Competitive Market Plan - American Public Power Association
Transcription
Competitive Market Plan - American Public Power Association
APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update A Roadmap for Reforming Wholesale Electricity Markets R APPA’s Competitive Market Plan Update 2011 A Roadmap for Reforming Wholesale Electricity Markets June 2011 Copyright 2011 by the American Public Power Association. All rights reserved. Published by the American Public Power Association, 1875 Connecticut Ave., NW, Suite 1200, Washington, DC 20009-5715 • www.PublicPower.org Acknowledgements APPA would like to acknowledge the many individuals who provided valuable writing assistance, suggestions, comments and feedback, including Kenneth Rose, Ph. D., Independent Consultant; Gary J. Newell, Thompson Coburn, LLP; James A. Jablonski, Executive Director, Public Power Association of New Jersey; Robert McCullough, McCullough Research; Paul Williams, Pennsylvania Steel & Cement Manufacturers Coalition and Howard Spinner, Virginia State Corporation Commission. The views expressed in this paper are those of APPA alone and should not be attributed to any individual who kindly assisted us in this effort. Table of Contents Executive Summary ................................................................xii I. Introduction ............................................................................1 II. Background.............................................................................7 III. Overview of Proposed Market Structure ................................12 IV. Role of State Regulatory Agencies.........................................15 V. Bilateral Contracts .................................................................21 VI. Market Power .......................................................................27 VII. Residual Short-Term and Imbalance Services: The Optimization Market........................................................30 VIII. RTO Operations to Support Non-Discriminatory Transmission Access .............................................................34 IX. Renewable Energy.................................................................38 X. Resource Adequacy and Planning .........................................42 XI. Transmission Planning ...........................................................47 XII. Transition Issues ....................................................................49 XIII. Conclusion ............................................................................50 Appendix A: Division of Responsibilities for Resource Adequacy in Current RTO Market Structures ..................52 www.PublicPower.org APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update iii Preface to the Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update I n February 2009, the American Public Power Association (“APPA”) released a proposal to reform the centralized markets run by Regional Transmission Organizations (“RTOs”), which it called the “Competitive Market Plan” (“CMP”). In doing so, APPA hoped to “jumpstart” a dialogue among industry participants to develop much needed reforms to RTO-run markets. As APPA noted at the close of its proposal (CMP at 39): The debate should no longer be about who can best massage the statistics or whether it is more virtuous to support “competition” or “regulation.” Instead, the industry must work together to develop a regulatory regime for electricity markets in RTO regions that will truly benefit consumers, businesses and the environment. Unless the electric utility industry and its regulators can agree on a market design and regulatory paradigm that fairly balances the interests of both load and generation, the industry will be condemned to continued upheaval. Unfortunately, the release of APPA’s CMP did not have the effect that APPA had hoped. There was plenty of public reaction by incumbent generation owners to the plan, but it consisted primarily of mischaracterization and resultant dismissal of APPA’s proposal,1 and claims that APPA in fact wanted to return to cost-of-service ratemaking or institute a “pay-as-bid” auction regime.2 Those asset owners with financial interests in maintaining the current RTO market structure (including locational capacity markets) expended their energies on a public relations effort to discredit the CMP and APPA, rather than to use the CMP’s issuance as an opportunity to engage in an actual debate about possible RTO market reforms3. The result has been the “continued upheaval” that APPA feared. Litigation at the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (“FERC” or “Commission”) and in the appellate courts regarding RTO market features continues apace, as generator and load interests attempt to craft specific market rules and procedures that work best for their respective interests. This new version of the CMP updates APPA’s 2009 proposals and concerns to address several iv APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 1 See, e.g., John D. Chandley and William W. Hogan, Electricity Market Reform: APPA’s Journey Down The Wrong Path, LECG, prepared for the COMPETE Coalition, April 16, 2009, http://www.competecoalition.com/files/LECG%20study.pdf 2 For example, at page 8 of their paper, Chandley and Hogan characterize the CMP as follows: “It is not an exaggeration, therefore, to describe this approach as akin to detailed less-thancost-of-service regulation.” APPA found these criticisms somewhat mystifying, given that the CMP retained a “single clearing price” (SCP) auction format, and expressly called for continuation of market-based rates for bilateral contracts. 3 This was in marked contrast to some limited informal feedback from the asset owner sector that APPA staff received, to the effect that the proposal, while not acceptable in its current form, was indeed a thoughtful and good faith proposal worth further discussion. www.PublicPower.org Against this backdrop of continued inadequate market oversight, are increasingly successful attempts by incumbent generation owners to develop new sources of revenue, either through changes to current market rules or through the creation of new markets – almost always over the strenuous objections of consumer and load-side representatives. issues that have since risen to prominence in RTO markets, and raise additional concerns for public power. Events over the past two- and- a-half years continue to illustrate the absence of adequate regulation and oversight of RTO markets by FERC. For example, APPA’s and others’ experiences with the development of RTO performance metrics illustrate the barriers to developing necessary measures that accurately assess the costs and benefits of wholesale electricity markets. In response to a 2008 report by the Government Accountability Office (“GAO”)4, FERC issued a set of proposed RTO performance metrics in February 2010, developed largely in conjunction with the RTOs themselves. APPA and many others of the commenters stated that the proposed performance metrics were insufficient, primarily because they lacked essential measures of comprehensive revenue streams from wholesale markets, generator profits and accurate price-cost differentials.5 The final measures that FERC approved were similar to those recommended by the RTOs and did not include such key measures. The ISO/RTO Council then provided a report to FERC that was essentially a recounting of the many achievements of RTOs. Hence, the entire exercise failed to meet the original intent of the GAO’s recommendation --— to accurately measure the validity of such claims about market benefits.6 Against this backdrop of continued inadequate market oversight, are increasingly successful attempts by incumbent generation owners to develop new sources of revenue, either through changes to current market rules or through the creation of new markets – almost always over the strenuous objections of consumer and load-side representatives. Such enhancements of revenue streams, however, are being implemented absent any measures to ensure a reliable supply of power in the future to justify the payment of such revenues. Illustrative of these types of controversies are the proposal for scarcity pricing 4 The GAO found that “FERC has not conducted an empirical analysis to measure whether RTOs have achieved these expected benefits or how RTOs or restructuring efforts more generally have affected consumer electricity prices, costs of production, or infrastructure investment.” Electricity Restructuring: FERC Could Take Additional Steps to Analyze Regional Transmission Organizations’ Benefits and Performance, GAO-08-987, September 2008, p.55, http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d08987.pdf. 5 Initial Comments of the American Public Power Association and the Electricity Consumers Resource Council, Docket AD10-5-000, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, March 5, 2010, http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/APPAELCONAInitialCommentsAD105352010asfiled.pdf 6 ISO/RTO Performance Metrics, Commission Staff Report, Docket No. AD10-5-000, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, October 21, 2010, http://www.ferc.gov/legal/staffreports/10-21-10-rto-metrics.pdf. The ISO/RTO Council subsequently issued its report on the data required by the metrics. APPA’s response to that report is at: http://appanet.cms-plus.com/files/PDFs/APPAResponsetoRTOMetricsReport121310.pdf www.PublicPower.org APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update v in PJM, the recent battles over measures to prevent state-procured new generation resources from participating in ISO New England’s Forward Capacity Market (“FCM”) and PJM’s Reliability Pricing Model (“RPM”), and the bitter disputes in the PJM Interconnection (“PJM”) regarding the specific load forecasts that PJM uses in administering its RPM. But even more disturbing to APPA has been the reappearance of “RTOhopping,” i.e., the practice of transmission- owning utilities with affiliates that have unregulated generation units moving from one RTO to another to take advantage of more lucrative payments for their generation assets. The prime examples of this were First Energy’s migration from the Midwest Independent Transmission System Operator (“MISO”) to PJM, proposed in August 2009 with full integration planned for June 2011, followed by Duke Energy’s June 2010 proposal to move its Ohio and Kentucky transmission and generation assets (including jointly-owned assets) from MISO to PJM, expected to be completed in January, 2012.7 The desire of these companies to maximize the revenues from their unregulated generation assets is certainly understandable. And FERC’s decision to allow such transfers,8 while deeply disappointing is also at least understandable, given the terms of the contracts under which these transmission owners had previously agreed to join MISO. What APPA had not expected, however, and what it finds both profoundly anti-consumer and deeply alarming, was the attitude of the current Chairman of FERC regarding these transfers. As reported in the October 22, 2010 Energy Daily (at 3) regarding the Duke Energy transfer: FERC Chairman Wellinghoff said there was nothing wrong with utilities switching RTOs, whether for capacity market payments or other reasons. It is healthy for utilities to evaluate “where is the most competitive RTO that provides them the best opportunity for their business models to operate,” he said. And from the RTOs’ perspective, he said it was a good thing “to have other RTOs realize that there may be another RTO that may have a superior structure that is attracting more utilities and that they maybe should consider changing their structure.” When the concept of “competition” in RTO regions has devolved from determining which RTO (and RTO market designs) can best harness vi APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 7 FirstEnergy and Duke market integration materials are available at: http://www.pjm.com/markets-and-operations/market-integration.aspx 8 Order Addressing RTO Realignment Request and Complaint, Dockets ER09-1589-000 and EL10-6-000, 129 FERC ¶ 61,249 (December 17, 2009); and Order Addressing RTO Realignment Request ,Request, Dockets ER10-1562-000 and ER10-2254-000, 133 FERC ¶ 61,058 (October 21, 2010). www.PublicPower.org competition to deliver just and reasonable prices to consumers (as the Federal Power Act (“FPA”) requires)9 to which RTO can offer generation asset owners the most dollars to join their organization, something is badly amiss. FERC regulation of RTOs under the FPA has reached the point where, when the GAO criticized FERC for not sufficiently evaluating and assessing RTO market performance, FERC turned to the RTOs themselves to design “metrics” to measure their own performance, and then adopted those metrics with very few changes,10 as described above. Predictably, this lack of evenhandedness in balancing the interests of generation and load in the design of RTO markets, the application of RTO market rules, and FERC oversight of RTO markets and activities, has resulted in consternation and restiveness among load side interests. This has been seen most recently and clearly in the ongoing events in Maryland and New Jersey, two states in PJM that have been required to pay high rates in PJM’s RPM capacity auctions. Both states are located in transmissionconstrained areas of the PJM footprint. New Jersey Governor Chris Christie signed legislation in January, 2011 providing for a “self help” remedy in the form of mandated bilateral generation contract procurements for the utilities that provide default retail power supply service in New Jersey, to “anchor” the construction of new generation capacity.11 The Maryland Public Service Commission issued a draft RFP for long-term contracts and indicated that it is strongly considering implementing a measure similar to New Jersey’s.12 Because a key component of these states’ plans is to bid the resulting new generation into PJM’s capacity market auctions, thus potentially lowering the price, owners of existing generation in PJM (PJM Power Providers or “P3”) filed a complaint with FERC aimed at preventing new generators with bilateral contracts from seeking to lower capacity prices.13 Following a drop in prices in the New England capacity market, www.PublicPower.org 9 16 U.S.C. §§ 824d and 824e. 10 Notice Requesting Comments on RTO/ISO Performance Metrics, Docket AD10-5-000, 75 Fed. Reg. 7,581 (February 22, 2010); Initial Comments of the American Public Power Association and the Electricity Consumers Resource Council, Docket AD10-5-000, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, March 5, 2010 http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/APPAELCONInitialcommentsAD105352010asfiled.pdf; and ISO/RTO Performance Metrics, Commission Staff Report. 11 New Jersey P.L.2011, Chapter 9, Senate, No. 2381, §§1,3,4 - C.48:3-98.2 to 48:3-98.4 §5 C.48:3-60.1, http://www.njleg.state.nj.us/2010/Bills/AL11/9_.PDF 12 Notice of Comment Period on Request for Proposals for New Generating Facilities , Case No. 9214, Maryland Public Service Commission, December 29, 2010, http://webapp.psc.state.md.us/Intranet/Casenum/NewIndex3_VOpenFile.cfm?ServerFilePath=C:\Casenum\9200-9299\9214\\34.pdf 13 Complaint and Request for Clarification Requesting Fast Track Processing, PJM Power Providers Group, Docket EL-20-000, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, February 1, 2011, http://www.p3powergroup.com/siteFiles/News/BA60285E201B5659BBD906367C86FBC9.pdf APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update vii the New England generators filed a similar complaint seeking to mitigate the effects of Connecticut’s or other states’ bidding of procured generation as a price taker (referred to as “out-of-market resources”).14 In response to these complaints both RTOs proposed changes in their respective capacity markets. In April 2011, FERC approved changes to PJM’s RPM that would make it very difficult for new natural gas-fired resources contracted for outside of RPM—- such as resources obtained under a state procurement program like New Jersey’s or by a municipal utility for selfsupply—- to bid into the auctions at zero.15 Without the option to bid into an auction at zero, these resources now face the danger that they would not clear the auction, thus potentially endangering their construction. In New England’s FCM market, FERC also approved the ISO’s development of a minimum price requirement for bids from new resources into the capacity market16, which will likely have an similar effect similar to the approved RPM rule change. APPA notes that these state actions are consistent with APPA’s recommendation in the first edition of the CMP (at 17) that “state public service commissions establish competitive power supply procurement processes to develop diversified resource portfolios for incumbent [investorowned utility load- serving entities], with a significant portion of their power supplies being obtained under longer-term contracts or owned-generation arrangements.” APPA noted that such measures could “provide much needed price discipline in RTO-run centralized markets.” Id. The Commission’s recent rulings, however, seem to ensure that states will not have the necessary tools at their disposal to assure reasonable rates for electric power supply to their own citizens. The frustration in Maryland, New Jersey and other states (such as Connecticut) stems from a basic flaw in RTO-run centralized markets --— they do not sufficiently support new generation investment but instead overcompensate existing generators. While those supporting locational capacity markets claimed to regulators and load-side interests that such markets would send “price signals” to generators as to where to invest in new generation, there has been no demonstrated relationship between prices and investments in new resources.17 Instead, consumers have paid viii 14 Motion to Intervene and Protest of the New England Power Generators Association, Docket ER10-787-000, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, March 15, 2010, http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/OpenNat.asp?fileID=12292579 15 Order Accepting Proposed Tariff Revisions, Subject To Conditions, And Addressing Related Complaint, 135 FERC ¶ 61,022 (April 12, 2011), http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/OpenNat.asp?fileID=12617771 16 Order On Paper Hearing And Order On Rehearing, 135 FERC ¶ 61,029 (April 13, 2011), http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/File_list.asp?document_id=13909713 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update www.PublicPower.org literally billions of dollars through these markets to incumbent generators with existing units. While it is true that these markets have supported development of new demand response resources, and existing generation that might have otherwise retired has stayed on line, it is questionable whether these benefits justify the very high associated costs. The failure of RTO-run centralized locational capacity markets to support substantial new generation investment leads directly to the most important reason why the industry now needs to engage in the “rational debate” on the design of RTO markets that APPA had hoped to spur in 2009 --— the likely retirement of a substantial portion of the nation’s coal-fired electric generation fleet in the next several years. The Environmental Protection Agency (“EPA”) is currently planning to issue a panoply of new and revised regulations in the 2010-20 time frame, dealing with everything from NOx, SO2 and mercury emissions to power plants’ continued use of once-through cooling, to storage and disposal of coal ash. The cumulative effect of these new regulations will likely make a substantial number of existing coal-fired generation units uneconomic to operate in the future. There are many estimates of the plant closures likely to occur, ranging from 30 to 70 gigawatts (GW) of coal generation within the next ten years, with most estimates trending towards the higher end of this range.18 RTO regions currently have excess generation capacity, due to the impacts of the recession and the payments made to keep existing generation units (some of them old and inefficient) in operation. But this situation could well change quickly once demand begins to increase if the recession eases, and as generation unit owners assess their units’ continued economic viability in www.PublicPower.org 17 Despite the payment of $42 billion in the first seven auctions, actual new generation net of deactivations and retirements, has equaled just 0.5 percent of the total generation that has cleared the market and 3 percent of the average cleared in each auction. Moreover, a recent analysis shows that high prices within the constrained zones within PJM’s Reliability Pricing Model have not incented greater levels of new generation clearing the RPM auctions or existing plant upgrades, demand response, energy efficiency resources, and net imports offered in constrained zones. See Direct Testimony of James F. Wilson in Support of First Brief of the Joint Filing Supporters, Docket ER10-787, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, July 1, 2010, Section V, http://www.wilsonenec.com/FCM_Testimony_July_1.php 18 Studies of projected coal plant closures have been undertaken by: The North American Electric Reliability Corporation (10 - 35 GW of coal and 40 - 70 GW of all capacity by 2018), 2010 Special Reliability Scenario Assessment, October, 2010, Table IV-6, http://www.nerc.com/files/EPA_Scenario_Final.pdf; Credit Suisse Equity Research (60 GW of coal capacity between 2013 and 2017), Growth From Subtraction: Impact of EPA Rules on Power Markets, September 23, 2010, http://op.bna.com/env.nsf/id/jstn-8actja/$File/suisse.pdf; The Brattle Group (50 – 66 GW of coal capacity by 2020), Potential Coal Plant Retirements Under Emerging Environmental Regulations, December 8, 2010, http://www.brattle.com/_documents/UploadLibrary/Upload898.pdf, and FBR Capital (30 – 70 GW in the next few years), EPA regs may shut 70,000 MW of U.S. coal plants: FBR, Reuters, December 13, 2010 http://www.reuters.com/article/2010/12/13/us-utilities-epa-coal-idUSTRE6BC3JN20101213 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update ix light of these new EPA regulations. The industry and its regulators need to start considering now how best to manage the transition to new, more efficient and cleaner generation. Current RTO locational capacity markets, with their relatively short (3-5 year) payout periods, simply cannot support the required new generation investment. Something will have to give, and relatively soon. In short, APPA believes it is now even more important than it was in 2009 that the industry begins the honest dialogue among its participants in RTO regions that will be needed to manage this transition to a lower-carbon generation future. APPA is therefore updating and re-releasing its CMP as its contribution to the debate. It urges other sectors of the industry to see this as a new opportunity to discuss the huge challenge before all of us, rather than to continue the partisan battles now taking place in RTO stakeholder processes and Commission proceedings. Such a result would be the triumph of hope over APPA’s past experience with its release of the first version of the CMP, but hope survives nonetheless. x APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update www.PublicPower.org Executive Summary T his paper presents an updated version of the American Public Power Association’s (APPA) Competitive Market Plan for reform of wholesale electricity markets administered by regional transmission organizations (RTOs). The plan, originally released in February 2009, was developed based upon results of investigative studies carried out under APPA’s Electric Market Reform Initiative (EMRI) and in consultation with APPA members, other market participants and electricity industry experts. APPA developed the Competitive Market Plan to attempt to remedy the absence of meaningful competition and consumer protections under the current RTO market model, while still assuring resource adequacy. The changes proposed in this paper are only for regions with RTO-run centralized wholesale power supply markets under federal jurisdiction. APPA is not suggesting that geographic regions without RTOs adopt these proposals. Along with the proposed reforms, APPA is also recommending a moratorium on the development of new RTO markets, at least in the absence of strong, widespread RTO member support for them. APPA is recommending the following primary changes to the Day 2 RTO markets. These changes are intended to move these markets from de facto oligopolies to more competitive markets, while ensuring reliable electric service at just and reasonable rates. Power Supply Markets • Current RTO-run energy and ancillary services real-time and day-ahead markets would be replaced by an RTO-run “optimization” market, in which customers can could balance supply deficiencies or excess purchases, and generators can could sell excess generation. • Offers to sell into the optimization market for both energy and ancillary services would be limited to generators’ marginal costs of generation. Generators would be required to submit their unit-specific operating costs to the RTO market monitor in advance to provide cost support for their offers. Prices would be set initially using a cost-based single-clearing price mechanism, with evaluation of the results of that mechanism after three years of operation. • The optimization market would use a marginal cost-based, single-clearing price model for the purpose of generation resource commitment and dispatch. • Generator offers into the optimization market would be made public on the next operating day, including the identity of bidders. • FERC-jurisdictional power suppliers entering into bilateral contracts with load-serving entities (LSEs) in an RTO region would not be subject to cost-based restrictions, i.e., they could use market-based rates if they have obtained such authority from FERC. APPA recommends, however, that FERC separately evaluate generation market power for long-term power xii APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update www.PublicPower.org supply products in determining seller eligibility for market-based rate authority. • Generators would be subject to a must-offer requirement into the optimization market for energy not already committed under bilateral contracts or LSE-owned generation arrangements (subject to forced outages, scheduled maintenance, and special rules for limited-run units). • Demand-side resources could sell into the optimization market, but would not be subject to a cost-based offer restriction; rather, they would take the single-clearing price that clears the market net of the foregone retail rate, assuming they have previously offered to reduce demand at that price level. Resource Adequacy • Existing RTO-administered locational capacity markets would be phased out over time and capacity would be supplied through bilateral contracts entered into by LSEs with resource suppliers (both generation and demand response), LSE-owned generation arrangements and LSEmanaged demand response. • The RTOs would determine and implement overall resource adequacy standards applicable to LSEs within the RTO footprint. States would have substantial input into RTO development of regional transmission plans and regional resource adequacy requirements. • States would establish resource acquisition processes to secure a diversified portfolio of generation and demand-side resources for stateregulated investor-owned utility (IOU) LSEs. In retail choice states, competitive procurements, including consideration of both LSE selfbuild/self-supply and third-party supplier options, would be conducted for state-regulated IOU LSEs, with an option for locally regulated LSEs to participate. • States and LSEs would be free to explore broader LSE resource procurement initiatives, such as regional procurements or LSE resource pooling. RTO Dispatch and Transmission Operation • RTOs would conduct centralized least-cost dispatch of generators based on actual marginal costs. Generators and demand response providers would be paid based upon contracted prices for quantities sold through the bilateral market. For quantities sold through the optimization market, generators and demand responders would receive the cost-based market-clearing price. • Data on bilateral contracts would be submitted to the RTO for the purposes of market monitoring, running feasibility tests to assess transmission adequacy, and developing regional transmission plans. • Financial transmission rights (“FTRs”) would be allocated to LSEs. Long- www.PublicPower.org APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update xiii term FTRs would also be granted to support longer-term (e.g., 10-year) bilateral power supply arrangements and LSE-owned resources. Because such FTRs support physical transactions, they would be exempted from otherwise applicable collateral or margin posting requirements. • Existing transmission rights would be maintained to the maximum extent feasible. • RTOs would continue to ensure non-discriminatory open access to the transmission system. APPA recommends as part of its Plan that FERC conduct periodic reviews of wholesale power supply markets in RTO regions, to assess long-term price stability, possible exercises of market power, justness and reasonableness of rates, and reliability. To the extent that reformed RTO markets are not making adequate progress in providing balanced incentives and benefits to both generator and load interests, further reforms would need to be considered. xiv APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update www.PublicPower.org I. Introduction T his paper presents the American Public Power Association’s (APPA) updated plan for reform of wholesale electricity markets administered by regional transmission organizations (RTOs). The initial plan was developed based upon results of investigative studies carried out under APPA’s Electric Market Reform Initiative (EMRI) and consultation with APPA members, other market participants, and electricity industry experts. The updated plan contains modifications suggested by two additional years of experience with RTO-administered centralized markets. APPA initiated EMRI in 2006 following a series of fundamental changes in the wholesale electricity markets. The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) shifted its policy emphasis from ensuring non-discriminatory open access transmission service to implementing centralized RTO-run wholesale electric markets, with only limited wholesale price regulation. (A map of the geographic regions covered by the RTOs is shown below.) Meanwhile, many states implemented retail access programs to provide retail electric consumers with a choice of electricity providers. In many of these states, investor-owned utilities (IOUs) sold off their generating plants to third parties (in many cases, their unregulated affiliates), which can now sell their power at prices that are no longer tied to the costs of production, and are subject only to limited RTO “market mitigation” rules. Source: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission www.PublicPower.org APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 1 In response to growing problems that public power utilities were experiencing obtaining power supplies in RTO regions with centralized power supply markets, APPA launched EMRI in March 2006 to investigate restructured wholesale electricity markets and develop needed reforms to those markets. Under this initiative, APPA commissioned a series of studies investigating the restructured RTO-run wholesale markets under federal jurisdiction.19 Based on the results of these studies, APPA concluded that RTO-run centralized wholesale markets had substantial problems, and were not yielding “just and reasonable rates,” as the Federal Power Act (FPA)20 requires. APPA therefore embarked on the development of potential reforms to these markets. A fundamental reason for restructuring of electricity markets was the expectation that the combination of open access transmission service and RTO-operated centralized wholesale markets would promote “competition.” This increased competition in turn would spur efficiencies and innovation, ensure adequate supplies and, most importantly, lower rates for consumers. But the EMRI studies and the real-world experience of consumers shows how the opposite has occurred. These deregulated markets produced both higher prices and higher profits than one would expect in a competitive market. Prices exceed those prevailing in the remaining regions that have not restructured and have instead retained cost-of-service regulation. The greatest beneficiaries of restructuring are not consumers, or the new, innovative companies that were promised to emerge under competition, but the owners of large fleets of previously regulated, largely depreciated generation units. These central concerns still remain over more than two years after the release of APPA’s Competitive Market plan (“CMP” or “Plan”). In fact, APPA concluded that several significant developments have necessitated updates to the CMP. Those developments include the capacity market difficulties, the increasing role of demand response, greater concerns over transmission costs, planning and rate incentives, and additional and increasingly complex RTO market proposals. Another significant change is that the recession of the past two years has reduced demand, which in turn lowered energy prices and lessened previous concerns about potential supply shortages in the short term. Because these price drops were the result of external economic factors, they do not by themselves affirm or negate the success of the markets in providing benefits for consumers. The absence of a connection between RTO markets and recession-induced price decreases, however, have has not stopped supporters 2 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 19 The results of these studies are available on the EMRI section of APPA’s Web site at: www.PublicPower.org/emri.cfm 20 FPA Sections 205 and 206, 16 U.S.C. §§ 824d, 824e. www.PublicPower.org of the markets from citing these lower prices as evidence of the “competitiveness” of the markets.21 While wholesale energy prices fell in 2009 and began to rebound in 2010, overall retail prices in both in regulated and deregulated states have continued to increase. But prices in deregulated states within RTO regions have been 50 percent greater than regulated states in the past two years.22 Part of the reason for this wholesale/retail disparity is the many nongeneration costs that directly affect retail rates, such as local distribution costs. Another factor is that indices of wholesale energy prices by themselves do not provide a complete picture of all components of generation costs. Sources of wholesale market revenue to generators include capacity market, ancillary service, and uplift payments, as well as revenue from bilateral contracts, such as those arranged for provision of standard offer service. It is highly likely that the declines in wholesale prices reflect just a temporary drop that affects primarily the energy spot markets, and not other RTO markets. First, an increasing amount of revenue has been flowing through the capacity markets, and prices in the constrained areas in the PJM23 and NY ISO24 locational capacity markets have been increasing. Second, the pending closure of some coal plants, especially in RTO regions, in response to EPA 21 For example, the Electric Power Supply Association (EPSA), in a statement on the 2009 market monitor reports, asserted that: “The annual reports note that the organized wholesale markets are appropriately reflecting dramatically lower fuel prices with electricity prices dropping by roughly 50 percent from 2008 levels across the markets. The reports once again underscore the benefits to consumers of independent operation of the transmission system and markets that are quickly responsive to lower costs.” Organized Wholesale Markets Are Competitive and Delivering Benefits to Consumers, EPSA PowerFact, August 25, 2010, http://www.epsa.org/forms/documents/DocumentFormPublic/view?id=16CC400000002. In 2009, Joel Malina, Executive Director of COMPETE, stated that: “In competitive electricity markets all over the country electricity prices are on the downturn. This evidence should put to rest the superficial arguments suggesting that competitive markets aren’t working.” Rates Continue to Decrease in Competitive Markets, Including Ohio, Massachusetts, Pennsylvania, New York, Illinois and Maryland, Compete Coalition, June 10, 2009, http://www.competecoalition.com/newsroom/rates-continue-decrease-competitive-markets-including-ohio-massachusetts-pennsylvania-new-y www.PublicPower.org 22 Retail Electric Rates in Deregulated and Regulated States: 2010 Update, APPA, March 2011, http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/RKWFinal2010.pdf 23 As determined by the capacity market auctions, prices in the transmission-constrained areas are scheduled to increase in June 2012, and again in June 2013, more than doubling the June 2011 price. See PJM’s Base Residual Auction Results at http://www.pjm.com/markets-and-operations/rpm/rpm-auction-user-info.aspx#Item06. 24 Capacity prices in New York City increased by 92 and 57 percent in the second and third quarters of 2010 and compared to the same quarters for 2009, while falling slightly in other areas. Quarterly Report on NY ISO Electricity Markets, Second Quarter 2010, July 2010, p. 3, Third Quarter 2010, October 2010, p. 3; http://www.nyiso.com/public/webdocs/documents/mmu_quarterly_reports/2010/NYISO_Quarterly_Report_2010Q2.pdf; and http://www.nyiso.com/public/webdocs/documents/mmu_quarterly_reports/2010/NYISO_ Quarterly_Report_2010Q3.pdf APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 3 regulations is likely to constrain supply and result in the dispatch of more expensive power plants, increasing both energy and capacity prices.25 Transitory price decreases should not affect conclusions about the overall costs and benefits of the RTO-operated electricity markets. Evaluating costs and benefits requires a determination of whether prices produced in the RTO-operated markets are what one would expect to see from a truly competitive market, as indicated by prices being equal to (or at least close to) the actual costs of production, accounting for a contribution to fixed costs. In contrast, two APPA analyses showed that high profits continued in 2009 and 2010 for the largest owners of unregulated generation in PJM, as measured by net operating income and returns on equity. These high profits indicate that rates remain substantially above the costs of production of electricity incurred by these merchant generators.26 The impact of RTO markets on generator profits, and in turn on the consumer, varies depending upon whether the state regulatory regime employs retail choice or vertical integration with an obligation to serve customers. For example, in the Midwest region almost all LSEs fall into this second category. For these generation-owning utilities with an obligation to serve, the excess profits recovered by baseload generators in the RTOoperated markets are passed back to the consumer, not retained by shareholders as profit. Two companies owning merchant generation located within the Midwest ISO, First Energy and Duke Energy, are in the process of moving their transmission and generation assets from MISO to PJM.27 The greater capacity prices in PJM’s market will provide a more lucrative earnings opportunity for these companies. In an apparent attempt to avoid future departures, and support the entrance of the Entergy operating companies, MISO is in the process of developing a proposal for a centralized forward 4 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 25 Credit Suisse projects that the likely supply constraints resulting from the coal plant closures would increase power prices by at least $5 per MWh in PJM-West and MISO, as well as putting upward pressure on capacity prices. Growth From Subtraction: Impact of EPA Rules on Power Markets, Credit Suisse Equity Research, September 23, 2010, pp. 47-48, http://op.bna.com/env.nsf/id/jstn-8actja/$File/suisse.pdf 26 2009 Financial Performance of Owners of Unregulated Generation: High Profits Earned in Restructured Wholesale Electricity Markets During the Recession, APPA, May 2010, http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/2009FinancialPerformanceMay2010.pdf; and Financial Performance of Owners of Unregulated Generation in PJM: 2010 Update, www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/FinancialPerformance2010UpdateMay2011.pdf 27 FirstEnergy Service Company’s move into PJM is planned to be completed by June 1, 2011, and will include the American Transmission Systems, Inc. (ATSI) transmission assets, the regulated distribution utilities (The Cleveland Electric Illuminating Company, Ohio Edison Company, The Toledo Edison Company, and Pennsylvania Power Company) and the merchant generation owner, FirstEnergy Solutions. Duke Energy’s move is planned for January 1, 2012, and includes the transmission assets of Duke Energy Ohio, Inc. and Duke Energy Kentucky, Inc., as well as the Duke Energy generation assets. See the Market Integration section of PJM’s web site at http://www.pjm.com/markets-and-operations/market-integration.aspx www.PublicPower.org capacity market, resembling PJM’s Reliability Pricing Model.28 APPA developed its CMP to attempt to remedy the absence of meaningful competition and consumer protections under the current RTO market model, while still assuring resource adequacy. The changes proposed in this paper are only for regions with RTO-run centralized wholesale power supply markets under federal jurisdiction. APPA is not suggesting that geographic regions without FERC-jurisdictional RTOs adopt these proposals. Along with the proposed reforms, APPA is also recommending a moratorium on the development of new RTO markets, at least in the absence of strong, widespread RTO member support for them. Although the changes APPA proposes would require a lengthy implementation period, APPA made substantial efforts to work within the existing RTO structure. Current RTO market structures are extremely complicated and cannot be easily modified, due in large part to a stakeholder process that is heavily influenced by generation owners. To the extent that current features of RTO markets are maintained in the CMP, this should not be construed as an APPA endorsement of such features, but rather recognition that a complete overhaul of the existing markets would be very difficult to accomplish. Goals of the Competitive Market Plan APPA intends that its Plan would produce the following outcomes: • Increase the availability of long-term bilateral power supply contracts (e.g., a 10-year term) and opportunities for LSE-owned generation, in turn enhancing the viability of financing new generation and renewable energy technologies. • Reduced opportunities for market participants to exercise market power. • Transmission planning and construction processes that support longterm bilateral contracts/generation ownership and the new generation resources developed with the support of such power supply arrangements. • Greater opportunities for LSEs to hedge congestion and reduced speculative opportunities for financial-only market participants. • Reduced power supply price volatility and wholesale electricity rates that better comport with the just and reasonable standard of the Federal Power Act. 28 www.PublicPower.org Midwest ISO Resource Adequacy Enhancements Proposal, Supply Adequacy Working Group, Midwest ISO, December 9, 2010, https://www.midwestiso.org/Library/Repository/Meeting%20Material/Stakeholder/SAWG/2010/20101209/20101209%20SAWG%20Item%2003 %20Midwest%20ISO%20RA%20Enhancement%20Proposal.PDF; and other materials from the MISO Supply Adequacy Working Group meetings, https://www.midwestiso.org/Library/MeetingMaterials/Pages/SAWG.aspx APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 5 • Resource adequacy standards, increased bilateral contracting, use of owned generation, and an optimization market that together would improve the reliability of electricity service. 6 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update www.PublicPower.org II. Background T his plan originated in a proposal, first presented in APPA’s February 2008 paper “Consumers in Peril,”29 to restructure current “Day Two” RTOs as “Day One” RTOs.30 After careful investigation and refinement of this concept, APPA decided that the best approach would be to develop a hybrid of the best elements of both RTO structures. Current Day Two RTOs operating in the United States include the PJM Interconnection (“PJM”), the Midwest Independent Transmission System Operator (“MISO”), ISO-New England (“ISO-NE”), and the New York Independent System Operator (“NYISO”) and the California ISO (“CAISO”). The Southwest Power Pool (“SPP”) is currently the only example of a FERC-approved Day One RTO.31 For the remainder of this paper, the term RTO will be used to refer to a Day Two RTO. This paper will not delve into all of the problems LSEs have experienced with RTOs. To briefly summarize, the CMP was developed to remedy the most problematic aspects of RTO markets at the time, which are briefly outlined below and discussed in greater detail in Consumers in Peril:32 • The use of bid-based offers into the day-ahead and real-time markets provides opportunities for potential exercises of market power through the use of strategic bidding strategies, and the absence of any real relationship between prices and marginal costs reduces the price transparency needed for true competition. • The lucrative nature of the RTO-operated energy and capacity markets had has produced supra-competitive profits and has made incumbent sellers reluctant to enter into long-term bilateral power supply contracts at prices not directly linked to RTO-run spot market prices (plus substantial premiums in some cases). While new market entrants are now interested in long-term power supply contracts to support the financing of their generation projects, it is difficult for them to find www.PublicPower.org 29 “Consumers in Peril: Why RTO-Run Electricity Markets Fail to Produce Just and Reasonable Electric Rates,” APPA, February 2008 available at: http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/ConsumersinPeril.pdf . The policy recommendation to restructure RTO markets appears in Section 5, which is the focus of this document. 30 A “Day Two” RTO refers to a market structure where the RTO manages the transmission grid within its footprint to ensure non-discriminatory transmission access and reliability, runs centralized markets for energy (day-ahead and real-time) priced using locational marginal pricing concepts, and provides financial transmission rights (FTRs) to hedge the associated transmission congestion costs. Depending on the market design, a Day Two RTO may also run centralized markets for ancillary services and capacity. A Day One RTO does not administer centralized spot markets, except perhaps for a balancing market, but does oversee management of the transmission grid for reliability and open-access purposes. 31 SPP is has announced its intent to implement a Day Two market, and the most recent estimate for implementation is March 2014. Integrated Marketplace Project Milestones, SPP Market Working Group, October 25, 2010, http://www.spp.org/section.asp?group=1985&pageID=27 32 See Ch. 4 of “Consumers in Peril: Why RTO-Run Electricity Markets Fail to Produce Just and Reasonable Electric Rates.” APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 7 LSEs in restructured states that are able and willing to enter into longterm contracts to support such projects, due to the shorter-term nature of retail default supply regimes. • Excessive reliance by RTOs on often ineffective market and pricing signals and incentives to address transmission congestion and anticipated capacity shortfalls has substantially increased costs to electric consumers over what they would otherwise be. • Locational capacity markets are producing high capacity prices and opportunities for economic withholding, leading to substantial overpayments for capacity retention and additions. • Hedge funds, investment banks and other financial entities are participating in RTO markets through Financial Transmission Rights (“FTR”) auctions and virtual bids in spot markets, potentially increasing costs to consumers through their speculative activities. Moreover, since the issuance of APPA’s original CMP, actions by states to find alternative means to the centralized capacity markets to develop needed generation at reasonable prices have elicited vehement protests by generators, resulting in FERC-approved changes to the capacity market rules to prevent such state actions. All of these problems point to markets that are inherently uncompetitive, requiring significant interventions from market monitors and other regulators to keep generators from exercising overt market power and raising prices even during non-peak periods. Even with aggressive market monitoring, these RTOs’ market rules and institutions have created a system where the benefits of competition flow disproportionately to owners of existing generation. FERC and the RTOs have been largely unwilling to investigate and acknowledge the problems with these markets.33 In response to a 2008 Government Accountability Office (“GAO”) report, FERC issued a set of proposed RTO performance metrics in February 2010. In its comments on these metrics, filed jointly with the Electricity Consumers Resource Council, APPA stated that the proposed “performance metrics shed little 8 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 33 For example, a 2008 study by the Government Accountability Office (GAO) found that “FERC has not conducted an empirical analysis to measure whether RTOs have achieved these expected benefits or how RTOs or restructuring efforts more generally have affected consumer electricity prices, costs of production, or infrastructure investment.” Electricity Restructuring: FERC Could Take Additional Steps to Analyze Regional Transmission Organizations’ Benefits and Performance, p.55, GAO-08-987, September 2008 (“GAO Report”), http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d08987.pdf. 34 Initial Comments of the American Public Power Association and the Electricity Consumers Resource Council, Docket No. AD10-5-000, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, March 5, 2010. www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/APPAELCONInitialCommentsAD1OS352010asfiled.pdf www.PublicPower.org light on whether such prices are just and reasonable and reflect levels that would be produced in a truly competitive market.”34 Almost half of the commenters stated that the performance metrics were insufficient.35 While the Commission on October 21, 2010, issued a Staff Report on ISO/RTO Performance Metrics,36 the metrics set out in that report continued to omit the fundamental measure requested by APPA and others -- the profits earned by generators from all wholesale electricity markets. In response to the FERC staff metrics, the ISO/RTO Council provided a report to FERC that was essentially an assertion of the many achievements of RTOs, a number of which were unrelated to or unsubstantiated by the actual data presented in the rest of the report.37 FERC then issued a Report to Congress essentially summarizing the RTOs’ own reports.38 In the continued absence of any meaningful FERC investigation into the operation of RTO-run centralized markets and their benefits to consumers, each difficulty in the markets is met by the RTOs themselves with a new, increasingly complicated market and/or pricing incentive, often approved by FERC without sufficient scrutiny of how or whether this new feature will achieve the desired goals. For example, in the face of looming shortfalls in generation capacity, RTOs in the past responded only to complaints of generators that RTO mitigation rules and protocols prevent them from earning sufficient revenues in the energy market to recover the fixed costs or going-forward costs of generating units (the “missing money” problem). In response, the RTOs have created a number of secondary markets, such as those for locational capacity and ancillary services. A number of reports have challenged the validity of the missing money problem and suggested that these secondary markets are even less 35 Reply Comments of the American Public Power Association and the Electricity Consumers Resource Council, Docket No. AD10-5-000, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, March 19, 2010, http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/APPAELCONAD105ReplyComments31910asfiled.p df 36 ISO/RTO Performance Metrics, Commission Staff Report, Docket No. AD10-5-000, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, October 21, 2010, http://www.ferc.gov/legal/staffreports/10-21-10-rto-metrics.pdf. The ISO/RTO Council subsequently issued its report on the data required by the metrics. APPA’s response to that report is at: http://appanet.cms-plus.com/files/PDFs/APPAResponsetoRTOMetricsReport121310.pdf www.PublicPower.org 37 http://www.isorto.org/atf/cf/%7B5B4E85C6-7EAC-40A0-8DC3003829518EBD%7D/2010%20ISO-RTO%20Metrics%20Report.pdf. For APPA’s response to the report, see APPA Calls Recently Released ISO/RTO Market Report ‘Inadequate’, News Release, December 13, 2010, http://appanet.cms-plus.com/files/PDFs/APPAResponsetoRTOMetricsReport121310.pdf 38 Performance Metrics for Independent System Operators and Regional Transmission Organizations, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Office of the Chairman, April 2011, http://www.ferc.gov/industries/electric/indus-act/rto/metrics/report-to-congress.pdf APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 9 competitive than RTO-run spot energy markets.39 And despite the very substantial dollars paid, these markets have resulted in few new generation projects. The most recent example of yet another layer of a complex pricing incentive with the potential to yield lucrative results for generators rather than reliability benefits is PJM’s June 2010 “scarcity pricing” proposal.40 Under this proposal, energy prices could climb up to $2,700 per megawatt-hour (compared to the current cap of $1,000) during times when operating reserves dip below a threshold level. PJM’s Market Monitor described the proposal as a “proposed radical alteration of the PJM market design in a manner that would raise the overall price of wholesale electric service in PJM with no corresponding benefit to its wholesale customers.”41 Further complicating the array of new markets is that they are increasingly linked to each other. Scarcity pricing, for example, would directly impact both the locational capacity and reserves markets. FERC also ordered in Docket No. RM10-17-00042 that RTOs are to pay demand response resources bidding directly into RTO wholesale energy markets the “full LMP” (locational marginal price) in all hours, as long as such dispatch of the demand resource passes a net benefits test. This payment of LMP has no offset to reflect the fact that demand response resources are avoiding the cost of purchasing power from their LSEs, even though these LSEs are incurring the costs to stand ready to serve the retail customers participating in such wholesale demand response bids. Aside from the 10 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 39 See, for example, T. Mount, Investment Performance in Deregulated Markets for Electricity: A Case Study of New York State, report for APPA, September 2007. Available at: http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/StudyMountEMRIreportNYISOCapacity09%2D07.p df. Also, see James Wilson, Raising the Stakes on Capacity Incentives: PJM’s Reliability Pricing Model, report for APPA, February 2008, available at http://publicpower.org/files/PDFs/RPMreport2008.pdf. Reports from the PJM market monitor also concluded that the capacity markets are often not competitive. For example, Joseph Bowring, PJM’s market monitor, concluded that “the market design for capacity leads, almost unavoidably, to structural market power in the capacity market. The capacity market is unlikely ever to approach a competitive market structure in the absence of a substantial and unlikely structural change that results in much greater diversity of ownership.” Analysis of the 2013-2014 RPM Base Residual Auction, Monitoring Analytics, July 14, 2010, p.1, http://www.monitoringanalytics.com/reports/Reports/2010/Analysis_of_2013_2014_RPM_ Base_Residual_Auction_20100714.pdf 40 PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., Compliance Filing, Docket ER09-1063-006 , Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, June 18, 2010, http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/file_list.asp?accession_num=20100621-0201 41 Protest and Compliance Proposal of the Independent Market Monitor for PJM, Docket ER091063-006 , Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, July 18, 2010, p. 2, http://elibrary.ferc.gov/IDMWS/File_list.asp?document_id=13832963, 42 Order No. 745, Demand Response Compensation in Organized Wholesale Energy Markets, 134 FERC ¶ 61,187, 76 Fed. Reg. 16,658 (March 24, 2011). The net benefits test calls for the full LMP to be paid to demand response resources when the cost of payments to demand response is outweighed by the benefits of the decrease in LMP as a result of reduction in load. www.PublicPower.org difficult measurement and verification issues that payment of such dollars to entities that are reducing their retail energy usage raises, there is the separate question of whether the availability of such dollars at wholesale undermines retail efforts to implement demand response using time-differentiated prices, and the substantial investments, e.g., smart grid installations, that often accompany such efforts. While APPA certainly understands the desire to foster demand response as a resource, retail and wholesale programs and pricing need to be harmonized, not enacted in a piecemeal and conflicting fashion. Moreover, the implications of relying on increasingly high levels of demand response to provide the equivalent of generation capacity needs to be fully understood, given the absolute need to maintain reliable RTO operations. The layering on of new markets and pricing policies has created such a level of complexity that highly sophisticated entities have a built-in advantage in participating in RTO markets. Such complexity also impairs transparency and makes the task of market monitoring more difficult. www.PublicPower.org APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 11 III. Overview of Proposed Market Structure A • • • • PPA developed its Competitive Market Plan to support the following design goals: • Reduced opportunities for the exercise of market power, and sufficient data transparency to identify market power abuses; For load not served by owned resources, an increased emphasis on longterm bilateral contracts (e.g., 5-10 years or longer) to support reliable service to customers at reasonable rates and to finance needed new generation and demand response resources, with minimal dependence on short-term energy markets to obtain power supplies; Provision of open-access non-discriminatory transmission service; Transmission and resource planning to meet reliability and environmental stewardship goals over time at the lowest reasonable cost from the most feasible set of resources, rather than merely to support long-distance, short-term transactions or the agendas of particular transmission or generation project developers; and Minimization of market and operations complexity, and maximum procedural and data transparency for market participants, regulators and the general public. To accomplish these goals, APPA recommended that current RTO Day Two markets be reformed to retain the beneficial functions of RTOs, while modifying or phasing out problematic market design features. Under this plan, an RTO would offer transmission service to support open access to the transmission system, operate a marginal cost-limited single-clearing price “optimization market” for short-term procurement of energy and ancillary services, implement RTO-determined region-wide resource adequacy requirements, and plan for transmission facilities and service needed to support LSE-owned and contracted-for resources. Longer-term bilateral agreements between LSEs and generators/demand-side providers and LSEowned resource arrangements would be the primary methods of procuring resources. APPA concluded, based on communications with APPA’s members and observations of the current markets, that it would be very difficult to radically overhaul the current RTO-operated markets. In particular, it would be difficult to revert to the use of physical transmission rights rather than financial rights. To do so would upend numerous contracts and arrangements to serve load, as well as planned and ongoing construction of power plants. APPA’s Competitive Market Plan therefore would include the following features, which are described in greater detail in this paper: • RTO operation of a residual, marginal cost-limited single-clearing price “optimization market” for balancing and short-term procurement of energy and ancillary services, but without limitations on the quantity of 12 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update www.PublicPower.org power sold through the optimization market. • Use of longer-term bilateral agreements and resource ownership as the primary methods of obtaining generation and demand-side resources. • Power procured through the bilateral contracts would continue to clear through the RTO-operated energy markets, with a financial settlement for the differences made by the contract parties outside of the RTO market. • Non-discriminatory open access to the transmission system and provision of long-term transmission rights to support LSE resource arrangements. • Provision of data on generator costs and optimization market offers to the public on a timely basis. • Centralized RTO dispatch of generation, using actual marginal-cost data as the basis of dispatch, rather than bid-based offers, but retaining the single-clearing price feature. • Phase-out of existing locational capacity markets over a time period long enough to ensure that existing obligations are fulfilled. • Phase-in of RTO-determined resource adequacy requirements for all LSEs to be met through portfolios of generation, demand response and energy efficiency resources. • State supervision of resource procurement for state-regulated IOU LSEs in retail access states, with emphasis on developing a diverse portfolio of resources of varying fuel types and terms. • Public reporting by FERC of RTO market performance metrics that at a minimum include data on revenues earned and costs incurred by generation units. The purpose of emphasizing longer-term bilateral contracts and generation ownership arrangements is to make the market structure more compatible with current financial realities and longer-range system planning for generation, transmission and demand response. Under the current market structure, investment decisions must be based on far-forward expectations of spot and capacity market prices, the volatility of which may discourage the development of appropriate risk-management products and practices.43 The RTO would continue to act as a regional transmission-management entity, but its operations would shift in focus to supporting bilateral resource contracts and owned- generation arrangements, rather than operating expansive centralized spot markets. The RTO would continue to dispatch generation centrally to ensure open-access and reliability, but would provide long-term transmission rights (“LTTRs”) more compatible with the use of bilateral and resource ownership arrangements for long-term power supply. The RTO would perform residual centralized real-time optimization market 43 www.PublicPower.org L.B. Lave, J. Apt and S. Blumsack, Deregulation/Restructuring Part I: Re-Regulation Will Not Fix the Problems, Electricity Journal 2007, 20 (8), pp. 9 – 22. APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 13 functions. APPA expects, however, that under its proposal, sales in the optimization market would constitute a smaller portion of total energy sales. Finally, the distribution side of the market would not change substantially, with regulated distribution utilities still responsible for physical delivery of power supplies to end-use customers.44 The reforms laid out in this paper could not be implemented within a short time frame. It has been over 10 years since Order No. 2000 was issued, encouraging the initial formation of RTOs. The problems with RTO markets have been building ever since, and would take a number of years to address. In recent years, RTO markets have proliferated, increasing the complexity of undertaking any reforms. A number of complex FERC proceedings would be required to develop and approve tariff changes for each RTO, many of which are likely to be contentious. Moreover, there are differences among the RTOs themselves. Implementation of the APPA Plan would therefore need to be tailored on an individual RTO basis. But the longer the industry and FERC wait to begin this important task, the longer it will be before consumers begin to see the benefits of the needed market reforms. APPA recommends as part of its Plan that FERC conduct periodic reviews of wholesale power supply markets in RTO regions, to assess long-term price stability, possible exercises of market power, justness and reasonableness of rates, and reliability. These reviews should encompass a wide array of performance metrics, including measures of profitability. 44 14 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update Third-party retail suppliers may have a diminished role in the new market regime. Retail access policy decisions should still be up to individual states, but competitive retail suppliers would need to be willing and able to meet longer-term resource adequacy requirements applicable to LSEs, either directly or through arrangements with third parties. www.PublicPower.org IV. Role of State Regulatory Agencies W hile much of this paper is focused on the policy decisions FERC and the RTOs must make regarding wholesale market design and regulation, needed reforms to the wholesale markets cannot be accomplished without parallel changes to retail choice state policies. As discussed earlier, there is a significant difference in the degree to which consumers are impacted by RTO markets in states where utilities are vertically integrated and those where the bulk of the power is generated by unregulated power plants. In fact, events over the last few years make clear that problems in the retail access states are the most likely impetus for needed market reforms. Since states are closest to retail customers and see the adverse impacts of federal RTO policies first hand, they are more likely to seek reforms to improve RTO operations in their regions. These recommendations are therefore directed at retail access states with a high percentage of power from merchant generation. Retail access policies would still be left up to individual states, but, under the APPA Plan, competitive LSEs providing service in retail access states would have to meet the more rigorous resource adequacy requirements applicable to LSEs, either directly or through arrangements with third parties. The power purchases that incumbent non-vertically integrated IOU LSEs in retail access states make to support default supply service to retail customers that have not chosen a third-party supplier (often called “standard offer service” or SOS) have a substantial impact on wholesale market prices. In such states, the power supplies that incumbent LSEs use to provide SOS are typically purchased through state-run auctions for relatively short-term (usually two-to four-year) contracts.45 As discussed later in this plan, the prices offered under these contracts are frequently based on forward projections of the prices likely to be set in RTO-run centralized spot markets. The relatively short-term nature of the SOS procurement auctions have therefore actually reinforced the connection between RTO-run spot market prices and bilateral contract prices, rather than allowing bilateral contract prices to act as a check on spot market prices. Generators selling under SOS auction contracts effectively obtain the benefits of RTO spot market pricing, as well as additional risk premiums included in the auction prices. Given such profit opportunities, it is not surprising that other LSEs and large end users attempting to procure wholesale power supplies through bilateral contracts, such as public power systems and large industrials, would find it difficult to obtain reasonably priced contracts. 45 www.PublicPower.org One such auction is the New Jersey Basic Generation Service or BGS auction. Contracts for residential and small business customers last three years with one-third of load procured each year, and commercial and industrial customers are supplied in one-year contracts. A full description of the BGS auction regime can be found at: State of New Jersey, Board of Public Utilities, BGS Auction, http://www.state.nj.us/bpu/divisions/energy/bgs.html APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 15 Changes in state policies that would allow their incumbent LSEs to purchase or build generation facilities or enter into longer-term (e.g., 5-15 year) power supply arrangements to provide SOS to their retail customers would impose needed discipline on the wholesale market. An essential component of APPA’s Competitive Market Plan is a strong recommendation that state public service commissions establish competitive resource procurement processes to develop diversified resource portfolios for incumbent IOU LSEs that no longer have the obligation to serve customers, with a significant portion of their power supplies being obtained under longer-term contracts or owned-generation arrangements. These measures could provide much needed price discipline in RTO-run centralized markets, as well as a steady revenue stream to support construction of new generation resources and investment in demand response technologies.46 Such a statelevel procurement process is described in greater detail in Section X (Resource Adequacy and Planning). APPA recognizes that state commissions may have some reluctance to require the LSEs they regulate to lock-in long-term prices, for fear that prices will subsequently decline, leaving LSEs on the “wrong side” of current market prices. Long-term contracts entered into by many utilities in the 1970s and 1980s were later found to be “above-market,” causing the payment of stranded costs following state-level deregulation.47 The Competitive Market Plan contains two recommendations to hedge the potential long-term contract risk. The first is to procure a portfolio with a blend of long-, medium- and shortterm resource contracts to minimize the price risk associated with any one resource arrangement. Longer-term contracts could be targeted to new generation units and resource arrangements that require more revenue certainty to secure financing and ensure a reasonable cost of capital, while medium- and short- term arrangements could be targeted to older, largely 46 A 2008 report by the Maryland Public Service Commission finds that long-term power purchase agreements (PPAs) would encourage needed generation and lower wholesale market costs. Final Report of the Public Service Commission of Maryland to the Maryland General Assembly Options for Re-Regulation and New Generation, December 2008, p. 28, http://webapp.psc.state.md.us/Intranet/sitesearch/MD%20PSC%20SB400%20Final%20Report%20to %20the%20MD%20General%20Assembly.pdf In a Connecticut proceeding, Levitan & Associates found that “[n]ew generation in Connecticut anchored under a long-term contract should thus help put downward pressure on energy prices in Connecticut,” and that “[f]uel diversity objectives in New England could be promoted through long term contracts.” Comments Of Levitan & Associates, Inc., DPUC Development and Review of Standard Service and Supplier of Last Resort Service Docket 06-01-08PH01 Jan. 30, 2007, pp. 4 and 11, http://www.dpuc.state.ct.us/dockhist.nsf/ f068a53a31082a558525664e00498f40/3bf2ed4f4da8cfe3852573f000640cf6/$FILE/LAI%20C omments%2030Jan07.pdf 47 16 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update Electric Utilities: Deregulation and Stranded Costs, Congressional Budget Office, October 1998, http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/9xx/doc976/stranded.pdf. Of course, in many cases the assets in question were eventually found to be “in the market” rather than “above-market.” www.PublicPower.org depreciated units and other resources that do not demand high up-front capital commitments. The second recommendation, discussed below, is to allow incumbent utilities to construct their own power plants on a going forward basis if there are insufficient or unacceptable options put forth by third-party generators. As part of such an improved SOS resource procurement process, retail access states should allow their incumbent IOU LSEs to consider “self-builds” and “self-provision” of demand response as resource options. In many retail choice states, incumbent LSEs are currently prohibited from building new generation (except perhaps through an unregulated affiliate), even though they still bear responsibility for providing SOS service. The availability of selfbuild options brings additional competitive discipline to bear on third-party suppliers submitting generation supply offers in power supply procurements. While concerns about pending generation supply shortages that were prevalent in 2006 and 2007 have been mitigated by increased demand response and recession-induced load decreases,48 such state-implemented measures to provide additional sources of supply when needed would also reduce potential for tighter supply conditions in the future that could drive up prices,49 especially those resulting from the potential closure of coal plants as will be discussed later in this document. Recent experience with state legislative and regulatory actions to procure new generation resources outside of the centralized capacity markets, and encourage the development of cleaner and more efficient generation, illustrate potential difficulties for undertaking such efforts. These actions, while beneficial to the states’ interests in protecting consumers, improving reliability and reducing power plant emissions, also adversely affect the profits of incumbent power plant owners. As a result, such merchant generators have successfully exerted pressure on the RTOs and FERC to change the rules governing the capacity markets to prevent such state measures in the future. One of the earlier undertakings began with Connecticut’s signing of longterm contracts with a number of new peaking units in accordance with www.PublicPower.org 48 These changes can be illustrated by the findings of the Long-Term Reliability Assessment (LTRA) issued annually by the North American Electric Reliability Corporation (NERC). In the 2007 LTRA, NERC stated that: “Long-term capacity margins are still inadequate.” In the 2010 LRTA, released in October 2010, NERC concluded that “NERC Regions and subregions have sufficient plans for capacity to meet customer demand over the next ten years.” http://www.nerc.com/page.php?cid=4|61 49 A 2009 Wall Street Journal article notes: “Some wonder whether the deregulated markets of the Eastern U.S., Midwest, Texas and California will be especially hard hit if demand comes roaring back. That’s because utilities in these markets no longer are required to build new resources. It’s left up to the power generators to determine when the market conditions are ripe.” Rebecca Smith, “Electricity Prices Plummet,” The Wall Street Journal, August 12, 2009, http://online.wsj.com/article/SB125003563550224269.html, Subscription required. APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 17 legislation passed in 2005 and 2007 aimed at lowering congestion costs, spurring new generation, demand response and renewable energy.50 When ISO New England’s Forward Capacity Market (FCM) auctions began in early 2008, Connecticut bid contracted units into the auction as “price takers.” More recently, in early 2011, Governor Christie of New Jersey signed legislation and the Maryland Public Service Commission issued a draft RFP for the procurement of new generation resources through long-term contracts with the distribution utilities.51 In both cases, the states were responding to the absence of new, efficient and cleaner generation resulting from PJM’s RPM and concerns about future reliability. The contracted-for capacity would then be bid into the capacity markets at zero or a very low price to ensure that it would clear the auction, with the secondary benefit of a lower capacity price for all capacity that cleared the auction. In New England, the capacity price has reached the floor price in the last auction and the lower bound of the price collar in the prior three auctions.52 While it is not certain that the Connecticut resource bids directly caused the low capacity price, which may have resulted more from the large quantity of demand response bids, the coincidence of these state-procured resources and the low price spurred a complaint with FERC by the merchant generator association (the New England Power Generators Association or “NEPGA”). Similarly, in response to concerns over a possible future reduction in capacity market revenue from the New Jersey and Maryland actions,53 the PJM Power Providers or “P3” filed a complaint with FERC. In response to these complaints, both RTOs proposed changes in their capacity markets to prevent the price-lowering effects of such separately procured resources. In April 2011, FERC issued its orders in both dockets.54 At the core of each 50 Public Act 05-01, An Act Concerning Energy Independence, July 2005, http://www.cga.ct.gov/2005/ACT/Pa/pdf/2005PA-00001-R00HB-07501SS1-PA.pdf; and Public Act 07-242, An Act Concerning Electricity and Energy Efficiency, June 2007, http://www.cga.ct.gov/2007/ACT/PA/2007PA-00242-R00HB-07432-PA.htm 51 New Jersey P.L.2011, Chapter 9, Senate, No. 2381, §§1,3,4 - C.48:3-98.2 to 48:3-98.4 §5 C.48:3-60.1, http://www.njleg.state.nj.us/2010/Bills/AL11/9_.PDF; Notice Of Comment Period On Request For Proposals For New Generating Facilities, Maryland Public Service Commission, December 29, 2010, http://webapp.psc.state.md.us/Intranet/Casenum/NewIndex3_VOpenFile.cfm?ServerFilePath=C:\Casenum\9200-9299\9214\\34.pdf. 52 FCM Calendars and Auction Results, http://www.isone.com/markets/othrmkts_data/fcm/cal_results/index.html 53 Monitoring Analytics conducted analyses of the New Jersey legislation and Maryland PSC draft RFP showing a reduction in capacity revenues of $3 billion dollars per year ($2 billion from New Jersey and $1 billion from Maryland). http://www.monitoringanalytics.com/reports/Reports/2011/NJ_Assembly_3442_Impact_on_PJM_Capacity_Market.pdf; and http://www.monitoringanalytics.com/reports/Reports/2011/IMM_Comments_to_MDPSC_Case_No_9214_20110128.pdf 18 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update www.PublicPower.org APPA is most concerned by the Commission’s holdings in these two orders, and in particular its seeming lack of recognition or respect for the states’ traditional role in assuring that retail electric service is both reliable and reasonably priced. APPA has in the past called for a respectful dialogue on these issues, and renews that call here. order are rule changes that will impose minimum prices on offers from new natural gas generators. As a result, new natural gas-fired resources procured by either the state or another LSE, such as a public power utility or a cooperative, would be likely to have their low-bids replaced with a higher offer price, making it very difficult for such resources to clear the market. These rule changes are a significant threat to both LSE self-supply and to statesponsored power procurements. Following the PJM decision, Lee Solomon, President of the New Jersey Board of Public Utilities, stated that FERC’s order “does not address the failure of the PJM market to deliver new capacity which is desperately needed to reduce New Jersey’s energy prices, and to replace aging, dirty, and inefficient generation facilities.” President Solomon also stated that the BPU plans to pursue “options available to us that are outside of FERC’s jurisdiction,” concluding that he does “not believe that New Jersey forfeited its sovereignty when PJM became the regional transmission operator.”55 APPA is most concerned by the Commission’s holdings in these two orders, and in particular its seeming lack of recognition or respect for the states’ traditional role in assuring that retail electric service is both reliable and reasonably priced. APPA has in the past called for a respectful dialogue on these issues, and renews that call here. www.PublicPower.org 54 Order Accepting Proposed Tariff Revisions, Subject To Conditions, And Addressing Related Complaint, 135 FERC ¶ 61,022 (April 12, 2011), http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/common/OpenNat.asp?fileID=12617771; and Order On Paper Hearing And Order On Rehearing, 135 FERC ¶ 61,029 (April 13, 2011), http://elibrary.ferc.gov/idmws/File_list.asp?document_id=13909713 55 News Release, New Jersey Board of Public Utilities, April 13, 2011, http://www.state.nj.us/bpu/newsroom/news/pdf/20110413a.pdf APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 19 20 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update www.PublicPower.org V. Bilateral Contracts O ne of the core features of APPA’s RTO market redesign proposal is that LSEs would serve their loads with a combination of owned generation/demand-side resources and generation/demand-side resources obtained under longer- term bilateral contracts. Market participants (wholesale buyers and sellers) could enter into any contractual arrangement acceptable to both parties, subject to state and RTO requirements governing the resource portfolio of each LSE and the eligibility of the seller for market-based rate authority (as discussed below). APPA is not in this Plan recommending any requirements for LSEs to enter into bilateral contracts, nor does this plan place any restrictions on the amount or percentage of power purchased through the optimization market. Rather, the reforms proposed here are likely to both incent and remove barriers to bilateral contracting, and reduce potential for excess earnings in the current market structure. An important component of the Competitive Market Plan is the phase-out of existing locational capacity markets. Payments established under auctions for future delivery years would still be honored for their terms, but going forward past that time, generation owners and demand response providers would need to make contractual arrangements to sell their resources, or sell their resources into the RTO’s optimization market without the financial backstop of separate capacity market payments. To support the financing of new power plants, ownership arrangements or bilateral contracts of at least 10 to 15 years in length would likely be needed. Such arrangements and contracts would also provide needed price stability for LSEs and their retail customers. APPA, however, is not in this proposal specifying minimum or specific contract lengths and terms. Instead we recommend, and expect, that each LSE would likely develop a portfolio of diverse resources of varying lengths and terms. The Competitive Market Plan is intended to improve the overall market environment by making a significant number of long-term resource arrangements of 10 years or longer readily available to buyers and sellers. The RTO’s optimization market would allow for residual optimization of LSE energy supply arrangements and balancing in real-time. APPA originally proposed these market structure changes in response to reports from APPA members and large end-use customers that in RTO markets, long-term, reasonably-priced bilateral contracts were difficult to arrange (especially full-requirements contracts).56 Many buyers reported 56 www.PublicPower.org Communications with APPA members, and testimony summarized in “Executives describe real-world problems with RTOs,” Public Power Daily, Feb. 29, 2008, http://publicpower.org/newsletters/ppdailydetail.cfm?ItemNumber=21269&sn.ItemNumber=0 (Login required) APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 21 that the high prices sellers could obtain in the bid-based RTO-run spot markets discouraged the signing of long-term contracts, or resulted in contract offers directly linked to spot market prices.57 Studies of bilateral markets in RTO regions have shown that such RTO markets pose impediments to reasonably priced long-term bilateral contracting.58 APPA now believes that there is an additional reason to foster the signing of at least some longer-term generation contracts that can support the development of new resources—the need to revamp the nation’s generation fleet over the coming years to address environmental concerns. The Environmental Protection Agency (“EPA”) is currently conducting a series of rulemakings to regulate emissions of greenhouse gases from large stationary sources, including power plants. In addition, the EPA is in the middle of a substantial number of other rulemakings, dealing with coal ash, mercury, and other hazardous air pollutants, criteria pollutants (smog), water use in once-through cooling systems, and a number of other items. As these various rules go into effect, their cumulative effect will likely make it uneconomic for generators to continue to operate a substantial number of existing coal-fired power plants. Estimates of coal plant closures range from 30 to 70 gigawatts (GW) of coal generation within the next ten years, with most estimates trending towards the higher end of this range.59 A substantial portion of that retiring capacity will have to be replaced, mostly with natural -gas- fired units. And coal-fired power plants constitute a very substantial portion of the generation fleets of a number of RTOs. 22 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 57 For example, Walter Brockway of Alcoa testified before FERC that: “We found no supplier willing to discuss supplying us with anything other than electricity priced to reflect peak load generation, as well as placing on us all the risk of trans-mission congestion.” Technical Conference to Examine the State of Competition in Wholesale Power Markets, Docket AD07-7-000, May 8, 2007, http://www.ferc.gov/EventCalendar/Files/20070508083948-Brockway,%20Alcoa.pdf. 58 E. Hausman, R. Hornby and A. Smith, Bilateral Contracting in RTO Markets, Synapse Energy Economics, April 2008, http://publicpower.org/files/PDFs/EMRISynapseBilateralsReport2008.pdf; also, see the discussion of fixed-price contracts and supplier behavior in Frank A. Wolak and Shaun D. McRae, Merger Analysis in Restructured Electricity Supply Industries: The Proposed PSEG and Exelon Merger, November 2007, ftp://zia.stanford.edu/pub/papers/pseg_exelon_merger.pdf 59 Studies of projected coal plant closures have been undertaken by: The North American Electric Reliability Corporation (10 - 35 GW of coal and 40 - 70 GW of all capacity by 2018), 2010 Special Reliability Scenario Assessment, October, 2010, Table IV-6, http://www.nerc.com/files/EPA_Scenario_Final.pdf; Credit Suisse Equity Research (60 GW of coal capacity between 2013 and 2017), Growth From Subtraction: Impact of EPA Rules on Power Markets, September 23, 2010, http://op.bna.com/env.nsf/id/jstn-8actja/$File/suisse.pdf; The Brattle Group (50 – 66 GW of coal capacity by 2020), Potential Coal Plant Retirements Under Emerging Environmental Regulations, December 8, 2010, http://www.brattle.com/_documents/UploadLibrary/Upload898.pdf, and FBR Capital (30 – 70 GW in the next few years), EPA regs may shut 70,000 MW of U.S. coal plants: FBR, Reuters, December 13, 2010 http://www.reuters.com/article/2010/12/13/us-utilities-epa-coal-idUSTRE6BC3JN20101213 www.PublicPower.org In addition to the financial incentives for owners of existing merchant generation to constrain the capacity supply, many current RTO market structures simply cannot support the development of new resources by newer market entrants. Unlike generation owned by a vertically- integrated utility, the future earnings of merchant generation owners would be higher for their remaining existing plants if a portion of generation is shut down and the supply of power becomes constrained. One likely scenario is for merchant generators to strategically close the plants that are the most costly to retrofit while allowing the remaining plants, especially nuclear and lower emission coal plants, to benefit from the resulting higher prices.60 Several recent analyses have found that the closure of coal plants is in fact likely to be greater for merchant units. The Brattle Group found that most of the coal plants likely to retire will be merchant units, accounting for 64 to 76 percent of merchant coal capacity compared to 1 to 4 percent of regulated coal, whose regulated owners would be much more likely to retrofit the plants.61 APPA therefore believes the industry will need to make substantial investments in new gas-fired and renewable generation resources as these coal-fired power plants leave the fleet. In addition to the financial incentives for owners of existing merchant generation to constrain the capacity supply, many current RTO market structures simply cannot support the development of new resources by newer market entrants. Such generation projects take time to construct, and they generally require secure financing, anchored by long-term (ten-year or more) power purchase agreements or other “take-away” commitments.62 This problem www.PublicPower.org 60 For example, Credit Suisse notes that “the retrofit / closure decision will not occur in a vacuum such that plants ‘on the bubble’ for investment could be attractively economic as other plants are pulled from the market.” Credit Suisse Equity Research, p. 36. Similarly, Fitch Ratings concluded that: “Merchant generation that does not rely on coal (or coal-fired generation that is already highly controlled) could increase its profitability if a significant portion of coal-fired generation in the same region is retired and heat rates rise in the region due to stringent enforcement of new EPA rules.” Time to Retire? US Coal Plants in Environmental Crosshairs, FitchRatings, February 2011, p. 2 http://www.fitchratings.com/creditdesk/reports/report_frame.cfm?rpt_id=604365 61 The Brattle Group, p. 6 62 In comments submitted by Competitive Power Ventures (CPV) to the Maryland Public Service Commission on RPM, CPV attached several letters from lenders asserting that long-term contracts are critical for obtaining financing for new generation projects. For example, the Bank of Tokyo-Mitsubishi wrote that it “favor[s] the projects which operate in markets with transparent and stable regulatory regimes and projects which benefit from long-term fixedprice power purchase agreements with investment grade counterparties.” Comments of CPV Maryland, LLC, In the Matter of the Reliability Pricing Model And the 2013/2014 Delivery Base Year Residual Auction Results, Maryland Public Service Commission, Administrative Docket PC22, October 1, 2010, Attachment B, http://webapp.psc.state.md.us/Intranet/AdminDocket/NewIndex3_VOpenFile.cfm?ServerFilePath=C%3A%5CAdminDocket%5CPublicConferences%5CPC22%5C35%2Epdf 63 For a detailed discussion of the greater adverse impact on reliability and prices in RTO regions resulting from EPA regulations, see Issue Brief: Why New CO2 Regulations Could Produce Windfall Profits and Unproductive Costs for Consumers, American Public Power Association, March 2011, http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/IssueBriefWindfallProfitsandEPARegsMarch2011.pdf APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 23 will be especially pronounced in RTOs with restructured retail markets.63 APPA does not expect that increased reliance on longer-term bilateral contracts and owned generation will immediately produce lower prices. It is, however, likely to produce more stable and reasonable prices in the long run. Shorter-term power supply contracts of three years or less, such as those procured to provide SOS, frequently include generation prices above the spot prices set in RTO markets, in part due to the inclusion of risk premiums.64 Diversified LSE resource portfolios that include longerterm contracts of 10, 20 or more years may still entail some risk premium because suppliers would be absorbing the risk of reduced demand. But such premiums are likely to be mitigated by APPA’s proposed price formation mechanism for the optimization market. This market structure should better discipline spot prices, which in turn should discipline bilateral contract prices formed through responses to LSE requests for proposals, where suppliers of generation and demand response must compete directly with each other, as well as with the prospect of LSEowned projects. Any risk premiums that suppliers do require are likely to be exceeded by the benefits of greater price stability. There is not sufficient data to ascertain the current status of bilateral contracting in RTO regions. For example, PJM’s State of the Market reports provide data on the percentage of power purchased through bilateral contracts, self-supply and spot markets. In the 2010 State of the Market Report, these data show that 11.8 percent of the power purchased in the real-time and 4.9 percent in the day-ahead market was sold through bilateral contracts, a decrease of 1.1 percentage points from the prior year for the real-time market, and no change in the day-ahead market.65 But PJM does not break down these data according to the length of the contract or the pricing terms. Theoretically, a one-week agreement to sell power at a price indexed directly to prices set in PJM’s spot market would be counted as a bilateral contract. 24 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 64 Testimony of Kenneth Rose, Ph.D., Independent Consultant, before the Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission, November 6, 2008, http://www.puc.state.pa.us/electric/pdf/EnBancWEM/Ttmy-Kenneth_Rose110608.pdf , p. 8 – 11. A presentation by Pennsylvania PUC Chairman James H. Cawley noted that PECO’s default price “includes a risk premium to account for future load level uncertainty.” Philadelphia Business Journal, 2010 Energy Summit, October 28, 2010, http://www.puc.state.pa.us/electric/pdf/PPT-PBJ_Presentation102810Cawley.pdf 65 2010 State of the Market Report for PJM, Section 2, Monitoring Analytics, March 20, 2011, p. 106-107, http://www.monitoringanalytics.com/reports/PJM_State_of_the_Market/2010/2010som-pjm-volume2-sec2.pdf. These data are reported at the level of the parent company such that bilateral sales between generation-owing and load- serving regulated utility affiliates would be reported as self-supply and not as a bilateral contract. In the State of the Market reports for 2008 and earlier, these data were also reported for the billing company which reported that about 96 percent of real-time sales were made through bilateral contracts. www.PublicPower.org No data on bilateral contracts was found in the ISO New England and the Midwest ISO State of the Market reports.66 New York ISO reports only on “physical bilateral contracts,” which involve settlements with the New York ISO for transmission charges and between the parties privately for the commodity prices and do not include bilateral contracts that are settled privately. Physical bilateral contracts comprised about 50 percent of the day-ahead load in New York City and Long Island, 40 percent in East upstate, and 60 percent in West upstate in 2008, the last year for which these data are available.67 As with PJM, there is no information provided on length or pricing terms. Moreover, the RTO definition of a bilateral contract does not require that a contract be tied to associated capacity, such as a specific generating unit. Some of the bilateral contracts are sales of power to utilities for the provision of standard offer service load, whose prices are often based on RTO spot market prices. These SOS contracts need not be tied to specific generating units, and even if the supplier is delivering electrons from its own generating assets, prices are still tied to the spot markets, and not the costs of producing electricity from such units.68 In many other cases, the bilateral contracts used in RTO regions are standardized and the power product choices do not include capacity obligations or other provisions that would support new generation infrastructure. For example, the EEI/NEMA Master Agreement used in many eastern RTOs contains standardized language for product definitions, credit requirements and buyer/seller obligations.69 A typical contract will specify a delivery point, price, quantity and time frame (for example, “20 MW delivered at [a selected trading hub] during on-peak hours in calendar year 2008”). These contracts also include “liquidated damages” or other liability provisions outlining financial responsibility for www.PublicPower.org 66 An e-mail from ISO New England Customer Services, Dec. 24, 2008, in response to an APPA inquiry about bilateral contracting data states that “we do not report the bilateral contract or spot market activities.” No response was received from MISO, although the MISO 2009 State of the Market Report notes that the small portion of capacity clearing the Voluntary Capacity Market indicates that “most LSEs’ capacity needs [are] satisfied through owned capacity or bilateral purchases.” (p. 24), http://www.midwestiso.org/publish/Document/55f670_12a43afcc88_7f610a48324a/2009%20State%20of%20the%20Market%20Report.pdf?action=download&_pro perty=Attachment 67 2008 State of the Market Report, New York ISO, p. 68-69 http://www.nyiso.com/public/webdocs/documents/market_advisor_reports/2008/NYISO_2008_SOM_Final_9-2-09.pdf (The 2009 and 2010 State of the Market Reports contain less detail and do not provide separate bilateral load data.) 68 For example, see Letter from Constellation Energy to President Miller and Speaker Busch, May 31, 2006, http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1004440/000110465906038686/a0612885_1ex99d1.html. 69 The provisions of the EEI/NEMA Master Contract are available at http://www.eei.org/industry_issues/legal_and_business_practices/master_contract. APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 25 failure to perform under the terms of the contract. Under such agreements, a failure to supply power is not a breach of the agreement, but merely triggers the obligation on the part of the buyer to “cover” by obtaining replacement supplies at whatever price the buyer can obtain in the market at that time, with the seller paying the difference between the contract and market price. Such contracts may work well for financial parties interested in trading contracts, but are less than ideal for LSEs attempting to assemble a portfolio of power supply resources that can in fact be used to serve load.70 Under APPA’s proposal, a truly vibrant bilateral market would rely less on standardized contracts developed primarily for trading purposes, and more on individually negotiated agreements sufficient to support the development of new generation and demand-side resources. In October 2008, FERC required each RTO to dedicate a portion of its web site for market participants to post offers to buy or sell power on a long-term basis, concluding “that greater transparency from a bulletin board for long-term power sales will benefit long-term contracting.”71 A multiple-RTO bulletin board was set up in response, but appears to have been of limited use. Periodic visits since February 2010 show no more than four contract offers posted at a given time. All but one of the contracts displayed have been just one year in length. On September 21, 2010, only one contract offer was posted -- for the sale of 2 MW of capacity for a oneyear time frame. No offers were posted on the bulletin board, when it was again visited on April 15, 2011. It is not clear why this bulletin board has not been more widely used, but the creation of a more viable market for bilateral contracting will require much more substantive market reforms than an on-line bulletin board. 26 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 70 Many “net buyer” APPA members have found the standard EEI/NEMA contract terms and options unsuitable for their own power procurement needs. APPA therefore developed a package of modifications to that contract (suitable for use by such buyers), available upon request. 71 Wholesale Competition in Regions with Organized Electric Markets, Order No. 719, 125 FERC ¶ 61,071, 73 Fed. Reg. 64,100 (October 28, 2008), p.165 www.PublicPower.org VI. Market Power W ithout new generation entry or a significant expansion in demand response and efficiency investments, generators may still have market power in the long-term bilateral contract markets, just as they now do in spot and locational capacity markets. This market power cannot be wished away. Generators are likely to attempt to exercise market power even if APPA’s Competitive Market Plan is implemented, particularly in the early days of new market operations. Still, there are a number of reasons to believe that market power may become less of a problem (at least in the long run) and that markets would be more competitive under APPA’s Plan: • In current Day Two RTO markets, suppliers interact with each other frequently, since the RTO auctions clear on very short time intervals. This repeated interaction allows generators to observe the strategies of other bidders and respond in kind, encouraging coordinated bidding strategies and even tacit collusion.72 A recent study found that the entities bidding generation units frequently are not the owners, and can change their contractual control of the units, possibly gaining important knowledge regarding their competitors’ units.73 Bilateral contracting processes, especially ones conducted under formal requests for proposals (RFPs) subject to public scrutiny, such as state-supervised procurements, would be less likely to be subject to such ongoing coordination. • Bilateral contracting provides a greater opportunity for customers and suppliers to negotiate “customized” products to meet the supplier’s and customer’s particular needs, rather than being force-fit into a standardized form agreement. Capacity prices arranged through contracts negotiated under RFP procedures could better reflect the fixed costs attributable to different resources, whereas centralized capacity markets pay the same price to all resources regardless of whether they are a new resource facing a tight financing market, an existing and largely depreciated facility or a demand response offer with limited upfront investments required. Contract lengths could also be tailored to the type of resource – shorter-term for energy efficiency measures or longerterm for new capital-intensive generation projects. • Bilateral contracting affords the customer the ability to select among different counter-party suppliers based on creditworthiness and other non-price factors relevant to performance over the long term. • Compared to transactions in a spot or short-term market, longer-term www.PublicPower.org 72 Experiments at Carnegie Mellon and Cornell “show that hourly auction markets are ideally designed to teach participants to manipulate the market to raise profit.” Lester Lave, Jay Apt, and Seth Blumsack, Deregulation/Restructuring, Where Should We Go from Here? Carnegie Mellon Electricity Industry Center, 2007, p. 14, http://wpweb2.tepper.cmu.edu/ceic/papers/ceic-07-07.asp 73 John Kwoka, Finnegan Professor of Economics , The Effect of Cross-Control on Bidding Behavior and Prices in Electricity Auction Markets, Northeastern University, September 2010, http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/kwokacrosscontrol.pdf APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 27 bilateral arrangements provide revenue stability that makes it possible for potential suppliers to finance capital-intensive generation projects at more reasonable capital costs, reducing barriers to entry into the generation market.74 • Within a day-ahead or hour-ahead time frame, many suppliers have operational constraints (unit commitment, ramping, etc.) that keep them from being active bidders in RTO-run spot markets. Since there is more operational flexibility built into a long-term bilateral contract, a given buyer could have more potential counterparties. • Because the Competitive Market Plan would provide the transmission access and financial rights necessary for LSEs to have more and better power supply choices, including self-build and ownership of generation if they receive non-competitive supply offers, LSEs should in the long run have fewer problems with market power being exercised in the bilateral market. To incent participation in bilateral markets, APPA is also proposing that generators in each RTO region that pass the FERC’s relevant market-based rate screens should be permitted to sell at market-based rates in bilateral forward markets. The screens used to determine market power should include, at a minimum, the existing measures used by FERC and individual RTO market monitors, such as PJM’s “three pivotal supplier” test. However, to guard against the exercise of generation market power, APPA believes that FERC should separately assess market-based rate applicants’ generation market power in long-term power supply product markets. To the extent that applicants do not pass such long-term market power screens, their marketbased rate authority would be appropriately conditioned or, if merited, revoked. FERC must also ensure that RTO Market Monitors (“MMs”) are truly independent and have all of the resources necessary to perform their functions. As APPA recommended in Consumers in Peril, RTO MMs should have the full cooperation of market participants in data gathering, including access to company-specific financial information and generating unit cost and operating data, as well as sufficient resources to carry out their duties. RTO MMs should also monitor bilateral contract markets, and act on complaints regarding anticompetitive behavior by sellers or buyers in those markets. 74 28 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update This is especially relevant in light of the recent economic downturn. A 2009 study commissioned for the Maryland Public Service Commission found that: “The breakdown in the capital markets and recent credit implosion make it more difficult for new merchant resources to attract financing on competitive terms absent long-term contracts with creditworthy counterparties.” Financial Risk Analysis of the Return to Rate Base Regulation , Levitan & Associates, Inc. & Kaye Scholer LLP, March 11, 2009, http://webapp.psc.state.md.us/Intranet/sitesearch/Kaye%20Scholer_Supplement%20to%20Final%20Report_Financial%20Risk%20Anal ysis%20of%20the%20Return%20to%20Rate%20Base%20Regulation.pdf www.PublicPower.org Moreover, MM State of the Market reports should provide much clearer and detailed information on bilateral contracts, indicating the length of such contracts, whether they are backed by the capacity of specific generating units or other appropriate arrangements, and whether prices are fixed or indexed to RTO prices. APPA, however, remains quite concerned that due to the high concentration in wholesale power supply markets, exercise of generation market power in bilateral markets could indeed occur even if APPA’s proposed reforms are implemented. For this reason, APPA proposes that FERC conduct a review of regional bilateral wholesale markets three years after implementation of APPA’s Competitive Market Plan, to investigate whether market power remains a substantial concern. If the commission finds that market power exercise is a problem in bilateral markets in RTO regions, appropriate modifications should be made to FERC’s market-based rate regulations and RTO market rules to address this problem. www.PublicPower.org APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 29 VII. Residual Short-Term and Imbalance Services: The Optimization Market B ecause generator availability and customer demand cannot be perfectly predicted, and electricity cannot (yet) be stored economically in sufficiently large quantities, APPA’s proposal includes an RTO-operated residual “optimization” market. This market would allow for the co-optimization of offers by generators to sell excess energy and ancillary services, and for LSEs to obtain economy energy and clear imbalances. The optimization market also would provides an opportunity for the sale of variable generation75 not committed under bilateral agreements and allows for the purchase of replacement power for variable generation not available at a given time. APPA believes it is not in the interest of either buyers or sellers to place set limits on the percentage of load that can be met through the optimization market. Such limits reduce needed flexibility for LSEs, including their ability to purchase power from variable generation resources, and restrict the flexibility of generators (especially variable generators) as well. APPA’s proposed RTO-run optimization market is designed to minimize the size of the spot market and encourage bilateral contracting for load not served by owned resources to the maximum extent possible without unduly restricting market participant options. Key design features of the optimization market include: 1) Generator offers to sell into the optimization market would be limited to no more than their short-run marginal costs (SRMC). The SRMC includes only those costs that vary with the level of output, primarily fuels and operations, maintenance and administrative costs that vary with output. (For example, periodic inspection, replacement and repair of system components would be included because such maintenance depends upon the level of output.76) Opportunity costs would not be included in the calculation of the SRMC77, including for ancillary services, which will be co-optimized with energy dispatch. 30 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 75 By “variable generation” APPA means resources that have little control over when they generate due to their dependence on renewable “fuels,” e.g., wind and solar resources. 76 Serkan Bahceci, Julia Frayer, Amr Ibrahim, and Sanela Pecenkovic, A Comparative Analysis of Actual Locational Marginal Prices in the PJM Market and Estimated Short-Run Marginal Costs: 2003-2006, London Economics International, Section 5.2, February 2007, http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/LEIReport2012007.pdf 77 An example of the potential problems arising from the inclusion of opportunity costs can be seen in PJM’s Regulation Market. Participants in this market must submit cost-based offers, and if they fail the three pivotal supplier test, their offers are capped at the lower of the pricebased or cost-based offer, plus a margin and opportunity costs. Changes to the margin and the calculation of opportunity costs increased the cost of Regulation and led PJM’s Market Monitor to conclude that the results of the Regulation Market were not competitive. 2010 State of the Market Report for PJM, Section 6, Monitoring Analytics, March 20, 2011, p. 448-9, http://www.monitoringanalytics.com/reports/PJM_State_of_the_Market/2010/2010-sompjm-volume2-sec6.pdf www.PublicPower.org Limited-run resources (e.g., generation units subject to air quality limitations on run times, and hydro units that must be operated for water use and recreational purposes as well as power supply production) would be allowed to include opportunity costs in the event that they are dispatched during a time when energy prices are lower than they would otherwise earn. Generators participating in RTO-run markets (whether the generators are inside the RTO footprint or importing into the RTO region) would be required to submit auditable SRMC information on the company’s entire portfolio of generation units to the MM. These data would be available to the public on RTO Web web sites, as would the offers submitted into the market. Any differences between supply offer curves submitted to the RTO optimization market and the cost data held by the MM would need to be justified by the generator upon request by the MM.78 A potential difficulty with implementation of the SRMC offer cap is that the generators will have an incentive to inflate their costs. APPA therefore recommends that FERC develop proxy costs based on available databases or individual supplier data,79 as well as cost data submitted for units of similar ages and technologies. Owners of units whose costs exceeded proxy cost data would be asked to provide additional documentation to the MM explaining the differential. If this could not be supplied, their offers would be capped at the proxy cost. Even in the absence of a cost cap on offers into the optimization market, APPA strongly recommends that all data on offers to sell into wholesale energy markets be provided to the public on the next operating day, along with operating cost data submitted to the RTO, with the identities of the generating units unmasked. This would allow third parties to evaluate market performance and behavior in a way that only MMs currently can, enhancing transparency. To facilitate demand response participation in these markets, demand response offers would not be subject to the cost disclosure requirement; instead they would submit load-reduction demand curves or minimum price offers above which they would pledge to curtail a specified amount of load. Demand response offers clearing the market would receive the LMP less an appropriate offset to reflect the serving LSE’s cost of providing retail electric service to the reducing customer.80 78 79 80 www.PublicPower.org The existence of these differences would depend on the frequency with which generators submit cost data to RTOs. Very short-term swings in fuel prices, for example, might cause actual generator costs to deviate from the cost data held by the RTO. (One possible alternative would be to include some fluctuating fuel-specific index component in generator cost submissions.) William H. Dunn, Jr., Data Required for Market Oversight, December 2007, p. 7 and footnote 5, http://appanet.cms-plus.com/files/PDFs/dunn2007.pdf This issue is discussed in great detail in the record of FERC Docket No. RM10-17-000. See, e.g., Post-Technical Conference Comments of APPA, filed October 13, 2010, available at http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/APPAPostTCDRcommentsRM1017101310asfiled.pdf APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 31 2) LSEs would be required to demonstrate to the RTO that they possess adequate amounts of generation capacity (either owned or contracted for) and demand-side resources to meet projected future needs. This RTO-established resource adequacy requirement for individual LSEs would prevent them from “leaning” on the optimization market and avoiding contracts for or investments in generation and demandside resources. It would also prevent the potential exercise of “buyer market power” (to the extent it might exist, a point which APPA does not concede), by imposing an obligation on buyers to enter into contract arrangements with sellers. Close coordination between regional and state-level policies and between RTOs and the state regulatory authorities in their footprints would be required to develop these resource requirements. The RTO would be responsible for determining the overall required level of reserves within its footprint, while state (or local) authorities would determine acceptable resource portfolios and other power supply attributes, e.g., contract terms, fuel mixes, and demand-side/generation ratios for their respective LSEs. The resource adequacy provisions of the APPA Plan are discussed further in Section X. 3) A “must offer” requirement into the optimization market would apply to available resources, including resources not scheduled to serve loads under LSE ownership arrangements or bilateral agreements. This requirement would limit opportunities for strategic withholding behavior. Limited-run resources (e.g., generation units subject to air quality limitations on run times, and hydro units that must be operated for water use and recreational purposes as well as power supply production) would be exempted from the must offer requirement under most circumstances. Participation of variable resources, of course, would also be subject to their availability. Owners of generation would be required to submit a schedule of planned maintenance or refueling outages to the RTO and to demonstrate compliance with the must offer requirement periodically with the RTO. Providers of demand-side resources would be required to offer their resources and products into the optimization market to the extent required by any contractual or tariff provisions to which they had agreed. Another critical issue in designing a new RTO optimization market is the methodology used to establish prices. Current RTO markets use singleclearing-price auctions, where the market-clearing price is paid to all generators offering a price below the highest accepted offer, irrespective of their individual offers. To avoid too dramatic a departure from current market design and in an effort to achieve a compromise, APPA’s proposal would retain, at least initially, the single-clearing-price structure for use with the optimization market. Because of past issues with the single-clearing-price mechanism, however, APPA believes FERC should assess the operation of the 32 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update www.PublicPower.org revamped optimization market with this pricing mechanism no later than three years after the start of the market, with a focus on the restructured states where most generation is unregulated, to determine whether further market design changes are necessary to achieve just and reasonable rates, and therefore benefits to consumers. The ability to earn short-term profits above SRMC could, at the margin, drive some lower-cost resources into the RTO’s spot markets.81 Simultaneously, the single-clearing-price auction would provide short-run and long-run price incentives for LSEs to develop longer-term portfolios of owned and contracted-for resources, to reduce reliance on the optimization market. However, the ability of bidders to engage in behavior intended to increase the single clearing price well above the marginal cost of even the clearing resource, (e.g., so-called “hockey stick bidding”), to the mutual benefit of all resource providers being paid the clearing price, would be greatly reduced by the SRMC-based offer requirement. Even more than short-term energy markets, ancillary services markets are particularly susceptible to the exercise of market power, in part because some services can be supplied only by a limited number of providers.82 Given the cost-based offer and must-offer requirements in this proposal, the RTO can co-optimize supply offers across the energy and ancillary services markets. Under such a co-optimization, the RTO would simultaneously dispatch energy and ancillary services centrally,83 paying generators meeting the technical criteria and selected to supply ancillary services on a cost-reimbursable basis, if they are not dispatched. www.PublicPower.org 81 In theory, at the margin the uniform-price auction structure would also provide incentives for investment in low-cost generation resources. However, this is unlikely to be a significant factor in APPA’s proposed market redesign, in part because it is expected that this optimization market would be a small portion of overall electricity sales. Investment decisions would be driven primarily by the resource planning process. 82 See, e.g., 2010 State of the Market Report for PJM, Section 6 at 418 (“The Regulation Market structure was evaluated as not competitive because the Regulation Market had one or more pivotal suppliers which failed PJM’s three pivotal supplier (TPS) test in73 percent of the hours.”) At 426, the report concluded that “Economic withholding remains a problem in the DASR [Day-Ahead Scheduling Reserve Market].” 83 As recommended by PJM’s MM, operating reserves should continue to be committed on an hour-ahead basis in combination with a five-minute joint energy market optimization, based on energy offers. For a more detailed discussion, see Protest and Compliance Proposal of the Independent Market Monitor for PJM, pp. 51-53. APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 33 VIII. RTO Operations to Support Non-Discriminatory Transmission Access U nder APPA’s proposal, RTOs would emphasize activities that support wholesale power supply markets — ensuring nondiscriminatory transmission access and managing congestion on the transmission grid, thus ensuring reliability. RTOs would continue to provide transmission service under open access transmission tariffs (“OATTs”), dispatch generating units in merit (lowest cost) order subject to system constraints, manage integration of variable resources, determine price differentials arising from congestion, and assist LSEs in hedging congestion. In a market environment focused primarily on supporting long-term resource arrangements, including both bilateral contracting and LSE-owned resources, RTOs would need to improve their management of transmission congestion. As explained in greater detail in this chapter, they would need to: • Allocate financial transmission rights (“FTRs”) designed to support LSE power supply arrangements required to serve load. • Collect data on bilateral contracts entered into by market participants transacting within the RTO footprint. • Centrally dispatch generation in least-cost (merit) order based on actual costs of generation units submitted to the RTO. Financial Transmission Rights and Long-Term Transmission Rights RTOs would continue to offer OATT transmission service, but would implement policies to provide greater support to long-term power supply arrangements. RTOs would allocate annual FTRs or equivalent rights directly to LSEs based upon a percentage of the LSE’s peak load. Even where the bulk of energy is transacted through bilateral contracts, because all contracts would clear through the market, a hedge would still be needed against congestion costs. LSEs with mid-year changes to loads or resources should be permitted to apply to the RTO for a change in their FTR allocations. Any remaining congestion revenues would be distributed to network and long-term firm transmission customers to ensure that market participants paying the embedded cost of the transmission system would receive the full economic value of their payments or equivalent rights. Non-load-serving market participants would not be eligible to receive an allocation of FTRs, but LSEs would retain the right to resell their allocated FTRs if they chose. RTOs would also allocate LTTRs to LSEs to support bilateral contracts or owned resources, with a priority for power supply arrangements of 10 years or longer.84 These LTTRs would be paired with LSEs’ power supply arrangements developed to comply with the RTO’s resource adequacy requirements, and applicable state resource procurement requirements. One means to distribute LTTRs would be to provide the 34 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update www.PublicPower.org LTTR along with approval of new network transmission service for the LSE. However, without adequate transmission infrastructure in place during the term of the LTTR to support transmission service, the LTTRs might not provide a sufficient hedge to LSEs against congestion costs. Under the regulations promulgated in Order No. 2000, an RTO must possess the authority “for directing or arranging necessary transmission expansions, additions and upgrades that will enable it to provide efficient, reliable and non-discriminatory service.”85 FERC decisions since that order, however, have cast some doubt on this requirement, and hence on the potential revenue adequacy of LTTRs over their full term.86 Such financial uncertainties in turn make it more difficult and costly to develop new generation resources. RTOs should be required to demonstrate that the data on projected loads and planned resources is incorporated into transmission system planning and expansion plans, to ensure that the RTO’s transmission system is sufficiently robust to support LSE resource portfolios. The Commission’s currently pending Notice of Proposed Rulemaking in Docket No. RM10-23-00087 proposes to revise regional transmission planning and cost allocation protocols and procedures. APPA believes that if properly done, regional transmission planning could support allocations of LTTRs to support LSE resource plans. Such resource plans would inevitably reflect applicable state resource procurement policies (such as renewable portfolio standards). Therefore, transmission facilities that are in fact needed to support LSE-selected generation resources will be necessarily included in RTO’s regional transmission plans, presuming those plans are based upon the resource plans of LSEs in the region. Reductions in reliance on transmission facilities due to increased use of energy efficiency and distributed generation would likewise be taken into account. APPA, however, is quite concerned that FERC’s Order No. 741, its final rule on RTO credit requirements issued on October 21, 2010, in Docket 85 18 C.F.R. § 35.34(k)(7). 86 Midwest Independent Transmission System Operator Inc., 125 FERC ¶ 61,061, P 34 (2008) (“While we recognize that the Midwest ISO has the obligation to facilitate generation interconnections and expansion planning, it cannot force utilities to build capacity. The Midwest ISO therefore cannot be required to build sufficient transmission capacity to ensure deliverability of all resources for their useful life.”); Midwest Independent Transmission System Operator Inc., 125 FERC ¶ 61,062, P 162 (2008) (“Also, while the Midwest ISO is obligated to facilitate generation interconnection and expansion planning, it cannot force utilities to build capacity and therefore it cannot assure deliverability for all projects’ useful lives.”). 87 www.PublicPower.org Transmission Planning and Cost Allocation by Transmission Owning and Operating Public Utilities, 75 Fed. Reg. 37,884 (June 30, 2010). APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 35 No. RM10-13-000,88 will greatly discourage LSEs from attempting to obtain LTTRs to support new generation resources, including renewable resources. The Commission in that order decided to require LSEs holding FTRs, including LTTRs, to post full financial security to support all such holdings, despite the acknowledged difficulty in valuing such holdings for security purposes. Providing such security could well make it so financially onerous to hold LTTRs that LSEs will be faced with the decision either to (1) simply accept the risk of transmission congestion costs associated with such long-term resource transactions; or (2) not enter into such longer-term transactions in the first instance. Neither result will assist in assuring the development of the new generation resources that will undoubtedly be needed in the coming years as increasing numbers of coal-fired power plants leave RTO generation fleets. Collection of Bilateral Contract Data LSEs would submit their proposed bilateral contracts and owned generation resource arrangements to the RTO. The RTO would then subject these contracts and arrangements to a simultaneous feasibility test to determine whether they violate any transmission system constraints or overload any system equipment. This information, however, would not affect the dispatch, which would be done according to actual generator costs and transmission constraints and would be performed separate from the terms of the contracts. Bilateral contracts would act as financial arrangements determining the payment streams between buyers and sellers. The feasibility test would, however, feed into determinations of FTRs/LTTRs and plans for transmission expansions and upgrades. Guidelines for allocating FTRs and LTTRs would need to be established in the event that all of the power supply arrangements submitted to the RTO during a particular time window cannot pass the feasibility test. For example, priority could be given to LSE power supply arrangements with longer terms, or arrangements that LSEs enter into to meet their service obligations, as discussed above. The RTO should include such contracts and arrangements in its regional transmission plan, and ensure that sufficient transmission facilities are constructed as needed to support them. Centralized Dispatch The RTO would centrally dispatch all generation within its footprint, regardless of whether it is an owned resource, scheduled under a bilateral contract, or offered to the optimization market. The RTO would use a cost88 36 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 75 Fed. Reg. 65,942 (October 27, 2010). www.PublicPower.org based security-constrained economic dispatch formulation (similar to how current RTOs operate, except that the RTO would be using actual cost data of the bidders, rather than submitted bids).89 The terms of the bilateral contracts would reflect the financial arrangements to be settled between the buyers and sellers, and would be settled separately from the actual dispatch. Generators would be paid based on prices negotiated through the bilateral contracts, or set in the optimization market, as applicable. 89 www.PublicPower.org Generators would be permitted to designate a zero cost for dispatch purposes if they needed to dispatch owned resources, to meet contractual obligations or to keep a unit running for operational reasons. APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 37 IX. Renewable Energy A t least 30 states90 states have implemented renewable portfolio standards (RPS) or goals under which LSEs are required to provide a portion of their sales or capacity requirements from renewable or lowemissions generation sources, or from energy efficiency measures. Moreover, proposals have been made in Congress to enact a national renewable electricity standard (RES) or clean energy standard (CES). From the point of view of the RTO, such requirements effectively amount to giving alternative renewable energy sources some level of priority in the dispatch mix. Some alternative energy sources, such as biomass or geothermal, can simply participate in the bilateral market along with traditional fossil and nuclear generators. Variable renewable generation sources such as wind and solar, however, can be more difficult to integrate into RTO dispatch mixes, since there may be a higher risk of unavailability during a particular time interval. APPA designed its proposed market reform plan to be compatible with such renewable energy goals and the complications associated with scheduling variable energy sources. Rather than being set by the “market,” the penetration level of these variable renewable generation sources will likely be set based on RPS requirements and other policy considerations determined by federal, state and local regulators, governors and legislatures. Operationally, the RTO would simply have to schedule these resources when they are available (either directly or through individual LSE schedules), possibly backing down other sources of generation in the process (this becomes an issue when variable generation resources reach a significant penetration level within an operating area). In the Day Two markets, which require a day-ahead commitment of generating units, short-term changes in output of such variable resources may require the purchase of conventional power in real-time if the variable resource cannot deliver the day-ahead commitment in real time, or a reduction in other committed resources if there is a greater amount delivered. Since variable resources often are not available at the full contracted amount in a particular hour, they must be “firmed up” in some manner. One way to do this would be to require LSEs scheduling wind or solar resources to develop portfolios of resources that include appropriate backup capacity (e.g., natural gas or hydroelectric power).91 But cost of the capacity should be borne by the variable resource provider as an incentive to schedule as accurately as they can, as discussed below. These portfolios could be 38 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 90 Renewable Portfolio Standards and State Mandates by State, U.S. Energy Information Administration, August 2010, based on 2008 data, http://www.eia.doe.gov/cneaf/solar.renewables/page/trends/table28.html 91 This type of arrangement has been explored by C.L. Anderson and J. Cardell , Reducing the Variability of Wind Power Generation for Participation in Day-Ahead Markets, Proc. of the 41st Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences, Waikoloa, Hawaii, 2008. www.PublicPower.org determined by the states in the power supply planning processes described in Chapters IV and X. Alternatively LSEs would be required to purchase adequate operating reserves through the ancillary services market to support their variable resources, with the cost reimbursed by the variable resource provider. Since this could involve large amounts of operating reserves, the RTO and state-level regulators would need to cooperatively determine regional solutions for handling variable resources as part of the resource adequacy and transmission planning processes.92 One step that could be taken to reduce the amount of capacity or operating reserves needed is not related to RTO- markets, and simply involves improvements in the science of forecasting. Obtaining more accurate data and incorporating that data into scheduling regimes, would be more fruitful than developing entire new market design features to accommodate variable resources. In recognition of the difficulty of precisely scheduling variable resources, APPA has supported the elimination of third-tier imbalance penalties. But variable resource owners and operators also should have the financial incentive to schedule as accurately as possible. A combination of carrots and sticks (e.g., increased opportunities for variable resources to schedule within the scheduling day and hour, payment by such resources of the associated capacity and operating reserves, increased access to better forecasting data, and more coordination by transmission service providers across balancing areas) should serve to both assist and discipline variable resource providers. FERC proposed certain measures to promote the integration of variable resources in a proposed rule issued in November, 201093 that would require transmission providers to offer all customers the option to schedule transmission service at 15-minute intervals instead of the current hourly scheduling norm, and to offer regulation service to generators located within a transmission provider’s balancing authority area.94 The proposed rule also would amend the standard interconnection agreement for large generators to require variable generators to provide meteorological and operational data to www.PublicPower.org 92 In its comments filed on the Commission’s Notice of Inquiry in Integration of Variable Energy Resources, FERC Docket No. RM10-11-000, on April 12, 2010, APPA commented at length on possible measures FERC could require transmission providers to take to better integrate variable energy resources into regional transmission systems. APPA’s comments are available at http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/APPARM1011Comments41210asfiled.pdf 93 Integration of Variable Energy Resources, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 133 FERC ¶ 61,149, (November 18, 2010), 75 Fed Reg. 75,336 (December 2, 2010) 94 The proposed rule would add a new rate schedule for this mandatory service, including a mechanism through which transmission providers can recover the costs. A transmission provider could not require a variable generator to purchase greater volumes of generator regulation service than conventional generators unless the transmission provider offers 15minute scheduling and power production forecasting, and can demonstrate that any requirement that variable generators purchase more regulation service is commensurate with their proportionate effect on net system variability. APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 39 The increased reliance on longer termlonger-term PPAs in the APPA plan may therefore better support new renewable resource development than the current shortterm RTO market model. transmission providers, and "encourage" transmission providers to develop power production forecasting for variable generators. As additional amounts of variable resources are integrated into the grid, there will be a greater need for capacity and operating reserves as backup power. This additional resource need reinforces the importance of market reforms to avoid expenditure of additional and unnecessary costs. For example, recent increases in locational capacity prices in PJM would make wind power integration more expensive as additional capacity to back up the wind power has to be purchased at these higher prices. In the event that scarcity pricing is implemented, tapping into operating reserves could trigger the increases in the price ceiling and similarly create additional costs for consumers. Reforming capacity markets and limiting the use of scarcity pricing would therefore make integration of renewable resources more affordable. APPA also notes that distributed (local) generation, energy storage and micro-grids are emerging alternative energy sources that may not be included in current RPS regimes but may benefit consumers more when compared to the price of purchasing energy from the grid. During times of peak or rapidly fluctuating demand, local generation or energy storage may also impart significant benefits to the grid as a whole, relieving strain on transmission and generation facilities. The RTO would need to develop tariff provisions accommodating LSE use of these distributed generation sources as a way to meet resource adequacy requirements. An assertion that has been made repeatedly in the ongoing debate over restructured markets is that RTO-operated markets are more advantageous for renewable power.95 As stated earlier, because this Plan leaves intact the beneficial functions of RTOs, such as the ability to dispatch a wide array of resources and elimination of pancaked transmission rates, these advantages of RTOs for renewable power would not change. Finally, RTO operations are secondary to the importance of providing longterm revenue stability for investors in renewable energy through long-term contracts. The importance of long-term contracts for renewable power is demonstrated by a Department of Energy (DOE) finding that in 2009, 58 percent of new wind capacity was purchased by investor-owned or public power utilities under long-term contracts.96 Regarding the 38% of wind sold as merchant power into the wholesale markets, the DOE concludes “that it is 40 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 95 For example, see Joint Statement Supporting Competitive Wholesale Electricity Markets, American Wind Energy Association and the COMPETE Coalition, October 2010, http://www.competecoalition.com/resources/compete-awea-joint-statement-supporting-competitive-wholesale-electricity-markets 96 2009 Wind Technologies market Report, Office of Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy, US Department of Energy, August 2010, http://www1.eere.energy.gov/windandhydro/pdfs/2009_wind_technologies_market_report.pdf, www.PublicPower.org possible that many projects that sold power on a merchant basis in 2009 may now be seeking longer-term PPAs in order to gain increased revenue stability.” In fact, it has become increasingly apparent, that, without a long-term contract, financing renewables is nearly impossible in many cases. An article on renewable energy projects in The International Business Times states: “Now, projects without strong institutional backing and a signed, long-term PPA won't even make it to bank credit committees.” The increased reliance on longer-term PPAs in the APPA plan may therefore better support new renewable resource development than the current short-term RTO market model. 97 www.PublicPower.org The Week in Green Energy: The Bankable Project, International Business Times, November 21, 2010; http://uk.ibtimes.com/articles/20101121/week-green-energy-bankable-project.htm APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 41 X. Resource Adequacy and Planning A PPA’s Competitive Market Plan does not include any explicit RTOadministered payments or markets for generation capacity. Studies of the PJM and NY ISO capacity markets reveal that these markets have generated payments to generators far in excess of what would be needed to cover the actual costs of new capacity needed for reliability.98 A recent analysis shows that high prices within the constrained zones in PJM’s Reliability Pricing Model have not incented greater levels of new generation clearing the RPM auctions or higher offers of existing plant upgrades, demand response, energy efficiency resources, and net imports in constrained zones.99 Given these flaws in the RTO-operated capacity markets, APPA believes it would be far better to use a combination of resource adequacy requirements, a comprehensive transmission planning process, and long-term bilateral power supply and demand response arrangements to ensure adequate supply resources in RTO regions in future years. If desired by the stakeholders in a particular RTO region, a voluntary residual capacity market could also be included in the array of options for those LSEs finding themselves short of capacity in the nearer term. Overall RTO-established resource adequacy standards applicable to all LSEs are an important feature of the APPA proposal.100 These standards may have to be tailored by the RTO for specific subregions within its footprint, depending on transmission constraints and other factors. APPA is aware that there are jurisdictional disputes over the exact level and nature of RTO-set resource adequacy requirements. Generation adequacy requirements traditionally have been the purview of state utility regulators and reliability entities. An increased RTO/federal role would require coordination and cooperation among state regulators, RTOs, and FERC in establishing and approving regional resource adequacy plans. This section lays out in more detail the resource adequacy provisions of the Competitive Market Plan. Appendix A of this paper provides a background discussion on the current resource adequacy provisions in restructured markets. APPA’s proposal would establish a multi-state regional process to develop needed RTO-wide resource adequacy requirements under agreed-upon policy goals. States would then implement procurement processes to ensure that state-regulated IOU LSEs obtain a diversified portfolio of power supply and demand-side resources of varying lengths and terms that will assist in meeting 42 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 98 See Mount (2007) and Wilson (2008). 99 Direct Testimony of James F. Wilson in Support of First Brief of the Joint Filing Supporters, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Docket ER10-787, July 1, 2010, Section V, http://www.wilsonenec.com/FCM_Testimony_July_1.php 100 These standards would be applied to a number of years going forward, with the precise time frame to be determined. www.PublicPower.org the RTO-wide resource adequacy requirements.101 States and LSEs could also agree to pool their LSEs’ respective resource needs for procurement purposes, rather than having each individual state or LSE act on its own. Such procurement processes would greatly benefit new suppliers of generation, demand response and energy efficiency technologies by providing revenue streams needed to support long-term financing. Sufficient safeguards also need to be included in the selection process to ensure that third-party suppliers get fair and equitable consideration of their offers and proposed projects.102 Demand response resources should be fully considered in developing LSE resource portfolios. But caution should be exercised to avoid overreliance on demand response resources, which have accounted for an increasingly substantial percentage of the reliability requirements in recent years.103 In the 2010 auction in ISO-NE’s Forward Capacity Market, 8.7 percent of the capacity procured was demand response.104 In PJM, demand response was 6.3% of peak load in the 2010/2011 delivery year, approaching PJM’s prior 7.5% limit for the limited demand response product.105 101 Public power and cooperative utilities in RTO regions, because they have retained their obligation to serve retail customers, already develop and implement such resource adequacy plans, under the supervision of their local governing bodies. They conduct periodic generation procurements, assessing “buy v. build” generation options, as well as the use of demand response and energy efficiency measures to reduce demand, in lieu of securing additional generation. Because they are not-for-profit and do not earn a return on owned generation assets as investor-owned utilities do, they approach these decisions from a consumer-benefit perspective. For these reasons, public power utilities should continue to procure their resources under their own plans, unless they choose to opt into a larger state procurement process. 102 State competitive procurement “best practices” are discussed at length in a 2008 paper prepared for the Collaborative on Competitive Procurements between FERC and the National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC). Susan Tierney and Todd Schatzki, Competitive Procurement of Retail Electricity Supply: Recent Trends in State Policies and Utility Practices, July 2008, http://www.naruc.org/Publications/NARUC%20Competitive%20Procurement%20Final.pdf 103 The North American Electric Reliability Corporation (NERC) listed the “Uncertainty of Sustained Participation in Demand Response Programs” as one of the Emerging Reliability Issues in 2010, stating that: “While many similarities exist between Demand Response and generating capacity, key differences in terms of availability, performance, and sustainability may appear as a given system becomes more stressed… Demand Response is increasingly being used to balance system load and relieve resource adequacy and transmission reliability issues. Decreased or insufficient participation could lead to operational challenges where peak demand is not able to be met by current generation or transmission resources.” 2010 Long Term Reliability Assessment, p. 59. 104 Final Capacity Auction Results: Surplus Resources Available for 2013–2014, ISO-New England, http://www.iso-ne.com/nwsiss/pr/2010/fca4_filing_release.pdf. The table on p. 3 shows that 37,501 MW of capacity was acquired, of which 3, 261 MW was demand resources. 105 www.PublicPower.org Demand Resource Saturation Analysis, Resource Adequacy Planning Department, PJM, May 2010, http://www.pjm.com/~/media/committees-groups/committees/oc/20100817/20100817-item03-demand-response-saturation-report.ashx. PJM has recommended increasing the limit to 8.5% for the RTO, finding that this level would produce a low probability (10%) of a resource being interrupted more than 10 times APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 43 Given these high levels, the risks of future potential non-performance of demand response resources need to be assessed. Were large amounts of demand response not to materialize when called upon, the result would be an adverse impact on system operations comparable to the sudden loss of a large amount of variable generation. APPA accordingly supports the right of the RTO to impose technical requirements and verification criteria on demand response resources to ensure that these resources do perform as intended, if they are to be counted in an LSE’s resource portfolio. Such requirements and criteria, however, must be well supported to avoid discriminating against demand response and in favor of other resources. Energy efficiency investments as an alternative to generation resource obligations must also be fully considered. Given that utility LSEs already provide retail service to end-use customers, the LSE may be the lowest-cost supplier of demand response or efficiency services. But as part of the regional procurement process, third-party demand response providers could bid to provide such services to LSEs. Because demand-side resources may in fact be the lowest-price supply options (in addition to being the lowest carbonemitting options), they should be an important part of the resource portfolio for the region and for LSEs. State requirements and policy preferences for fuel diversity (such as state RPS and energy efficiency goals, and state/regional carbon mitigation regimes) should be honored in developing LSE resource portfolios. The RTO would have to ensure, however, that the LSE resource portfolios developed are, taken as a whole, both technically feasible and operationally reliable.106 (For example, an LSE’s 50 percent wind portfolio might exceed an applicable state RPS requirement, but it would not necessarily be adequate or reliable from the RTO’s standpoint unless sufficient backup supply/storage were available.) Another important issue in constructing competitive procurements for stateregulated LSEs is to determine who will conduct the solicitation for bids and evaluate the submitted bids. The details of current programs vary from state to state, but in general, current state auctions or bidding programs to determine which suppliers will supply retail customers are either conducted by the state commission directly (for example, Maine or New Jersey) or by the regulated utility (that is, the LSE) under the supervision and oversight of its state commission (for example, Delaware, Maryland, or Massachusetts).107 An 44 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 106 One issue that may arise is whether to allow “liquidated damages” contracts to be included in an LSE’s resource portfolio, and to count towards meeting the RTO’s resource adequacy requirement. Although not directly linked to a specific generating unit, such contracts should be allowed at least for a transitional period, so that LSEs may continue to use existing agreements in their portfolios to meet the relevant standards in the short run, and transition to qualifying power supply arrangements. 107 If the regulated utility is to take the lead, this should be done under the close supervision of the relevant state commission. www.PublicPower.org independent third party designated by the state or LSE (with state approval) could also administer the procurement process. Once the selection of the resources is determined, contractual arrangements with the suppliers or providers of the resources (including arrangements for selected self-build options) would be made. The objective would be for LSEs to have a diversified portfolio of resources, including longer-term supply commitments that provide customers electricity at a relatively stable and reasonable price, while assuring suppliers a steady revenue stream that can support financing of new resources. APPA’s intention here is to recapture the benefits to consumers of the long-term commitments and obligations that regulated utilities had under traditional cost-based regulation to provide reliable electricity at a just and reasonable price, while at the same time taking full advantage of available wholesale competitive options to discipline prices and suppliers. As previously discussed, these longer-term contracts would be balanced by a portfolio of medium- and short- term contracts. APPA’s plan has the following advantages over the current system: • The planning and procurement process can provide a means for meeting individual state policy goals in a regional process (such as renewable portfolio standards or demand management programs). • Progress can be monitored as the process moves through the planning and procurement stages and any necessary adjustments can be made along the way. Accountability for LSE resource adequacy is left primarily to the states and LSEs. • This method allows the resource planning and procurement process to be conducted by the parties involved (LSEs and states), after the RTOwide determination is made on overall resource adequacy requirements. • The use of competitive procurement processes, including self-build options, to make the actual resource selections allows for competitive forces to provide price discipline on wholesale resource decisions. • Increased reliance on longer-term supply commitments should reduce the supply adequacy problems caused by overreliance on short-term RTO-run energy markets and the overpayments for existing capacity produced by some RTO-run locational capacity markets. www.PublicPower.org APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 45 46 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update www.PublicPower.org XI. Transmission Planning A parallel effort to create a more integrated transmission planning, siting and construction process would also be necessary to implement APPA’s proposed market reforms. A critical and yet to be resolved issue is transmission congestion that remains in key pockets of regional transmission systems. Relying on the transmission owner members of RTOs themselves to build transmission facilities in response to congestion-based “pricing signals” in Day Two RTOs generally has not worked well. The Commission’s pending notice of proposed rulemaking on transmission planning and cost allocation is clearly intended to improve transmission planning processes. APPA believes that RTO transmission planning and cost allocation processes could be greatly improved by more specifically incorporating LSE resource plans, and that such incorporation is in fact required under Section 217(b)(4) of the Federal Power Act.108 Current RTO transmission planning processes lack a clear linkage between LSEs’ long-term resource commitments and long-term transmission availability (in the form of viable LTTRs that would fully hedge associated transmission congestion costs). As discussed earlier, not only does the Competitive Market Plan recommend that LSEs with long-term power supply arrangements be given priority in allocating LTTRs/FTRs, but also that LSEs’ long-term resource portfolio choices feed directly into RTO transmission planning. Priority should be given to transmission infrastructure needed to support such resource arrangements. RTO transmission planning processes require cooperation among the RTO’s transmission owners to construct the transmission facilities needed to serve the present and future needs of the entire region. Incentives to do so, however, are muddied by thorny cost allocation issues, the prospect of tough siting battles and generation/transmission cross-ownership. A related problem is that of transmission constraints that affect resource decisions. For example, if an LSE wishes to contract for long-term power supplies from a generation unit at a specific location in the RTO’s footprint, but there are transmission constraints between the proposed resource and the LSE’s load, how should this be handled? Ultimately, the RTO would need legal support from state authorities and FERC to require member transmission owners to construct sufficient transmission upgrades to support LSEs’ long-term power supply choices, as incorporated into their resource portfolios. Even when transmission owners in RTO regions have undertaken substantial 108 www.PublicPower.org For a fuller discussion of APPA’s views on the Commission’s pending NOPR on transmission planning and cost allocation, see the initial comments APPA filed on September 29, 2010, in Docket RM10-23-000, available at http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/APPARM1023Comments92910asfiled.pdf APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 47 new transmission projects, they have insisted on (and generally obtained from FERC) very generous transmission rate incentives that unduly increase retail electric rates to consumers. The granting of transmission rate incentives, rather than being reserved for those cases in which incentives are truly needed to move a transmission project forward, are now often being granted by the Commission routinely. Moreover, the packages of incentives granted, taken together, can go far beyond what is required to reduce the risk of a transmission project to reasonable levels. While it is indisputable that additional transmission infrastructure is needed, the Commission’s failure to keep the costs of that additional infrastructure within reasonable bounds is contributing to growing opposition to the allocation of the resulting costs of such projects. APPA therefore supports the Commission’s issuance of its May 2011 Notice of Inquiry109 seeking comments on its transmission rate incentive policy first set out in Order No. 679.110 APPA believes that transmission rate incentives should be granted only to extraordinary transmission projects that are found to be needed and that would not be constructed but for the granting of such incentives. Moreover, the incentives should be limited to a reasonable package of measures that, taken together, reduce the risk of the project to acceptable levels for both project applicants and end- use consumers, without resulting in unjust and unreasonable rates. 111 109 Promoting Transmission Investment through Pricing Reform, Notice of Inquiry, 135 FERC 61, 146 (May 19, 2011) 110 Promoting Transmission Investment Through Pricing Reform, Order No. 679, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,222 (2006), order on reh’g, Order No. 679-A, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,236, and order on reh’g, 119 FERC ¶ 61,062 (2007). APPA welcomes recent indications from the Commission that it recognizes the need for such a review. For example, FERC Commissioner John Norris voiced concerns similar to those of APPA in his 2010 concurrence to an order approving certain incentives for a transmission project in the PJM region: “…[T]he Commission’s current approach may not appropriately balance the different types of incentives awarded to a project. Some incentives, such as the collection of rates during construction work in progress (CWIP) and the approved recovery of prudently incurred costs if the project is abandoned, serve to substantially lower risk for investors in the project. Other kinds of incentives, such as an incentive ROE adder, give investors the opportunity for greater rewards. The Commission has not articulated a sufficiently clear framework to balance requests for packages of incentives that individually seek to both limit downside risk and provide greater potential upside rewards.” [Emphasis supplied.] Potomac Appalachian Transmission Highline, L.L.C., 133 FERC ¶ 61,152 at 61,737 (2010) (PATH) 111 48 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update For a more detailed discussion of the transmission rate incentives issue, see the Joint Comments of the American Chemistry Council, et al., Docket RM10-23-000, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, September 29, 2010, http://www.publicpower.org/files/PDFs/JointCommentsRM102320100929.pdf www.PublicPower.org XII. Transition Issues I t has now been over a decade since the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission issued Order No. 2000. The course of RTO market development since that time has been difficult and controversial. The transition period to implement needed RTO market reforms is also likely to be prolonged and contentious, with bumps in the road and the possible need for mid-course corrections. For market participants that have made investments and resource procurement decisions under existing market structures that would be undergoing changes, implementation of the APPA Plan would likely require mechanisms to avoid or at least minimize economic injury during a substantial transition phase. For example, owners of capacity and demand response providers receiving payments under an RTO-run locational capacity market may require an orderly phasing out of such payments over the remaining term of the RTO’s forward market auction windows, even as resource adequacy requirements for LSEs are phased in. APPA’s proposed market redesign, which couples bilateral contracts and resource ownership with centralized dispatch, is compatible with FTRs, as are current RTO markets. Because this plan would not reinstitute physical transmission rights, the transition would be less difficult. The transition might, however, still impact the FTR holdings of some market participants. Since real-time dispatch would be based on costs rather than on market-based offers, the pattern of power flows in the transmission network would change to the extent that past market-based supply offers have been different than costs. Many aspects of the APPA Plan, such as the requirement for submission of short-run marginal costs for dispatch and optimization markets, may require FERC proceedings to work out the details, and likely would prove contentious. The recommendations for state-supervised procurement processes for state-regulated LSEs will likely entail state-level regulatory changes, or even new legislation. But even before the completion of the transition, steps taken to implement the Plan’s features could have near-term positive impacts on financing availability, by increasing the confidence in electricity markets on the part of lenders and investors. Moreover, reform of the RTOs’ short-term markets alone might have a salutary effect on the bilateral markets, providing an incentive for generators to offer more customized and attractive products and to bargain in a more meaningful fashion with prospective buyers. www.PublicPower.org APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 49 XII. Conclusion I mplementation of the Competitive Market Plan would take a substantial period of time. Many thorny transition issues would have to be resolved. There are substantial institutional and political obstacles as well. Differences in market design details among RTOs and differences in state retail regulatory regimes would require customized application of APPA’s Plan in each RTO. Hence, APPA suggests its Plan as one path to reach necessary long-term goals for the electric utility industry, including the development of new financial arrangements necessary to support new resource development in the wake of the 2008 financial crisis and subsequent deep recession, and in anticipation of a coming wave of coal generation unit retirements triggered by EPA regulatory actions Above all, APPA intended by proposing its Plan in 2009 to start a rational debate about the future of RTO markets—a debate the industry now more than ever needs more than ever to have. RTO-run centralized power supply markets are not working as originally envisioned. The resulting dysfunction has had substantial negative implications for the economy, reliability and the cost of retail electric service in RTO regions. The industry needs to start talking about necessary reforms. Before this dialogue can commence, however, those who advocate “competition” in wholesale electric markets have to acknowledge the current substantial problems with RTO-run centralized power markets. The debate should no longer be about whowhom can best massage the statistics or whether it is more virtuous to support “competition” or “regulation.” Instead, the industry must work together to develop a regulatory regime for electricity markets in RTO regions that will truly benefit consumers, businesses and the environment. Unless the electric utility industry and all of its regulators, retail and wholesale, can agree on a market design and regulatory paradigm that fairly balances the interests of both load and generation, the industry will be condemned to continued upheaval. 50 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update www.PublicPower.org APPENDIX A Division of Responsibilities for Resource Adequacy in Current RTO Market Structures The current RTO market structure has not provided for a robust set of resources to meet future projected demand at reasonable costs, nor has it produced sufficient diversity of fuel supply or low-carbon energy development. In short, sole reliance on “market” forces to determine resource amounts and fuel mixes is not likely to achieve such goals. Long-term planning and better-supervised resource procurement is therefore needed for resource adequacy of supply and demand resources and transmission. Achievement of such goals is critical to the RTO’s ability to support longerterm power supply arrangements, operate short-term energy markets, provide transmission service and ancillary services, and carry out other RTO functions. This section outlines the shortfalls in the current resource adequacy procedures and provides additional background to the Resource Adequacy provisions in Section X of the Competitive Market Plan. Resource adequacy under cost-based regulation Under a cost-of-service based regulatory framework, states and utilities developed and used procedures for decades to ensure that sufficient resources were available to meet projected customer demand. As the regulatory system evolved over time, utilities had the responsibility to plan and maintain the system to reliably meet customer demand.112 Since utilities were generally the sole providers of electricity to customers (and were usually granted exclusive franchises to operate in their service territory), they were regulated and provided sufficient funds to operate, maintain and expand their systems, and to earn a return on their investment. States generally had the authority to regulate retail rates of their jurisdictional utilities, and approved prudent costs for new generation that was deemed used and useful for customers. Table 1 summarizes resource acquisition under cost-based vertically integrated regulation. Utilities generally took the responsibility and did the planning to acquire new resources, and had both the incentive and the obligation to do so. FERC’s authority was limited to regulation of “sales for resale” (wholesale sales) and wholesale transmission service—having only limited impact on the resource choices of vertically integrated utilities (except for the siting of hydroelectric generation facilities). In general, this arrangement worked well enough to build a great deal of the infrastructure we still use today. It was not 112 52 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update Many states still use this form of cost-of-service or “traditional” regulation, and likely will continue to use it for the foreseeable future. However, some states in RTO areas, and particularly states with retail access, have either modified how utilities or other LSEs acquire new resources or have shifted responsibility for new resources shifted from primarily utilities to the region or RTO markets. www.PublicPower.org perfect, of course. Utilities were sometimes provided incentives to overcapitalize or over-build their systems.113 To offset that incentive, states developed the prudent investment and used- and- useful tests. Application of these tests added to the administrative costs and may have caused some reluctance on the part of state-regulated utilities to add capacity. However, from an overall pragmatic standpoint, this system supported the construction and maintenance of a reliable and affordable system, much of which we still rely on to this day.114 Table 1. Resource adequacy under cost-based regulation. Load- Serving RTO Entities (utilities) Responsibility FERC States X Authority X Incentive X Planning X Resource adequacy with an RTO structure Under the current RTO system, responsibility, authority, and planning have become more fragmented among federal, state and non-governmental RTO authorities. RTOs plan for the needed resources for the system (on a systemwide basis), but they do not build anything themselves and have been highly reluctant to force anyone else to do so. States authorize projects within their jurisdiction, approving siting of generation and transmission facilities. FERC, even with its expanded role under restructuring,115 can only provide “incentives,” but does not order (or has not yet tried to order) specific generation or transmission projects. Neither FERC nor the states usually become directly involved in constructing projects. Generators, left to their own choice, will choose technologies and fuels that make the most economic sense from their standpoint and investment time frame, which does not necessarily match the needs of the overall regional system. A generation www.PublicPower.org 113 This includes the Averch-Johnson effect, also called “goldplating,” and “ratebase padding.”= 114 Perhaps one of the most famous failures of this system, one that helped usher in industry restructuring, was the nuclear power plant cost overruns of the 1970s and 1980s. However, it could be argued that this was simply the result of poor regulation, not a failure of the system itself. 115 As wholesale and retail restructuring has developed since the late 1980s, the amount of electricity that passes through some type of FERC-regulated control has increased. This has occurred as a result of both federal and some state legislation and regulatory changes, such as divestiture of IOU generation. APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update 53 resource mix with an overreliance on one fuel may be inadequate for reliability purposes. As can be seen in Table 2, under an RTO system, responsibility, authority, incentive, and planning are divided among LSEs, RTOs, FERC, and states. The misalignment of responsibility with incentive and planning, in particular, creates a challenge that has been addressed in cumbersome and costly ways. For example, RTOs have created forward capacity markets to provide incentives to provide new generation capacity and demand response. The incentive to build has shifted from utilities to IPPs and others willing to take on the financial risk. However, these generators have no responsibility to maintain system reliability, no obligation to customers beyond their specific contract arrangements, and no system planning requirements. Table 2. Resource adequacy within RTO footprint. Load- Serving Entities (utilities) Responsibility RTO Planning States * X X Authority Incentive FERC ** X * Very limited backstop transmission siting authority for projects sited in “national interest transmission corridors,” as designated by DOE, and siting authority for hydroelectric facilities. ** Only for remaining vertically integrated utilities with supply obligation to retail customers. A similar misalignment has occurred with transmission planning and expansion. Under cost-based regulation, responsibility for grid reliability was clearly with the utility. If there were any interruptions of service, the utility was directly responsible. But this responsibility has now been shifted to RTOs. RTOs do the planning, but they do not build any transmission facilities and generally have not required their member transmission owners to do so. FERC can authorize recovery of transmission project costs if an entity proposes to build new transmission or expand its existing transmission system (including rate incentives), but has not tried to order such entities to do so. States approve the siting of new transmission lines and (in many cases) approve significant expansion of existing lines, but only rarely have required a transmission owner to expand its system. Moreover, the incentive for transmission owners that also own generation is often to not expand their facilities because it will lower prices for their generation. 54 APPA’s Competitive Market Plan: 2011 Update www.PublicPower.org American Public Power Association 1875 Connecticut Avenue, NW 202.467.2900 Suite 1200 www.PublicPower.org Washington, DC 20009-5715