation was replicated several times, each replication being referred to as a session. In each session, the subjects were initially endowed with notes (a risk free asset), cash, and two risky securities, all of which expired at the end of the session. The two risky securities (“stocks”) paid complementary dividends between 0 and 50¢: if the first security, called stock X, paid x cents, then the second security, called stock Z, would pay 50‐x cents. The notes always paid 50¢. Allocation of the securities and cash varied across subjects, but the total supplies of the risky securities were equal; hence, there was no aggregate risk, and, theoretically as well as based on observations in prior experiments with a similar number of subjects [Bossaerts, Plott and Zame (2007)], prices should converge to levels that equal expected payoffs; that is, risk‐neutral pricing should arise. 8 Subjects could trade their holdings for cash in an anonymous, electronic continuous open‐book exchange system called jMarkets (see http://jmarkets.ssel.caltech.edu/). Subjects were not allowed to trade security Z, however. Consequently, risk or ambiguity averse subjects who held more of X than of Z would want to sell X to obtain a diversified (or perhaps a completely balanced) position; those who held more of Z than of X would need to buy X. Because there was an equal number of shares of Z and of X, price pressures from trading X because of risk or ambiguity aversion can be expected to cancel out. After markets closed, liquidating dividends were paid, which, together with the remaining cash, were credited to an account. This account cumulated the earnings from each session, and at the end of the experiments, subjects took home the balance on their accounts, in addition to a show‐up reward of $5. All accounting was done in U.S. dollars and subjects made $55 on average, with a range stretching from $5 (minimum) to over $100 (maximum). Our trading system, jMarkets, ensured that subjects could only submit orders such that, if executed, they would not default on their obligations at the end of a session. In calculating whether a proposed order would violate this bankruptcy constraint, the system took into account the information a subject possessed. If, for instance, a subject knew for sure that the dividend on X was not going to be above 15 cents, then we allowed the subject to take an unlimited shortsale position as long as the price was above 15. 9 In total, 13 sessions were run. Each new session started with a fresh allocation of securities and cash. As such, sessions were independent replications of the same situation, with one exception, namely, the information provided to subjects about the final dividend. Indeed, in sessions to be referred to as test sessions, a number of subjects (the “insiders”) were given an estimate of the dividend in the form of a common signal within 10¢ of the actual dividend. All subjects were always informed whether there were insiders; in some sessions, only the insiders knew how many insiders there were. Notice that all insiders were given the same signal. Since there were at least two insiders, insiders at all times knew they were competing. Sessions without inside information will be referred to as control sessions. Full parametrization of the markets experiment (initial endowments, signals and outcomes, etc.) can be found in the Internet Appendix (Part 2). The reader can also consult the web pages through which the experiment was run: http://clef.caltech.edu/exp/info/. These pages include instructions and a chronology of the public messages sent to the subjects. A copy of the instruction pages is included in the Internet Appendix (Part 3). The results of the experiment are typical; the same setup has since been replicated more than twenty times, with little qualitative change in the order flow and price evolution. The reader interested in these replications is referred to Bossaerts, Frydman and Ledyard (2009). B. The Brain Imaging Experiment 10 Eighteen (18) new subjects (undergraduate and graduate students at Caltech) were shown a replay of the 13 sessions from the markets experiment (Section I.A), in random order, and while their brains were being scanned with functional magnetic resonance imaging (fMRI). It is important to realize that these subjects had not been in the markets experiment. Since the fMRI experiment was held about one year after the markets experiment, we expected little contamination (in a small community like Caltech, potential subjects may talk to each other about experiments that they participated in). The new subjects played the role of uninformed: while they were given the instructions of the markets experiment, they were not given any signals. At the beginning of a session, subjects were first told whether there were insiders (but never how many). Subjects then had to chose whether they would take a position in 10 units of stock X or of stock Z. This feature was designed to add an element of “double blind” control: the experimenter may have known that stock X would not do well in the upcoming session, but the subject could choose stock Z instead; likewise, the subject is in control of her choice, but does not know the outcome. Subsequently, the order flow and transaction history of stock X was replayed in a visually intuitive way. During replay, subjects were only asked to push a button each time they saw a trade. As such, they could not change their position (say, from a position in X to a position in the complementary security, Z). At the end of the session, the liquidating dividend of the stock they had chosen was shown, and the subject was paid accordingly. 11 The fMRI task was deliberately kept simple. In particular, we refrained from allowing the subject to change trading position during replay of the order and trade flow. We were interested in detecting, through specific patterns in brain activity, what subjects were thinking as the price of stock X, and hence, the value of their position, went up or down. In sessions without insiders, these price movements should have been considered without consequence, as the subject was only compensated based on the final dividend on the initially chosen position. When insiders were present, however, price changes of stock X would give the subject estimates of changes in the expected final value of the chosen position. We wanted subjects to think only about the implications of order flow and market prices for the final value of their position. If we had allowed our subjects to change positions during replay, they would also naturally have thought about the effect of their transactions on their cash position, and how changes in the latter would impact the value of their final position. Since we wanted to focus our experiment on inferring value estimates from order flow and market prices, we disallowed position changes during the session. Subjects paid a small penalty every time they missed a trade during replay of a session. This way, we made sure that our subjects paid attention. Still, the bulk of the total earnings came from the dividends on the positions subjects chose before a session started. In total, the typical fMRI experiment lasted about 1 1/2 hours. The fMRI experiment revealed increased activation in specific brain regions when insiders were present relative to when insiders where absent, and this 12 activation differential increased as the price moved away from the unconditional expected payoff (25 cents). Such price movements should have indicated that insiders had received a signal that the value of Stock X was substantially different from 25 cents. Brain regions that activated could immediately be recognized as those that are involved in ToM thinking [Gallagher and Frith (2003) list the regions]. The most important of these is the medial paracingulate cortex, a region in the middle of the forebrain, high above the eyes. [Figure 1 about here] Figure 1 displays a medial cross‐section of a typical human brain, from front (left hand side) to back, onto which the significant differential activation in paracingulate cortex is mapped (small squares; color changes from red to yellow correlate with increases in significance level). The localization is based on a random‐effects analysis of the fMRI signals of the 18 subjects. Details can be found in the Internet Appendix. Surprisingly (although this finding will also be corroborated in the behavioral experiment), brain regions known to be involved in formal mathematical and logical thinking were no more activated when insiders were present than when they were not. Thinking about markets when there are insiders appears to be an unequivocal ToM occupation. These brain activation patterns prompted us to formulate the hypothesis that ToM is engaged when insiders are present. However, brain areas are generally engaged in multiple activities. As such, activation does not necessarily imply use of 13 one specific ability. We thus turned to a behavioral experiment that we predicted would show the existence of significant correlation between, on the one hand, performance in predicting price changes when insiders are present, and, on the other hand, ToM skills as traditionally measured. We also wanted to verify the absence of significant correlation with other skills (specifically, mathematics and logical thinking), since the imaging experiment only revealed engagement of ToM regions. We now describe this experiment. C. The Behavioral Experiment Forty‐three (43) new subjects (undergraduate and graduate students at Caltech, Pasadena City College, and UCLA) were given a series of four tasks that were administered in random order. These subjects had participated neither in the markets experiment nor in the fMRI experiment. The four tasks were as follows. The first was a Financial Market Prediction task (“FMP Test”), in which the order and trade flow from sessions with insiders in our markets experiment was replayed at original speed and paused every 5 seconds. During half of the pauses, we asked subjects to predict whether the last trade in the next 5 seconds was going to occur at a higher, lower, or identical price as the last trade before the pause. (When no trade occurred in the 5 second interval, the price was considered to have remained the same.) For the other half of the pauses, we reminded subjects of their predictions and informed them of their success (whether their bet had been right or not). A penalty was imposed for absence of response within a short time interval. 14 Order and trade flow was replayed using an intuitive graphical display, discussed in more detail below. The second task was a ToM task based on the Heider movie (“Heider Test”), a display of geometric shapes whose movements imitated social interaction [Heider and Simmel (1944)]. As with the FMP task, we paused the movie every five seconds and asked subjects to predict whether two of the shapes would get closer or not. For the other half of the pauses, we reported the outcome (whether the shapes had moved closer) and subjects’ success or failure in predicting the outcome. We ran this ToM test in the spirit of our markets prediction test, namely, as a forecasting exercise where correct forecasts are rewarded and wrong forecasts are not. This is unlike the way the test is usually applied in psychology. Psychologists ask for a description of the situation and rely on verbal evidence of anthropomorphization to determine to which extent a subject engages in ToM during replay of the Heider movies. Our variant of the test is more direct (anthropomorphization is sufficient for ToM, but not necessary), objective (verbal accounts may be misleading), and it agrees with the standards of experimental economics (we paid for performance). The third task was a ToM task based on eye gaze [“Eye Gaze Test”; Baron‐ Cohen, Jolliffe, Mortimore and Robertson (1997)]. A number of photographs of eye gazes were shown consecutively, and the subject is asked to pick among four possibilities which best described the mental state of the person whose eyes were shown. To facilitate this task, the subject was first given a list of words that described mental states (such as “anxious,” “thoughtful,” “skeptical,” “suspicious”), 15 along with a short explanation. This ToM task provided a standard test of ToM skills. In contrast with practice in psychology, we paid for performance, rewarding the subject for correct answers. Based on our hypothesis, our conjecture was that performance in the FMP task would be correlated with scores on both the Gaze and Heider tasks. The fourth task, the Mathematics task, consisted of a number of standard mathematics and logic questions of the type frequently used in Wall Street job interviews – see Crack (2004). For instance, one question was a variation on the Monty Hall problem, a test of understanding of Bayesian inference, which has been used elsewhere in experimental finance [Kluger and Wyatt (2004); Asparouhova, Bossaerts, Eguia and Zame (2009)]. A table with the seven questions used in the Mathematics Test is available in the Internet Appendix. We added the Mathematics Test as control: we were interested in determining whether performance in the market prediction test was correlated specifically with ToM skills and not with other skills that arguably may also play a role in reading prices in markets with insiders. In the FMP (Financial Markets Prediction) task, we used an intuitive graphical replay of the order and trade flow. We put all the (limit) orders on the diagonal or counter‐diagonal, in the form of circles. Blue circles, below the midpoint, indicated offers to buy (bids), while red circles, above the midpoint, indicated offers to sell (asks). The circles were ordered by price level. The price level itself was written inside the circle. The diameter of the circles increased with the number of 16 units bid or asked at the corresponding price level. Whenever a trade occurred, the best bid (if a sale) or best ask (if a purchase) briefly (0.5s) changed color, to green, after which the circle either shrank (if units remained available after the trade) or disappeared (if all units were traded). The circles constantly re‐arranged to ensure that the best bid and ask straddled the midpoint of the screen in a symmetric way. Time remaining in the session was indicated in the unused top quadrant. [Figure 2 about here] Figure 2 provides a snapshot of the graphical display. We used this display instead of the original trading interface through which subjects traded in the markets experiment, because it revealed all the information without having to navigate the page, though it missed the functionality to submit orders. II. Results We first describe the trading data that emerged from the markets experiment, and on which the behavioral (as well as imaging) experiment was based. We subsequently discuss the results from the four performance tasks of the behavioral experiment. A. Trading Data From The Markets Experiment [Figure 3 about here] 17 Figure 3 displays the evolution of transaction prices throughout the markets experiment. The horizontal axis denotes time; the vertical axis price level (of stock X). Blue lines delineate sessions. Red vertical line segments denote final dividend level (of stock X) while green line segments denote the signal (if there were insiders). Number of insiders (I) is displayed for each period. “#K” indicates whether everyone (“All”) or only the insiders (“Ins”) knew how many insiders there were. Trading was brisk, independent of the type of session; on average, traders entered or cancelled an offer every 0.7s and one transaction took place every 3.2s. In test sessions (when insiders were present), prices tended to move towards the signal, although revelation is not perfect. Closer inspection reveals that there is a relationship between price quality (how far the final price is from the insider signal) and the proportion of informed subjects, consistent with the noisy rational expectations equilibrium REE [Grossman and Stiglitz (1976); Admati (1985)]. This relationship is explored further in Bossaerts, Frydman and Ledyard (2009). In control sessions, prices tend to remain close to the competitive equilibrium (25 cents), but occasionally deviate substantially (e.g., in session 8). These results confirm the findings from many prior studies on information aggregation in financial markets, starting with Plott and Sunder (1988). The amplification of information through the order and trade flow is not perfect, however. But the amount of revelation is still surprising, especially because subjects do not have the structural knowledge of the situation at hand to known how prices 18 relate to signals, unlike in the theory (the rational expectations equilibrium REE). For instance, they do not know that there is no aggregate risk, and hence, that in equilibrium pricing is as if the marginal investor is risk neutral. Yet they need this information to correctly infer information from prices. It is clear that our subjects are rather good at inferring information from the order and trade flow, despite their lack of formal financial training. One can therefore conjecture that the situation exploits a skill that they are good at. Theory of Mind is one skill that humans are generally good at, and our behavioral experiment was meant to verify whether indeed Theory of Mind is at work in markets with insiders. The imaging experiment suggested that subjects did think “Theory of Mind” when watching the replay of a market in which they held a stake. B. Performance Across Tasks In The Behavioral Experiment In the Financial Markets Prediction task, subjects were quite successful at forecasting the direction of price changes in the presence of insiders. Their forecasts were correct in approximately 2/3 of the cases on average. Randomly switching between forecasting an increase in price, a price decrease, and a level price, would only have produced a score of 33%; a better naive strategy, to always predict the previous outcome, would have generated a score of 56%. As such, subjects somehow managed to read enough information from the order flow to beat naive forecasting rules. 19 There was significant variation in performance across subjects. The worst subject forecasted correctly in 46% of the cases (slightly worse than the best naive strategy), and the best one forecasted correctly in 78% of the cases. We conjectured that ToM skill provided the main explanation for this discrepancy in performance. ToM skill was measured in two ways: through the score on the Heider Test and through the score on the Eye Gaze Test. These scores provide only a rough metric of how good one is at ToM tasks, so we refrain from using them as explanatory variables in a regression of Financial Markets Prediction performance. Instead, we here report correlations and their significance, because correlations allow both dependent variable (FMP task performance) and explanatory variables (Heider or Eye Gaze test score) to be observed with error, unlike projections. [Figure 4 about here] Figure 4 displays the correlation line of performance in the Financial Market Prediction task with scores on the Heider Test, while Figure 5 shows the same for the Eye Gaze Test (bottom panel). In both cases, the correlations are significant (p=0.048 and p=0.023, respectively). This confirms our hypothesis that ability to predict price changes in the presence of insiders is correlated with ToM skill. [Figure 5 about here] In contrast, as Figure 6 shows, there is no significant correlation between performance in the financial task (forecasting price changes when there are 20 insiders) and the score on the Mathematics task (which tests mathematical and logical reasoning capacity). [Figure 6 about here] Interestingly, we did not find any significant correlation either between the scores on the two ToM tests (Figure 7). It thus seems that these two tests look at different aspects of Theory of Mind, a finding that should be of interest to psychologists, who generally consider the tests to be interchangeable. In our case, the lack of (significant) correlation between the scores on the two ToM tests actually is a good thing: it indirectly confirms that general intelligence or state of attentiveness cannot explain the significant correlations between scores on the performance on the Financial Markets Prediction task and the ToM tests. [Figure 7 about here] Self‐reports after the behavioral experiment did not show any evidence of personalization (anthropomorphization) in the Financial Markets Prediction task, but we found plenty of it in the Heider ToM test. We did not observe significant gender differences for any test (although our subject pool was not gender‐balanced: only 16 out of 43 were female). The absence of significant correlation between the scores on the Financial Markets Prediction task and the Mathematics test further corroborates our hypothesis that the former is a ToM task. Indeed, performance on some ToM tasks has been found to be generally uncorrelated with capacity to perform formal 21 mathematical and logical reasoning. Specifically, through brain imaging, it has recently been found that strategic game play also constitutes a ToM task [it engages the usual ToM brain regions; McCabe, Houser, Ryan, Smith and Trouard (2001); Gallagher, Jack, Roepstorff and Frith (2002)]. Coricelli and Nagel (2009) have shown that skill in playing the beauty contest game is not correlated with the ability to do the very calculations implicit in skillful play of that game. Likewise, we find here that the ability to forecast the direction of price changes in the presence of insiders is not correlated with the capacity at formal mathematical reasoning. III. Theory of Mind in Markets with Insiders: What Patterns To Attend to? Our finding that forecasting price changes in markets with insiders and ToM skill are related may not come as a surprise. After all, both activities concern reading the mind of an intentional source or an entity behind which there are intentional sources. In one case, it is the market’s mind that is to be read; in the other case, it is another person’s (or persons’) mind that is to be deciphered. Still, formally, ToM remains a rather elusive concept. It is mostly defined only vaguely, and often in terms of specific tasks [Gallagher and Frith (2003)], or in terms of activation of particular brain regions [McCabe, Houser, Ryan, Smith and Trouard (2001), Gallagher, Jack, Roepstorff and Frith (2002)]. It is generally accepted, however, that ToM concerns pattern recognition. 22 In the context of strategic games, recent studies have successfully identified the patterns in the moves of one’s opponent on which ToM builds [Hampton, Bossaerts and O'Doherty (2008); Yoshida, Dolan and Friston (2008)]. The import of such findings is that ToM can be concretized in terms of precise mathematical quantities that characterize an opponent’s actual play. Specifically, ToM concerns “online” or “on the fly” learning of game play. This is consistent with the proposition that ToM involves pattern recognition. Therefore, in the context of strategic games, ToM contrasts with Nash reasoning, where players would simply hypothesize that opponents choose Nash equilibrium strategies and that they would stick to them. Nash reasoning can be “offline:” it works even if one never sees any move of one’s opponent. Nash reasoning is also abstract: it posits only what the opponent could rationally do and how to optimally respond. Consistent with the idea that ToM and Nash thinking have little in common, brain regions that are known to be engaged in abstract mathematics do not display significant activation during game play, and – we mentioned this before – skill in strategic play and mathematical capabilities are uncorrelated [Coricelli and Nagel (2009)]. In our financial markets with insiders, however, it is as of yet unclear which patterns subjects could be exploiting when attempting to read the mind of the market. In fact, it has not even been established whether there are any patterns that distinguish markets with and without insiders. But our finding that subjects engage in ToM to comprehend insider trading and the view that ToM concerns pattern recognition, predict that such patterns should exist. This provided the impetus to search for them in our own markets data. 23 We looked at a host of time series properties of the trade flows in the markets experiment that formed the basis of our study, such as duration between trades, or skewness in transaction price changes. In the end, it was persistence in the size of transaction price changes in calendar time that provided the only statistically significant discrimination. As such, GARCH‐like features appeared to distinguish our sessions with and without insiders. Specifically, we computed transaction price changes over intervals of 2s.2 We followed standard practice and took the last traded price in each 2s interval as the new price, and if there was no trade during an interval, we used the transaction price from the previous interval.3 [Figure 8 about here] We then computed the first five autocorrelations in the size (absolute value)4 of transaction price changes. Figure 8 (a) plots the results for two adjacent sessions, Sessions 7 and 8. As can be inferred from Figure 2, there were 14 insiders (out of 20 subjects) in Session 7, while there were none in Session 8. The patterns in the autocorrelations of the absolute price changes in the two sessions are very different. There is substantial autocorrelation at all lags for Session 7 (when there were insiders) while there is none for Session 8 (when there were no insiders). Figure 8 (b) shows that this is a general phenomenon. Plotted is the sum of the absolute values of the autocorrelation coefficients for lags 1 to 5 against the number of insiders. We refer to the former as “GARCH intensity” because it measures the extent to which there is persistence in the size of price changes. We 24 sum the absolute values because closer inspection of the data revealed that autocorrelation coefficients can be significantly negative as well as positive when there are insiders. GARCH intensity increases with the number of insiders; the slope is significant at the 5% level and the R‐squared, at 0.32, is reasonably high given the noise in the data. Consequently, it appears that GARCH‐like features in transaction price changes provided one way to recognize the presence of insiders, and hence, a foundation on which ToM thinking could build. Future research should clarify the link, which is likely to be complex. For instance, we did not find a significant correlation between GARCH intensity for a session and subjects’ performance on the financial market prediction task for the same session. Also, future research should determine whether GARCH‐like features typify markets with insiders more generally, rather than just our experimental markets. IV. Concluding Remarks We reported here how skill in forecasting price changes in markets with insiders is correlated with the general ability to detect intentionality in one’s environment, namely, Theory of Mind (ToM). This possibility was first suggested by a brain imaging experiment, whereby we contrasted activations during replay of markets with and without insiders. The emergence of activation in specific brain regions (and absence of activation in others) suggested that ToM may be at work. 25 Thus, the results from the original imaging experiment, and those from the behavioral experiment, fully corroborate each other. We did not find any (significant) correlation between performance in the financial markets prediction task and ability to solve abstract mathematical and logical problems, nor did the imaging experiment reveal any activation in the brain regions known to be engaged in solving such problems. This finding resonates well with the extant ToM literature. Skill in playing strategic games, for instance, is uncorrelated with ability to explicitly perform the calculations that such skill implies [Coricelli and Nagel (2009)]. Our findings are of interest not only to finance. In psychology, the scope of ToM has always been confined to small‐scale social interaction. Here, we demonstrate that ToM is relevant for thinking about large‐scale, anonymous social structures as well. In our case, it concerns competitive financial markets. One can envisage that it encompasses political systems as well, like voting in an election where the chance that one is pivotal is miniscule [which has left political scientists wondering why people vote at all; see, e.g., Blais (2000)]. Our finding that scores on two widely accepted ToM tests are not correlated should also be of interest to the psychology community; it suggests that ToM is not one‐dimensional. And our results demonstrate that forecasting prices in markets with insiders involves multiple aspects of ToM, as performance correlates with scores on both tests. 26 We set out to study “trading intuition,” but we should caution the reader. For reasons spelled out earlier, in the imaging experiment, we only looked at what people where thinking when replaying markets (subjects did have to take a position, but only before the replay, and could not change it during replay). Likewise, the behavioral experiment is about forecasting price changes in markets with insiders. Subjects were paid for the accuracy of their (directional) forecasts, and could not take positions. Of course, thinking about prices and forecasting them are integral to successful trading, but it leaves out the placing of orders itself. Trading intuition concerns not only assessment of what’s going on in the market and prediction of prices in the future, but also submission of the right orders. Our study only considers the first two facets; future work should shed light on the third. Our discovery that transaction prices in our sessions with insiders exhibit GARCH patterns should instill further work. One would like to know whether this is true in general. Also, we still miss identification of the precise aspects of GARCH patterns that allow uninformed market participants to read the “mind of the market” (i.e., the information of the insiders). We don’t know whether the ToM brain activation we recorded was in response to GARCH features. One could potentially get at it by running further markets experiments like the one presented here, and recording subjects’ choices, eye gaze, and brain signals. The latter would be facilitated by the knowledge decision neuroscience has gained in recent years about the nature and location of brain signals related to updates of expected reward [McClure, Berns and Montague (2003); O'Doherty, Dayan, Friston, Critchley and Dolan (2003)], and of reward risk [Preuschoff, Quartz and Bossaerts (2008)]. 27 Our findings should inspire research to improve visual representation of order and trade flow. Since humans often are best at recognizing the nature of intention in moving (animate or inanimate) objects [Heider and Simmel (1944), Castelli, Happe, Frith and Frith (2000)], we suggest that traders may be more likely to successfully detect insider trading when order and trade flows are presented in a moving display, as opposed to the purely numerical listings commonly found in the industry. Our (untrained!) subjects were successful in forecasting price change in the presence of insiders (on average, they performed significantly better than the best naïve strategy). One may wonder whether this success should be attributed to our using a purely graphical interface, where order and trade flows are translated into movement of circles of various sizes and colors. Finally, the finding that markets with insiders prompt people to use a skill (ToM) that they are generally good at, may explain the popularity of betting and prediction markets, where information asymmetries abound. Uninformed participants may feel confident that they will detect insider trading when it emerges. It may also explain why people are willing to participate in markets that require advanced problem solving skills even when they know that there are others in the marketplace that are better [Meloso, Copic and Bossaerts (2009)]. ToM by itself cannot explain, however, why people want to participate if such markets constitute zero‐sum games. Other explanations need to be invoked, such as overconfidence. 28 Figure 1. Main result from the imaging experiment. Subjects’ brain activation was contrasted during replay of markets with insiders against replay of markets without insiders. Shown is a cross‐section of the typical human brain from front (left hand side) to back (“saggital cross‐section”) along the brain midline. Voxels (cubic sections of 3mm3) are mapped where the fMRI signal increased more intensely as a function of the difference between the transaction price and the unconditional expected payoff on stock X (25 cents) when there were insiders relative to when there were none. Significance level increases with color grade, from red to yellow. The two clusters of significant voxels are in the paracingulate cortex. See Internet Appendix for precise coordinates of the voxel with highest significance level (located in the cluster inside the yellow circle). 29 Figure 2. Snapshot of the graphical replay of the order and trade flow in the Financial Markets Prediction (FMP) task. Red circles are asks; blue circles are bids; size of the circles increases with number of units available; the best ask (bid) temporarily turns green when a purchase (sale) occurs; time remaining is indicated in the top left corner (minutes:seconds:hundreds). 30 Figure 3. Evolution of transaction prices (of stock X) in the markets experiment. The thirteen sessions are delineated by the blue vertical lines; trading in a session lasted 5 minutes. Red line segments denote final liquidating dividends of stock X. Green line segments denote insider signals. Red asterisks denote trade prices. In text boxes: I denotes number of insiders; K# denotes whether All (subjects) or only insiders (Ins) knew how many insiders there were. All subjects always knew whether there were insiders, even if not all may have known how many. 31 Figure 4. Correlation between score on the Heider ToM test (horizontal axis) and performance on the Financial Markets Prediction Task (vertical axis). Number of observations: 43; Correlation Coefficient: 0.348 (p=0.022). 32 Figure 5. Correlation between score on the Eye Gaze ToM test (horizontal axis) and performance on the Financial Markets Prediction Task (vertical axis). Number of observations: 43; Correlation Coefficient: 0.303 (p=0.048). 33 Figure 6. Correlation between score on the Mathematics test (horizontal axis) and performance on the Financial Markets Prediction Task (vertical axis). Number of observations: 43; Correlation Coefficient: 0.061 (p=0.699). 34 Figure 7. Correlation between scores on the Heider ToM test (horizontal axis) and the Eye Gaze ToM test (vertical axis). Number of observations: 43; Correlation Coefficient: 0.019 (p=0.904). 35 (a) (b) Figure 8. (a) Autocorrelation coefficients (lags 1 to 5) of absolute transaction price changes over 2s intervals in the markets experiment, Sessions 7 (insiders) and 8 (no insiders). Autocorrelation is more sizeable in Session 7. Vertical line segments indicate 90% confidence intervals. (b) Sum of absolute values of first five autocorrelation coefficients of absolute price changes (“GARCH intensity”) for all sessions in the markets experiment, arranged by number of insiders; Fitted line is significant at p=0.05. 36 References Admati, Anat R., 1985, A Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium for Multi‐asset Securities Markets, Econometrica 53, 629‐657. Asparouhova, E, P Bossaerts, J Eguia, and W. Zame, 2009, Cognitive Biases, Ambiguity Aversion, And Asset Pricing In Financial Markets, Caltech working paper. Baron‐Cohen, S., T. Jolliffe, C. Mortimore, and M. Robertson, 1997, Another advanced test of theory of mind: evidence from very high functioning adults with autism or Asperger Syndrome, Journal of Child Psychology and Psychiatry 38, 813‐822. Biais, Bruno, Peter Bossaerts, and Chester S. Spatt, 2009, Equilibrium Asset Pricing Under Heterogeneous Information, Review of Financial Studies in print. Blais, Andre, 2000. To Vote Or Not To Vote: The Merits and Limits of Rational Choice Theory (University of Pittsbrugh Press, Pittsburgh). Bossaerts, P, C. Frydman, and John O. Ledyard, 2009, Speed Of Information Revelation And Eventual Price Quality In Markets With Insiders, Caltech working paper. Bossaerts, Peter, Charles Plott, and William Zame, 2007, Prices and Portfolio Choices in Financial Markets: Theory, Econometrics, Experiments, Econometrica 75, 993‐ 1038. 37 Castelli, F., F. Happe, U. Frith, and C. Frith, 2000, Movement and mind: a functional imaging study of perception and interpretation of complex intentional movement patterns, NeuroImage 12, 314‐325. Coates, J. M., and J. Herbert, 2008, Endogenous steroids and financial risk taking on a London trading floor, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 105, 6167‐ 6172. Coates, John M., Mark Gurnell, and Aldo Rustichini, 2009, Second‐to‐fourth digit ratio predicts success among high‐frequency financial traders, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 106, 623‐628. Coricelli, G., and R. Nagel, 2009, Beauty Contest in the Brain; a Neural Basis of Strategic Thinking, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences (forthcoming). Coricelli, G., and R. Nagel, 2009, Beauty Contest in the Brain; a Neural Basis of Strategic Thinking, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 23, 9163‐9168. Crack, T. F., 2004. Heard on the Street: Quantitative Questions from Wall Street Job Interviews (Timothy Crack, Dunedin, New Zealand). Engle, Robert F., 1982, Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity with Estimates of the Variance of U.K. Inflation, Econometrica 50, 987‐1008. Fama, Eugene F., 1991, Efficient Capital Markets: II, The Journal of Finance 46, 1575‐ 1617. 38 Fenton‐O'Creevy, Mark, Nigel Nicholson, Emma Soane, and Paul Willman, 2005. Traders: Risks, Decisions, and Management in Financial Markets (Oxford University Press). Gallagher, H. L., and C. D. Frith, 2003, Functional imaging of 'theory of mind', Trends in Cognitive Sciences 7, 77‐83. Gallagher, H. L., A. I. Jack, A. Roepstorff, and C. D. Frith, 2002, Imaging the intentional stance in a competitive game, NeuroImage 16, 814‐821. Gallagher, H. L., AI Jack, A Roepstorff, and CD Frith, 2002, Imaging the intentional stance in a competitive game, NeuroImage 16, 814‐821. Green, Jerry, 1973, Information, Efficiency and Equilibrium, Harvard Institute of Economic Research Discussion Paper. Grossman, Sanford J., and Joseph E. Stiglitz, 1976, Information and Competitive Price Systems, The American Economic Review 66, 246‐253. Hampton, Alan N., Peter Bossaerts, and John P. O'Doherty, 2008, Neural correlates of mentalizing‐related computations during strategic interactions in humans, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 105, 6741‐6746. Hasson, Uri, Yuval Nir, Ifat Levy, Galit Fuhrmann, and Rafael Malach, 2004, Intersubject Synchronization of Cortical Activity During Natural Vision, Science 303, 1634‐1640. 39 Heider, F., and M. Simmel, 1944, An experimental study of apparent behavior, American Journal of Psychology 57, 243‐249. Kluger, Brian D., and Steve B. Wyatt, 2004, Are Judgment Errors Reflected in Market Prices and Allocations? Experimental Evidence Based on the Monty Hall Problem, The Journal of Finance 59, 969‐997. Kuhnen, C M, and B Knutson, 2005, The neural basis of financial risk taking, Neuron 47, 763‐770. McCabe, Kevin, Daniel Houser, Lee Ryan, Vernon Smith, and Theodore Trouard, 2001, A functional imaging study of cooperation in two‐person reciprocal exchange, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 98, 11832‐11835. McClure, S. M., G. S. Berns, and P. R. Montague, 2003, Temporal prediction errors in a passive learning task activate human striatum, Neuron 38, 339‐46. Meloso, Debrah, Jernej Copic, and Peter Bossaerts, 2009, Promoting Intellectual Discovery: Patents Versus Markets, Science 323, 1335‐1339. O'Doherty, J. P., P. Dayan, K. Friston, H. Critchley, and R. J. Dolan, 2003, Temporal difference models and reward‐related learning in the human brain, Neuron 38, 329‐ 37. Plott, Charles R., and S. Sunder, 1988, Rational Expectations and the Aggregation of Diverse Information in Laboratory Security Markets, Econometrica 56, 1085‐1118. 40 Preuschoff, Kerstin, Steven R. Quartz, and Peter Bossaerts, 2008, Human Insula Activation Reflects Risk Prediction Errors As Well As Risk, J. Neurosci. 28, 2745‐ 2752. Radner, Roy, 1979, Rational Expectations Equilibrium: Generic Existence and the Information Revealed by Prices, Econometrica 47, 655‐678. Smith, Vernon, L., Gerry L. Suchanek, and W. Williams Arlington, 1988, Bubbles, Crashes, and Endogenous Expectations in Experimental Spot Asset Markets, Econometrica 56, 1119‐1151. Stone, V. E., S. Baron‐Cohen, and R. T. Knight, 1998, Frontal lobe contributions to theory of mind., Journal of Cognitive Neuroscience 10, 640‐656. Yoshida, Wako, Ray J. Dolan, and Karl J. Friston, 2008, Game Theory of Mind, PLoS Comput Biol 4, e1000254. Zhuanxin, Ding, W. J. Granger Clive, and F. Engle Robert, 2001, A long memory property of stock market returns and a new model, in Essays in econometrics: collected papers of Clive W. J. Granger (Harvard University Press). 41 1 Our study was set up as an open‐ended reverse correlation exercise; see Hasson, Uri, Yuval Nir, Ifat Levy, Galit Fuhrmann, and Rafael Malach, 2004, Intersubject Synchronization of Cortical Activity During Natural Vision, Science 303, 1634‐1640. By examining brain activation during particular episodes of market replay, and armed with knowledge of functionality of brain regions in tasks involving financial risks, one can potentially identify what subjects were thinking. We were initially looking at signals in the striatal regions of the brain as well as the anterior insula, because of known correlations with changes in assessment of expected reward and risk, respectively. See, e.g., Kuhnen, C M, and B Knutson, 2005, The neural basis of financial risk taking, Neuron 47, 763‐770. Activation in ToM regions came as a surprise, as these rarely activate in financial tasks, unless they involve a significant strategic component. See Hampton, Alan N., Peter Bossaerts, and John P. O'Doherty, 2008, Neural correlates of mentalizing‐related computations during strategic interactions in humans, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 105, 6741‐ 6746. 2 A trade occurred every 3.7s on average, so calendar time tick size was chosen to be slightly shorter than average duration between trades. 3 Note that we compute autocorrelations in calendar time. Autocorrelations are affected by stale prices, because when no trade occurs, the transaction price is set equal to the last traded price. As such, autocorrelations of absolute price changes indirectly capture persistence in duration between trades as well. Still, we found no significant correlation between autocorrelation in duration between trades, on the one hand, and numbers of insiders, on the other hand. 4 We focused on autocorrelations of absolute values of price changes because, in field markets, persistence is known to be higher for absolute values instead of the more widely investigated squared price changes. See Zhuanxin, Ding, W. J. Granger Clive, and F. Engle Robert, 2001, A long memory property of stock market returns and a new model, in Essays in econometrics: collected papers of Clive W. J. Granger (Harvard University Press). 42 Internet Appendix for ‘Exploring the Nature of “Trader Intuition”’∗ The Internet Appendix consists of six parts. In the first part, we elaborate on the brain imaging experiment. The second part discusses the parametrization of the markets experiment. The third, fourth and fifth parts cover the instructions for the markets, imaging and behavioral experiments, respectively. The sixth part lists the questions on the mathematics section of the behavioral experiment, along with the correct answers. The markets and brain imaging experiments were run at Caltech and were approved by Caltech’s ethics committee. The behavioral experiments were run at Caltech and UCLA and were approved by the ethics committees of both institutions. Antoine J. Bruguier, Steven R. Quartz and Peter Bossaerts, 2009, Internet Appendix to “Exploring the Nature of “Trader Intuition,”” Journal of Finance [vol #], [pages], http://www.afajof.org/IA/[year].asp. Please note: Wiley‐Blackwell is not responsible for the content or functionality of any supporting information supplied by the authors. Any queries (other than missing material) should be directed to the authors of the article. ∗ 1 Part 1. Brain Imaging Experiment Experimental Design We replayed the order and trade flow to 18 subjects while we recorded their brain activity. The subjects had not been in either the markets experiment or behavioral experiment. First, we explained to the subjects how we had acquired the order and trade flow. We familiarized them with the markets experiment, showing the instructions that the subjects in that experiment were given, and how they would have traded. Second, we gave them instructions for the imaging experiment and asked them to sign a consent form. (The instructions are in Part 3 of this Internet Appendix.) We made sure that they understood the experiment by administering a quiz. We reminded subjects that they would not be able to trade in the market after taking an initial position, and hence, that they would only act as observer of the replay of a previously recorded market. We also instructed them that the term “insider” did not refer to illegal “insider trading,” but only to the fact that insiders had superior information. We replayed the thirteen sessions of the original markets experiment in a different random order for each subject. Each session began with a “blind bet:” we asked subjects to choose between Stock X or Stock Z, after we informed them whether there were insiders. Subjects automatically took a position in 10 units of their chosen stock. Because of the perfect complementarity between payoffs on X and Z, taking a 2 position in 10 units of Z is equivalent to holding 10 notes and a short position in 10 units of X. After the subjects had made a choice, we replayed the order and trade flow for stock X, regardless of their choice, at double the speed (2 minutes and 30 seconds instead of 5 minutes). Finally, we displayed the dividend on the stock that they had chosen before the replay. The various steps for a single session are shown in Figure IA1. 3 Figure IA1. Timeline of fMRI experiment and sample screenshots. (i) At the start of each session, subjects were shown a screen that informed them of whether or not the session contained insiders and instructed them to make a choice (a blind bet) between stock X or the (complementary) stock Z. They were then endowed with 10 units of the stock they chose. (ii) A blank screen was subsequently presented for 10 seconds, (iii) a market session was then replayed at double speed (the screenshot shown is illustrative; red circles indicated asks; blue circles indicated bids; orders turned green for 0.5 seconds to indicate a trade; bids and asks were arranged along the diagonal or counter‐diagonal in increasing order of price; price level was displayed inside the circle (not shown); size of circles correlated with number of units available at the corresponding price), (iv) after the session, a blank screen was shown again for 10 seconds, after which (v) subjects were informed of the dividend paid to the stock they had chosen. This was repeated 13 times (for the 13 sessions in the markets experiment). ITI=”inter session interval.” We replayed the order and trade flow (section (iii) of Figure IA1) with an intuitive interface (Video IA1). This video‐game‐like representation was necessary for 4 fMRI analysis. Indeed, the more complex the representation is, the higher the number of unwanted signal processes in the brain. The representation contains all the information actual traders in the markets experiment had, but does not have trading functionality. Available at: http://www.bruguier.com/pub/stockvideo.html Video IA1. Display of the trading activity. Each circle represents an offer to buy (bid, blue circle) or to sell (ask, red circle) at a certain price indicated by the number inside the circle. The diameter of the circle indicates the number of units of the stock offered. This number is the aggregate of all the offers at this price. We ordered the circles by increasing value, along one diagonal, chosen at random. The circles move, grow, and shrink with the incoming orders. Every time a trade occurs, the corresponding circle (bid or ask quote that is involved in the transaction) turns green for 500ms, shrinks by the number of stocks traded, and then returns to its original color (unless no more stocks remain to be traded, in which case it disappears). Specifically, we represented the price levels for the offers to buy and sell (“bids” and “asks”) with a circle. The number inside a circle indicated the price in cents and the 5 diameter of the circle represented the number of units offered. Blue circles represented bids, and red circles represented asks. For example, if at a given time there was a single bid at 25¢, three asks at 27¢, and one ask at 28¢, the subject would see three circles: a small blue circle with the number 25 inside, a larger red circle with the number 27 inside, and a small red circle with the number 28 inside. A example is in figure IA1 (iii). When a trade occurred at a certain price, the corresponding circle turned green for 500ms, after which the circle’s diameter shrank, reflecting the lower number of bids or asks available after trade. In case no more units remained available, the circle would disappear. The circles are aligned roughly along one diagonal of the screen, by increasing price. The middle of the book remained at the center of the screen. As the trading advanced in time, the circles grew, shrank, appeared, and disappeared, reflecting the changes in outstanding asks and bids. We rearranged the circles dynamically to reflect the changes in price levels of the offers and trades. See Video IA1 for examples. The locomotion between sessions with and without insiders did not display any obvious differences. In order to monitor attention, we asked subjects to press a key every time a trade occurred. Subjects paid a small penalty for missed trades ($0.05). Discussion of the Design Our design was chosen purposely. First, the subjects did not trade during the replay (they did have to take positions before the replay). While the question of how the human brain executes financial decisions is interesting, we needed first to understand how humans perceived or judged a stock market with insiders. By not introducing 6 decision‐making, we avoided a confounding factor. Second, the periods without insiders were controls. Since the data acquisition method, the display screens, and the number of traders were the same, the two types of sessions were identical in every respect except for the presence or absence of insiders. Third, by adding a blind bet, we elicited a feeling of “randomness.” Indeed, if we had forced subjects to choose stock X for every session, the payoff would have been the same fixed number for every subject. Moreover, we could not have separated an increase in stock price from a higher expected reward, as these two signals would have been perfectly correlated. Instead, by introducing a blind bet, we orthogonalized changes in subjects’ expected rewards and stock prices. Brain Imaging Analysis During the experiment, subjects were scanned using functional Magnetic Resonance Imaging (fMRI). This technique allows one to locate temporary changes in distribution of oxygenated blood throughout the brain. Concentration of oxygenated blood increases where neurons are active. It is generally understood that this activity reflects signaling from upstream neurons [Goense and Logothetis (2008)]. The fMRI signal is generally referred to as the BOLD signal, short for Blood Oxygen Level Dependent signal. To identify areas of significant brain activation in the insider sessions relative to the control sessions, we used a standard approach as implemented in the package BrainVoyager. We fit a time series General Linear Model (GLM) to the (filtered, motion‐ corrected) BOLD signal for each “voxel” (a cubic volume element of 27mm3) with, aside 7 from auxiliary predictors (regressors that capture activation due to motion and visual effects), the following predictors (see Figure IA2 for sample time series plots of the predictors/regressors and the variables used to construct them): • The expected reward, computed as follows: o When there were insiders, the expected reward was proxied by the transaction price (if the subject chooses to bet on X) or 0.50 minus the transaction price (if subject bet on Z). o When there were no insiders, the expected reward was set equal to a constant (0.25). This construction reflected the following reasoning. During sessions with insiders, a higher price for stock X indicates that the dividend was likely to be higher, resulting in a higher expected reward in the case of a blind bet on stock X and a lower expected reward on stock Z. When there were no insiders, the price does not carry any information, so we kept the expected reward at 0.25 irrespective of the price. • Two parametric regressors, based on the absolute deviation of the stock’s trading price and 25¢. One tracked this deviation in sessions with insiders, and the other one in sessions without insiders. When there are insiders, this regressor should quantify the effect of the insiders on the stock price. The separate parametric regressor for sessions without insiders is used as control, against which brain activation during the sessions with insiders could be compared. 8 • Two block regressors (dummy variables in the language of econometrics), to identify sessions with and without insiders – to capture activation not modulated by the transaction price. 9 Figure IA2. Construction of predictors in the GLM used in the analysis of brain activation data. Shown are five fictive periods of different combinations of presence/absence of insiders and whether the subject chose stock X or Z. On top, the evolution of the stock price of X is displayed; this price was used to construct parametric predictors. The first parametric predictor was the expected reward (ER); it was computed from the stock price, the presence/absence of insiders, and the blind bet (see main text for detail). As a proxy of insider activity, we used the absolute value of the difference between the trading price (top ) and 25¢ (|price‐25|). From this proxy, two parametric predictors were constructed. First, a parametric predictor (ParamIns) modeled the effect of insider activity during session with insiders. Second, an analogous predictor (Paramno Ins) was constructed for sessions without insiders. In addition, we added the following block predictors (dummy variables): a block predictor capturing mean brain activation during sessions with insiders (BlockIns), and a block predictor capturing mean brain activation during sessions without insiders (Blockno Ins). 10 The effect of neuronal activation on blood oxygen level is both delayed and spread over time. Thus a sharp, on/off neuronal signal related to, e.g., a change in the expected reward, will not result in a sharp, on/off response in the BOLD signal. Instead, we expect to see a smooth ramping up and down. The effect is referred to as the “hemodynamic response,” and the function known to describe this response is a gamma function. The impact of a sequence of changes in a regressor is additive. Because of this, all regressors only needed to be convolved with this hemodynamic response function. Effectively, we transformed the original time series of a predictor xi to a new time series y, as follows: where h is the hemodynamic response function and t denotes time. We then fit the transformed regressors to the BOLD signal using least squares: We used Generalized Least Squares, because the error process e is (first‐order) autocorrelated. The GLS is repeated for all other subjects, providing a cross‐section of estimated slope coefficients bi, referred to as betas, and more importantly, their differences (difference between a beta for the insider sessions and the corresponding beta for the control sessions). The t statistic and associated p value are then computed using 11 standard analysis of random effects models (thus assuming that subject‐specific betas reflect both a population effect and an individual effect). We repeat this procedure for every voxel in the brain. For each difference in betas, this gives us a geometric map of t statistics. We eliminate of voxels where the t statistic does not reach a cut‐off p value (here: p<0.001) or for which neighboring voxels (here: at least 4) do not reach this cut‐off p level. The result is a map like the one displayed in Figure 1 in the main text of the paper. Results We found a significant contrast in the betas for the parametric regressors in one large region of paracingulate cortex (PCC; Figure 1 in the main text of the paper and re‐ produced here as Figure IA3 (a), and Table IAI). The contrast reveals that activation in PCC is more sensitive to deviations of prices from 0.25 during sessions with insiders than during sessions without insiders. We also found significant differences in the betas across insider sessions and sessions without insiders in a smaller region in the frontal part of the anterior cingulate cortex (Figure 1 in the main text of the paper and re‐ produced here as Figure IA3 (a), and Table IAI). Finally, we found strong differential sensitivity to deviations of prices from 0.25 in right amygdala (Figure IA3 (b) and Table IAI) and left insula (Figure IA3 (c) and Table IAI). 12 Figure IA3. Location of significant contrasts of slope coefficients (“betas”) of the parametric regressors between insider and no‐insider sessions (p<0.001, random effects, minimum cluster size=5 voxels): (a) Sagittal view of the activation in paracingulate cortex (Talairach coordinates ‐9; 41; 36; Brodmann areas 9/32; extends for 22 voxels). (b) Amygdala activation in coronal view (‐14; 23; 39; extends for 5 voxels). (c) Activation of the left insula in axial view (‐30; ‐7; 11; extends for 5 voxels). 13 X Y z cluster size t17 Area ‐30 ‐7 11 5 4.476 left insula ‐14 23 39 5 4.688 frontal part of the anterior cingulate cortex ‐9 41 36 22 5.380 paracingulate cortex ‐9 32 45 6 4.290 frontal part of anterior cingulate cortex 17 36 43 6 6.322 frontal part of the anterior cingulate cortex 21 ‐10 ‐12 5 5.160 right amygdale Table IAI. Areas with significant difference in slope coefficients (“betas”) to parametric regressors (insiders vs. no‐insider). Standard coordinates (Talairach x,y,z) are used. We report regions with 5 or more voxels of 27mm3 each activated at p<0.001 for a random effect GLM. The parametric regressor is the absolute difference between the last traded price and the 25¢. The cluster size is specified in number of contiguous voxels. t17 indicates t statistic for the difference in betas (17 degrees of freedom). 14 Figure IA4. Location of significant contrast of slope coefficients (“betas”) of the block regressors between insider and no‐insider sessions. Threshold: p<0.001 (minimum cluster size=5 voxels; random effect). There are two clusters of activated voxels, one in the lingual gyrus and the other in cerebellum. Significant contrasts for the block predictors showed up in a large area of lingual gyrus (Figure IA4 and Table IAII), as well as a small area of cerebellum (Figure IA4 and Table IAII). No other areas with five or more voxels exhibited significant contrasts (at p=0.001). x Y z cluster size t17 Area ‐13 ‐58 ‐30 9 4.485 Cerebellum ‐9 ‐65 ‐6 25 4.440 lingual gyrus Table IAII. Areas with significant difference in slope coefficients (“betas”) for block regressors (insiders vs. no‐insider). Standard coordinates (Talairach x,y,z) are used. Random effects, thresholded at p<0.001 and with minimum cluster size=5. t17 indicates t statistic for difference in betas (17 degrees of freedom). These results suggested that Theory of Mind (ToM) is involved when subjects are facing markets with insiders. Indeed, the activated brain regions belong to the brain circuitry that is known to be engaged in traditional ToM tasks. • PCC (paracingulate cortex) activation is standard in tasks involving ToM [Gallagher and Frith (2003)], and in strategic games in particular [Gallagher, Jack, Roepstorff and Frith (2002), McCabe, Houser, Ryan, Smith and Trouard (2001), Bhatt and Camerer (2005)]. The PCC has also been observed in tasks that involved attribution of mental states to dynamic visual images, such as 15 intentionally moving shapes [Castelli, Happe, Frith and Frith (2000)], and hence, not unlike the circles in our display that represent offers. • We found that activation in the right amygdala and the left anterior insula increased as transaction prices deviated from the uninformed payoff. While a number of studies have reported the involvement of these structures in ToM tasks [Baron‐Cohen, Ring, Wheelwright and Bullmore (1999), Critchley, Mathias and Dolan (2001), King‐Casas, Sharp, Lomax‐Bream, Lohrenz, Fonagy and Montague (2008)], they are more typically regarded as involved in affective features of social interaction. Specifically, the amygdala is a critical structure in the recognition of facial emotional expressions of others [Phillips, Young, Scott, Calder, Andrew, Giampietro, Williams, Bullmore, Brammer and Gray (1999), Phan, Wager, Taylor and Liberzon (2002), Morris, Ohman and Dolan (1998)] while the anterior insula is thought to play a critical role both in subjective emotional experience [Bechara and Damasio (2005)] and in the perception/empathetic response to the emotional state of others [Singer, Seymour, O'Doherty, Kaube, Dolan and Frith (2004)]. A complementary interpretation of insula activation is that it may reflect subjects’ own emotional responses to the winner’s curse in markets with insiders, which would square our finding with activation of insula when trust is broken during play of the trust game [King‐Casas, Sharp, Lomax‐Bream, Lohrenz, Fonagy and Montague (2008)]. Another possible interpretation is that subjects perceive more risk when there are insiders. This would be consistent both with a recent report that insula is involved in financial risk learning [Preuschoff, Quartz and Bossaerts 16 (2008)] and with psycho‐physiological evidence that financial market participation engages somatic marker (emotional) circuitry during heightened market volatility [Lo and Repin (2002)]. Future research should shed more light on potential links between market participation, emotions and risk assessment. • We also found activations in the frontal part of the ACC (anterior cingulate cortex). Our activation is in a slightly more posterior and dorsal location than when ToM is used in strategic and non‐anonymous, simple two‐person games [Gallagher, Jack, Roepstorff and Frith (2002), McCabe, Houser, Ryan, Smith and Trouard (2001)]. • The increased activation of lingual gyrus in the presence of insiders provides further support for the role of ToM in market perception. For example, the lingual gyrus is involved in perception of biological motion, a key cue for mentalizing [Servos, Osu, Santi and Kawato (2002)]. However, increased activation of lingual gyrus may also be related to accounts that this structure activates in complex visual tasks where subjects are asked to extract global meaning despite local distractors [Fink, Halligan, Marshall, Frith, Frackowiak and Dolan (1996), Fink, Halligan, Marshall, Frith, Frackowiak and Dolan (1997)]. When there are no insiders, subjects can concentrate on the task we imposed, namely, to track trades. In our display, transactions were a local feature, indicated by changes in color of circles in the middle of the screen. In contrast, when there were insiders, the entire list of orders may have reflected information with which to re‐evaluate the likely payoff on the securities, but at the same time subjects are still asked to report all transactions, which then 17 amounted to a local distraction. Future research should determine to what extent lingual gyrus activation reflects ToM (through motion of objects) or the proverbial conflict between the “forest” (insider information) and the “trees” (trades). We did not observe significant differences in betas (at p=0.001 and with requiring clusters of at least 5 significant adjacent voxels) between sessions with and without insiders in any other brain areas. Curiously, no differential activation emerged for brain regions known to engage in formal mathematical reasoning. In particular, there was no evidence of estimation of probabilities [Parsons and Osherson (2001)] or arithmetic computation [Dehaene, Spelke, Pinel, Stanescu and Tsivkin (1999)]. We also did not observe any significant activation in brain areas related more generally to logical problem‐solving or analytical thought [Newman, Carpenter, Varma and Just (2003)] or reasoning [Acuna, Eliassen, Donoghue and Sanes (2002)]. This finding has also been highlighted in a recent study of ToM in strategic games [Coricelli and Nagel (2009)]. 18 Part 2. Parameters For The Markets Experiment Type Stock X Stock Z Notes Cash 1 0 7 0 $1.75 2 10 3 0 $0.75 Table IAIII. Subjects in the Markets Experiment were of one of two types, differentiated by initial allocations. Shown are initial holdings of X, Z, Notes and Cash. 19 How Many Who Knows How Session Length Insiders? Insiders? Many Insiders? Signal Outcome (x) 1 5' Yes 6 Everyone 0.25 0.21 2 5' Yes 2 Insiders Only 0.39 0.43 3 5' Yes 2 Everyone 0.27 0.26 4 5' No 0 N/A N/A 0.10 5 5' Yes 10 Insiders Only 0.38 0.34 6 5' Yes 2 Nobody 0.39 0.42 7 5' Yes 16 Everyone 0.09 0.01 8 5' No 0 N/A N/A 0.34 9 5' Yes 6 Insiders Only 0.21 0.19 10 5' Yes 10 Everyone 0.42 0.42 11 5' Yes 6 Nobody 0.33 0.25 12 5' Yes 14 Insiders Only 0.43 0.36 13 5' Yes 10 Nobody 0.24 0.21 Table IAIV. Insiders, signals and outcomes across the 13 sessions. 20 Part 3. Instruction Set For The Markets Experiment (See also http://clef.caltech.edu/exp/info/instructions.html) Instructions 1. Situation The experiment consists of a number of replications of the same situation, referred to as periods. At the beginning of each period, you will be given securities and cash. Markets will open and you will be free to trade some of your securities. You buy securities with cash and you get cash if you sell securities. At the end of the period, the securities expire, after paying dividends that will be specified below. Your period earnings has two components: the dividends on the securities you are holding after markets close, plus your cash balance. Period earnings are cumulative across periods. At the end of the experiment, the cumulative earnings are yours to keep, in addition to a standard sign-up reward. During the experiment, accounting is done in real dollars. 2. The Securities You will be given two types of securities, stocks and bonds. Bonds pay a fixed dividend at the end of a period, 21 namely, $0.50. Stocks pay a random dividend. There are two types of stocks, referred to as X and Z. Their payoffs depend on the drawing of a variable x, which is a number between 0 and 0.50. The payoffs on stocks X and Z are complementary: Stock X pays $x, and stock Z pays $0.50-x, as displayed in the following table. Stock X Stock Z Bond Dividend $x $0.50‐x $0.50 You will be able to trade Stock X as well as the Bond, but not Stock Z. You won't be able to buy Stock X or bonds unless you have the cash. You will be able to sell Stock X and the Bond (and get cash) even if you do not own any. This is called short selling. If you sell, say, one Stock X, then you get to keep the sales price, but $x will be subtracted from your period earnings after the market closes. If at the end of a period you are holding, say, -1 Bond, $0.50 will be subtracted from your period earnings. The trading system checks your orders against bankruptcy: you may not be able to submit orders which, if executed, could generate negative period earnings. 3. Inside information For each period, x is drawn randomly from the numbers {0.01, 0.02, 0.03, ...., 0.49, 0.50}. Outcomes in previous periods have no effect on the drawing. The draw is not disclosed to anybody until the end of the period. 22 Some participants, however, may get inside information about x before the start of trading. This will take the following form. A signal S is drawn from the numbers {x-0.10, x-0.09, x-0.08, ..., x+0.09, x+0.10}. E.g., if x is 0.30, then S is drawn from {0.20, 0.21, 0.22, ..., 0.39, 0.40}. You can use S to infer what x could be: if S is 0.05, then x could be anywhere from 0.01 to 0.15. This signal S is then revealed to some participants. The same signal is revealed to all insiders. The number and identities of participants who receive inside information vary across periods. Sometimes nobody receives inside information. In certain periods when inside information is distributed, only insiders know the number of insiders while in others nobody is told this number. This is made clear in the News page. 23 Part 4. Instruction Set For The fMRI Experiment Instructions Market Replay Experiment Setup In this experiment we replay several episodes, “periods,” of a real securities market. You will see the history of the order flow (buys; sells) and the trades precisely as they happened. Your actions will obviously not have any effect on the history. However, you incur the same risk as some players did in the market – without the ability to trade. There were two types of securities in the market, stocks and bonds. Bonds paid a fixed dividend at the end of a period, namely, $0.50. Stocks paid a random dividend. There were two types of stocks, referred to as X and Z. Their payoffs depended on the drawing of a variable x, which is a number between 0 and 0.50. The payoffs on stocks X and Z were complementary: Stock X paid $x, while stock Z paid $0.50‐x. You will be exposed to the risk of either stock X or stock Z. Before the experiment starts, you choose which stock you want to be exposed to. You only see a 24 i pn . A cT ThxcAi . A cT t i I c Ai xcA I w s r h . Ao TAAx cA apAx cA cT i hxI A cA I m c hnx A cT t i I cx i pi Ash hr cT hr xci o chAr xT cx Ai cT t i I c pn . i xm T . Ir f mT . nxA pi Ash cc T xT cxm T x f i cT apn hr . Ao a cn. f T c cT pn . i x c hnx Ar TAf cT p . A x Ar cT x oi hch x i c i t hr m e i pn . cT ThxcAi . A cT A i x r cT ci nAf m r i T o o n i pi x r cx n x i x nn Ai hr xh xc r x Ai r Ai r ot i A or hcx A i cT c A cT o m oi i r c xc r hr 1 Ai i xm Ai a t pn wcT i cA o. xm c. ph nx i no c R2m 9Em T xh, ox cT xh, A cT n f hcT pi h R2m 9EwcT i i cf h R2m 90 cT r c R2m 9Em 9N i m no no o A cT o o r hx i pi A o nx i o. Ai n f hcT cT r ot o ix i v9Ey n Ai i xpAr x cA cT n f hcT pi h R2m 90 hx cf h x t r . xc r hr 1 A i x UcA o. L c Only offers for the five best price levels are shown. There might be more offers at inferior prices. Orders with higher price levels are always above those with lower price levels. The bubbles shrink or may even disappear when market players cancel orders. They also shrink or disappear after an order is taken, in which case there is a trade. If that happens, the bubble will first turn green for one second before shrinking or disappearing. Your Task Besides watching the orders and trades, you are to perform a simple task. Each time you see a trade, you immediately press a button. You will be penalized if you fail to do so or if you do so incorrectly. Button presses obviously have no impact on the history of the market; nor do they influence the risk of the security you are exposed to. How You Make (Or Lose) Money The amount of money you receive depends on the payoff on the security that you choose to be exposed to. Orders and transaction prices in the replay of the market do not determine your earnings, although they may be a good indicator of the likely payoff. 26 Indeed, sometimes inside information about the payoff was available. The number and identities of players who received inside information varied across periods. Sometimes nobody received inside information; in other periods, inside information was available, but only insiders knew how many players had received the information; while in the remaining periods, everyone was told how many insiders there were. This will be made clear in the first screen you see before a market is replayed. The attached instructions sheets for the market players provide details of the nature of the inside information. 27 Attachment: Instructions For Market Players (http://clef.caltech.edu/exp/info/instructions.html) Instructions 1. Situation The experiment consists of a number of replications of the same situation, referred to as periods. At the beginning of each period, you will be given securities and cash. Markets will open and you will be free to trade some of your securities. You buy securities with cash and you get cash if you sell securities. At the end of the period, the securities expire, after paying dividends that will be specified below. Your period earnings has two components: the dividends on the securities you are holding after markets close, plus your cash balance. Period earnings are cumulative across periods. At the end of the experiment, the cumulative earnings are yours to keep, in addition to a standard sign-up reward. During the experiment, accounting is done in real dollars. 2. The Securities You will be given two types of securities, stocks and bonds. Bonds pay a fixed dividend at the end of a period, 28 namely, $0.50. Stocks pay a random dividend. There are two types of stocks, referred to as X and Z. Their payoffs depend on the drawing of a variable x, which is a number between 0 and 0.50. The payoffs on stocks X and Z are complementary: Stock X pays $x, and stock Z pays $0.50-x, as displayed in the following table. Stock X Stock Z Bond Dividend $x $0.50‐x $0.50 You will be able to trade Stock X as well as the Bond, but not Stock Z. You won't be able to buy Stock X or bonds unless you have the cash. You will be able to sell Stock X and the Bond (and get cash) even if you do not own any. This is called short selling. If you sell, say, one Stock X, then you get to keep the sales price, but $x will be subtracted from your period earnings after the market closes. If at the end of a period you are holding, say, -1 Bond, $0.50 will be subtracted from your period earnings. The trading system checks your orders against bankruptcy: you may not be able to submit orders which, if executed, could generate negative period earnings. 3. Inside information For each period, x is drawn randomly from the numbers {0.01, 0.02, 0.03, ...., 0.49, 0.50}. Outcomes in previous periods have no effect on the drawing. The draw is not disclosed to anybody until the end of the period. 29 Some participants, however, may get inside information about x before the start of trading. This will take the following form. A signal S is drawn from the numbers {x-0.10, x-0.09, x-0.08, ..., x+0.09, x+0.10}. E.g., if x is 0.30, then S is drawn from {0.20, 0.21, 0.22, ..., 0.39, 0.40}. You can use S to infer what x could be: if S is 0.05, then x could be anywhere from 0.01 to 0.15. This signal S is then revealed to some participants. The same signal is revealed to all insiders. The number and identities of participants who receive inside information vary across periods. Sometimes nobody receives inside information. In certain periods when inside information is distributed, only insiders know the number of insiders while in others nobody is told this number. This is made clear in the News page. 30 Part 5. Instruction Set For Behavioral Experiment In this experiment, you are given four (4) problem‐solving tasks. Your earnings depend on how well you do on each of them. The tasks cover a broad range of skills, so if you feel that one task is hard, another one may be easy for you. The four tasks are: 1. Moving Objects Task: you are asked to predict movements of geometric shapes 2. Stock Market Task: you are asked to predict stock price movements 3. Faces Task: you are asked to describe the intentions, beliefs or emotions reflected in a person’s gaze 4. Riddles Task: you are asked to solve a number of logic problems You will be invited to perform these tasks in random order. 31 ri a .1 1 x x Ao f hnnf c T cf A t Ash x A cTi 1 At ci h A e cxb hi n w r cf A xdo i x Ai cf A ci h r 1n xwAr xt nn r cT AcT i Ar n i 1 m T A e cx t As hr xh r Aoc A r cT Aam wf hcT hi n r cf A ci h r 1n xw. Ao i t As t r c A cT n i 1 ci h r 1n m T t Ash f hnn f hnn i Aor whr cAw xcApp xI cA pi c i 02xw c f Th T pAhr c . Ao 1hs r Nx cA TAAx f T cT i whr 02xwcT n i 1 ci h r 1n hx 1Ahr 1 cA “9 h c cT Ai farther away from the small triangle than at present. You indicate your choice with the arrow keys: push the “up” key if you think the large triangle is going to be farther away; push the “down” key if you think it will be closer; push the “right” key if you think the large triangle will remain at the same distance. In the second movie, with a circle and two squares, you are asked to predict the movement of the large square. The movie will be stopped every 10s, at which point you will be given 5s to choose whether, in 10s, the large square is going to be closer to or farther away from the small square. You indicate your choice with the arrow keys, just like for the first movie. After your choice, we play the movie for another 10s, stop the movie again, and a message will be displayed to indicate whether you won (if your prediction was right), or whether you pay a penalty because you failed to make a decision within the allotted time. We then re‐start the movie for 10s, after which you are again asked to predict the movement of the large triangle (first movie) or large square (second movie), etc. We will continue these cycles until the end of the movie. 33 You win $1 for every correct prediction. You pay a penalty of $0.25 for any failure to decide. 34 Stock Market Task In this test, you are asked to predict price changes in a market where students traded a stock for real money. Explanation Of The Stock Market About one year ago, we collected trading data in a financial markets experiment that was set up as follows. In a large computer room, 20 students were given cash, as well as a certain number of a security called stock. They could trade this stock over an anonymous electronic market. When market closed, the stock expired, after paying a dividend. This dividend was anywhere between ¢0 and ¢50. The traders were not told the exact size of the dividend before markets closed. Traders’ earnings depended on the cash they were holding at the end of trading, as well as the number of stock and the stock’s dividend. For example, if, after markets close, trader Alice owned $2 in cash and 10 units of the stock, and if the dividend was ¢45, Alice was paid $2 + 10 x $0.45 = $6.50. Note that the prices at which Alice could have traded the stock do not directly influence Alice’s earnings; it would, of course, have 35 affected her cash holdings (if she bought one unit of the stock at ¢35, then ¢35 would have been subtracted from her cash holdings). We repeated this situation several times. Every repetition is referred to as a period. Periods were independent in that the dividend in one period had no influence on the dividend in another period. Please note that we actually paid them: the experiment was not a “pretend.” Students left the trading room with actual money in their hands. In principle, the stock is worth about ¢25, since it paid a dividend chosen at random between ¢0 and ¢50. But we did something to make the market more interesting. We separated the traders in two groups: insiders and outsiders. The insiders were given an estimate of the dividend. This estimate was within ¢10 of the true dividend. The outsiders did not get this estimate. 36 The insiders bias the market. For example, if trader Bob is an insider and has an estimate of the dividend of ¢40, he knows that the true dividend of the stock is between ¢30 and ¢50. If he sees an offer to sell the stock at ¢25, he would want to accept the offer. He would make a profit of at least ¢5 and up to ¢25 per unit bought. But because Bob buys the stock, its price tends to increase, which is what we mean when we state that insiders bias the market. Both insiders and outsiders must act with care. Insiders must trade discreetly in order to avoid revealing their knowledge of the estimate to outsiders. Similarly, outsiders need to observe the trades carefully in order not to buy at too high a price or sell at too low a price. Your Task We will replay four periods exactly as they happened. Every so often, you will be asked to predict the price at which the stock will trade 10s later. Replay Interface 37 We will use an intuitive graphical display of the orders and trades in the electronic market. To understand this display, you should know how trade took place. At any time, traders could submit offers to sell or to buy a certain number of stock at a certain price. For example, trader Alice may offer to sell 3 units at ¢37 and trader Bob may offer to buy 2 units at ¢35. If Alice decides that a sales price of ¢35 isn’t bad after all, she may cancel two units of her sell offer at ¢37 and sell these two units at ¢35 by submitting a sell offer for two units at a price of ¢35 or lower. Thus, actual sales take place when a trader submits a sell offer at a price at least as low as the highest buy offer; actual purchases take place when a trader submits a buy order at a price at least as high as the lowest sell offer. Remember that our market was anonymous. It means that even though everyone could see all the offers, nobody knew where they came from. Participants did not know how many traders there were in the marketplace, let alone what other traders’ holdings of cash and stock were. In the graphical replay of the market, bubbles correspond to offers in the marketplace. See the sample video. Blue bubbles are offers to buy stock and the red bubbles are offers to sell stock. The number inside the bubbles indicates the price (in 38 cents). The size of the bubble indicates the number of units offered at the indicated price. All the offers are aligned along one diagonal, decreasing in price. Bubbles move constantly so that the best buy offer and the best sell offer at any moment in time stay close to the middle of the screen. Trades are shown in green. They flash for half a second, after which the bubble shrinks or disappears, to indicate the reduction in the number of units offered as a consequence of the trade. From one period to another, we will randomly change the diagonal along which offers and trades are displayed. Your Task In Detail So what do you have to do? We want you to predict the stock price changes. Every 10s, we stop the replay. At every stop, you will be reminded of the latest trading price and we will ask you to make a prediction: will the transaction price in 10s 39 be higher, lower, or the same as the latest transaction price? Use the keyboard to enter your prediction: • up arrow: • down arrow: trade price will go down • right arrow: trade price will stay the same trade price will go up Remember, we are asking about the trade prices (trades are indicated by green flashing of offer bubbles), not the buy or sell offer prices. If no trade takes place in the subsequent 10s, we assume that the trade price stays the same. You will be given 5s to respond. After that, we re‐start the replay for 10s. At the end of this 10s interval, we briefly stop the replay once more, to indicate whether you won, or whether you paid a penalty because you did not choose within the allotted 5s. We then restart the replay for another 10s, after which we stop and ask again for a prediction. These cycles continue until markets close. You will make $1 for every correct prediction. If you fail to answer within the allotted 5s, you will be fined $0.25. 40 41 Riddles Task In this task, we want you to solve logic problems. The interface should look as above. 42 You will have 30s to read the question, to type your answer in the field at the bottom and to click OK. There are 7 problems, and you will be paid $2 for each correct answer. You pay $1 when you fail to provide an answer within the allotted 30s. 43 Faces Task In this task, we want you to interpret a person’s gaze. The interface should look as above. For each gaze, click on the term that best describes what the person in the picture is thinking or feeling. You may feel that more than one term is applicable but 44 please choose just one term. Before making your choice, make sure that you have read all four (4) terms! You will only have 10 seconds to observe the person’s gaze, to read the terms and to indicate your chocie. There will be 36 trials, and you will be paid $0.25 for each correct answer. You pay $0.10 each time you fail to make a choice within the allotted time. Before we start the test, please take some time to read the definitions of the terms we’ll be using. These are listed on the next page. 45 ACCUSING blaming The waiter was very apologetic when he spilt soup all over the customer. The police officer was accusing the man of stealing a wallet. ARROGANT conceited, self‐important, having a big opinion of oneself The arrogant man thought he knew more about politics than everyone else in the room. AFFECTIONATE showing fondness towards someone Most mothers are affectionate to their babies by giving them lots of kisses and cuddles. ASHAMED overcome with shame or guilt The boy felt ashamed when his mother discovered him stealing money from her purse. AGHAST horrified, astonished, alarmed Jane was aghast when she discovered her house had been burglarized. ASSERTIVE confident, dominant, sure of oneself The assertive woman demanded that the shop give her a refund. ALARMED fearful, worried, filled with anxiety Claire was alarmed when she thought she was being followed home. BAFFLED confused, puzzled, dumbfounded The detectives were completely baffled by the murder case. AMUSED finding something funny I was amused by a funny joke someone told me. BEWILDERED utterly confused, puzzled, dazed The child was bewildered when visiting the big city for the first time. ANNOYED irritated, displeased Jack was annoyed when he found out he had missed the last bus home. CAUTIOUS careful, wary Sarah was always a bit cautious when talking to someone she did not know. ANTICIPATING expecting At the start of the soccer match, the fans were anticipating a quick goal. COMFORTING consoling, compassionate ANXIOUS worried, tense, uneasy The nurse was comforting the wounded soldier. The student was feeling anxious before taking her final exams. CONCERNED worried, troubled The doctor was concerned when his patient took a turn for the worse. APOLOGETIC feeling sorry 46 The animal protester remained defiant even after being sent to prison. CONFIDENT self‐assured, believing in oneself The tennis player was feeling very confident about winning his match. DEPRESSED miserable George was depressed when he didn't receive any birthday cards. CONFUSED puzzled, perplexed Lizzie was so confused by the directions given to her, she got lost. DESIRE passion, lust, longing for Kate had a strong desire for chocolate. CONTEMPLATIVE reflective, thoughtful, considering John was in a contemplative mood on the eve of his 60th birthday. DESPONDENT gloomy, despairing, without hope Gary was despondent when he did not get the job he wanted. CONTENTED satisfied After a nice walk and a good meal, David felt very contented. DISAPPOINTED displeased, disgruntled The Red Sox fans were disappointed not to win the World Series. CONVINCED certain, absolutely positive Richard was convinced he had come to the right decision. DISPIRITED glum, miserable, low Adam was dispirited when he failed his exams. CURIOUS inquisitive, inquiring, prying DISTRUSTFUL suspicious, doubtful, wary Louise was curious about the strange shaped parcel. The old woman was distrustful of the stranger at her door. DECIDING making your mind up The man was deciding whom to vote for in the election. DOMINANT commanding, bossy The sergeant major looked dominant as he inspected the new recruits. DECISIVE already made your mind up Jane looked very decisive as she walked into the polling station. DOUBTFUL dubious, suspicious, not really believing Mary was doubtful that her son was telling the truth. DEFIANT insolent, bold, don’t care what anyone else thinks DUBIOUS doubtful, suspicious 47 In the dark streets, the women felt fearful. Peter was dubious when offered a surprisingly cheap television in a pub. FLIRTATIOUS brazen, saucy, teasing, playful EAGER keen Connie was accused of being flirtatious when she winked at a stranger at a party. On Christmas morning, the children were eager to open their presents. FLUSTERED confused, nervous and upset EARNEST having a serious intention Sarah felt a bit flustered when she realised how late she was for the meeting and that she had forgotten an important document. Harry was very earnest about his religious beliefs. EMBARRASSED ashamed FRIENDLY sociable, amiable After forgetting a colleague's name, Jenny felt very embarrassed. The friendly girl showed the tourists the way to downtown. ENCOURAGING hopeful, heartening, supporting GRATEFUL thankful All the parents were encouraging their children in the school sports day. Kelly was very grateful for the kindness shown by the stranger. ENTERTAINED absorbed and amused or pleased by something GUILTY feeling sorry for doing something wrong I was very entertained by the magician. Charlie felt guilty about having an affair. ENTHUSIASTIC very eager, keen HATEFUL showing intense dislike Susan felt very enthusiastic about her new fitness plan. The two sisters were hateful to each other and always fighting. FANTASIZING daydreaming HOPEFUL optimistic Emma was fantasizing about being a film star. Larry was hopeful that the post would bring good news. FASCINATED captivated, really interested At the seaside, the children were fascinated by the creatures in the rock pools. HORRIFIED terrified, appalled The man was horrified to discover that his new wife was already married. FEARFUL terrified, worried 48 After seeing Jurassic Park, Hugh grew very interested in dinosaurs. HOSTILE unfriendly The two neighbors were hostile towards each other because of an argument about loud music. INTRIGUED very curious, very interested A mystery phone call intrigued Zoe. IMPATIENT restless, wanting something to happen soon IRRITATED exasperated, annoyed Jane grew increasingly impatient as she waited for her friend who was already 20 minutes late. Frances was irritated by all the junk mail she received. IMPLORING begging, pleading JEALOUS envious Nicola looked imploring as she tried to persuade her dad to lend her the car. Tony was jealous of all the taller, better‐looking boys in his class. INCREDULOUS not believing JOKING being funny, playful Simon was incredulous when he heard that he had won the lottery. Gary was always joking with his friends. NERVOUS apprehensive, tense, worried INDECISIVE unsure, hesitant, unable to make your mind up Just before her job interview, Alice felt very nervous. Tammy was so indecisive that she couldn't even decide what to have for lunch. OFFENDED insulted, wounded, having hurt feelings When someone made a joke about her weight, Martha felt very offended. INDIFFERENT disinterested, unresponsive, don't care Terry was completely indifferent as to whether they went to the cinema or the pub. PANICKED distraught, feeling of terror or anxiety On waking to find the house on fire, the whole family was panicked. INSISTING demanding, persisting, maintaining After a work outing, Frank was insisting he paid the bill for everyone. PENSIVE thinking about something slightly worrying Susie looked pensive on the way to meeting her boyfriend's parents for the first time. INSULTING rude, offensive The baseball crowd was insulting the umpire after he gave a invalidated the home‐run. PERPLEXED bewildered, puzzled, confused Frank was perplexed by the disappearance of his garden gnomes. INTERESTED inquiring, curious 49 The businessman felt very resentful towards his younger colleague who had been promoted above him. PLAYFUL full of high spirits and fun Neil was feeling playful at his birthday party. SARCASTIC cynical, mocking, scornful The comedian made a sarcastic comment when someone came into the theatre late. PREOCCUPIED absorbed, engrossed in one's own thoughts Worrying about her mother's illness made Debbie preoccupied at work SATISFIED content, fulfilled Steve felt very satisfied after he had got his new flat just how he wanted it. PUZZLED perplexed, bewildered, confused After doing the crossword for an hour, June was still puzzled by one clue. SCEPTICAL doubtful, suspicious, mistrusting Patrick looked sceptical as someone read out his horoscope to him. REASSURING supporting, encouraging, giving someone confidence SERIOUS solemn, grave Andy tried to look reassuring as he told his wife that her new dress did suit her. The bank manager looked serious as he refused Nigel an overdraft. REFLECTIVE contemplative, thoughtful George was in a reflective mood as he thought about what he'd done with his life. STERN severe, strict, firm The teacher looked very stern as he told the class off. REGRETFUL sorry SUSPICIOUS disbelieving, suspecting, doubting Lee was always regretful that he had never travelled when he was younger. After Sam had lost his wallet for the second time at work, he grew suspicious of one of his colleagues. RELAXED taking it easy, calm, carefree SYMPATHETIC kind, compassionate On holiday, Pam felt happy and relaxed. The nurse looked sympathetic as she told the patient the bad news. RELIEVED freed from worry or anxiety At the restaurant, Ray was relieved to find that he had not forgotten his wallet. TENTATIVE hesitant, uncertain, cautious Andrew felt a bit tentative as he went into the room full of strangers. RESENTFUL bitter, hostile 50 TERRIFIED alarmed, fearful The boy was terrified when he thought he saw a ghost. THOUGHTFUL thinking about something Phil looked thoughtful as he sat waiting for the girlfriend he was about to break‐up with. THREATENING menacing, intimidating The large, drunken man was acting in a very threatening way. UNEASY unsettled, apprehensive, troubled Karen felt slightly uneasy about accepting a lift from the man she had only met that day. UPSET agitated, worried, uneasy The man was very upset when his mother died. WORRIED anxious, fretful, troubled When her cat went missing, the girl was very worried 51 Part 6. Mathematics Section Of Behavioral Experiment: Questions and Answers Question Answer Consider a game played with a deck of three cards: spades, clubs, and hearts. Your goal is to identify the hearts. switch The cards are shuffled and displayed in a row, face down. You make your choice. The dealer then turns over one of the two remaining cards, provided it is not hearts. He then offers you the possibility to change your choice and switch to the other card that is left face down. What is the best strategy? Should you switch, stay, or does it not matter? Answer below "switch", "stay" or "either". Consider a deck of four cards: spades, clubs, hearts, and diamonds. The cards are shuffled and displayed in a More row, face down. You choose one card at random and it is discarded. Then the dealer turns over two cards, chosen at random, but provided they are not hearts. Now there is only one card left unturned. If the two cards the dealer turns over are diamonds and clubs, is the probability that the remaining one is hearts more than, less than, or equal to 0.5? Answer below "more", "less" or "same". There are 8 marbles that weigh the same, and 1 marble that is heavier. The marbles are all uniform in size, 3 appearance, and shape. You have a balance with 2 trays. You are asked to identify the heavier marble in at most 2 (two) weightings. How many marbles do you initially have to place on each tray? Input a number below. Divide 100 by 1/2. Is the result more, less than or equal to 100? More Answer below "more", "less", or "same". Jenn has half the Beanie Babies that Mollie has. Allison has 3 times as many as Jenn. Together they have 72. More Does Mollie have more than, less than, or equal to, 20 Beanie Babies? Answer below "more", "less" or "same". Johnny’s mother had three children. The first child was named April. The second child was named May. What was the third child's name? Type the name below. 52 Johnny The police rounded up Jim, Bud and Sam yesterday, because one of them was suspected of having robbed the Jim local bank. The three suspects made the following statements under intensive questioning. Jim: I'm innocent. Bud: I'm innocent. Sam: Bud is the guilty one. If only one of these statements turns out to be true, who robbed the bank? Type the name of the robber below. Table III. The Mathematical (M) test. We presented subjects with seven questions in a random order. Subjects had 30 seconds to type the answer. We ignored typing mistakes. 53 References Acuna, B., J. Eliassen, J. Donoghue, and J. Sanes, 2002, Frontal and parietal lobe activation during transitive inference in humans, Cerebral Cortex 12, 1312‐1321. Baron‐Cohen, S., H. A. Ring, S. Wheelwright, and E. T. Bullmore, 1999, Social intelligence in the normal and autistic brain: an fMRI study, The European Journal of Neuroscience 11, 1891‐1898. Bechara, A., and A. R. Damasio, 2005, The somatic marker hypothesis: A neural theory of economic decision, Games and Economic Behavior 52, 336‐372. Bhatt, M., and C. Camerer, 2005, Self‐referential Thinking and Equilibrium as States of Mind in Games: fMRI Evidence, Games and Economic Behavior 52, 424‐459. Castelli, F., F. Happe, U. Frith, and C. Frith, 2000, Movement and mind: a functional imaging study of perception and interpretation of complex intentional movement patterns, NeuroImage 12, 314‐325. Coricelli, G., and R. Nagel, 2009, Beauty Contest in the Brain; a Neural Basis of Strategic Thinking, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences (forthcoming). Critchley, H. D., C. J. Mathias, and R. J. Dolan, 2001, Neural activity in the human brain relating to uncertainty and arousal during anticipation, Neuron 29, 537‐45. 54 Dehaene, S., E. Spelke, P. Pinel, R. Stanescu, and S. Tsivkin, 1999, Sources of Mathematical Thinking: Behavioral and Brain‐Imaging Evidence, Science 284, 970‐ 974. Fink, G. R., P. W. Halligan, J. C. Marshall, C. D. Frith, R. S. Frackowiak, and R. J. Dolan, 1996, Where in the brain does visual attention select the forest and the trees?, Nature 382, 626. Fink, G. R., P. W. Halligan, J. C. Marshall, C. D. Frith, R. S. Frackowiak, and R. J. Dolan, 1997, Neural mechanisms involved in the processing of global and local aspects of hierarchically organized visual stimuli, Brain 120, 1779‐1791. Gallagher, H. L., and C. D. Frith, 2003, Functional imaging of 'theory of mind', Trends in Cognitive Sciences 7, 77‐83. Gallagher, H. L., A. I. Jack, A. Roepstorff, and C. D. Frith, 2002, Imaging the intentional stance in a competitive game, NeuroImage 16, 814‐821. Goense, Jozien B. M., and Nikos K. Logothetis, 2008, Neurophysiology of the BOLD fMRI Signal in Awake Monkeys, Current biology 18, 631‐640. King‐Casas, Brooks, Carla Sharp, Laura Lomax‐Bream, Terry Lohrenz, Peter Fonagy, and P. Read Montague, 2008, The Rupture and Repair of Cooperation in Borderline Personality Disorder, Science 321, 806‐810. Lo, A. W., and D. V. Repin, 2002, The Psychophysiology of Real‐Time Financial Risk Processing, Journal of Cognitive Neuroscience 14, 323‐339. 55 McCabe, K., D. Houser, L. Ryan, V. Smith, and T. Trouard, 2001, A functional imaging study of cooperation in two‐person reciprocal exchange, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 98, 11832‐11835. Morris, J. S., A. Ohman, and R. J. Dolan, 1998, Conscious and unconscious emotional learning in the human amygdala, Nature 393, 467‐470. Newman, S., P. Carpenter, S. Varma, and M. Just, 2003, Frontal and parietal participation in problem solving in the Tower of London: fMRI and computational modeling of planning and high‐level perception, Neuropsychologia 41, 1668‐1682. Parsons, L., and D. Osherson, 2001, New evidence for distinct right and left brain systems for deductive versus probabilistic reasoning, Cerebral Cortex 11, 954‐965. Phan, K. L., T. D. Wager, S. F. Taylor, and I. Liberzon, 2002, Functional Neuroanatomy of Emotion: a Meta‐Analysis of Emotion Activation Studies in PET and fMRI, NeuroImage 16, 331‐348. Phillips, M. L., A. W. Young, S. K. Scott, A. J. Calder, C. Andrew, V. Giampietro, S. C. Williams, E. T. Bullmore, M. Brammer, and J. A. Gray, 1999, Neural responses to facial and vocal expressions of fear and disgust, Proceedings of Royal Society of London. 265, 1809‐1817. Preuschoff, Kerstin, Steven R. Quartz, and Peter Bossaerts, 2008, Human Insula Activation Reflects Risk Prediction Errors As Well As Risk, J. Neurosci. 28, 2745‐ 2752. 56 Servos, P., R. Osu, A. Santi, and M. Kawato, 2002, The neural substrates of biological motion perception: an fMRI study, Cerebral Cortex 12, 772‐782. Singer, T., B. Seymour, J. O'Doherty, H. Kaube, R. J. Dolan, and C. D. Frith, 2004, Empathy for Pain Involves the Affective but not Sensory Components of Pain, Science 303, 1157‐1162. 57
Similar documents
Internet Appendix for - American Finance Association
bids, and red circles represented asks. For example, if at a given time there was a single bid at 25¢, three asks at 27¢, and one ask at 28¢, the subject would see three circles: a small blue c...
More information