Lecture 9: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn 2007
Transcription
Lecture 9: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn 2007
Lecture 9: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn 2007 Lars Calmfors 1 Theory of consumption Keynesian consumption function C = C(Y – T) Consumption depends on current disposable income 0 < MPC < 1 • But it is more reasonable to believe that consumption depends on forward-looking decisions: Irving Fisher, Milton Friedman, Franco Modigliani and Robert Hall • Intertemporal decisions • Fisher’s two period model 2 Figure 16.1 The Keynesian Consumption Function Mankiw: Macroeconomics, Sixth Edition Copyright © 2007 by Worth Publishers 3 Intertemporal budget constraint Period 1: S = Y1 - C1 Period 2: C2 = (1 + r)S + Y2 Substitution of (1) into (2) gives: C2 = (1 + r)(Y1 - C1) + Y2 C1 = 0 ⇒ C2 = (1 + r) Y1 + Y2 C2 = 0 ⇒ C1 = Y1 + Y2 /(1 + r) C1 = Y1 and C2 = Y2 is always possible C1 + C2 /(1 + r) = Y1 + Y2 /(1 + r) (1 + r) is the price of consumption in period 1 in terms of lower consumption in period 2. It is thus always more expensive to consume in period 1 than in period 2. r = 0 ⇒ C1 + C2 = Y1 + Y2 Present value of consumption = Present value of income. 4 Figure 16.3 The Consumer’s Budget Constraint Mankiw: Macroeconomics, Sixth Edition Copyright © 2007 by Worth Publishers 5 Figure 16.4 The Consumer’s Preferences Mankiw: Macroeconomics, Sixth Edition Copyright © 2007 by Worth Publishers 6 Figure 16.5 The Consumer’s Optimum Mankiw: Macroeconomics, Sixth Edition Copyright © 2007 by Worth Publishers 7 Figure 16.6 An Increase in Income Mankiw: Macroeconomics, Sixth Edition Copyright © 2007 by Worth Publishers 8 Figure 16.7 An Increase in the Interest Rate Mankiw: Macroeconomics, Sixth Edition Copyright © 2007 by Worth Publishers 9 • Expected future income changes influence consumption already now - Oil revenues in Norway - Future pensions - Anticipated future productivity increases in the US: explanation of low savings and large current account deficits • Consumption smoothing • Households try to smooth consumption over time (equalise marginal utility of consumption) - decreasing marginal utility of consumption - the same consumption level each period if subjective discount rate = market interest rate 10 Figure 16.8 A Borrowing Constraint Mankiw: Macroeconomics, Sixth Edition Copyright © 2007 by Worth Publishers 11 Figure 16.9 The Consumer’s Optimum With a Borrowing Constraint Mankiw: Macroeconomics, Sixth Edition Copyright © 2007 by Worth Publishers Borrowing constraints • Around ¼ of households are rationed in the credit market • The MPC of rationed households is unity (one) • A temporary income increase of ΔY gives a permanent income rise by rΔY (the permanent return if the income rise in invested in the credit market) for non-rationed households. MPC ≈ r • Hence, aggregate MPC = ¼ x 1 + ¾ x r ≈ 1/4 If consumption in each period depends on expected life income, it should follow a “random walk”, that is consumption changes cannot be predicted: they occur only when there are unexpected news (as with stock prices and exchange rates) – Robert Hall Ct = α0 + α1Ct-1 + εt Time-inconsistent preferences • Behavioural economics • Too low savings because of ”pull of instant gratification”? Question 1: 1000 SEK today (A) or 1100 SEK tomorrow (B)? Question 2: 1000 SEK in 100 days (A) or 1100 SEK in 101 days (B)? • Many people choose A in question 1 and B in question 2. • This is an example of time inconsistent preferences. • Individuals do not adhere to a long-term plan but deviate from it. Franco Modigliani’s life cycle hypothesis R = Remaining years of work Y = Annual income W = Wealth T = Remaining years of life C = (W + RY)/T C = W/T + RY/T T = 50, R = 30 ⇒ C = W/50 + 30/50Y = 0,02W + 0,6Y MPCW = 0,02 MPCY = 0,6 T = 21, R = 1 ⇒ C = W/21 + 1/21Y≈ 0,05W + 0,05Y Figure 16.10 The Life-Cycle Consumption Function Mankiw: Macroeconomics, Sixth Edition Copyright © 2007 by Worth Publishers Figure 16.11 How Changes in Wealth Shift the Consumption Function Mankiw: Macroeconomics, Sixth Edition Copyright © 2007 by Worth Publishers Figure 16.12 Consumption, Income, and Wealth Over the Life Cycle Mankiw: Macroeconomics, Sixth Edition Copyright © 2007 by Worth Publishers • Changes in asset prices (shares, houses) nowadays play a large role for the development of private consumption • Risks of “boom-bust cycles” – sudden “asset price reversals” tend to reinforce cyclical variations - property price bubble in Sweden, Finland and the UK in the 1980s and “asset price deflation” in the early 1990s - similar developments in Japan in the 1980s, after that prolonged recession (depression) - worldwide boom in stock prices in the late 1990s, then stock price falls when the dotcom bubble burst - are we now watching the beginning of a prolonged fall in house prices (US, UK, Ireland, Spain, Sweden????) • Difficult problem for central banks: Should they just have inflation targets for the CPI or should they also try to counteract large swings in asset prices (as Alan Greenspan and the Fed have done several times before)? - if asset prices rise too much, they may later fall a lot and make it impossible to avoid a deep recession and deflation (since the nominal interest rate cannot become negative: Japan is a prime example) - are central banks better than financial markets in identifying asset price bubbles? - Riksbanken has been criticised for an unclear policy strategy - ECB uses money supply increases as an indicator of the risks of asset price bubbles Fig. 2.1 Real house prices 200 Index, 2000=100 200 Spain 180 180 160 160 Italy Ireland 140 140 120 120 Euro area 100 100 80 80 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Source: OECD (2006). EEAG Report 2007 The monetary situation in the euro area Fig. 1.13 1) 12 Changes in M3 money supply % Over previous month 10 % 12 2) 10 8 8 6 6 4 4 ECB reference value Over previous year 2 2 0 0 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 3) 14 Credit growth % % Lending for house purchase 12 14 12 10 10 8 8 6 6 4 2 4 Corporate credit Consumer credit 2 0 0 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 1) M3=Currency in circulation, overnight deposits, deposits with agreed maturity up to two years; index, seasonally adjusted, 3-month moving average in % (centred).- 2) Extrapolated to annual rates. 3) Changes over previous quarter; corporate credit = credit to nonfinancial corporations; Lending to house purchase = credit to private households and NPISH. Sources: European Central Bank; Ifo Institute calculations. EEAG Report 2007 10 Savings and the pension system • Pay-as-you-go system (fördelningssystem) – each generation pays the pensions of the previous generation • A funded system (premiereservsystem) – each generation pays for its own pensions through pre-funding, which gives a higher savings rate • If one introduces a pay-as-you-go system, the first generation in the system is a winner (since it does not pay for any pensions for the preceding generation): our earlier ATP-system, which was introduced in the 1960s • The earlier ATP-system was not sustainable: it built on too optimistic projections of future growth: this was the background of the Swedish pension reform in the 1990s • Problem: if a pay-as-you-go system is replaced by a funded system, the last generation in the pay-as-you-go system becomes a loser (one has to pay twice: first for the pensions of the previous generation and then for the own pensions) • Swedish pension reform: combination of a pay-as-you-go system (the larger part is an actuarial pay-as-you-go system where all labour income earns pension rights) and a funded system (the PPM system) • The Swedish pay-as-you-go system is based on defined contributions and not as before on defined benefits - benefits are automatically adjusted to contributions - benefits are indexed to the developments of wages per employed - automatic brake adjusts benefits downwards if the financial viability of the system is at risk • Many other countries would need to do similar pension reforms as in Sweden - higher contributions - lower pensions (Finland: indexation to average longevity) - higher retirement age (Denmark: indexation to average longevity) - partial shift to funded system The effects of ageing on per capita output Dependency ratio Austria Belgium Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Ireland Italy Luxembourg Netherlands Portugal Spain Sweden UK EU 15-Average 2004 0.24 0.27 0.23 0.23 0.25 0.27 0.28 0.17 0.29 0.21 0.21 0.24 0.25 0.27 0.24 0.24 2050 0.55 0.47 0.42 0.46 0.46 0.49 0.62 0.41 0.65 0.35 0.42 0.53 0.68 0.47 0.38 0.49 Participatio n rate 80.00 67.00 81.00 74.00 70.00 76.00 66.00 70.00 63.00 67.00 70.00 76.00 71.00 76.00 76.00 72.20 Gains in per capita output Constant participation Increasing participation If no ageing 1.44 1.77 1.84 1.71 1.76 1.70 1.29 1.73 1.20 2.01 1.79 1.51 1.04 1.77 1.99 1.64 1.44 2.11 1.81 1.85 2.01 1.79 1.56 1.98 1.53 2.40 2.05 1.59 1.17 1.86 2.09 1.82 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 2.44 Cyprus Czech Republic Estonia Hungary Latria Lithuania Malta Poland Slovakia Slovenia Average 0.18 0.2 0.24 0.22 0.24 0.22 0.19 0.18 0.16 0.21 0.21 0.39 0.59 0.57 0.5 0.56 0.43 0.46 0.5 0.47 0.64 0.51 NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA 2.26 1.56 1.72 1.95 1.76 2.22 2.03 1.85 1.92 1.38 1.86 Japan US 0.29 0.18 0.72 0.32 78.00 85.00 0.96 2.02 Note: NA: not available Source: EEAG. 0.99 2.16 3.04 3.04 3.04 3.04 3.04 3.04 3.04 3.04 3.04 3.04 3.04 2.44 2.44