Special Issue No. 11, 2013: To Rescue or not Rescue
Transcription
Special Issue No. 11, 2013: To Rescue or not Rescue
VSEBINA/CONTENT UVODN A BESEDA/FOREWORD Klaus Liebscher: Kako rešiti finančni in realni sektor / How to rescue the financial and the real sector 1 U V O D N I K / E D I TO R I A L Boštjan Jazbec: Zdrave banke za gospodarsko rast – ali nasprotno? / Which comes first: bank rescue or economic growth? 3 S I S T E M S K I V I D I K S A N A C I J E B A N Č N E G A S E K TO R J A S Y S T E M I C A S P E C T O F B A N K I N G S E C TO R R E H A B I L I TAT I O N Guido Ravoet: Ključne dileme bančne sanacije evropskega finančnega sistema Key dilemmas of the bank rehabilitation in the European financial system France Arhar in Matej Tomec: Prestrukturiranje sistemskih bank EMU v primerjavi s Slovenijo Restructuring of systemic banks in EMU compared to Slovenia Albrecht F. Michler and H. Jörg Thieme: Sanacija finančnega sektorja – primer nemških bank Rehabilitation of Financial sector – The case of German banks Otto Lucius: Sanacija finančnega sektorja – primer avstrijskih bank Rehabilitation of Financial sector – The case of Austrian banks Alan Dukes: Sanacija finančnega sektorja – primer irskih bank Rehabilitation of Financial sector – The case of Irish banks Antonio Carrascosa and Mario Delgado: Rehabilitacija finančnega sektorja – primer španskih bank Rehabilitation of Financial sector – The case of Spanish banks Ivan Ribnikar: Kapital in lastništvo bank z vidika bančne sanacije pri nas Bank capital and ownership in light of bank rehabilitation in Slovenia P R AV N O O KO L J E I N Z A KO N O DA J N I O K V I R I P R E S T RU K T U R I R A N JA P O DJ E T I J LEGAL ENVIRONMENT AND LEGISLATIVE FRAMEWORK OF COMPANY RESTRUCTURING Andrej Simonič: Zakonodaja o sistemskem razdolževanju / Systemic deleveraging legislation Mojca Trstenjak: Bančna zakonodaja in ukrepi za prestrukturiranje bank Banking legislation and bank rehabilitation measures MAKROEKONOMSKI VIDIKI SANACIJE BANK IN PRESTRUKTURIRANJA PODJETIJ MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING Holger Schmieding: Makroekonomski trendi in bančna kriza v EU / Macroeconomic trends and EU banking crisis Marko Simoneti in Božo Jašovič: Razdolževanje bank v EU in Sloveniji / Bank deleveraging in EU and Slovenia Marjan Hafner in Urška Lušina: Zadolženost slovenske ekonomije in kreditna vrzel Indebtedness of Slovenian economy and credit-to-GDP gap Gonzalo Caprirolo: Makroekonomske posledice razdolževanja bank in podjetniškega sektorja Macroeconomic implications of banks and corporate sector deleveraging PRIMERI DOBRE PRAKSE/BEST PRACTICE C ASES AND LESSONS Boštjan Kavčič in Andraž Kotolenko: Problematika zunajsodnih prodaj in težave bank v insolvenčnih postopkih Insolvency proceedings – legal concerns and bank experience Maja Koritnik in Peter Merc: Reševanje bank z zasebnimi sredstvi / Bail-in tool for bank resolution S K L2013_Layout E P N E M I1S26/6/13 L I / C10:45 O N CPage L U S1 I O N kolofon REMARKS 4 8 16 25 33 40 49 56 61 68 75 85 92 103 112 Emil Lah: Slovenske banke med Scilo in Karibdo / Slovenian banks between rock and hard place 118 S TAT I S T I Č N A P R I LO G A / S TAT I S T I C A L A P P E N D I X 120 Bančni vestnik REVIJA ZA DENARNIŠTVO IN BANČNIŠTVO THE JOURNAL FOR MONEY AND BANKING ISSN 0005-4631 Uredniški odbor: mag. Božo Jašovič (predsednik), mag. Janez Fabijan (namestnik predsednika), mag. Peter Kupljen (mag. Kristijan Hvala), mag. Damijan Dolinar, Davorin Leskovar, univ. dipl. ekon., mag. Emil Lah, dr. Damjan Kozamernik, dr. Mojmir Mrak, dr. Ivan Ribnikar (dr. Marko Košak), dr. Rasto Ovin (dr. Dušan Zbašnik), dr. Marko Simoneti, Alenka Smerkolj, dipl. filolog, odgovorni urednik: mag. Emil Lah, strokovna sodelavka: Azra Beganović, lektorica: Alenka Regally, AD in oblikovanje: Edi Berk/KROG, oblikovanje znaka ZBS: Edi Berk/KROG, fotografija na naslovnici: Kreb Ide, prelom: Camera, tisk: Roboplast, naklada: 1000 izvodov. Izhaja enkrat mesečno, letna naročnina 80 EUR, za študente 40 EUR. Razmnoževanje publikacije v celoti ali deloma ni dovoljeno. Uporaba in objava podatkov in delov besedila je dovoljena le z navedbo vira. Rokopisov ne vračamo. Poštnina je plačana pri pošti 1102 Ljubljana. Revijo subvencionira Banka Slovenije. Revija je indeksirana v mednarodni bibliografski bazi ekonomskih revij EconLit. Editorial Board: Božo Jašovič (Chairman), Janez Fabijan (Deputy Chairman), Peter Kupljen (Kristijan Hvala), Damijan Dolinar, Davorin Leskovar, Emil Lah, Damjan Kozamernik, Mojmir Mrak, Ivan Ribnikar (Marko Košak), Rasto Ovin (Dušan Zbašnik), Marko Simoneti, Alenka Smerkolj, Graphic pre-press: Camera; Cover design and ZBS logo: Edi Berk/KROG; Cover photography: Kreb Ide; English-language editing: Vesna Mršič; Printed by: Roboplast; Number of copies: 1000. Bančni vestnik is published monthly. Annual subscriptions: EUR 80; for students: EUR 40. Reproduction of this publication in whole or in part is prohibited. The use and publication of parts of the texts is only allowed if the source is credited. Manuscripts will not be returned to the author. Postage paid at the 1102 Ljubljana Post Office. This journal is co-financed by the Bank of Slovenia. The journal has been indexed and abstracted in the international bibliography of economic literature EconLit. Uredništvo in uprava Bančnega vestnika pri Združenju bank Slovenije / The Bank Association of Slovenia, Šubičeva 2, p.p. 261, 1001 Ljubljana, Slovenija, Telefon / Phone: +386 (0) 1 24 29 756, Telefax / Fax: +386 (0) 1 24 29 713, E-mail: bancni.vestnik@zbs-giz.si, www.zbs-giz.si, TRR / Bank account: SI56 0201 7001 4356 205. FOREWORD How to rescue the financial and the real sector Dear reader, The current issue of “Bančni Vestnik“ focuses on bank rehabilitation and company restructuring. The foreword should give a brief overview on how to rescue the financial and the real sectors, by focusing on developments in Europe. As of August 2007, notable turbulences in the financial markets emerged, and, due to the subprime crisis in the United States, the risk aversion of banks increased. After the Lehman Brothers Bankruptcy in 2008, a lot of financial institutions got into serious difficulties. A worldwide financial crisis evolved and spilled-over to the real sector. There were prompt reactions by the EU policy makers and by policy makers on national level in order to restore financial market stability. A lot of European countries, including Austria, introduced schemes to rescue banks by granting State aid. In the context of the financial crisis, approximately twenty European countries introduced bank rescue schemes. A wave of far-reaching restructuring of individual banks started. The European Commission’s DirectorateGeneral for competition is responsible for assessing and approving State aid for banks. According to information from that authority, approximately 1.6 trillion euros of public means was granted in State aid to banks in the EU between 1 October 2008 and the end of 2011. The amount of guarantees (guarantees for banks‘ liabilities and other guarantees) granted by EU governments was even three times greater. In the meantime, a number of States granted further State aid to banks. Also the ECB reacted promptly. Inter alia, it carried out the following measures: The ECB granted liquidity to the interbank markets by a series of operations as banks started to be reluctant to grant interbank loans. The ECB substantially decreased interest rates and accepted additional assets as being eligible collateral BV 11/2013 for providing liquidity to banks. In December 2011, the ECB agreed to carry out two longer-term refinancing operations (LTROs), each with duration of 36 months. In the course of the financial crisis, a lot of European banks had to be rescued and/or far-reaching restructured, inter alia banks in the following countries: Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Netherlands, Portugal, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, and United Kingdom. A number of European banks were resolved. A key aspect in bank restructuring is that banks should have a competitive and viable business model that supports the real economy. In order to give the first impression of what has happened in the EU Member States, there is Austria as an example. Austria introduced a banking rescue scheme in 2008, inter alia consisting of the possibility to grant capital injections (e.g. participation capital which is a kind of preference shares capital without voting rights, which Austria injected to an extent of 5.4 billion euros) and guarantees (60 billion euros originally; as at the end of July 2013, approximately 8 billion euros in guarantees was outstanding on the basis of the two respective laws: the interbank market support act and the financial market stability act). Five Austrian banks have received public support and started far-reaching restructuring programmes. Two banks had to be nationalised. For one of these banks, a wind-up institution was created in 2009. Currently, there are considerations whether a wind-up institution should also be set up for the second nationalised bank. To stabilise the European financial sector and to increase the bank resilience, a lot of additional regulations were introduced or will be introduced. For example, the capital rules will be tightened (Basel III) and a so called “banking union“ is under consideration; with a centralised banking supervision under the responsibility of the 1 European Central Bank as well as a common deposit insurance scheme and a common mechanism for bank resolution. In the context of bank resolution, there is a proposal from the European Commission containing, among others, a bail-in component regarding banks which are under resolution. According to the proposal, the decision making structures of the “Single Resolution Mechanism“ (European Commission, Single Resolution Board and the national resolution authorities) shall decide on, respectively exercise, the write down and conversion powers regarding claims of inter alia certain investors and shareholders. As of 1 August 2013, there is already a partial anticipation of the bail-in component, namely for the banks having a capital shortfall and applying for public capital support. According to the EU State aid rules, these banks will have to obtain contributions from shareholders and subordinated debtholders before resorting to public recapitalisations or asset protection measures. Following the financial crisis, some European countries, especially in the periphery, got into severe economic troubles. After a short recovery in 2010, the euro area fell in a slow-down of its economic performance and is still in a recession. Only some countries, like Austria among others, show meagre economic growth. The real problems of these developments lie in failures of the past in the fields of fiscal and structural policies. The biggest challenge is to reduce general debts and to achieve balanced public budgets. In addition, there is a need for better economic coordination, for a strict adherence to sustainable fiscal policies and for improved surveillance mechanisms to support solid economic growth and high employment. Klaus Liebscher, Chairman of the Managing Board, FIMBAG BV 11/2012 UVODNA BESEDA Kako rešiti finančni in realni sektor Spoštovani bralec, Tema izdaje Bančnega vestnika, ki jo trenutno prebirate, je sanacija bank in prestrukturiranje gospodarskih družb. Uvodnik ponuja kratek pregled načinov za reševanje finančnega in realnega sektorja na podlagi dogodkov, ki smo jim priča v Evropi. V avgustu 2007 je zaradi krize drugorazrednih hipotekarnih kreditov v ZDA prišlo do prvih resnih pretresov na finančnih trgih in se je odpor do tveganj skokovito povečal. Po propadu investicijske banke Lehman Brothers leta 2008, se je veliko finančnih institucij znašlo v resnih težavah. Svetovna finančna kriza se je razširila in zajela tudi realni sektor. Institucije Evropske unije so se nemudoma odzvale na te dogodke enako kot institucije na nacionalni ravni s ciljem, da se ponovno vzpostavi stabilnost finančnih trgov. Veliko število evropskih držav med katerimi je bila tudi Avstrija, je sprejelo programe za reševanje bank skozi podelitev državne pomoči. V okviru odziva na finančno krizo, je približno dvajset evropskih držav vpeljalo programe za reševanje bank. Sprožil se je val daljnosežnega prestrukturiranja posameznih bank. Generalni direktorat za konkurenco pri Evropski Komisiji je pristojen za ocenjevanje in odobritev državne pomoči za banke. Iz podatkov GD za konkurenco je razvidno, da je bankam v Evropski uniji bilo odobreno približno 1600 milijard evrov sredstev iz javnih virov kot državna pomoč v obdobju med 1. oktobrom 2008 in koncem leta 2011. Znesek jamstev vlad držav članic Evropske unije (jamstva za obveznosti bank in druge vrste garancij) je bil celo trikrat višji. Tudi Evropska centralna banka (ECB) se je hitro odzvala. Med ostalim je izpeljala naslednje ukrepe: ko so se banke vse težje odločale za odobritev medbančnih posojil, je Evropska centralna banka ponudila likvidnost medbančnim trgom skozi niz operacij denarne politike. Evropska centralna banka je bistveno znižala obrestne mere in sprejela dodatna sredstva kot zavarovanje, na podlagi katerega so banke dobile likvidna sredstva. V decembru 2011 se je ECB odločila za vpeljavo dveh operacij dolgoročnega refinanciranja (LTRO), pri čemer je vsaka trajala 36 mesecev. V času trajanja finančne krize je bilo potrebno reševati veliko evropskih bank in/ali so banke potrebovale temeljito prestrukturiranje. Med temi bankami so se, med ostalim, znašle banke v naslednjih državah: Avstrija, Belgija, Ciper, Danska, Finska, Francija, Nemčija, Grčija, Madžarska, Irska, Italija, Latvija, Nizozemska, Portugalska, Slovenija, Španija, Švedska in Združeno kraljestvo. Marsikatera evropska banka je bila tudi rešena. Ključni aspekt prestrukturiranja bank je, da naj bi banke imele konkurenčen in vitalen poslovni model, ki nudi podporo realnemu gospodarstvu. Z namenom, da na kratko orišemo kaj se je dogajalo v državah članicah Evropske unije, lahko za primer vzamemo Avstrijo. Avstrija je vpeljala shemo za reševanje bank leta 2008, ki zajema, med ostalim, možnost, da se bankam odobrijo injekcije svežega kapitala (npr. dokapitalizacije bank v obliki ene vrste prednostnih delnic brez glasovalnih pravic, ki jih je Avstrija dokapitalizirala v višini 5,4 milijard evrov) in jamstva (prvotno je bil določen znesek v višini 60 milijard evrov, medtem ko je konec julija 2013, bilo še približno 8 milijard v jamstvih na voljo na podlagi dveh zakonov: Zakon o podpori medbančnemu trgu in Zakon o finančni stabilnosti). Pet avstrijskih bank je prejelo podporo iz javnih virov in začelo s temeljitimi programi za prestrukturiranje. Dve banki sta morali biti nacionalizirani. Za eno od teh bank je leta 2009 bila ustanovljena posebna institucija za likvidacijo. Trenutno se vodi razprava o tem, ali naj se ustanovi tovrstna institucija tudi za likvidacijo druge nacionalizirane banke. Cela kopica dodatnih predpisov je bila že vpeljana ali bo vpeljana z namenom, da se stabilizira evropski finančni sektor in okrepi prožnost bank. Kapitalska pravila, na primer, bodo poostrena (Basel III.) in na mizi je predlog ustanovitve t.i. “bančne unije“; centralizirani bančni nadzor bo v pristojnosti Evropske centralne banke, enako kot sku- 2 pna shema za zavarovanje bančnih depozitov in skupni mehanizem za reševanje bank. V okviru problematike reševanja bank, je na mizi predlog Evropske komisije v katerem se, med ostalim, predlaga t.i. »bail-in komponenta« za banke, ki so v postopku reševanja. Skladno s tem predlogom, upravljavske strukture “Enotnega mehanizma za reševanje bank“ (Evropska komisija, Enotni svet za reševanje bank in nacionalni organi za reševanje bank) so pristojne, da sprejmejo odločitve in spremljajo njihovo izvršitev v zvezi z odpisi in imajo pristojnost, da odobrijo konverzijo terjatev, med ostalimi, nekaterih investitorjev in delničarjev. Dne 1. avgusta 2013 je že začela veljati delna preliminarna »bail-in komponenta«, ki velja za banke z nezadostno višino kapitala in ki zaprosijo za kapitalske injekcije z javnimi sredstvi. EU pravila o državni pomoči določajo, da bodo te banke morale pridobiti prispevke od svojih delničarjev in imetnikov podrejenih dolžniških kapitalskih instrumentov preden zaprosijo za dokapitalizacijo s sredstvi davkoplačevalcev ali za ukrepe zaščite premoženja. Po finančni krizi so se nekatere evropske države zlasti s periferije Evropske unije znašle v resnih gospodarskih težavah. Po kratkem obdobju okrevanja leta 2010, je evroobmočje doletela upočasnitev gospodarske dejavnosti in je še vedno v recesiji. Le posamezne države, kot je, na primer, Avstrija, kažejo znake slabe gospodarske rasti. Dejanski problemi v ozadju dogodkov, ki smo jim bili priča, so spodrsljaji iz preteklih let na področju fiskalnih in strukturnih politik. Največji izziv je zmanjšanje proračunskega primanjkljaja in vzpostavitev uravnovešenega državnega proračuna. Poleg tega je potrebno delovati usklajeno na gospodarskem planu, strogo se držati trajnostne fiskalne politike in izboljšati nadzorne mehanizme s ciljem, da se ustvarijo pogoji za solidno gospodarsko rast in visoko stopnjo zaposlenosti. Klaus Liebscher, Predsednik Upravnega odbora, FIMBAG BV 11/2013 UVODNIK/EDITORIAL Zdrave banke za gospodarsko rast – ali nasprotno? Boštjan Jazbec* S lovenija je na pomembnih razpotjih, saj je od začetka recesije naprej soočena s številnimi ekonomskimi in družbenimi težavami ter šibko gospodarsko rastjo. Za državo, gospodarstvo in družbo kot celoto je obrat nujen. Osnovna naloga bank je posredniška vloga med varčevalci in investitorji. V krizi je ta naloga omejena zaradi visokih stroškov pridobivanja virov, prevelike zadolženosti številnih podjetij in slabšanja kakovosti posojil. Neučinkovitost posredniške funkcije bank se kaže tudi v omejitvah izvajanja denarne politike oziroma v precej višjih obrestnih merah za posojila podjetjem kot v povprečju evrskega območja. Večina naših bank je trenutno v procesu celovitega preverjanja stanja svojih bilanc in kapitalske osnove v primeru dodatnih šokov v makroekonomskem okolju. Ta proces je skladen z zahtevami evropskih institucij pri dodeljevanju državne pomoči bankam. Namen tega procesa v Sloveniji je odstraniti slabe terjatve iz bančnih bilanc in zagotoviti kapitalske temelje za stabilen in učinkovit finančni sistem. To je nujen, ne pa tudi zadosten pogoj za izhod iz krize in ponovno gospodarsko rast. Gospodarska aktivnost bo odločilno vplivala na to, ali bo ozdravitev bank zgolj začasna in ali bodo banke v prihodnje spet učinkovito opravljale posredniško funkcijo. Temeljno vprašanje tega trenutka ni le, kako zagotoviti stabilnost bank, temveč tudi, kako v prihodnje omogočiti vzdržno gospodarsko rast. Dogajanje pred krizo je pokazalo, da le-ta v majhnem odprtem gospodarstvu dolgoročno ni mogoča le na podlagi velikih infrastrukturnih projektov in domačega trošenja, še zlasti, če je slednje podprto z izdatnim dolžniškim financiranjem iz tujine. Rezultati takšne rasti gospodarstva so danes vidni v bilancah bank, podjetij in saldu javnih financ. Uspešnost izhoda iz krize in preprečitev nastanka ponovne negativne povratne zanke med realnim in bančnim sektorjem bo pretežno pogojena s prestrukturiranjem bilanc podjetij in izboljšanjem strukture virov financiranja. Po dokapitalizaciji bančnega sistema in ob ustreznih pravnih rešitvah bi lahko banke bolj uporabljale instrument pretvorbe dela bančnih posojil v kapital podjetij. To bi podjetjem z dobrimi poslovnimi načrti in potencialom za rast omogočilo razbremenitev bilanc, banke pa bi lahko pridobljene lastniške deleže, ko bo njihova ekonomska vrednost višja, prodale po višji ceni. Investicije v infrastrukturo morajo v naslednjih letih * Dr. Boštjan Jazbec, guverner Banke Slovenije. BV 11/2013 3 prispevati k večanju produktivnosti zasebnega sektorja, njihovo financiranje pa ne sme obremenjevati javnih financ. Zato bi se Slovenija morala bolj odpreti tujim neposrednim investicijam z davčnimi olajšavami, stabilnim gospodarskim okoljem in krčenjem administrativnih ovir. Njena primerjalna prednost ne sme biti slabo plačana in neizobražena delovna sila, ampak morajo novo ustvarjena delovna mesta prinašati visoko dodano vrednost. Tudi tako bomo preprečili trend izseljevanja mlade in izobražene delovne sile. Pretežni del naše gospodarske rasti mora izvirati iz menjave s tujino. Izvozni del gospodarstva se je doslej izkazal kot izjemno prilagodljiv, tako z vidika prilagajanja stroškov kot tudi iskanja poslovnih priložnosti na novih trgih. Zato mu moramo z ukrepi ekonomske politike omogočiti nadaljnjo rast. Zaradi pridobivanja konkurenčnosti na tujih trgih je izvozni sektor prisiljen v dodatno večanje stroškovne učinkovitost, ki ne sme temeljiti na zmanjševanju spodbud zaposlenim za večanje produktivnosti. Namesto tega moramo postopoma zmanjševati druge stroške dela, ki neposredno ne odsevajo prispevka posameznika k uspešnosti podjetja. Stroški gospodarstva se bodo morali posredno znižati tudi z racionalizacijo in optimizacijo poslovanja v dejavnostih z nižjo ravnijo konkurence. Edini dejavnik, ki lahko na dolgi rok spodbudi gospodarsko rast, je večanje produktivnosti proizvodnih dejavnikov. Ukrepi, ki to zagotavljajo, delujejo počasi, zato bi jih bilo treba začeti izvajati čim prej. Učinkovitost kapitala je pogojena z uvajanjem novih tehnologij in spodbujanjem inovacijske dejavnosti. Podlaga za učinkovitost delovne sile pa je kakovostno izobražena delovna sila. Kriza je pokazala, da moramo v Sloveniji nujno spremeniti miselnost in namesto stremljenja za hitrim zaslužkom in varovanja ozkih interesnih skupin začeti ustvarjati razmere za dolgoročno gospodarsko rast in transparentno upravljanje države. Predvsem pa se moramo zavedati, da država ne more poskrbeti za vse in da je njena naloga predvsem, da prepreči razkrajanje socialne kohezije in poskrbi za kakovosten institucionalni okvir delovanja države in gospodarstva. Le tako bo mogoče ustvariti družbo s stabilno in vzdržno gospodarsko rastjo in čim večjo blaginjo njenih prebivalcev. Takrat se nam tudi ne bo več treba ukvarjati s sanacijo bank. SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION UDK 336.71:061.1EU Key dilemmas of the bank rehabilitation in the European financial system KEY DILEMMAS OF THE BANK REHABILITATION IN THE EUROPEAN FINANCIAL SYSTEM There has been a tremendous change the European banking sector has been undergoing. One such key change has been the increasing regulation imposed on the sector and its consequences. This article attempts to present those challenges and solutions (to be) implemented by the banking sector in order to succeed in an evolving complex environment, and contribute to the European economy recovery. JEL G01 G21 G28 U Guido Ravoet* ntil less than a decade ago, Europe’s banks have, arguably, been one of the most trusted institutions at the heart of every community. This has changed with the crisis which has brought a range of new challenges for the banking sector: liquidity and sovereign risks, ever-increasing policy interventions and protracted low interest rates have distorted the market environment in which both financial organisations and investors operate. This year reveals a continued general trend of shrinkage and disintegration of the European banking sector. The economic situation is less than favourable: different nations within the European Union take different approaches to dealing with their challenges. To generalise, the euro area banking sector is taking the strongest hit (banking presence reduced in terms of numbers and financial activity), while the non-euro area banks are faring better.1 Furthermore, financial stability is undermined. A paradigm shift in the area of financial supervision is taking place, in order to solve the fundamental trilemma of financial supervision. All banks have been impacted by the crisis. Their current decisions will determine their position in the global competition and more specifically how they will be able to take advantage from the recovery in mature markets as well as from the new regulatory environment. * Guido Ravoet, Chief Executive, EBF Secretariat. EBF, Facts and Figures, 2013. 1 4 BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION It will take a long time, maybe 5 or even 10 years for the sector to recover from the reputational blow and the economic turmoil. European banks’ figures on their Return on Equity (ROE) remain weak. For 2012, EU 27 banks ROE median value is only 3.4%2. Even where that metric is still healthy, external factors such as persistently low interest rates are disrupting their business models. The banking sector has acquired a highly negative reputation and customer trust remains fragile. In spite of their needs in terms of banking services, customers are more and more looking for alternative financial services providers (shadow banking)3. Banking associations have played a key role in helping solve the crisis. They have stood as banks’ interlocutors with policy-makers, defending and representing the interests of their members in adverse circumstances. They have often taken blows in the name of the sector, have stood up in sometimes difficult positions defending what seemed in the eyes of regulators to be the undefendable. In the meantime, the main challenge for banks has been to acknowledge the poor state of their reputation – with customers, investors, but also other banks. Concretely, banks have already made profound improvements in their risk management by down-sizing and de-risking their balance sheets. They are also developing numerous market solutions as well as changing their attitude and culture progressively, looking towards more sustainable business models. Banks are now aware that incremental change is no longer a sustainable response to the global shift facing the industry. Several banks have already launched repositioning strategies in order to adapt to the new environment, but many more need to follow suit. BV 11/2013 **** Financial institutions, users of financial services, politicians and regulators – all have reacted to the crisis in different ways, which has resulted in a lack of mutual understanding and counterproductive initiatives. In order to tackle the dramatic decline of trust in the banking industry experiences among its customers4, policy-makers are putting in place tougher regulation. They conveyed the same message as the media: the banking industry is at the heart of the crisis and should bear the cost The euro area banking sector is taking the strongest hit. of its misbehaviour. Further damage has been done to the industry itself; bankers’ bonuses, benchmarks manipulation... Once trust is broken, it takes a long time to rebuild it … In that context, banks are struggling to strike the right balance between profitability and funding the real economy. Competition is indeed fiercer than ever, and banks need to maintain their position in the market if they are to be profitable. At the same time, they need to keep playing their key role, which is that of funding the economy, businesses and households. The financial sector provides a variety of functions which are essential to our economies but is it understood well enough? 5 Regulation, the political solution In the aftermath of the current financial and economic crises, the European banking sector has been undergoing the regulatory ‘tsunami’. In the run-up to the 2007-8 crisis, some banks went too far in excessive leveraging, resulting from shareholder-driven profit-seeking. As a consequence, banks, regardless of their business model, are now faced with tougher regulation on a vast array of issues: from capital and liquidity requirements, to limitations to financial leverage, to greater investor protection and increased transparency, to governance and remuneration issues, to reduction of over-the-counter derivatives, to the way the sector is structured, and more. There has been a strong and understandable reaction from politicians and regulators to the financial crisis. But it is clear now that regulation cannot solve everything. At the EBF, we strongly believe that the industry needs improved regulation, better response to the needs of the wider economy, but certainly not ‘more and more of everything’5. Regulatory reforms are aimed at making financial institutions safer, ensuring stability of the financial system, and relocating the cost of failures from taxpayers to the creditors of failing institutions. The ever-growing list of initiatives is endless. It covers not only tougher requirements for individual banks but also macroprudential policies aimed at improving financial stability and the resilience of the financial sector as a whole. 1 EBF, Facts and Figures, 2013. ECB 3 E&Y, Global Banking Outlook, 2013-2014. 4 According to E&Y, across Europe, 45% of respondents said that the crisis has had a negative impact on their trust in financial institutions 5 KPMG, The scope for better regulation 2 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION However, additional regulation should not be considered as a miracle solution; there are limits to what regulation can achieve. It is high time for regulators to step back and evaluate the cumulative impact of their multiple reform initiatives. The consequences of the sweeping reform compliance cause collateral damages. Implementing those regulations increases banks’ costs, may slow down innovation in financial services and reduce ability for banks to provide credit, trade finance and risk management services. The current reform package also diminishes returns to investors in financial institutions and also weighs on economic growth. For instance, while banks are deleveraging, economic growth in Europe is weak (or even negative). Negative short-term impact on economic growth may be a reasonable price to pay to avoid future financial crises. But evidence shows that the waves of regulatory reforms are now leading Europe and the global financial system beyond the ‘tipping point’ where the costs of ever more regulation have begun to exceed the benefits6. The banking sector is far from being reluctant to any regulatory development. Since last year, the European banking sector has embraced wholeheartedly the Banking Union project. It fully supports the initiatives of a Single Supervisory Mechanism and will contribute positively to the initiatives on resolution and deposit guarantees, the two outstanding issues to complete the regulatory overhaul. Besides, the European Banking Federation has always called for and worked to achieve a European Single Market in financial services. The Banking Union is the first concrete project which will allow for actual stability in the future, by facilitating convergence and establishing the basis for a level playing field at European level. European banks welcome the dialogue established in order to build the Banking Union and the increasing recognition of the importance of maintaining the capacity of banks to finance the economy. One may not forget however that banking will always be about managing risk; this is the inherent nature of the sector. Future failures will occur, there is little to do about some of those. Nevertheless, the way failures are addressed is decisive. While the cumulative cost of regulation paid by the wider economy may have been seriously underestimated, no one can shy away from their responsibility. For 2012, EU 27 banks ROE median value is only 3.4%. How to restore trust? Although customers have been and still are broadly satisfied with their individual banking relationships, the banking industry is now tarnished by recent scandals. To help regulators ease back and to restore trust and confidence of all stakeholders, banks have a strong motivation to demonstrate their efforts to conduct responsible and ethical banking. The industry is shifting from a reactive to a proactive stance. Demonstrating the crucial role that banks play as intermediaries for businesses and investors will indeed facilitate the process. The range of measures (to be) taken is far-reaching: change in culture and behaviours, delivering much higher standards of governance, better risk management, improved customer 6 service, improved products and services, better disclosure of asset quality and risk; as well as corporate social responsibility and financial education programmes. As banks adapt to the new environment, new challenges to the way they operate are rising. Firstly, it appears that most operating models and structures are no longer suitable. Restructuring of banks is a reality; the EU banking sector is shrinking. Some brands will disappear as consolidation intensifies among smaller banks. In Europe, many survivors will be much smaller as deleveraging is expected to shrink balance sheets by more than USD 2.5 trillion by December 20137. Many banks that invested to expand themselves at the international level are now forced to give up their ambitions. European banks feel a real pressure to focus on their core business in their home markets and have already started restructuring. As subsidiaries are sold and branches closed, the ability to serve international customers will be at risk. In the process of offering customers more transparent, consistent and comprehensive service, banks will tend to restructure banking services in order to both reduce costs and significantly improve operating efficiency. This requires innovation and technology. It will enable banks to analyse client activity and provide much more targeted services and solutions. The promising mobile banking trend will also respond to the new needs consumers have. Banks will need to anticipate shifts in behaviour of their customers. Digital banks have become first intermediaries between customers and the financial world so communications will be crucial. In that sense, pres- 6 7 KPMG, The scope for better regulation E&Y, Global Banking Outlook, 2013-2014. BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION ence in social media is an essential communication platform, particularly with clients. Despite their obvious benefit for consumers, those policies have a cost. New regulations are already placing considerable stress on banks’ data and reporting platforms. In addition, cybersecurity is also an ever-more prominent issue, particularly with outdated systems and data storage requirements that tend to grow exponentially. At the same time, customer behaviour is changing and expectations are increasing. As competition intensifies across Europe, customers become less loyal to their bank and as alternative providers enter the market, only banks offered differentiated products or services will benefit from that opportunity. Consumer and investor support is essential Investors in financial institutions and customers also need to play their part in addressing the balance between regulation and economic growth. By implementing financial education programmes and launching public relations campaigns, banks have an opportunity to explain how financial services are important but also that there is a cost attached to providing them. In turn, the trade-off between risk and returns also has to be acknowledged. By better understanding banks’ business models and risks, both consumers and investors will develop a more realistic environment, in particular in a world where failures are more likely to result in the bailingin of creditors than a bailing-out by taxpayers. **** The banking sector acknowledges that certain parts of the new regulaBV 11/2013 tory framework enhance the resilience of the industry. Nonetheless, it has become clear that the important role of banks needs to be preserved by creating favourable conditions for banking business. Should regulators fail to strike the right balance, it will be to the detriment of Europe’s economic recovery. Banks need an effective and efficient supervisory framework, but they also need to have some room for manoeuvre. Will banks be able to deal with this changing landscape?8 Time has come to fully accept that the environment has been entirely European banks feel a real pressure to focus on their core business. reshaped. Banks’ business, governance, culture and values therefore need to change accordingly. The ability of banks to rehabilitate in the European and global financial market depends on their aptitude to demonstrate their own commitment to a more constructive environment by implementing significant cultural and behavioural change. Taking proactive measures regarding risk management and disclosure are essential. It will also be impacted by their ability to constructively cooperate with regulators and supervisors in order to implement better regulation. It will also be crucial to communicate effectively about the value of the banking activities to the wider public. Finally, developing strategic responses to competition and technological opportunities are crucial factors to 7 be taken into consideration. The European Banking Federation has consistently been calling for a true single market for financial services, based on a single rule book and a real level playing field amongst European banks and at a global level, to ensure the competitiveness of European banks in the world. In order to build a sustainable banking sector, aiming not to call on taxpayers’ money to bail out banks, a cumulative impact assessment to analyse the actual consequences of the new legislative framework and national measures implemented by individual Member States is required. Banks are doing their best to draw attention on the unintended consequences of the regulatory reactions to the crisis, and offering practical solutions. There is hope that the structural reform proposals can be amended in a way that reduces the perverse effects on trade and the economy as a whole, while preserving their effectiveness. Many challenges remain, whether in terms of shadow banking, integration, retail banking services and, most of all, rebuilding a trusting environment which will be the cornerstone for banks to play their full role of financing the economy. Finally, the regulators, the EU institutions, including the European Central Bank, are taking steps to improve the financing environment. These are to be encouraged. Banks, for their part, are ready to continue their role as lenders, financial intermediaries and advisers. They are, indeed, part of the solution to the crisis. REFERENCES: EBF, Facts and Figures, 2013 E&Y, Global Banking Outlook, 2013-2014 KPMG, The scope for better regulation, 2013 8 Banks at crossroads, EBF 2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION UDK 336.71:338.124.4(497.4):061.1EU Prestrukturiranje sistemskih bank EMU v primerjavi s Slovenijo France Arhar in Matej Tomec* RESTRUCTURING OF SYSTEMIC BANKS IN EMU COMPARED TO SLOVENIA Restructuring activities of most systemic banks in the EMU area have been carried out during the crisis to a satisfactory level. Both commercial and investment banks are faced with the challenges of consolidation, which is mainly based on the reduction of risky activities and interbank business, the ability to obtain new capital, deleveraging and cost control. In the case of the two largest Slovenian banks, we can see a very different picture, as the restructuring of these banks is in the early stages. Persisting problems of rising bad loans, poor corporate governance, problems in meeting capital requirements and reducing the amount of credit available are still present. Slovenian banks need a quick and effective consolidation, changes in lending policy, and especially privatisation. JEL G01 G21 O dvisnost gospodarstva od bančnega sektorja in njegova velikost še poudarita nujnost hitrega in učinkovitega prestrukturiranja bank v času krize. Na agregatni ravni ni moč zaslediti večjega obsega konsolidacije v času krize, ki pa je vendarle bolj prisotna v sistemskih bankah, tudi zaradi njihovega statusa. Različnost poslovnih modelov ter sposobnosti upravljanja s tveganji je med bankami precejšnja, vendar so se v času krize tako investicijsko kot tudi komercialno usmerjene banke soočile z velikimi težavami. Uvod Najpomembnejše aktivnosti prestrukturiranja sistemskih bank so sanacija slabega portfelja, razdolževanje, povrnitev stabilnosti in zaupanja ter donosnost, ki je v času krize upadla. V nasprotju z večino sistemskih bank EMU sta največji slovenski banki šele začeli aktivnosti prestrukturiranja. Problem slovenskih sistemskih bank je izjemno slabo upravljanje s tveganji v predkriznih časih, prehitra rast kreditiranja, slabo korporativno upravljanje in prevelik vpliv države kot prevladujočega lastnika. Prav tako poteka konsolidacija bank prepočasi in premalo učinkovito, kar se kaže predvsem v upadanju kreditne aktivnosti in negativnem vplivu na gospodarstvo. V luči teh problemov smo izpostavili nekaj nujnih korakov. Treba bi bilo spremeniti politiko kreditiranja, in sicer večje prakticiranje fiksnih obrestnih mer (sedaj se uporabljajo večinoma gibljive obrestne mere), saj so zaradi fiksnih pasivnih obrestnih mer in nizkega euribora obrestne mere negativne. Prav tako bi morali hitro ter učinkovito konsolidirati slovenski bančni sistem. Eden ključnih tovrstnih ukrepov je Družba za upravljanje slabih terjatev, ki mora delovati transparentno, hitro in pošteno. * Dr. France Arhar, direktor Združenja bank Slovenije, in Matej Tomec, univ. dipl. ekon., doktorski študent , Ekonomskoposlovna fakulteta Maribor. 8 BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION Po končani konsolidaciji je srednjeročno najpomembnejši korak prav gotovo privatizacija največjih bank, saj je to edina garancija, da se problemi s tako negativnim vplivom na državni proračun in gospodarstvo ne ponovijo tudi v prihodnje. V prvem delu poglavja na kratko predstavljamo bančni sistem EMU ter značilnosti sistemsko pomembnih bank. V drugem poglavju pa aktivnosti prestrukturiranja sistemskih bank v primerjavi z dvema največjima slovenskima bankama. Zadnje poglavje je namenjeno predstavitvi nekaterih izzivov, s katerimi se bo soočil slovenski bančni sektor in še posebej večje banke v prihodnje. Bančni sistem EMU v času krize Izjemna pomembnost bančnega sektorja v EMU se kaže v njegovi velikosti, ki je ob koncu leta 2012 obsegala 33 tisoč milijard €, kar je 345 % BDP EMU. Nizke obrestne mere, številne kompleksne finančne inovacije in visoka kreditna aktivnost so omogočile tako hitro rast bančnega sektorja, predvsem v letih pred nastankom finančne in gospodarske krize. Bančno financiranje je najpomembnejši vir financiranja v EMU, drugače kot npr. v ZDA, kjer so finančni trgi bolj razviti in sta sposobnost ter zmožnost realnega sektorja širši. To velja predvsem za številne večje korporacije, ki se lahko po ugodnih obrestnih merah same financirajo na trgu in niso toliko izpostavljene bančnemu financiranju ter tveganjem, ki jih tovrstna odvisnost prinaša. Finančna in gospodarska kriza leta 2008 je razkrila številne pomanjkljivosti v bančnih modelih v času pred krizo, ki sedaj ogrožajo stabilnost in zaupanje v celoten bančni sistem. Številne banke so rasle prehitro in na napačnih temeljih. Liikanen et al., (2012) so izpostavili problem izraziBV 11/2013 Slika 1: Bilančna vsota držav EMU v % nacionalnega BDP v letu 2012 Vir: ECB podatki in IMF podatki *Bilančna vsota v Luksemburgu znaša 2.180 % nacionalnega BDP. Številne evropske banke so rasle prehitro in na napačnih temeljih. tega povečanja investicijskih aktivnosti, ki ni imelo podpore v depozitih in je bilo izpostavljeno (pre)velikemu tveganju (kompleksne finančne inovacije) ter preveliki odvisnosti od kratkoročnega financiranja na trgu (predvsem medbančnega financiranja) in s tem povečanja bančne integracije in sistemskega tveganja. V času krize se je pokazalo, da banke z večjimi neobrestnimi prihodki (prihodki iz investicijskega bančništva in tržnih aktivnosti) predstavljajo večje sistemsko tveganje kot banke, ki so bolj usmerjene v tradicionalno bančništvo (Brunnermeier et al., 2012). Investicijske banke so bile v času krize prisiljene k obširnejšemu prestrukturiranju in razdolževanju, saj so bili investicijski portfelji v času krize najhitreje in najmočneje na udaru (npr. britanska Royal Bank 9 of Scotland). Kljub temu pa številni primeri komercialno usmerjenih bank prikazujejo, da so se tudi tovrstne banke soočale z velikimi težavami, predvsem v obliki naraščajočih slabih posojil (npr. italijanska UniCredit, slovenska NLB). Zaradi neustreznega upravljanja s tveganji in slabših gospodarskih razmer v državah EMU (število stečajev in prisilnih poravnav se je v času krize zelo povečalo) so bile banke primorane opraviti večje odpise in slabitve, ki so negativno vplivali na zaupanje in kapitalsko ustreznost. Izguba zaupanja je zmanjšala obseg depozitov v bolj tveganih bankah in povzročila zastoj v medbančnem financiranju, od katerega so bile banke preveč odvisne. Prevelika izpostavljenost medbančnemu tveganju se je v času krize pokazala kot zelo tvegana in predstavlja resno grožnjo globalni finančni stabilnosti (Ahrend in Goujard, 2012). Kljub splošnemu nezaupanju na trgu so se pojavile pomembne razlike pri dostopu do medbančnega financiranja med bolj stabilnimi (zdravimi) in manj stabilnimi bančnimi sistemi (Tintchev, 2013). Posledica tega so bili nestandardni ukrepi ECB, ki so povrnili likvidnost na trgu ter preprečili hujše posledice. Negotovost in slabšanje kapitalske ustreznosti sta zmanjšali obseg kreditne aktivnosti in povzročile t. i. SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION Slika 2: Tržna koncentracija v bančnem sistemu – bilančna vsota 3 največjih bank glede na nacionalno bilančno vsoto v letu 2012 (v %) Vir: Bankscope in ECB podatki. kreditni krč. Na eni strani se je zaradi prevelike zadolženosti realnega sektorja zmanjšalo povpraševanje po kreditiranju, na drugi strani pa so bile banke zaradi ostrejših kapitalskih zahtev (s strani evropskega bančnega regulatorja) prisiljene zaostriti pogoje kreditiranja ter tako zmanjšati kreditno aktivnost (Valencia, 2008). Pomanjkanje kapitala obstoječih lastnikov in nizka donosnost kapitala (ROE), ki se je v času krize izrazito zmanjšala, sta bankam predstavljala velik izziv pri pridobitvi novega kapitala. Kljub nizkim cenam delnic (cena delnice se je npr. pri Société Générale od leta 2007 znižala za več kot 72 %) so investitorji oklevali pri nakupu bančnih delnic, saj so imeli številni alternativni vrednostni papirji zagotovljene višje donose in so bili predvsem varnejši (npr. države obveznice). Dobršen del bančnega sektorja je bil tako odvisen od državne pomoči, ki je od začetka krize do konca leta 2011 v EU znašala 1600 milijard € (12,8 % BDP EU). Jamstva so znašala 1.085 milijard €, dokapitalizacije 322 milijard €, oslabljena sredstva 120 milijard € in likvidnostni ukrepi 89 milijard €. Države so finančnemu sektorju pomagale tudi posredno, in sicer v obliki državnih pomoči realnemu sektorju. Tovrstna pomoč je od začetka krize do konca leta Slika 3: Bilančna vsota največjih bank v državah EMU glede na nacionalni BDP v letu 2012 (v %) Vir: Bankscope; IMF podatki. 10 2011 znašala 83 milijard € (Evropska komisija, 2012). Države so tako pomagale podjetjem v gospodarstvu, katerih bankrot bi negativno vplival na bilance bank v obliki novih oslabitev in odpisov ter posledično povzročil še večji pritisk na kapitalsko ustreznost (v ZDA npr. AIG, v EMU npr. francoski Peugeot). Posebna pozornost je (bila) namenjena sistemskim bankam, saj bi propad le-teh lahko povzročil hujše negativne posledice za celoten nacionalni finančni sistem. Sistemske banke so najpogosteje opredeljene po svoji bilančni vsoti, vendar spadajo med takšne tudi banke, ki lahko zaradi medsebojne povezanosti, kompleksnosti in (ne)nadomestljivosti finančne infrastrukture pomembno vplivajo na celoten finančni sistem. Med sistemsko pomembne banke bi lahko uvrstili banke, ki so uvrščene v kriterije nadzora ECB v prihajajoči bančni uniji. Med sistemsko pomembne banke bi tako uvrstili banke, katerih bilančna vsota presega 20 % nacionalnega BDP, banke z več kot 30 milijardami € bilančne vsote oz. vsaj tri največje banke v državi. V primerjavi izbranih držav EMU lahko vidimo precej različne stopnje tržne koncentracije v bančnem sistemu. V državah, kjer imajo največje tri banke zelo veliko stopnjo tržnega deleža, so z vidika nacionalne sistemske pomembnosti tovrstne banke še toliko bolj zavarovane pred morebitnim propadom. V Sloveniji in Nemčiji je v ospredju še velikost največje banke v državi. Medtem ko je razlika med največjo banko in preostalima dvema v drugih izbranih državah manjša (manj kot enkrat večja), je v Nemčiji največja banka Deutsche Bank po bilančni vsoti kar 2,17-krat večja kot druga največja nemška banka. V Sloveniji je največja banka NLB 1,69-krat večja kot druga največja banka v državi. V nasprotju z največjo slovensko banko Deutsche Bank BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION kljub tako veliki razliki ne predstavlja problema, saj je banka v relativno dobrem stanju zaradi obsežnih aktivnosti prestrukturiranja ter dobrega gospodarskega okolja v Nemčiji. V Sloveniji je situacija povsem drugačna, ker slabe gospodarske razmere, slabo korporativno upravljanje in nezmožnost prevladujočega lastnika za hitro ter učinkovito konsolidacijo predstavljajo še posebno velik problem. V prihodnje bo tudi zaradi posebnosti in majhnosti slovenskega gospodarstva treba zmanjšati razlike med bankami, s tem normalizirati bančni sektor in ga približati evropski strukturi. Ali z nadaljnjim krčenjem največje banke ali s krepitvijo drugih dveh bank (ali kakšne nove). Sistemske banke uživajo zaradi svojega statusa določene konkurenčne prednosti, predvsem v nižjih stroških financiranja, saj veljajo za manj tvegane, ker bodo (oz. so bile) v primeru težav deležne državne pomoči (Demirgüc-Kunt in Huizinga, 2010). V številnih državah se je v času krize pojavil problem prevelikih bank za reševanje, saj se tudi države soočajo s težavami financiranja. Spirala med bankami in državami je v zadnjih letih v EMU še posebej prisotna, zato je treba sprejeti nadaljnje ukrepe, ki naj bi rešili dano situacijo in preprečili nastanek podobnih problemov v prihodnje. Eden izmed ključnih tovrstnih ukrepov je prihajajoča bančna unija. Aktivnosti prestrukturiranja v času krize Prestrukturiranje bančnega sektorja v EMU je bilo od začetka krize do sedaj zelo omejeno. Nekatere države so predstavile reforme za sanacijo in prestrukturiranje svojega bančnega sistema, vendar na agregatni ravni do sedaj ni moč zaslediti večjega napredka. Čeprav lahko zaznamo zastoj rasti pri večini bank, se bilančna vsota bank v času krize ni bistveBV 11/2013 Slika 4: Delež posojil glede na bilančno vsoto v letu 2012 (v %) Vir: Bankscope. Državna pomoč bankam je do konca leta 2011 v EU znašala 1600 milijard evrov. no spremenila. Na obseg aktivnosti prestrukturiranja vplivajo poslovni modeli bank pred nastankom krize ter zmožnost hitrega reagiranja na spremenjeno gospodarsko okolje v času krize. Hitrost prestrukturiranja je močno odvisna od vpliva okolja, v katerem banke poslujejo, ter finančne sposobnosti lastnikov za hitro ter učinkovito prestrukturiranje. Po petih letih finančne in gospodarske krize številne banke še vedno niso zaključile procesa prestrukturiranja in razdolževanja v zadostnem obsegu, kar je za obstoj, zdravo rast in uspešno poslovanje nujno potrebno. Posledice so vidne v zastoju oz. zmanjšanju kreditnih aktivnosti predvsem za majhna in srednja podjetja. Pri večjih sistemskih bankah lahko zaznamo večje aktivnosti prestrukturiranja kot pri manjših bankah. To je posledica številnih pritiskov, ki so jih te banke deležne zaradi svojega sta11 tusa, tako s strani evropske komisije (banke, ki so bile deležne državne pomoči), evropskega bančnega regulatorja EBA (z zviševanjem zahtevane kapitalske stopnje), držav, v katerih poslujejo (da povečajo obseg kreditiranja in pomagajo gospodarstvu) in nenazadnje tudi lastnikov, ki zahtevajo večje donose. Na hitrost prestrukturiranja so pomembno vplivali tudi ECB z likvidnostnimi ukrepi ter državne pomoči, ki so bankam omogočile daljše časovno obdobje konsolidacije. Najpomembnejši cilj prestrukturiranja bank je zmanjšati obseg poslovanja z bolj tveganimi finančnimi instrumenti in preveliko odvisnost od medbančnega financiranja, ki se je v času krize izkazala za zelo negotovo. Namen tega je povrniti stabilnost in zaupanje v bančni sistem ter zmanjšati tveganje sistemske problematike. Večina sistemskih bank spada v kategorijo t. i. univerzalnih bank, saj ponujajo zelo širok nabor bančnih storitev. Kljub temu pa so poslovni modeli sistemskih bank precej različni. Pri investicijskih bankah, kot sta npr. Deutsche Bank in Société Générale, predstavljajo velik del poslovanja izvedeni finančni instrumenti ter druge tržne aktivnosti. Investicijske aktivnosti bank so v predkriznem času postale zanimivejše zaradi visokih donosov in slabe regulacije na tem SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION Slika 5: Delež slabih posojil v bruto posojilih v letu 2012 (v %) Vir: Bankscope. področju. Številne finančne inovacije so bankam omogočile ustvarjati nova posojila ter tako pridobiti dodatno likvidnost in sprostiti omejitve v kapitalskih zahtevah. Bančne bilance pogosto niso primerno ocenile tovrstnih tveganj, saj so bile tržne vrednosti velikokrat precej nižje kot knjigovodske vrednosti, po katerih banke vrednotijo sredstva. Aktivnosti prestrukturiranja bank so večinoma usmerjene v zmanjševanje tovrstnega poslovanja, ki se je izkazalo kot zelo tvegano in je bankam povzročilo velike izgube. Pri investicijskih bankah lahko v času krize zaznamo izrazito zmanjšanje deleža neobrestnih prihodkov v vseh prihodkih (npr. Crédit Agricole za 46,7 %, Deutsche Bank za 25,3 %). Banke so neobrestne prihodke večinoma nadomestile z obrestnimi prihodki, z usmeritvijo v komercialno bančništvo, ki je ponavadi manj tvegano od investicijskega. Kljub večji negotovosti investicijskih bank pa lahko v času krize zaznamo primerljive težave tudi v komercialnih bankah, torej bankah, katerih večji del poslovanja temelji na zbiranju depozitov in dajanju posojil. Številne komercialne banke v EMU se soočajo z naraščajočim deležem slabih terjatev, ki so posledica neustreznega upravljanja s tveganji in slabih gospodarskih razmer, ki še dodatno poslabšujejo posojilni portfelj. Delež slabih posojil je še posebej zaskrbljujoč v dveh največjih slovenskih bankah. Medtem ko se je delež slabih posojil pri večini bank v času krize povečal za nekaj odstotnih točk, se je delež tovrstnih posojil od leta 2007 v NKBM povečal za 22,67 odstotne točke in v NLB za 29,82 odstotne točke. Ti dve banki lahko uvrstimo v skupino Slika 6: Povprečen donos na kapital (ROE) v času krize (v %) Vir: Bankscope. 12 bank z npr. grško največjo banko, kjer je zaradi slabih gospodarskih razmer delež slabih posojil izrazito narasel in obsega okrog 30 % bruto posojil. Tolikšen obseg slabih posojil nam jasno prikaže izrazito slabo upravljanje s tveganji v času pred krizo. Delno lahko vzroke pripišemo slabim gospodarskim razmeram, vendar le-te niso toliko slabše, kot je povprečje v EMU. Vzroke gre tako iskati predvsem v pomanjkanju učinkovitega korporativnega upravljanja bank in prevelikem vplivu države kot pomembnega lastnika. Prav tako je vzrok neučinkovita sanacija slabega posojilnega portfelja, predvsem zaradi prepočasnih in premajhnih dokapitalizacij, ki bankama niso omogočile ustreznih rešitev, saj so se soočile s kapitalskimi omejitvami. Evropski bančni regulator je v času krize zvišal zahtevano kapitalsko ustreznost za vse banke EMU z namenom povečanja varnosti in stabilnosti. Pri sistemskih bankah je zahtevana kapitalska ustreznost še višja, in sicer 9 % najkakovostnejšega kapitala Core Tier 1. Čeprav je bilo določeno relativno dolgo časovno obdobje za dosego zahtevane stopnje, so številne banke te zahteve že dosegle. Tako so večinoma ohranile zaupanje komitentov, saj bi se lahko v nasprotnem primeru soočile z zmanjšanjem depozitov in obsegom poslovanja. Kljub temu je pridobitev svežega kapitala za marsikatero banko predstavljala velik izziv (spomnimo na probleme banke UniCredit pri 8 milijardah evrov visoki dokapitalizaciji v letih 2011/2012). Slaba donosnost glede na tveganost naložbe in pomanjkanje kapitala sta poglavitna razloga, ki sta odvrnila investitorje v nakup delnic bank. Obstoječi lastniki velikokrat niso bili sposobni oz. niso želeli dokapitalizirati bank, saj je bila donosnost kapitala prenizka. V predkriznih časih je ROE dosegal 15, tudi nad 20 %, medtem ko je bila povprečna donosnost v BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION času krize bistveno nižja. Pri tovrstnih stopnjah donosnosti in negotovosti v bančnem sistemu so investitorji (predvsem institucionalni) raje posegali po bolj donosnih in manj tveganih investicijah (npr. obveznice korporacij in držav). Kljub nizkim cenam delnic bank, ki so pri večini bank upadle za več deset odstotkov, so bili investitorji skeptični do tovrstnih investicij. Tržna kapitalizacija je v času krize padla na zelo nizke ravni, npr. pri UniCredit banki za več kot 70 %, pri Crédit Agricole za več kot 60 %. Pri nekaterih bankah lahko sicer že zaznamo pozitivno rast delnic, ki nakazuje, da so te banke že v večjem obsegu prestrukturirale svoje portfelje ter tako spet postale zanimivejše za investitorje. Zaradi problemov pri pridobitvi svežega kapitala v obliki dokapitalizacij so se banke bolj posluževale t. i. instrumenta bail-in oz. pridobitve kapitala s konvertibilnimi obveznicami. Značilnost konvertibilnih obveznic je, da banka takoj dobi potreben kapital (katerega kvaliteta zadostuje kriterijem regulatorja), ki pa se konvertira v delnice po vnaprej določenih kriterijih. Največkrat uporabljeni kriterij je zmanjšanje kapitalske stopnje pod določeno mejo. Investitorji konvertibilnih obveznic v tem primeru postanejo lastniki delnic, če pa pogoji za konverzijo niso izpolnjeni, pa se konvertibilne obveznice štejejo kot navadne obveznice (npr. obveznice CoCo). Bail-in je v času krize pogosto uporabljen instrument pridobitve svežega kapitala pri bankah in ima pozitivne posledice, saj lahko ublaži sistemska tveganja povezana z nenadzorovanimi stečaji in zmanjša pritisk razdolževanja (Zhou et al., 2012). Koncept bail-in bi bil lahko v prihodnje uporabljen ne samo pri lastnikih obveznic, pač pa tudi pri imetnikih depozitov nad vrednostjo 100.000 €. Tovrstna konverzija je bila uporabljena na Cipru, kjer BV 11/2013 Slika 7: Medbančno poslovanje v % bilančne vsote Vir: Bankscope. so imetnikom depozitov v lastniški delež konvertirali tolikšno vrednost depozitov, kolikor so potrebovali za pokritje izgub. Če bodo v prihodnje mogoče tovrstne konverzacije, je treba vnaprej postaviti veliko bolj jasna in pregledna pravila, da se bo natančno vedelo, kakšni so pogoji in kakšno je tveganje. Prav tako bi bilo treba v tem primeru razmisliti o večjem sodelovanju upnikov pri nadzorovanju in upravljanju banke. Ena izmed možnosti je zagotovljeno mesto v nadzornem svetu banke, kjer bi lahko upniki v določenem odstotku tudi glasovali. Torej sprejeti bi bilo treba zaveze za nominacijo upnikov v nadzorni svet, saj bi bili ti sedaj v veliko bolj tveganem položaju v primeru težav banke. Večji del aktivnosti prestrukturiranja bank je bil prav tako usmerjen v zmanjšanje medbančnih aktivnosti in učinkovitejše obvladovanje stroškov. Financiranje investicijskih in tudi posojilnih aktivnosti bank je pretežno temeljilo na kratkoročnem zadolževanju na trgu, predvsem na medbančnih trgih, ki pa so se v času krize izkazali kot zelo negotovi. V kriznih časih se je zaupanje izrazito zmanjšalo in predvsem manjše banke so izgubile (ali je bil le-ta zelo omejen) dostop do finančnih in medbančnih trgov. Tako lahko pri večini bank zaznamo zmanjšanje medbančnega poslovanja v času krize. Na zmanjšanje medbančnega 13 poslovanja je poleg negotovosti pomembno vplivala Evropska centralna banka z nestandardnimi ukrepi, ki jih je uporabila v času krize. Predvsem triletne operacije refinanciranja po zelo ugodni obrestni meri v decembru leta 2011 in v februarju leta 2012 so izrazito pripomogle k zmanjšanju negotovosti in povečanju likvidnosti v bančnem sistemu. Banke v EMU so si v dveh tovrstnih operacijah od ECB izposodile več kot 1.000 milijard evrov. Medbančna posojila so navadno krajše ročnosti, ECB pa je z nestandardnim ukrepom omogočila dolgoročna posojila, ki so za banke bolj zanimiva, saj tudi same pogosto dajejo posojila daljše ročnosti kot za obdobje enega leta, kolikor je bila ročnost posojil pri ECB pred uvedbo nestandardnih ukrepov. ECB je poleg odobritve daljših posojil prav tako znižala kriterije zavarovanj z vrednostnimi papirji. Pred krizo je sprejemala le državne obveznice, v času krize pa je poleg državnih obveznic v zavarovanje sprejemala tudi obveznice podjetij. Tako je bistveno povečala sposobnost bank za najetje dolgoročnih posojil. Prav tako se je s tem ukrepom zelo povečala odvisnost bank EMU od financiranja pri ECB. Pri tem se poraja vprašanje, kako ECB vidi izhod iz te situacije. Zaradi gospodarskih težav in še nedokončane konsolidacije dobršnega dela bančnega sektorja EMU obstaja SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION velika verjetnost, da bo ECB z različnimi nestandardnimi ukrepi še naprej posegala na bančni trg. Prihodnji ukrepi ECB bodo znani najkasneje konec leta 2014, ko zapade prva tranša triletnih posojil. Prihodnost bančnega sektorja je usmerjena v bančno unijo, ki bo predvidoma zaživela v začetku leta 2014. Bančna unija bo temeljila na mehanizmu skupnega nadzora, evropski jamstveni shemi in na mehanizmu za reševanje bank (sicer pod strogimi pogoji). Učinkovitost prestrukturiranja bančnega sektorja v EMU ni zadostna, kar se kaže v zmanjšanjem obsegu kreditiranja in s številnimi težavami, s katerimi se po petih letih krize soočajo mnoge banke. Lahko predvidevamo, da bi bili problemi bančnega sektorja manj razsežni pod strožjim in enotnim nadzorom. Prav tako bi bile banke sposobne učinkoviteje pridobiti svež kapital ter hitreje konsolidirati bilance. Čeprav je bančna unija projekt prihodnosti, bo gotovo pripomogla pri pridobitvi ponovnega zaupanja na trgu že z ustanovitvijo prihodnje leto in bo tako lahko del rešitve velike odvisnosti bank od financiranja pri ECB. Izzivi slovenskih sistemskih bank Primerjava dveh največjih bank v Sloveniji z izbranimi sistemskimi bankami v območju EMU nam jasno pokaže razsežnost težav dveh največjih slovenskih bank. Ne zgolj to, da sta se banki soočili z večjimi problemi kot večina preostalih bank, tudi hitrost konsolidacije je potekala počasneje in premalo učinkovito, kar je razsežnost težav le še povečalo. Del težav izhaja iz specifičnosti slovenskega gospodarstva in bančnega poslovanja, saj je bil velik del kreditiranja namenjen za nakup nepremičnin in velikim podjetjem (predvsem gradbenim podjetjem in finančnim holdingom). Prihod finančne in gospodarske krize je poslabšal poslovanje teh podjetij in povzročil zastoj na nepremičninskem trgu, kar pa je zelo močno prizadelo banke, ki so bile izpostavljene tovrstnim tveganjem. Izkazalo se je, da so bila zavarovanja kreditov neprimerna in da je bilo prisotno izrazito slabo upravljanje s tveganji. Banke so nase prevzemale prevelika tveganja, pričakovale preveč optimistične scenarije in bile izpostavljene pritiskom Evropska bančna unija bo predvidoma zaživela v začetku prihodnjega leta. ter vplivu politike. Vse to se je pokazalo v močnem poslabšanju posojilnega portfelja v času krize, ki se je iz leta v leto z odplačilom dobrih posojil in povečanim številom stečajev in prisilnih poravnav še poslabševal. Na drugi strani pa se je zmanjšalo kreditiranje in bankam so upadli obrestni prihodki. Banke so zaradi oslabitev in odpisov utrpele velike izgube iz poslovanja, kar je vplivalo na kapitalsko ustreznost ter povečalo pritiske po dokapitalizaciji. Zaradi prevladujočega lastniškega deleža države v obeh bankah je dokapitalizacija potekala prepočasi in ni bila izvedena v zadostnem obsegu, kar je posledica pomanjkanja sredstev lastnikov ter političnih napetosti in nepriljubljenosti tovrstnih aktivnosti v javnosti. Banki tako nista bili sposobni počistiti slabega dela 14 portfelja in hkrati zadostiti kapitalskim zahtevam EBA. Zato sta bili prisiljeni v krčenje bilanc, predvsem v obliki zmanjšanja obsega kreditiranja, kar pa je imelo negativne učinke na gospodarsko rast. Slaba praksa domačega lastništva v času pred krizo in v času krize je jasen znak, da je treba banke privatizirati. Velik izziv slovenskim bankam v prihodnje je prav tako sprememba v politiki kreditiranja. Previsoke obrestne mere v slovenskem bančnem prostoru, ki so približno 2 odstotni točki višje kot v povprečju EU, vplivajo negativno na konkurenčnost našega gospodarstva. Del problema je v slabših bonitetnih ocenah bank, kar jim zvišuje stroške virov, drugi del pa je prakticiranje gibljive obrestne mere v Sloveniji. Pri nizkih vrednostih euribora in visokih fiksnih pasivnih obrestnih merah je pri gibljivi obrestni meri (euribor plus dodana marža) obrestna marža lahko hitro negativna. Ta portfelj prinaša pomemben minus, vsako dodatno znižanje euribora pa bo primanjkljaj še povečalo. Rešitev je v večjem prakticiranju fiksne obrestne mere, morda najprej za kratkoročne posle, nato še za srednjeročne in dolgoročne obrestne mere, saj bodo v tem primeru obresti za posojila v Sloveniji bolj primerljive evropskim. Drug predlog je, da bi stranke v pogodbo o dolgoročnih hipotekarnih posojilih zapisale, da bosta pogodbenika po petih letih ocenila, kje sta z obrestne mero glede na položaj na trgu. Stranki lahko določita tudi npr. meje koridorja, kjer nato pri spremembah zunaj tega koridorja določita za novo petletno obdobje nekaj novega. Zaradi zahtev evropskih institucij in slabih rezultatov bank je sedaj pravi trenutek, da se opravita konsolidacija in prestrukturiranje slovenskega bančnega sektorja. V prvi vrsti je treba zmanjšati tržni delež največje banke in s tem sistemsko tveganje, ki BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION jo ta nevarnost prinaša. Prav tako je treba konsolidirati slovenske banke, predvsem največje tri. Pomemben del konsolidacije bo opravljen s pomočjo Družbe za upravljanje slabih terjatev oz. t. i. slabe banke, ki bo nase prevzela slabe terjatve bank v zameno za državne obveznice in tako počistila slab portfelj bank. Cena prenosa terjatev bo predvidoma izvedena po realni, torej tržni ceni, ki je velikokrat nižja od knjigovodske vrednosti, zato bodo banke po prenosu potrebovale dodatni kapital. Po čiščenju portfelja in dodatnem kapitalu in ob sočasni konsolidaciji realnega sektorja bodo banke spet zmožne kreditirati gospodarstvo ter tako potegniti Slovenijo iz krize. Za manjše banke bo prav tako nujno združevanje z namenom znižati stroške in postati uspešnejši ter konkurenčnejši. Zadnji in verjetno najpomembnejši korak prestrukturiranja je privatiza- BV 11/2013 cija bank, saj se je izkazalo, da je država kot prevladujoči lastnik dveh največjih bank izrazito posegala v upravljanje banke. Banke so zaradi slabega korporativnega upravljanja omogočile tolikšno zadolženost realnega sektorja ter s slabim upravljanjem s tveganji povzročile velike izgube v bančnem sistemu, katerega sanacija finančno in moralno zelo vpliva na državo kot celoto. Prodaja bank je edina garancija, da se tovrstne težave v tolikšnem obsegu in vplivu na državni proračun ne bodo več ponovile. S privatizacijo največjih slovenskih bank bo omogočeno učinkovito korporativno upravljanje bank v prihodnje. Brnnermeier, M. K., G. Dong in D. Palia (2012) Banks’ Non-Interest Income and Systemic Risk. Princeton University. LITERATURA IN VIRI / REFERENCES: Zhou, J., V. Rutledge, W. Bossu, M. Dobler, N. Jassaud in M. Moore (2012) From Bail-out to Bail-in: Mandatory Debt Restructuring of Systemic Financial Institutions. IMF Staff Discussion Note 12/03, Monetary and Capital Market Department and Legal Department, International Monetary Fund. Ahrend, R. in A. Goujard (2012) International Capital Mobility and Financial Fragility – Part 1. Drivers of Systemic Banking Crises: The Role of BankBalance-Sheet Contagion and Financial Account Structure. OECD, Economics Department Working Papers, No. 902, OECD Publishing. 15 Demirgüc-Kunt, A. in H. Huizinga (2010) Are Banks Too Big To Fail or Too Big To Save? International Evidence From Equity Prices and CDS Spreads. European Banking Center Discussion Paper No. 2010-15. EK (2012) Poročilo komisije – Dopolnitev statističnega pregleda državnih pomoči za leto 2012. Poročilo o državnih pomočeh, ki so jih dodelile države članice EU. Evropska Komisija, Bruselj. Liikanen, E. et al. (2012) High-level Expert Group on reforming the structure of the EU banking sector. Final Report, Bruselj. Tintchev, K. (2013) Connected to Whom? International Interbank Borrowing During the Global Crisis. IMF Working Paper 13/14, Monetary and Capital Markets Department, International Monetary Fund. Valencia, F. (2008) Banks’ Precautionary Capital and Credit Crunches. IMF Working Paper 08/248, Western Hemisphere Department, International Monetary Fund. SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION UDK 336.71(430) Rehabilitation of Financial Sector – The case of German banks REHABILITATION OF FINANCIAL SECTOR – THE CASE OF GERMAN BANKS This paper investigates the adjustment processes of the German banking sector and the government support measures since the outbreak of the international financial crisis in 2007 / 2008 and its worsening through the sovereign debt crisis in the euro zone starting in spring 2010. With the help of government interventions and the previously introduced adjustment processes, the looming collapse of some credit institutions and overall risk of a systemic crisis was prevented. But in the long run, the increasing competitive pressure requires a reorientation of many business models and a further consolidation in the German banking sector to safeguard the financial stability. JEL G01 G18 G21 G28 I Albrecht F. Michler and H. Jörg Thieme* n the aftermath of the outbreak of the subprime crisis in the United States in 2007 and the severe turmoil on the U.S. and the international markets, the German banking system was affected as well, because some commercial banks and especially the state-owned Landesbanken had significant positions of toxic assets on their balance sheets or were directly involved in the construction and financing of special purpose vehicles. I. Introduction The partly dramatic problems of individual banks were exacerbated by the sovereign debt crisis in some member states of the euro zone (the GIPSY countries: Greece, Ireland, Portugal, Spain and Italy) since spring 2010. Finally, the economic stagnation in the developed countries and important emerging markets has slowed down the dynamic of the German economy at the end of 2008 and in 2009. The conditions for a sustainable recovery process of the German financial sector were very poor so far. How have the affected banks reacted in the crisis? To which extent were the individual commercial banks involved? Does sufficiently reliable empirical material exist about the potential and actual losses from bad investment and credit lending decisions of individual banks? Who had to compensate the realised losses and who will compensate the potential future losses? Finally: Which role do parliaments, governments and the European Central Bank play in the management of the financial crisis? Which ad hoc measures were realised by the policy? * Albrecht F. Michler and H. Jörg Thieme, Heinrich-Heine-University of Duesseldorf. 16 BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION et al. 2004). In addition, mortgage banks and building and loan societies operate in all pillars, providing mid- and long-term credits secured against real estate (Table 1). The privately-owned commercial banks represent the largest segment by assets and are currently composed of (a) four large banking groups (Deutsche Bank AG, Commerzbank AG, Deutsche Postbank AG and the foreign-owned UniCreditBank AG); (b) medium and smallsized banks; (c) and some branches of foreign banks (IMF 2011:4). The big banks are universal banks, operating retail and corporate banking as well as investment banking. Some banking groups have an international focus, other banks are more regionally oriented or otherwise specialised. The public banking sector consists of the Landesbanken as well as the Sparkassen (savings banks). The associated governance structure entail that multiple levels of government are involved: in the case of the Sparkassen the local governments and in the case of the Landesbanken the government of a German Federal Are the reactions only a short-term orientated regulation of processes to gain time or is a long-term strategy observable? To answer these questions some knowledge about the structure of the German banking system is necessary (II.). Then the problems of individual banks and banking groups are marked briefly without an extensive empirical analysis due to the limit space (III.). In chapter IV the various strategies and adjustment processes in the German banking sector to overcome the crisis are described and critically analysed. Finally, we give an outlook on the future development of the German banking sector (V.) II. The structure of the German banking system The German banking system is composed of three different pillars: commercial banks, banks of the public sector and credit cooperatives which differ with respect to objectives and ownership (for a detailed structural analysis, see IMF 2011 and the older analysis of Brunner Land, regional Sparkassen associations or the national savings association (Brunner et al. 2004:3; Hüfner 2010:8-9). The public owners have different interests: local governments may wish that the savings banks are engaged in public-policy or (politically) motivated activities in the community. If the local governments have equity holdings in their Landesbank, they are more interested in receiving high yields. On the other hand, the Federal Land Government, however, may be currently much less interested in the profitability of its Landesbank and more interested to preserve its stability. In former times the Landesbanken also were an instrument of industrial and structural policy objectives. With these publicly-owned banks unprofitable enterprises were saved and new corporate groups were founded. Only the Landesbanken were engaged in international business and for some Landesbanken like the former WestLB, investment banking overseas was a major business of their activities (for an overview see IMF 2011:6). For a long time, the the publicly-owned banks benefited from Table 1: Structural data on German credit institutions Category of banks All categories of banks Commercial banks - Big banks 1 - Regional banks - Branches of foreign banks Landesbanken Saving banks Regional institutions of credit cooperatives Credit cooperatives Mortgage banks Special purpose banks Memo item Building and loan associations Number of institutions 2006 2012 2,130 1,869 360 295 5 4 217 177 138 113 12 9 457 423 2 2 Number of branches in Germany 2006 2012 38,517 34,571 11,578 9,610 8,879 7,041 2,623 2,444 76 125 496 451 13,756 12,643 11 11 Number of employees 2006 2012 662,200 633,650 186,700 172,900 39,500 257,000 4,900 34,000 244,900 5,150 1,259 22 18 1,104 17 20 12,583 61 32 11,778 49 29 161,200 159,750 12,900 16,950 26 22 1,795 1,668 18,050 14,650 Source: Bundesbank (2007:19, 2012b:24, 2013:104). 1 Deutsche Bank AG, Dresdner Bank AG (until November 2009), Commerzbank AG, from January 1999. BV 11/2013 17 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION government guarantees (Anstaltslast and Gewährträgerhaftung) and the more favourable refinancing options on the capital markets. These government guarantees were terminated in July 2005 to bring the German system of government guarantees for publicly-owned banks in line with the state aid rules of the EC treaty. But the grandfathering arrangements in the period 2001-2005 remain valid until 2015. The cooperative banks (“Volksbanken”, “Raiffeisenbanken” and “Spar- und Darlehenskassen“) are owned by their members who are usually their borrowers as well as depositors. These banks usually operate on a regional scheme but are not limited. The major objective is to support their members, which represent more than half of the customers. Each cooperative bank has its own supervisory and executive board, but to a large extent they operate under a single brand. The cooperative sector has its own mutual guarantee scheme which maintains an institution (rather than a deposit) insurance to manage risk (Brunner et al. 2004:4). The two regional banks (DZ Bank AG and WGZ Bank AG) act as central institutions for the cooperative banks and provide a range of services for the primary banks. Since the beginning of the financial crisis, there has been a reduction in the number of credit institutions, the number of branches and of employees in the most categories of banks. However, the shrinking of the banking sector may have been caused not so much by the financial crisis, but it may reflect a strong consolidation trend of the last two decades. The number of banks has decreased by 44 per cent since 1990. But in contrast to other European countries with a similar banking system, the flexibility for cross-pillar restructuring in Germany was low. The consolidation has taken place largely within the same pillar and mostly in the public and cooperative sector. In many cases the consolidation was the result of a stress situation and not the result of a proactive business strategy. Currently the German law prohibits privately-owned banks to take stakes in publicly-owned banks that are created by law rather than incorporated. As a result, the banking system exhibits a lower degree of openness to private shareholders compared to that in other EU countries. Between commercial banks we see a few cases of consolidation (the take-over of Dresdner Bank AG by Commerzbank AG and the take- Some commercial banks suffered substantial losses from their investment portfolios. over of Deutsche Postbank AG by Deutsche Bank AG) in part driven by the financial crisis (IMF 2011:7). According to indicators on the supply of banking services, the German banking system exhibits more competition than banking systems in some other European countries. The number of credit institutions is relatively larger than in other EU countries. Also, the German system is less concentrated; Germany has a relative low Herfindahl concentration index. The large number of banks and employees mainly reflects the high number of primary banks in 18 the public and cooperative sector. But these two pillars operate largely on the regional principle and the competition within each pillar is low. Most empirical studies find no microeconomic evidence for a more intense competition in Germany than elsewhere. Like in other countries, empirical studies find monopolistic competition in the banking system (Brunner et al. 2004:21-23; Hüfner 2010:15). In contrast to this result, German banks have on average shown low profitability compared with the banking system in other European countries. Regardless of the measures used, none of three banking pillars compares favourably in performance with other European comparators. Es pecially for the larger banks the low profitability has not been compensated for by lower risk, the performance remains generally below average (IMF 2011:14-18; Hüfner 2010:1315). According to Bundesbank statistics (i each September the monthly report gives a detailed overview of the performance) the average after-tax return on equity (ROE) of the commercial banks was slightly above the return of the primary banks in the public and cooperative sector before the financial crisis (sample period 1994 – 2007). As a result of the crisis when the sample period is expanded to include 2008 and 2009 the performance of the commercial banks was slightly below the ROE of the primary banks. The profitability of the Landesbanken is, however, on average well below the performance of the two other banking groups (IMF 2011:14). The weak profitability of the banks is mainly attributable to weak revenue generation and, less importantly, relatively high operational costs, and relative cost efficiency remains at levels comparable to those of the EU peers. Nonetheless, German banks – and particularly BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION Sparkassen – show higher than average cost-to-income ratio, driven by the higher operational costs still faced, notwithstanding the ongoing consolidation. Partly the relatively low profitability of the German banking sector could reflect the fact that profit maximisation is not the major objective of the banks in the public and cooperative sector. Another conclusion is a widespread underpricing of risk and a lower proportion of high-value-added activities owing to a less innovative market environment (Brunner et al. 2004:18). III. Problems of the German financial sector and the government rescue measures During the crisis, the direct exposures to toxic assets as well as the turmoil in the interbank markets put several institutions into difficult. Particularly some commercial banks and the Landesbanken (LB) suffered substantial losses from their investment portfolios. Due to their weak business model and the related weak earnings, these banks had invested heavily in structured products before the crisis (Hüfner 2010:5, Table 1). With the hope that they can realise an additional yield pickup without a change in their overall risk situation. Without immediate government aid, these banks would have collapsed very quickly, whereas the primary banks of the public and the cooperative sector showed relatively stable profitability and had continuous access to stable funding from retail deposits. The government rescue measures can be divided into several phases (IMF 2011:8; Hüfner 2010:5). Until the fall of Lehman Brothers in autumn 2008, government involvement comprised mostly stand-alone actions for individual banks. Four banks (IKB and the three Landesbanken WestLB, BayernLB and SachsenLB) received capital injections, credit lines and asset-backed security loss guarantees. In a second period, a more comprehensive support package was followed the rescue of Hypo Real Estate (HRE) at the end of September 2008. On 5 October 2008 the Federal Government guaranteed all private bank accounts and one week later the government announced the installation of the Financial Market Stabilization Fund (SoFFin). This institution can guarantee up to EUR 400 bn of bank financing and use EUR 70 bn for recapitalisation and asset purchases (the amount can be increased by EUR 10bn on the approval of the Budget Committee of the parliament). Table 2 gives a summary of all rescue packages until mid-2013. On the one hand the government aid and guarantees have successfully stabilized the German banking sector in the short term and have merely prevents the collapse of the institutes and reduces the overall risk of a systemic crisis. But on the other side the situation of the institutions has not been sustainably improved through the various public interventions. None of the mentioned banks in Table 2 currently has a convincing business model for a long-run orientation. The balance sheets of troubled institutions will, however, take time and continued efforts to be cleaned up. Against this background the overall costs that must be paid by the taxpayer cannot be estimated reliably at current time. In addition, Table 2: Government rescue packages after the collapse of Lehman Brothers in 09/2008 Government aid EUR billions Commerzbank Hypo Real Estate 2 BayernLB LBBW IKB 3 HSH Nordbank 4 WestLB 1 Aareal Bank Government guarantees EUR billions total repaid total 18.2 9.8 10.0 5.0 8.4 3.0 3.0 0.5 13.1 0.0 0.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 5.0 124.0 19.8 12.7 10.0 10.0 5.0 4.0 State's holding Balance sheet in percent EUR billions at before after present the crisis the crisis 0.0 0% 17% 0.0 0% 100% 4.8 50% 75% 12.7 59% 59% 0.0 38% 0% 10.0 55% 85% 5.0 49% 100% 0.0 0% 0% 6155 395 416 500 48 204 268 40 637 169 266 307 28 121 686 44 Resolu- Losses tion for the agencies tax payers 7 EUR billions 136 137 27 16 44 82 -3.7 -19.1 -9.0 -3.8 -8.2 -1.0 -4.3 -0.1 Source: Wirtschaftswoche (2013:8). 1 main parts were carved out and sold; 2 including the loss compensation for the public bad bank FMS Wertmanagement; 3 costs were borne by the public development bank KfW, which assumed the credit lines for ist former subsidiary IKB; 4 wants to repay the state aid completely, 1 bio EUR of reserves were already formed; 5 without Dresdner Bank; 6 successor company Portigon; 7 profit and loss for the German taxpayers. BV 11/2013 19 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION it must be noted that the European Commission approved the rescue package only with conditions that means that these banks have to adjust their business models including cost-cutting, downsizing, refocusing, and ownership change to ensure long-term viability. IV. General adjustments of the banking system to the financial crisis Proactive adjustments of the banking groups In a first phase from mid-2007 to the end of 2009, major German banks with an international focus reduced their leverage by reducing their balance sheets and increasing their capital. The breakdown of the interbank markets was reflected in the balance sheets of the major banks – that did not offload toxic assets or liabilities to resolution agencies – in falling interbank claims and liabilities. The claims on and liabilities to banks fell by more than 35 per cent, which was much more than the rate of contraction of total assets (13 per cent). The institutions’ claims on nonbanks shrank by the smaller margin of just under 15 per cent. Domestic claims fell by round about 5 per cent and foreign claims by roughly 25 per cent. On the other hand, the major German banks increased equity by over 26 per cent However, this was mainly due to injections of government funds (Bundesbank 2012a:32). The observable reduction in credit lending was not the result of a credit crunch. The credit constraint indicator of the Ifo Institute – based on ca. 4,000 responses of firms industry and trade – for example showed no dramatic increase during the crisis years 2008 and 2009, and the indicator decreases significantly since the beginning of 2010. More than anything, the reduction in credit lending was the result of a weak economic development caused particularly by a strong fall in the net exports. Moreover, lending by those categories of banks which were less affected by the global financial crisis remained stable. The lending of primary banks of the public and cooperative sector increased between June 2007 and December 2009 (Bundesbank 2012a:33). The German banking system thus remained fully functional at the peak of the international financial crisis. For this reason, some of the monetary policy actions of the ECB in the last years to support the economic recovery in the euro zone were not mandatory from a German point of view. German banks concentrated their deleveraging on assets denominated in US dollar. This was a result of the USD funding gap of the institutes which had widened during the crisis. For a time, the gap amounted to more than USD 200 bn., which reflected a dangerous currency mismatch for German banks’ USDdenominated claims. Until the end of 2010, the institutions reduced their USD-denominated activities and issued more USD debt securities. Since autumn 2010, the gap of all German banks, including their foreign branches and foreign subsidiaries, has been below its pre-crisis level. The German banking system has thus become less susceptible to shocks in the USD markets. Therefore, German banks have been less affected by the US money market funds’ reduction of European exposures. The remaining demand for USD can now be covered through the swap markets (Bundesbank 2012a:33-34). Since the collapse of Lehman Brothers holdings of asset-backed securities (ABS) have declined markedly even at those institutions which have not offloaded assets or liabilities to banking resolution agencies. The falling book value was mainly due to maturities, repayments, redemp20 tions and amortisations. Following the large-scale impairment charges recognised at the start of the financial crisis, the remaining write-downs amounted to EUR 4.8 bn (Bundesbank 2012a:34). Since the beginning of 2010, nearly all major banks have seen deterioration in the average rating of their ABS portfolios. In the case of five institutions, at least a fifth of their paper is now rated as non-investment grade. The legacy portfolios of crisis-prone asset-backed securities continue to stress the German banking system. The European sovereign debt crisis has been impacting on the financial markets since spring 2010 with the tremendous refunding problems of Greece. It has triggered new adjustments in the German financial system, which so far have been accompanied by favourable domestic conditions, with robust economic activity and a good credit quality. The sovereign debt crisis is having a clear impact on the balance sheet structure of the German banking system. The banks’ balance sheets reflect the increasing fragmentation of the European banking system. Although the balance sheets of the major banks show a remarkable increase in claims on banks between the end of 2009 and 2012, this was mostly inflated by a rise in balances with central banks. After adjustment for claims on the Bundesbank, the corrected increase is significantly reduced (Bundesbank 2012a:35). The adjustment to the debt crisis made by the (major) banks is revealed by the marked reduction in their exposures to debtors from the GIPSY countries between mid-2010 and 2012. This reduces per se the danger of crossborder contagion effects. The debt sustainability of government budgets is now being seen in a much more nuanced way than at the start of the euro zone crisis. Yet the German banking sector does BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION not currently appear to be following a general strategy of reducing its international business model. The foreign lending business of the banks has fallen only moderately since the start of the sovereign debt crisis. By withdrawing to the domestic market, German banks would lose the opportunities on foreign growth markets and chances for diversification their business. The robust activity in the German economy – which was and is the result of a high (international) competitiveness and a high ability of shock absorption, due to the serious and at the same time painful structural ad justment processes within the 2000s years – has proved to be a major factor underpinning the profitability of the banks. Even in the crisis year 2009 the gross write-downs of all banks in Germany in domestic lending business showed only a marginal increase. The volatile net trading income, under which the high losses in 2008 also arose, showed a steady decline after picking up slightly for a time in 2009. As proprietary trading on the capital market proved to be unsustainable in the crisis, a number of institutions have stopped or reduced their prop trading activities (Bundesbank 2012a:36). The major banks have clearly increased their tier 1 capital ratios. These banks are thus responding to the heightened demands of the capital markets, the regulatory requirements of the European Banking Authority (EBA) and new Basel III capital rules, which have already been partly anticipated. Between March 2008 and September 2012, the tier 1 capital of the major banks increased from 8.3 per cent to 13.6 per cent of risk-weighted assets. Since March 2008, the leverage ratio – measured as the ratio of total assets to tier 1 capital – of the major banks has fallen from 43 to 32 (Bundesbank 2012a:37). The BV 11/2013 average leverage ratio was lowered, in particular, by conditions set by the EU Commission to reduce total assets in connection with reviewing state aid. In 2012, the credit cooperatives and savings banks had a distinctly lower tier 1 capital ratio than the major banks. They additionally possess undisclosed reserves, however. In mid-2012, their average leverage ratios, at 16.6 and 14.9, were well below the mean figure of the other banks. The lower leverage of the cooperative and savings banks is due to their business model, which is geared to traditional lending business. Despite the improvement, The number of banks has decreased by 44 per cent since 1990. German banks’ leverage is still high by comparison with other countries (IMF 2011: 10). The level of regulatory capital to be held by the major banks has declined since March 2008. This was due, first of all, to a shortening of the balance sheet. As exposures to banks have been reduced and the percentage of loans with a low probability of default has increased, the volume of risk-weighted assets has contracted markedly, and hence the required level of regulatory capital has also declined. Since the beginning of 2009, the average risk weight of the exposures held by the major banks has fallen. The nascent economic upturn in Germany has lowered the risk weight for exposures 21 to enterprises. Robust domestic economic activity has helped the German banking system to cope with the strains from the problem business areas. For example, it is currently helping to cushion the impact of the international shipping crisis. The market risks reported by the German credit institutions have undergone mixed developments since the outbreak of the financial crisis. The risk from changes in credit spreads already played a major role for some banks prior to 2010. Since the onset of the European sovereign debt crisis, it has become considerably more important owing to the price fluctuations of sovereign bonds. Interest rate risk, on the other hand, has been largely unchanged since beginning of the last decade. It results from traditional banking business, i.e. the granting of long-term loans which are refinanced by short-term customer deposits. Large banks with an international focus pass on much of their interest rate risk to insurers and other financial intermediaries, for example in the form of interest rate swaps. By contrast, many savings banks and credit cooperatives deliberately incur this risk in order to generate income from maturity transformation or to avoid the cost of hedging. In the middle of the past decade, equity price risk posed a substantial threat – especially to the larger, private commercial banks. Since then, its importance has steadily declined; like the risk from changes in volatility and unmatched foreign exchange positions, it is now, if anything, of secondary importance. Reactions of the other market side At the peak of the financial crisis many (private) bank clients in Germany rearrange their investments at the expense of risky assets and in favour of low-risk investments. The development was reinforced by the public announcement of the Federal SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION Government to guarantee all deposits in autumn 2008. Table 3 shows remarkable changes in the level of the deposits and borrowing from domestic enterprises and households as well as in the market shares of the different banking groups. Particularly notable is the rapidly increasing refinancing share of commercial banks in the domestic sector (from 26.4 per cent in 2006 to 33.6 per cent at the end of 2012). Interesting in the first phase of the crisis is also the increasing role of savings banks and credit cooperatives for the sight deposits. In contrast to the large commercial banks and public Landesbanken the primary banks of the public and cooperative sector had virtually no toxic assets on the balance sheets and enjoyed the confidence of the population. The increased liquidity flows in favour of the small banks, however, led to the problem, that the development of the high-quality lending business could not keep step with the business on their liabilities side. The declining distortions on the financial markets in the last years led to a rebound in risk appetite and to a reversal of the redeployment processes. The traditional breakdown of the banking relations plays a larger role again. The business account of small and mid-size enterprises is often held at the savings or cooperative banks because the lending process is less complicated and faster in comparison with the procedure at the major banks and their branches. However, the personal accounts of wealthy private customers are often found in major or private banks. The retail customers assume that these banks have a better expertise in private banking. As a result it can be stated that although the level of deposits and borrowing from domestic sources has risen significantly, the structural adjustments also point to increased competition between the domestic banking groups for scarce refinancing sources. The dependence of German banks on the international capital markets has decreased overall. Needless to say that this development has been supported by the international low-interest rate setting. V. Outlook A number of structural developments are posing a challenge to German banks’ profitability over the midterm. These structural shifts raise new issues concerning the balance of banks’ business segments. Credit institutions thus need to adapt their business models promptly to the changing environment. First, competitive pressure will increase in the domestic markets. From our point of view, the current low-interest rate environment could further continue also within the next years since the European sovereign debt crisis and the potential risks accompanying with that are not removed over the mid-term. The required structural adjustments in many member states of the euro area stand only at the beginning and their systematic continuation is permanently endangered. In connection with this, neither the European Central Bank nor the governments of the member countries are really interested in a higher interest rate level. There is rather the danger of a policy of “financial repression” with negative real interest rates – produced by a more or less moderate inflation and by low long-term nominal interest rates – which could reduce the real sovereign debt durably. In this scenario the pressure on margins will increase further in the German banking system because the interest margins remain constant (this is the most favourable case) or – this is the most probable case – will Table 3: Deposits and borrowing from domestic enterprises and households Banking groups All categories of banks EUR billions Commercial banks share in percent Saving banks share in percent Credit cooperatives share in percent Year 2006 2009 2012 2006 2009 2012 2006 2009 2012 2006 2009 2012 Total 2,394.6 2,829.7 3,090.2 26.4% 30.3% 33.6% 27.2% 25.4% 25.1% 17.7% 16.8% 17.3% Sight deposits 747.7 1,029.5 1,306.5 43.1% 42.1% 42.6% 29.0% 29.8% 28.8% 18.7% 19.5% 20.3% including: Time Savings deposits deposits 962.8 586.5 1,102.6 594.9 1,072.5 617.6 21.6% 16.1% 26.1% 20.8% 31.4% 19.8% 7.3% 50.9% 5.6% 47.7% 4.6% 47.9% 8.7% 30.1% 7.5% 29.0% 6.4% 30.0% Bank savings bonds 97.5 103.2 93.6 8.1% 13.5% 22.1% 67.1% 62.9% 58.3% 23.0% 19.9% 18.2% Source: Bundesbank (2013:68-71), Bundesbank online macroeconomic time series database and own calculations 22 BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION decrease further. The opportunities for an expansion of the non-interest business are also restricted and already have not realized any sustained increase in earnings within the last few years. Second, banks could be crowded out as financial intermediaries and thus lose some of their market share, as a result of the trend towards corporate funding via the capital markets. This trend remains unchanged – despite the increasing defaults of SME bonds (bonds of small and medium enterprises) in the last months – as long as non-financial corporations can issue their bonds to the same or even more favourable conditions than the major banks in Germany. The large credit institutions have to go more and more into the financing of small and medium-sized enterprises which cannot refinance their business via the capital markets. But these market segments are traditionally occupied by the savings and cooperative banks. The competitive pressure will increase further by the market entry of new competitors. The low-interest rate environment and the new regulatory framework (the future rules of Solvency II) in the insurance industry are the reasons already today that insurers enter the traditional segments of banks and especially the markets of the savings banks and credit unions. An example is the market for the financing of private real estates. Finally foreign banks will penetrate more and more into the German markets with the increasing financial integration between the European retail markets. The higher competitive pressure can be seen already today in the regions near the border. Third, essential regulatory measures will inevitably place a burden on banks’ earnings, as did the contribution to the German restructuring fund (bank levy), which was payable for the first time in 2011, and the regulaBV 11/2013 tory surcharge on the costs of synthetic lending business. The changed regulatory environment due to the new rules of Basel III will tighten the business conditions for all German banks. The leverage ratio introduced by Basel III might put additional pressure, particularly on the business model of the highly-leveraged institutions. Not only the new regulatory capital framework but rather the compliance with the new liquidity requirements can endanger especially the traditional business of savings banks and credit unions. The new Net Stable Funding Ratio (NSFR) German banks concentrated their deleveraging on assets denominated in US dollar. could restrict the opportunities of the maturity transformation between the two sides of their balance sheet. The competitive advantages of the saving banks and the credit unions over the major banks – due to the strong refinancing via the traditional deposit business – would be partly removed. Looking at the long-run adjustment strategies – particularly for smaller banks – the opportunities of the credit institutions are restricted. For the German savings banks and credit unions neither specialisation or niche strategy nor cost leadership is possible. At first, the banks will be able to encounter the increasing 23 competitive pressure with another cost reduction. Besides the elimination of existing X inefficiencies in the individual institutions, we will see another consolidation phase especially in the cooperative sector but also in the sector of the savings banks. The number – particularly the credit unions – will further drop considerably. This consolidation process is not only the result of the difficult market environment but also the result of the increased regulation of the banking sector which overburdens the smaller credit institutions especially covering the human and material resources. The further (cross-pillar) consolidation among banks in the public and the cooperative sector can help to stimulate the economies of scale and the economies of scope and therefore to improve the efficiency of the cost structure, to reduce the cost-toincome ratio, and to strengthen the business viability and stability in both pillars of the banking system for the next years. The experiences with the financial crisis also have shown that the German banking model has clear advantages despite the lower profitability and the apparently low efficiency in comparison with Europe. The smaller German banks with their low risk lending activities and their strong deposit banking business guaranteed the credit supply in Germany also when the financial crisis was at its peak, because these banks were not really influenced by the distortions on the international capital and interbank markets. The problems in the German banking sector were essentially concentrated in some larger credit institutions, in which particularly the troubles in numerous Landesbanken without a clear business model is conspicuous. As a result, these publicly-owned banks without an acceptable business model should gradually be liquidated or privatised and the influence of the politics SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION should be reduced quickly. The involvement of private shareholders in publicly-owned banks’ capital could increase monitoring of the banks’ activity, with some more improvements. Under this business environment banks would face clearer incentives to improve their efficiency, to achieve a balanced risk-return profile, and better disclosure and transparency are promoted. The impact of political motivated lending decisions would be reduced without, for example, basically questioning the social role of savings banks. The demand of some German politicians and bankers to establish a second national champion (for example the Commerzbank AG) beside the Deutsche Bank AG seems not useful from our point of view. In the international business Deutsche Bank AG is subject to the competition with other major banks with an international focus. The refinancing of German large-scale enterprises via the capital markets does not depend on the nationality of the (investment) banks. On the domestic markets the competitive pressure will not increase only for the small banks but also for Deutsche Bank AG. From a regulatory point of view there is a risk that a second global systemically important bank (G-SIB) is created, a bank that is too big to fail or to interconnected to fail. To achieve a sustainable financial stability, the number of systemically important banks should be kept as small as possible to ensure market entry and exit at any time. References: Brunner, A., Decressin, J., Hardy, D. and B. Kudela (2004), Germany’s three-pillar banking system. Cross-country perspectives in Europe, IMF Occasional Paper No. 233, Washington, D.C. Bundesbank (2007), The performance of German credit institutions in 2006, in: Deutsche Bundesbank Monthly Report 09/2012, 15-39 24 Bundesbank (2012a), The German banking system five years into the financial crisis, in: Financial Stability Review 2012, Frankfurt/M, 31-40. Bundesbank (2012b), The performance of German credit institutions in 2011, in: Deutsche Bundesbank Monthly Report 09/2012, 13-45. Bundesbank (2013), Banking Statistics, Statistical Supplement 1 to the Monthly Report, August 2013. Hau, H. and M. Thum (2009), Subprime crisis and board (in-)competence: Private vs public banks in Germany, in: Economic Policy, Vol. 24/60, 701-752. Hüfner, Felix (2010), The German banking system: Lessons from the financial crisis, OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 788, Paris. Ianotta, G., G. Nocera and A. Sironi (2007) Ownership structure, risk and performance in the European banking industry, in: Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 31, 2127-2149. IMF (2011), IMF Country Report 11/370, Germany: Technical note on banking sector structure, Washington, D.C. Weil, L. (2009), Convergence in banking efficiency across European countries, in: Journal of International Financial Markets, Vol. 19, 818-833. Wirtschaftswoche (2013), No. 37, 09.09.2013, 8-9. BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION UDK 336.71(436) Rehabilitation of Financial Sector – The case of Austrian Banks REHABILITATION OF FINANCIAL SECTOR – THE CASE OF AUSTRIAN BANKS The financial crisis unravelling in September 2008 led to unexpected shocks in the financial system and a deep mistrust into banks and banks distrusting each other. Liquidity pools were dry, the interbank market non-existent. In this critical situation the Austrian Government together with the competent authorities took quick and decisive measures to avert negative consequences from Austrian banks as much as possible. This paper discusses and evaluates the specific measures taken and tries to give an outlook based on lessons learnt. JEL G01 G18 G21 G28 F Otto Lucius* inancial crisis and / or financial stability (or to be more precise: the stability of the financial system) are buzzwords nowadays. This is true not only in economic discussions, but also for the public, including politicians and journalists. Why this? There are two simple reasons: First, in our times the financial system is far more complex than in the past. Times are gone when merchant banks with a capital ratio of 80 or 100 per cent were able to finance industrial development. And even when the so-called industrial revolution took place those privately owned banks, like Rothschild, Sal. Oppenheim, just to name a few, had to turn into stock listed companies in order to be able to finance huge industrial ventures, e.g. building of railways lines and other infrastructure measures. 1. Introduction The evolving industry itself quickly reached the limits of liquidity and had to rely on external financing. This is why some 200 hundred years ago capital markets gained such importance, now functioning as financing source besides traditional credit supply by banks. With the growing importance of capital markets not only financial instruments were at the heart of activities. It were derivatives on financial instruments gaining ever more importance especially over the last twenty years. Of course there were many reasons for this; however, one factor facilitating the growth of derivatives was freedom of capital movements and the resulting globalisation of financial markets. Prof. (FH) Mag. Otto Lucius, CFP, EFA, Managing Director Austrian Society for Bank Research (BWG). * BV 11/2013 25 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION Second, we experienced a financial crisis five years ago. And unlike other financial crises since the big banking crisis in the thirties, this crisis is not over yet. The shockwaves were manifold and still to be felt in everyday life. We have to keep in mind that the financial crisis of 2008 quickly turned into a debt crisis of sovereigns, this debt crisis still being unresolved. And sovereigns are heavily dependent on financing through the financial system. There is no quick solution with a guaranteed happy end. This is why the debate on a more resilient financial system is not going to end soon.1 Therefore, it might be useful to start with the unfolding of the financial crisis some years ago and to remember some simple facts. 2. The unfolding of the financial crisis2 The financial crisis of 2008 was often compared to the banking crisis of 1931 and the following Great Depression. Fortunately that’s not true. Of course we have experienced several crises since the fifties. There was, for example, the Asian crisis of 1997. And we witnessed the dot. com bubble bursting. And there were some minor crashes along. However, none of these crashes and crises lasted for longer than one or two years. To paraphrase a book title by Reinhart and Rogoff: “This time is different”. Is it really different? Of course there is never monocausality in explanations for a crisis. And there are many reasons for the last crisis. Anyway, the trigger for the crisis was rather simple and could have been seen if someone would have been willing to see. In 2002/2003, the political will that every American should have a home of its own and the policy of low interest rates of the Fed coincided. In the following years, the housing markets in the U.S. experienced a huge upswing. With everyone expecting rising prices in real estate “forever” US banks became rather negligent in their lending practices on the one hand and consumers became reckless about their ability to repay loans in the future. This caused consumers to invest more than they could afford into housing mortgages. The Fed, however, having followed a policy of “cheap money” for some years was forced to raise rates in 2006/2007.3 On the other hand, the booming Overall Austria registered 867 banks at year-end 2008. market of mortgage loans prompted financial engineering in the form of securitisation. As it often happens, history is influenced by a person having a completely different intention. This time it was a Chinese, David X. Li, an actuary having worked with Gaussian copula models in order to solve the question for his then employer, an insurance company, if there were any correlation between the death of an insured person and an eventual death of the beneficiary. Gaussian copula models proved to be helpful in solving the problem of correlated defaults. In the following years, Mr. Li tried to apply this model in finance and eventually published a paper on default correlation.4 This paper was eagerly picked up by the industry, especially rating agencies, as they were now able 26 to price asset backed securities. If the author remembers right, it was Moody’s being the first to pick up the paper and to implement it into its tool Credit Metrics. Now the industry thought to have a valid model to price CDOs and alike. However the application was met with scepticism. Besides some criticism by, for example, Nassim Nicholas Talib, the author of the Black Swan, it was David Li himself stating as early as 2005 that the model was applied the wrong way.5 But as the industry had found a simple way to price not only mortgage backed securities but also derivative contracts based on MBOs no one paid any attention to lonesome critics. And by pricing and rating those products they could be distributed worldwide. This led to the widespread belief that risk could be distributed and the burden of default would be shared. Now the financial system was much more resilient! Was it? 15 September 2008 proved the contrary. Early warning signs popped up in 2007. In June that year some hedge funds of Bear Stearns couldn’t refinance and had to be bailed out by the bank. Almost exactly one year before Lehman liquidity shortage of British mortgage bank Northern Rock caused a run by depositors on the bank. These obvious signs of liquidity problems weren’t read the correct way.6 The warning signs continued: 1 For a comprehensive discussion on financial stability see Andreas Dombret and Otto Lucius (eds.) (2013), “Stability of the Financial System – Illusion or Feasible Concept?”, Edward Elgar. 2 For a short yet concise summary of the financial crisis and the consequences see also Dombret (2013) pp. 4 - 8. 3 See historical data released by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, http:// www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/data.htm (accessed 8.9.2013). 4 Li, David X. (2000), “On Default Correlation: A Copula Function Approach”, published in Journal of Fixed Income, Vol. 9, Issue 4, pages 43–54. 5 Li (2008) in The Definitive Guide to CDOs, Ed. by Gunter Meissner, p. 71. BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION In March 2008 the FED had to rescue Bear Stearns by providing a credit facility of some 29 billion USD. Still the public had the feeling that the situation was in no way serious, because if a financial institution were in trouble the government would step in. Borio (2009) called this the “paradox of financial stability”.7 This means that the financial system looks strongest exactly when it is most vulnerable! As the quality of real estate credit portfolios steadily decreased it was the two housing financing institutions Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac that ran into trouble. They had to be taken over by the government, in other words to be nationalised. This happened one week before Lehman went bankrupt. And it was on 15. September 2008 that the till now unthinkable happened: Lehman Brothers went bankrupt. Not enough: Merrill Lynch had to be taken over by Bank of America, Wachovia had to be taken over partly by Citigroup, and AIG, the largest insurance group in the U.S., had to be rescued. During the first days after Lehman nearly nothing happened. The financial systems and its representatives were under shock. But out of a sudden the shock switched into deep mistrust. Liquid assets were withdrawn on a large scale as no one trusted any other financial institution. It might well be it were the next one to fail. Immediate consequence was a worldwide liquidity shortage to an extent until then without prejudice. Money market funds had to be closed and the whole financial system was shortly before a deadly collapse. Campa compared liquidity with water needed to cultivate land. A shortage of liquidity leads to problems as well as abundance of liquidity (sic!) that could compromise future growth by inflation.8 In this situation the U.S. Government BV 11/2013 Graph 1: Number of Banks in Austria 2004 – 2012 Graph 2: Number of Branches in Austria 2004 - 2012 and Congress reacted quickly and set up TARP, the Troubled Asset Relief Program with an amount of USD 700 billion. The reason for problems of banks was twofold: Either they lost money because Lehman was insolvent or they simply suffered under severe liquidity shortage. With only few exceptions, one of them being Canada, one country after another had to take action. 27 6 This is written in full awareness that it is always easier to judge with the wisdom of knowing the past – so to say providing ex post judgment. The author is not going to blame anyone for not reading the signs correctly. A very similar phenomenon can be watched nowadays with supervisors: After having designed one of the most complex rulebooks for banking, Basel III, supervisors now realise that not only the industry has to obey the rulebook but the supervisors themselves have to monitor the appropriate use of Basel III. In the light of the above said it is quite amusing to read the paper of Andrew Haldane and Vassileios Madouros “The dog and the frisbee”, based on a speech of Haldane in Jackson Hole in summer 2012. 7 C. Borio (2009), “Ten propositions about liquidity crises”, BIS working paper, no. 293, November. 8 José Manuel Campa (2013) „Stable Liquidity and Funding Flows“ in Andreas Dombret and Otto Lucius (eds.), Stability of the Financial System, E. Elgar, p. 425. SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION 3. The consequences for Austria The banking system in Austria is compared to GDP not the biggest one. Some say Austria is overbanked. In reality it is overbranched. The number of independent banks is steadily decreasing, this trend partly set off by rising numbers of branches. Overall Austria registered 867 banks at year-end 2008. Of these 551 belonged to Raiffeisen sector and another 68 to Volksbanken sector, both being credit unions. Savings banks summed up to 55 and commercial banks to 51. Details on banks and branches over time and sectors are shown in graphs 1 and 2. By end of the first half of 2011, the balance-sheet total of Austrian banks amounted to some 334 per cent of GDP, which is number eleven in EU ranking. In comparison Luxemburg is leading with a balance-sheet total of some 2,430 per cent of local GDP, followed by Ireland with 799 per cent of GDP and Malta with 796 per cent of GDP. At the other end of the scale is Lithuania with bank assets totalling only 79 per cent of local GDP.9 However, the “Top Ten” Austrian banks account for roughly 50 to 60 per cent market share, be it in terms of the balance-sheet total, credits or deposits. On the other hand, one has to admit that Austria is running a smaller concentration risk in the financial system compared to other countries. Looking at the two large banking groups in Austria, Erste Group and RBI, both account for roughly 100 per cent of GDP. Bank Austria accounts for two thirds of GDP, but theoretically a collapse of Bank Austria would be an Italian problem as Bank Austria is a subsidiary of UniCredit Group.10 If theory could withstand a practice test, remains to be seen – and will hopefully never be tested. An old wisdom says: “There is nothing bad that doesn’t have its merits”. The large number of relatively small banks makes the banking system in Austria rather resilient against shocks like the one triggered by the crisis. It was the large banks that were under potential threat, or it was banks badly managed. Looking at large banks all of those were potentially threatened by the crisis. Furthermore, Austria had four banks more or less heavily engaged in CESEE. Any problem there could The authorities tried to convince the largest banks to strengthen their capital base. have had a contagion effect. We will deal with this under 5 below. Nervousness spread after the Lehman collapse. Before this nervousness could turn into panic, it was a must to take counteractions. It is worth noting that on a European scale there was a strong political will to take action. On 12. October 2008, the heads of states of the euro area adopted the “Declaration on a concerted European Action Plan of the Euro Area Countries”. 4. Measures taken It soon turned out that the worldwide liquidity squeeze also affected banks in Austria. The interbank market was literally “dry”. Although the vast majority of banks were funded 28 by deposits, the danger was that depositors also lost confidence in the banking system and would start withdrawing deposits on a large scale. In other words, a bank run had to be prevented. In this potentially dangerous situation the Austrian Government after thorough consultation with OeNB, the Central Bank in Austria, took decisive action. On 8. October 2008, Chancellor Alfred Gusenbauer and Vice Chancellor and Minister of Finance Wilhelm Molterer informed the public that all deposits of all banks in Austria would be guaranteed to an unlimited extent by the Austrian Government. This unlimited guarantee would become effective retroactively starting on 1 October 2008. This was the first in a long row of measures that effectively helped to keep confidence in the banking sector alive. Upon proposal of experts, the government asked the Parliament of Austria to enact a series of acts and amendments to existing acts.11 The acts are incorporated in one legislative piece announced as BGBl I No. 136/2008. Altogether financial resources with a total of EUR 100 billion were provided. The mentioned EUR 100 billion were part of the so-called “banking rescue package“ and had been distributed as follows: • EUR 50 billion for guarantees on capital market issues of banks and for the activities of Oesterreichische Clearingbank AG on the basis of IBSG (see below 4.1.) • EUR 10 billion was allocated for liabilities in favour of Austrian 9 http://newsroom.sparkasse.at/osterreich-mit-765banken-auf-platz-zwei-in-eu/ (accessed 8.9.2013). 10 Numbers taken from Die Presse, 25. March 2013, http://diepresse.com/home/1380493/ Zypern-kann-ueberall-in-Europa-passieren (accessed 8.9.2013). 11 For a concise documentation of legal measures to stabilise financial markets in Austria and other European countries see Eder, Hörl and Winkler (2008), “Stabilising the Financial Markets in Europe”. BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION industrial companies. • EUR 15 billion was allocated for guarantees in order to stabilise the Euro. • EUR 10 billion was used to fund necessary measures of deposit protection. • EUR 15 billion has been allocated for measures according to FinStaG (see below 4.2.) We will now have a closer look on these acts and the measures taken. 4.1 The Federal Act on Strengthening the Interbank Market12 (Interbankmarktstärkungsgesetz – IBSG) In order to strengthen the interbank market and to facilitate liquidity supply for Austrian banks, the Act enabled the Ministry of Finance to take over guarantees of up to EUR 75 billion. The act also provided the basis to create a specialised institution called Oesterreichische Clearing Bank AG OeCAG. This special bank was founded by Austrian banks and located at the premises of Oesterreichische Kontrollbank OeKB. This bank became operational on 14 November 2008. The Republic provided for this special bank guarantees of up to EUR 4 billion. The European Commission agreed also with this measure because funds were provided without any discrimination, the interest rates were in line with market rates and the funds were limited in duration. All in all, the OeCAG performed 310 web-based auctions where deposits could be offered and loans within a time range of 1 to 12 months could be asked for. Allocations amounted to EUR 22.5 billion and USD 1.5 billion. The liability of the Republic never became active. The OeCAG paid to the Republic altogether EUR 19.1.million in commitment fees. This special measure was of utmost importance as it prevented distorBV 11/2013 tions in the interbank market and secured liquidity at all times. The Act was in force until 31 December 2010. Thus the OeCAG closed its operations in March 2011 and was then dissolved. The IBSG provided also for other guarantees besides those for OeCAG. Up to EUR 71 billion was the amount approved for the liability of the government for any obligations resulting of the issuance of securities. The goal was to revitalise medium-term refinancing of banks. None of these guarantees has ever become active. Some Austrian banks are highly active in the CESEE region. 4.2 Amendment of the Act on the Austrian Investment and Privatisation Agency (ÖIAG-Gesetz 2000) Before discussing the second part of this legislative initiative (see 4.3. below) it might be helpful to shed some light on the creation of a special company designed to administer capital measures. The above mentioned amendment enabled the creation of a new company called Finanzmarktbeteiligung Aktiengesellschaft des Bundes (FIMBAG), a holding company for shares in financial institutions (state owned as a consequence of bank recapitalisation). FIMBAG has been established as a subsidiary of Österrreichische Industrieholding AG (ÖIAG). Intended to support the Republic of 29 Austria in all measures related to FinStaG, the FIMBAG became operational on 11 November 2008. Its legal foundation is rooted in para 3 section 5 of FinStaG. FIMBAG plays an active role in managing financial support for banks and/or representing the Republic as owner or partial owner of some banks. 4.3. Financial Market Stabilisation Act (Finanzmarktstabilitätsgesetz – FinStaG) This act together with IBSG (see above 4.1.) was the core of the action plan the authorities had developed to fight consequences of the financial crisis. The act empowered the Minister of Finance to recapitalise individual banks and insurance companies in order to safeguard business activities in Austria, to secure macroeconomic balance and to protect the Austrian economy. The act allowed for the following measures: taking up liability for the payables of banks, e.g. by guarantees or collaterals, granting loans, contributing equity and acquiring participation. All of these measures had to be provided against marketbased fees. If a bank wanted to call recapitalisation measures under the conditions of the FinStaG, it had to allow the BMF to have discretionary power on certain aspects on banking operations, including usage of funds, salary schemes and the way dividends were distributed. For all measures taken under FinStaG a total of EUR 15 billion was available. Seen aside from the legal framework, it is worth noting that in 2008 only one bank was in need of rescue. This was Kommunalkredit AG, a bank specialised in financing communities 12 The English translation of the respective Austrian act titles (except the one dealt with under 4.6.) has been taken from Eder, Hörl and Winkler (2008), “Stabilising the Financial Markets in Europe”. SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION and public entities. Due to a misled very short term refinancing policy, the bank came under pressure when liquidity dried out. Furthermore, the bank had a rather large derivatives portfolio and was confronted with margin calls further tightening the liquidity squeeze. Kommunalkredit, at that time the eight-biggest bank in Austria and owned by ÖVAG with 50.78 per cent (Dexia holding 49 percent) had to be nationalised on 3. November 2008. The Republic bought 99.78 per cent for the symbolic price of two euro. Later on toxic assets of Kommunalkredit were carved out and transferred to the “bad bank”, a resolution bank named KA Finanz AG. Regardless of that case, no bank was really in need of immediate capital support at that time. However, the authorities OeNB and FMA tried to convince the largest banks to strengthen their capital base by tapping the funds of FinStaG. One of the first banks to do so was Erste Group, calling for EUR 1.224 billion in participation capital. (By the way, Erste Group was also the first bank to repay the full amount in 2013.) Then other banks followed suit: RBI with EUR 1.75 billion, BAWAG P.S.K. with EUR 0.55 billion (of which 50 million already paid back by now) and ÖVAG with the amount of EUR 1 billion. For an overview of the initial capital measures see table 1. Bank Austria never made a claim on state aid.13 Hypo Alpe Adria (a special case) and ÖVAG became subject to major restructuring at a later stage. The economic downturn in CESEE forced ÖVAG not only to merge with its Austrian daughter company Investkredit, but in later years to get rid of all CESEE operations by selling the respective banks to Sberbank. Only the Romanian bank is still with ÖVAG. The Republic meanwhile became a shareholder of ÖVAG to Table 1: Capital Measures as per 31.12.2009 Participation Capital: BAWAG P.S.K. Erste Group Hypo Alpe-AdriaBank International ÖVAG RBI Total Shares: Kommunalkredit Austria and KF Total in thousands EUR 550.000 1.224.000 900.000 1.000.000 1.750.000 5.424.000 609.000 609.000 Table 2: Capital held by FIMBAG as per 15.9.2013 Participation Capital: BAWAG P.S.K. Hypo Alpe-AdriaBank International ÖVAG RBI Total Shares: Kommunalkredit Austria and KF Total in thousands EUR 500.000 275.111 300.000 1.750.000 2.825.111 609.000 4.4. Amendment of the Banking Act (Bankwesengesetz) 609.000 the extent of 43 per cent of capital stock.14 The involvement of FIMBAG in capital measures at the end of 2012 can be seen in table 2. Taken altogether we have to state that the quick and decisive measures taken by the Republic and the authorities prevented the worst case scenario and helped the banking system to go through the shock waves of the financial crisis rather smoothly. As already stated, Hypo Alpe Adria is a special case. The bank was formerly owned by the Province of Carinthia. It drove a course of rapid expansion into the Alpe-Adria region, especially Italy, Slovenia and Croatia. It was sold to Bayerische Landesbank in 2007. A very often neglected fact is that the Carinthian government had accumulated guarantees of roughly EUR 20 billion 30 in liabilities for the bank. When the financial crisis broke out, the situation of Hypo Alpe Adria worsened. And in late 2009, the then owner Bayerische Landesbank was no more able or willing to further support it. A collapse of the bank would have triggered the liabilities, far too much to be borne by Carinthia. Taking over these liabilities by the Republic with consequences for public debt had to be considered as a serious danger for the standing of the Republic. Furthermore, Hypo Alpe Adria had been a very active player in its neighbouring countries. A collapse of the bank would have had disastrous consequences for the region already shaken by the crisis. There was international intervention to rescue the bank. Thus there was no alternative for the Republic but to take over Hypo Alpe Adria, which happened on 14 December 2009. The amendment of the Austrian Banking Act became necessary as one of the first measures to be undertaken at the very beginning of the financial crisis in order to strengthen the trustworthiness of the banking system by temporarily abolishing any restrictions on deposit protection. For natural persons as depositors there was no restriction on deposit protection, for SMEs a limit of EUR 50,000 was introduced. From 1 January 2010 onwards the limit for deposit protection vis-à-vis natural persons was limited to EUR 100,000 again. The amendment also created the power for the supervisor to demand so-called capital add-ons in a simplified procedure. 13 FIMBAG Lagebericht Geschäftsjahr 2011. FIMBAG Lagebericht Geschäftsjahr 2012. 14 BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION 4.5. Amendment of the Stock Exchange Act (Börsegesetz) Due to the turmoil and the increased volatility in the capital markets one measure was to reduce volatility at the Vienna Stock Exchange by prohibition of short selling at all, and to impose restrictions on short selling on certain financial instruments. The act empowered the Financial Market Authority FMA in Austria to issue regulations on short selling. Indeed short selling was never entirely forbidden, but a series of such regulations was put into place concerning a prohibition of uncovered short selling for shares of certain companies, namely Erste Group, RBI, UNIQA and VIG. The validity of the last regulation expired on 1 July 2013, as the EU regulation No. 236/2012 entered into force. 4.6. Economic Recovery Act 2008 (Konjunkturbelebungsgesetz 2008) This act entered into force on 10 November 2008 and was intended to revive and stimulate the Austrian economy. The steps taken were the establishment of an SME fund for projects with growth potential, benefiting from the SME initiative of the EIB, granting loans for research and technology projects, and lastly taking out loans from the European development funds for energy measures. 5. The Vienna Initiative As already mentioned, some Austrian banks are highly active in the CESEE region. This is mainly Bank Austria, Erste Group and Raiffeisen Bank International. ÖVAG, the head institution of the Volksbank sector has already retreated from this region and sold its operations (except BV 11/2013 Romania) to Sberbank. At the beginning of 2009 it was quite obvious that the financial crisis would turn into an economic crisis. At that time some commentators and rating agencies feared a meltdown in the CESEE countries. If this had happened Austrian banks operating there would have been heavily affected. However, at that time the threat of adverse developments in the CESEE and its negative consequences was deemed purely theoretical. The countries in the Eastern and South-eastern Europe came much better through the crisis than expected. Anyway, the constant debate about adverse effects threatened to have real negative consequences. Furthermore, outsiders realised the danger of possible withdrawal of liquidity from the countries in the CESEE region. This in turn would have the potential to trigger a crisis in this region. Therefore, the Austrian Ministry of Finance started what then became known as the “Vienna Initiative”. This initiative, officially named “Vienna Initiative/European Bank Coordination Initiative (VI/EBCI)”, was created in January 2009 as an informal forum.15 It was launched by the EBRD, the IMF and the Austrian Ministry of Finance at the height of the systemic financial crisis to provide a framework for coordinating the crisis management and crisis resolution of financial sector issues that were highlighted by the economic downturn and involved large cross-border bank groups systemically important in the emerging Europe region. Its aims were to prevent a large-scale and uncoordinated withdrawal of cross-border bank groups from the region; further to ensure that parent bank groups publicly commit to maintain their exposures and recapitalise their subsidiaries, as part of the overall balance-of-payments support to countries where IMF/EC macroeconomic support programmes have 31 become necessary (Bosnia and Herzegovina, Hungary, Latvia, Romania and Serbia). The initiative also aimed to ensure that national support packages of cross-border bank groups benefit their subsidiaries in emerging Europe and avoid a home bias in dealing with Europe’s banks. Next, to agree on basic crisis management and crisis resolution principles in the region. Host country authorities should be responsible for appropriate macroeconomic policies; liquidity support in local currency irrespective of bank ownership; and supporting their deposit insurance schemes. Parent bank groups – and the home country authorities behind them – should be responsible for providing funding in foreign exchange and recapitalising subsidiaries. Finally, the initiative aimed to strengthen crossborder regulatory cooperation and information sharing in the context of IMF/EC-supported programmes and beyond.16 According to Nitsche, the Vienna Initiative reached most of the goals set – the initiative can be perceived as a successful vehicle for publicprivate sector coordination in the financial crisis. It also contributed to shorten the perception lag of politicians with regard to the suddenly increased macro-financial risks in the fourth quarter of 2008 / beginning of 2009. It helped stabilisation and recovery in individual countries and it helped to build up mutual trust between the international banks, home and host country authorities and international financial institutions (IFIs).17 Nitsche also mentioned some areas where the VI failed: The attempt to agree on a general framework 15 W. Nitsche (2010), “The Vienna Initiative / European Bank Coordination Initiative: Assessment and Outlook”, BMF-WP 4/2010. 16 EBRD, Vienna Initiative – moving to a new phase, April 2012, p. 1. 17 See Nitsche (2010), p. 5. SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION was not successful. Although not being a problem in the short term it makes the platform very vulnerable. And it was not possible to achieve a common understanding on the division of tasks and burden sharing in crisis management. However, some elements for such an agreement emerged in the various country meetings.18 A very concrete step in helping to stabilise the CESEE region was the IFI Initiative. EBRD, EIB and World Bank joined forces in setting up a two-year programme for 2009 – 2010 providing EUR 24.5 billion committed for banking sectors and bank lending to enterprises.19 6. Evaluation of measures and outlook This paper discussed the measures taken in Austria. It is obvious that only due to the quick and unanimous decisions by the government major negative consequences of the financial crisis 2008 could be prevented. Confidence by depositors into banks remained stable, and liquidity supply in the interbank market could be supplied by OeCAG. The other newly created institution FIMBAG is a success story in itself. That two banks in Austria are still under pressure is only in a secondary way consequence of the financial crisis. It is by far due to non-appropriate business models, failure in risk management practices and overly optimistic and hastily expansion. Are there lessons to be learned? Yes indeed: • First, if problems become visible immediate and concerted action is needed. Any delay in action could make the situation even worse. Trust is of utmost importance. And trust can only be maintained by quick and trustworthy action. • Second, if a bank needs capital support but is in principle viable, the Austrian way of providing participation capital proved to be successful. Can one imagine a better investment today than lending capital against 8 per cent annual interest? • However, the American experience has taught us that in case restructuring is needed it might be better for the government to provide financial aid against shares. These shares can be sold with profit after successful restructuring. • Looking at the system as a whole, liquidity is at its core. The Austrian system of regular liquidity auction proved to be most helpful. Summarising we have to state the following: In case of a crisis, do not hesitate to act; instead, act immediately and instil confidence! Stability of the Financial System, E. Elgar, p. 425 sequ. Dombret, Andreas (2013), “Five Years after Lehman – Learning from the past, looking to the future”, Speech at the 24th European Business School Symposium, September, Deutsche Bundesbank. Dombret, Andreas and Otto Lucius (eds.) (2013), “Stability of the Financial System – Illusion or Feasible Concept?”, Edward Elgar. EBRD (2012), “Vienna Initiative – moving to a new phase”, April, http://www.ebrd. com/downloads/research/factsheets/viennainitiative.pdf. Eder, Stefan, Hörl, Johannes and Winkler, Andreas (2008), “Finanzmarktstärkung in Europa – Stabilising the Financial Markets in Europe”, NWV Verlag, Wien - Graz. FIMBAG (2011, 2012), Lagebericht (for the respective business year), http://www. fmarktbet.at/cms/cms.php?pageName=19 Haldane, Andrew and Vasileios Madouros “The dog and the Frisbee”, Bank of England, http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/ publications/Documents/speeches/2012/ speech596.pdf. IFI Initiative (2009), “EBRD, EIB and World Bank Group join forces to support Central and Eastern Europe”, http://vienna-initiative.com/wp-content/uploads/2012/08/ IFI-Initiative-EBRD-EIB-and-World-BankGroup-join-forces-to-support-Central-andEastern-Europe.pdf. Li, David X. (2000), “On Default Correlation: A Copula Function Approach”, published in Journal of Fixed Income, Vol. 9, Issue 4, pages 43–54. Li, David X. (2008), “An Overview on Copula Function Methods in Credit Portfolio Modelling”, in The Definitive Guide to CDOs, Ed. by Gunter Meissner, p. 39 sequ. Nitsche, Wolfgang (2010), “The Vienna Initiative / European Bank Coordination Initiative: Assessment and Outlook, BMFWP 4/2010. ReferenceS: Borio, Claudio (2009), “Ten propositions about liquidity crises”, BIS working paper, no. 293, November. Campa Fernandez, José Manuel (2013) „Stable Liquidity and Funding Flows“ in Andreas Dombret and Otto Lucius (eds.), 32 18 Cf. Nitsche (2010), p. 5. Factsheet on IFI Initiative http://vienna-initiative. com/wp-content/uploads/2012/08/IFI-InitiativeEBRD-EIB-and-World-Bank-Group-join-forces-tosupport-Central-and-Eastern-Europe.pdf (accessed 8. September 2013). 19 BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION UDK 336.71(417) Rehabilitation of Financial Sector The case of Irish banks REHABILITATION OF FINANCIAL SECTOR - THE CASE OF IRISH BANKS This paper outlines the factors that gave rise to the Irish banking sector crisis which led to the institution of a comprehensive guarantee scheme in September 2008. It then outlines the series of direct support measures and structural measures implemented to deal with the very substantial impairments of the balance sheets of the Irish banks. It refers to the difficulties arising from the lack of a settled bank resolution system in Ireland and in the eurozone. JEL G01 G18 G21 G28 O n 30 September 2008, the Irish Minister for Finance announced a state guarantee on all deposits and on a range of debt instruments in Irish banks. Six banks announced that they would participate in the scheme. Background The announcement came after a period of increasing turbulence in financial markets dating back to mid-2007 and events in the USA. Problems accumulated in rapid succession from then on. The following are some selected examples of these problems. • Sub-prime mortgages in the US proved to be extremely problematic, causing difficulties in other countries too. • The US SEC began an investigation of CDO issuers in June 2007, causing widespread concerns about securitisation. • In August 2007, the European Central Bank responded to tensions in euro money markets and embarked on a series of liquidity-provision measures. • Problems began to emerge among mortgage lenders in the UK, culminating in the nationalisation of Northern Rock in February 2008. • Bear Sterns suffered a massive drop in its liquid assets and had to be bought by JP Morgan in March 2008. • Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac joined the US problem list in mid-July 2008. • More problems emerged in the banking sectors in Sweden, France, Germany and the Netherlands, all leading to government intervention of one form or another. * BV 11/2013 Alan Dukes* Alan Dukes, Economist, Chairman of IBRC (formerly Anglo Irish Bank). 33 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION • On 15 August 2008, Lehman’s filed for bankruptcy. Market liquidity simply dried up. • In response to the liquidity crisis, the deposit protection level for depositors in Irish banks was raised on 20 September 2008 to €100,000 per depositor, per institution. • On 29 September 2008, the US Treasury’s first bailout plan – the $700bn TARP – was rejected by Congress but passed on 3 October. These and many other disruptive market factors led to increasing worries in Ireland about the liquidity of the banking sector. These worries led, in turn, to the Government decision on the bank guarantee. The announcement was greeted with surprise in Ireland. The face value of liabilities guaranteed amounted to over twice the value of Ireland’s GDP (see Table 1 below). While the Minister for Finance of the day claimed that it would be the “cheapest guarantee” in history (because, he claimed, it would never be called upon), many commentators took the view that the state should not be put at risk as a result of gross mismanagement and imprudence on the part of the boards and management of the banks. One bank in particular - Anglo Irish Bank (Anglo) – attracted special opprobrium. It had for over a decade been a star performer, showing a very rapid rate of increase in its balance sheet and high levels of profitability. When concerns about the performance of Irish banks in general began to emerge in late 2007, Anglo was not immune and its share price collapsed in March 2008. By the time the guarantee was announced, it was clear that there were very serious problems in Anglo. One view was that it should be allowed to fail or be liquidated. The government, however, took the view that “no bank could be allowed to fail” because of the risk of contagion. In his report (1), the Governor of the Central Bank observed (p. 131) that “…..a default by a €100 billion bank such as Anglo Irish Bank would undoubtedly have put funding pressure on the other main Irish banks via contagion, given the broad similarities in the type and geography of their property-related lending, their common implicit reliance on the backing of the Irish State, and even name confusion.” The announcement of the guarantee caused some unfavourable comment in other EU Member States. The UK Chancellor of the Exchequer was concerned that the move would result in a flow of bank deposits from the UK to Ireland. Similar views were expressed by the authorities of other Member States and by the European Commission. The Irish banks had experienced substantial deposit outflows prior to the guarantee. Anglo had been particularly hard hit. While the level of deposits stabilised somewhat after the guarantee (except for Anglo) there was no evidence of any significant inflow of deposits from other eurozone or EU Member States in the months following the guarantee. Moreover, the UK and German authorities had already intervened in their banking sectors before the Irish guarantee was announced and the Irish action was followed in the ensuing fifteen months by a series of further interventions by the governments of the UK, France, Germany and the Netherlands. In addition, and in common with the eurozone and most other European states, Ireland did not have any settled bank resolution rules, procedures or legislation. There was no settled procedure for dealing with the assets of a failed bank, even if some of its liabilities were simply to be repudiated. The Genesis of the Problem Table 1: Covered Banks: Liabilities Guaranteed by the State as at 30 September 2008 € billion 173.2 (47%) 124.2 (33%) 12.2 (3%) 49.1 (13%) 15.8 (4%) 0.7 (0%) 375.2 Customer Deposits Senior Unsecured Debt Dated Subordinated Debt InterBank Deposits Asset Covered Securities Financial Instruments Total Source: Department of Finance, Dublin, adapted from (3). 34 In September 2008, the problem in the Irish banking sector was perceived to be a liquidity problem. Only a short time before that, the banks had been subjected to a special study which concluded that they were “well capitalised”, a conclusion shared by the (then) Central Bank and Financial Services Regulatory Authority. The banks had a large and growing funding gap. At the end of 2002, the excess of domestic lending to residents over deposits amounted to €26bn: by the end of 2008, that gap had grown to €129bn. In general, loan to deposit ratios had increased over the years: Table 2 shows the change in one year from 2005 to 2006. BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION Table 2: Loan to Deposit Ratios for Selected Irish Financial Institutions*, 2005 and 2006 Allied Irish Banks Bank of Ireland Anglo Irish Bank Irish Nationwide Building Society Irish Life and Permanent Educational Building Society 2005 140% 210% 140% 135% 205% 140% 2006 145% 220% 135% 151% 250% 145% * Loan to deposit ratio calculated at group level, including foreign loans and deposits. Source: Annual Reports: adapted from (2) (R&W) All data at December 2006, except Anglo Irish Bank data September 2006 and Bank of Ireland data March 2007 In fact, lending activity in the banks participating in the guarantee scheme (the “covered institutions”) had been expanding rapidly for some years, as illustrated in Table 3. Table 3: Compound Average Annual Loan Growth for Selected Irish Financial Institutions, 2003 – 2006 Allied Irish Banks: 34% Bank of Ireland: 28% Anglo Irish Bank: 47% Irish Nationwide Building Society: 40% Irish Life and Permanent: 37% Educational Building Society: 35% Source: Annual Reports: adapted from (2) Bank of Ireland data are for financial year ending March in the following year Anglo Irish Bank data are for the financial year ending September Aggregate domestic lending had grown from €94bn. in 2002 to €262bn. in 2008. Annual growth rates were: 2003: 2004: 2005: 2006: 2007: 2008: 20% 28% 29% 28% 17% 5% The total of outstanding loans and advances from the covered institutions to customers grew from 1.2 BV 11/2013 times GDP in 2000 to 2.2 times GDP in 2008. Rapid growth in total lending, increasing loan to deposit ratios and substantial reliance on wholesale interbank funding (much of it from abroad) clearly gave rise to concerns about liquidity, particularly in the light of tightening liquidity in financial markets from late 2007 on. Other dimensions of the problem soon began to emerge. Ireland experienced over a decade of strong economic growth from the mid-1990s. This growth fuelled a massive property boom. Rising real personal incomes boosted demand for residential property, both among intending owner-occupiers and among those in the “buy to let” market. A further impetus was added by the emergence of a pattern of net immigration from about 2000 on, a phenomenon unknown in Ireland since the mid-19th century. Rising personal incomes also fuelled demand for retail centre development and leisure facilities. A buoyant economy which attracted substantial volumes of foreign direct investment produced vigorous demand for office, commercial and industrial construction. The State engaged in a hugely-increased infrastructure investment programme, partly financed by public-private partnerships, including the construction of motorways, schools, hospitals 35 and energy generation facilities and the modernisation and upgrading of port facilities, railways and railway rolling stock. The prices of land scheduled for development rose rapidly and even the “hope value” of land not yet scheduled for development increased. The boom was further inflated by the operation of a wide range of tax incentives for construction and development which began to be restricted only in 2007. By and large, both the Irish public in general and the political establishment have bought in to the proposition that “construction is good for the economy”. As a result, it is estimated that, by 2007, construction and related activities accounted for about 13% of Irish GDP. In most of the boom years, more residential units were constructed in Ireland, with a population of just over 4 million, than in the whole of the UK, with a population fifteen times as great. The property boom brought opportunities to the banks. Anglo was seen to be the first to ride the wave. It enjoyed a long period of rapid growth and high profitability based very largely on clients in the construction and property development sectors. In time, the other banks followed suit (BoI more slowly and less exuberantly than AIB). Anglo saw the need to diversify. It built a substantial wealth management operation which was, however, closely linked to its construction and property development clients and which invested heavily in the property sector. It also “diversified” by engaging in the property construction and development sectors in the UK and the USA. The buoyant property and development market in Ireland attracted new entrants, which took the view that they had to compete aggressively in order to gain market share. One of the aggressive tactics used by a new entrant was to offer 100% mortgages to first-time house buyers. SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION That succeeded so well that previously-established lenders eventually followed suit. In 2000, the covered institutions recorded after-tax profits of €2.5bn., or approximately 1.1% on their assets. After a dip in 2001, profits grew from 2002 to 2007, reaching €5.6bn. in that year, equivalent to about 0.9% on assets. In 2008, profits fell to €1.4bn., equivalent to some 0.2% on assets. The Nyberg Report (3), using data from the Investment Property Databank, shows that real indexed commercial property values (combined office, retail and manufacturing) increased by 43% from 2000 to the peak in 2007 and then declined by 25% by the end of 2008. Real indexed house prices (data from the Department of the Environment and from the Central Statistics Office) rose by 48% between 2000 and the peak in 2007 and then fell by 11% by the end of 2008. The Problem Crystallises By the middle of 2007, the Irish banking system had the following notable characteristics. • It was substantially dependent on interbank wholesale funding to underpin its operations. • It was heavily exposed to lending to an inflated property sector, not only in Ireland but also in the UK and in the USA (where the sub-prime mortgage problem had already erupted). • Loan to value ratios on a very large proportion of property-related lending were high. • The banks were exposed to a relatively small number of borrowers in the commercial property and development market. Many of these borrowers had loans from more than one of the Irish banks and some also had loans from banks in other states. In a number of cases, the “equity” element in a financing proposal was in fact supported by borrowing (sometimes from another bank but in some cases under a different group identity from the same bank which financed the main project). In “normal” market conditions, these were significant risk factors. In the circumstances of the time, they were extremely serious. The credit squeeze which followed the Lehman’s collapse meant that an important source of bank funding (interbank lending) effectively dried up. It also meant that significant numbers of the banks’ large clients in the property and development sector experienced their own funding difficulties, which in turn impaired their ability to service their loans. More was to come. In March 2007, the Irish Index of House Prices showed a decline for the first time in five years. Effectively, the house price bubble burst around mid-2007. By the end of 2008, house prices had fallen by 11% from the 2007 peak. The commercial property market (office, retail and manufacturing property and development) soon followed. By the end of 2008, commercial property prices had fallen by 25% from the 2007 peak. The banks now found themselves with large exposures to loans secured on assets which were rapidly losing value. Looking back on the genesis of the crisis in the Irish banking system, it is clear that there were serious failings in business models, business practices and risk assessment in the banks. Equally, there were serious failings in the regulatory sphere. Regulators had access to all the information necessary to identify the shortcomings in bank management, but failed to take the action required to redress the situation. It has to be said, however, that 36 neither the Irish banks nor the Irish regulators were alone in these failings: similar situations were common in other countries. Space does not permit a worthwhile analysis here: that is to be found in the three reports referenced below. It is, however, the case that conclusions have been drawn from the experience and that regulatory practices have been very substantially amended and regulatory resources increased. The Policy Response Liquidity, capitalisation, personnel The initial policy response, in the form of the 30 September 2008 guarantee, was articulated in the belief that the problem was one of liquidity. The Irish authorities were not alone in taking this view: liquidity was demonstrably a pressing problem throughout the western economies. In August 2008, the European Central Bank embarked on what was to become a major (and frequently controversial) expansion of its market activities. Without this action, the consequences, not only for the eurozone but for world financial markets, would have been incalculable. In Ireland, it quickly became clear that there was more to the problem than a crisis of liquidity. The collapse of the property sector had major economic and budgetary implications. At its peak, the construction sector accounted for over 12% of total employment in the Irish economy and of GDP. It was a major contributor not only to income tax revenue, but also to VAT and Stamp Duty revenue, which between them accounted for about 45% of total tax revenue. The property sector collapse had major implications for fiscal policy. The government introduced an emergency early budget on 13 October to begin to address BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION the situation. The implications of the collapse, however, had not yet been fully appreciated: the October 2008 budget included a forecast of tax revenue which, in the event, proved to be seriously over-optimistic. In 2009 and 2010, the government was obliged to tighten fiscal policy, with inevitably dampening effects on the level of economic activity and on incomes. These effects, in turn, exacerbated a downward spiral in the property and development sector. In its turn, this downward spiral impacted on a substantial part of the banking system’s asset base. The parameters of the crisis rapidly widened. In mid-December 2008, the government announced that it would allocate €10bn for the recapitalisation of the domestic banks. This announcement was followed a week later by the announcement that the government would invest a total of €5.5bn in preference shares in three banks: €1.5bn in Anglo, €2bn in AIB and €2bn in BoI. This was a clear acknowledgement that the problem was not simply one of liquidity. On 15 January 2009, the government announced the nationalisation of Anglo, citing as reasons the weak funding of the bank and the emerging evidence of unacceptable practices following the resignation of the Chairman after revelations about the treatment of loans he held from the bank. The Chairman’s resignation was quickly followed by those of the CEO and CFO. A new Board was put in place on nationalisation. A number of important personnel changes in other institutions took place or were announced during the course of 2009. • In January, the Minister for Finance announced the re-appointment of the Governor of the Central Bank. In early June, however, the Governor announced his intenBV 11/2013 • • • • • • • tion to retire with effect from 10 September. In early January, the Chief Executive of the Financial Regulator announced his retirement with effect from 31 January. In January, BoI announced the retirement of its CEO with effect from the summer of 2010. In early February, the CEO and two Directors of IL&P resigned in the wake of revelations of a chain of “balance sheet enhancement” transfers amounting to €7 billion between Anglo and IL&P in September 2008. Also in early February, the Chairman of INBS resigned. The CEO of INBS resigned at the end of April. At the end of April, AIB announced the resignations of the Chairman, the CEO and the Finance Director. In May, BoI announced the retirement of the Chairman with effect from July 2010. On 11 February, it was announced that the state’s investment in AIB and BoI would be increased to €7bn. In the first quarter of 2009, the new Board and management of Anglo carried out an internal review of the bank’s loss provisioning policies. This concluded that the immediate capitalisation need was €4bn., with a substantial downside risk linked to the continuing fall in property prices. The outcome of the review was reported to the Department (Ministry) of Finance on 15 April. This conclusion was separately validated both by an independent examination commissioned by the bank and by a further independent examination commissioned by the Department of Finance. The key factor identified by these examinations was an acceleration of the rate of decline in property prices in the last quarter of 2008, with an even further acceleration in 37 the early months of 2009. (Most observers believe that property values fell by between 50% and 60% from the 2007 peak to the 2010/2011 trough. The objective evidence is thin, both because of the lack of a comprehensive tracking system in the property sector and because there was so little activity in the market up to mid-2012). The government injected €4bn into the bank on 9 June. The result of Anglo’s review of its loss provisioning policy suggested that there had been serious deficiencies in the loss provisioning policies of all the banks, but the full import of these deficiencies did not become apparent until some time later. It was clear, however, that there were serious and, up to early 2009, unrecognised impairments on the balance sheets of all the banks. The quantum of provisions for impairment charges by the banks between 2000 and 2007 varied between €1.5bn. and €1.8bn. As a percentage of loans, however, this went from 1.2% in 2000 to 1.3% in 2001 but declined thereafter to about 0.4% in 2006 and 0.5% 2007. In 2008, the quantum increased to €5.8bn or 1.4% of loans. Dealing with impaired balance sheets In early April 2009, the government announced the outline of its plans to deal with the problem of impairments on the banks’ loan books. This took the form of a National Asset Management Agency – NAMA – which would take over the most impaired bank assets, issuing bonds in return and applying a discount to the value of the assets acquired. Initially, it was thought that NAMA might acquire assets up to a value of €90 billion, at a discount of about 30%. Legislation to set up NAMA was passed in November 2009 and it commenced SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION operations in the following month. NAMA operates through a holding company – NAMA Investments Ltd. – of which NAMA is a 49% shareholder, with 51% of the shares being held by three private concerns. As a result of this structure, NAMA debt does not form part of the General Government Debt for national accounts purposes. Table 4 sets out a summary of loan acquisitions by NAMA as at the end of 2011. Table 4: Summary of loan acquisitions by NAMA as at end-2011: € billion Loan balances transferred Consideration paid Discount • • Table 5: NAMA portfolio concentration by location Dublin Rest of Ireland London Rest of Britain Northern Ireland Rest of world 36% 18% 21% 12% 3% 10% Source: NAMA Table 6: NAMA portfolio concentration by sector. Development Office Retail Hotel and leisure Industrial Residential Land Other 25% 19% 19% 8% 3% 12% 9% 5% Source: NAMA In total, NAMA has acquired loans involving 772 debtor connections with an average nominal value per loan of €96mn. Up to the end of 2012, NAMA • disposed of €6.9 billion worth of assets, equivalent to just over Anglo 34.1 13.4 61% BoI 9.9 5.6 43% EBS 0.9 0.4 57% INBS 8.7 3.4 61% Total 74.0 31.8 57% Source: NAMA • Tables 5 and 6 set out the geographic and regional concentration of the loans acquired by NAMA. AIB 20.4 9.0 56% • 21% of the nominal consideration for the assets it acquired, completed sales transactions for over 3,900 individual properties, redeemed senior bonds and made debt repayments to a total of over €5bn since inception, had generated cash flow of €10.5bn since inception and had a cash balance of over €3.6bn. Government action in relation to the banks. At the end of March 2010, the Central Bank announced the conclusions of a PCAR it had carried out on the banks. It concluded that AIB had a capital requirement of €7.4bn and that BoI had a requirement of €2.7bn. These amounts were to be raised through share issues and asset sales. By the end of June, BoI had completed a capital raising programme amounting to €3.5bn. In September, AIB sold its Polish interests to Santander for a capital gain of €2.5bn. It nevertheless needed a further government injection of €3.7bn which was carried out in December and which brought the government’s shareholding to 93%. At the end of March also, Anglo had announced a loss of €12.7bn for 2009, the largest corporate loss in Irish history, due to impairments on its loan book. The government issued a promissory note in the amount of €8.3bn. It also issued a promissory note of €2.6bn to INBS. Between 38 end-March and end-December, a total of €25.3bn was issued to Anglo and €5.3bn to INBS in the form of promissory notes. These notes, as originally issued, carried an interest payment of €3.06bn per annum until 2023, reducing thereafter until a final payment in 2031. In September 2010, the government set out to clarify its plans for the banking sector in the interests of public information. The principal conclusions were that: • two “pillar banks” would be retained: AIB and BoI, and • Anglo would be wound down over the ten-year period to 2020 at a total cost which was forecast to be between €29bn and €34bn, • Anglo’s deposits were transferred to AIB. By the end of 2010, the government had committed a total of €46bn to the recapitalisation and support of the banking sector. In November 2010, the government agreed a bailout programme with the “Troika” of the European Commission, the ECB and the IMF. This included measures to support the funding of the government’s actions in relation to the banking sector. Requests by the then government and by its successor elected in 2011 to “bail in” senior bondholders in the banks were rejected. A number of liability management exercises involving bail-in of subordinated bondholders were, however, carried out. BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION In mid-2011, it was decided to merge INBS with Anglo and the merged entity was re-branded as the Irish Bank Reconstruction Corporation Ltd. (IBRC). In February 2013, IBRC was liquidated in order to replace the outstanding promissory notes by an alternative arrangement designed to spread the associated government debt over a longer period and reduce the fiscal pressure on the government. The remaining assets of IBRC will either be sold by the Special Liquidators appointed by the government or transferred to NAMA at the end of the year. Concluding overview The absence of a settled bank resolution policy at both national and eurozone level has been a major difficulty. It was not until two years after the bank guarantee of September 2008 that anything approaching a clear strategy for the Irish banking sector emerged. The actions taken in relation to Anglo/IBRC required two new pieces of dedicated legislation: the Anglo Irish Bank Corporation Act, 2009 and the Irish Bank Recon- BV 11/2013 struction Corporation Act, 2013. The two liquidity management exercises carried out by Anglo in relation to subordinated debt required specific Statutory Instruments. Ireland still has no bank resolution legislation. Legislation to reform the Central Bank of Ireland and the regulatory regime for banks was enacted in July 2010, to take effect in October of that year. It appears that the formulation of a Single Resolution Mechanism at EU level will take some time. The two “pillar banks” – AIB and BoI – have made progress in strengthening their balance sheets and in securing (so far rather limited) access to short-term funding markets. An Asset Quality Review is currently under way as a prelude to a PCAR to be carried out by the eurozone authorities during the course of 2014. Arrangements for the PCAR have still not been finalised by the eurozone authorities and there is apprehension in a number of Member States as to what it might reveal. Remediation of banking sector problems is still very much a “work in progress,” both in Ireland and in the eurozone generally. 39 Abbreviations: AIB: Allied Irish Banks Anglo: Anglo Irish Bank BoI: Bank of Ireland EBS: Educational Building Society ECB: European Central Bank IL&P: Irish Life and Permanent IMF: International Monetary Fund INBS: Irish Nationwide Building Society NAMA:National Asset Management Agency PCAR:Prudential Capital Asset Requirement bn: billion mn: million References: The Irish Banking Crisis: Regulatory and Financial Stability Policy 2003-2008: a Report to the Minister for Finance by the Governor of the Central Bank (the “Honohan Report”), 31 May 2010. A Preliminary Report on the Sources of Ireland’s Banking Crisis: Klaus Regling and Max Watson (the “Regling-Watson Report”), May 2010. Misjudging Risk: Causes of the Systemic Banking Crisis in Ireland: Report of the Commission of Investigation into the Banking Sector in Ireland (the “Nyberg Report”), March 2011. SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION UDK 336.71(460) Rehabilitation of Financial Sector – The case of Spanish banks Antonio Carrascosa and Mario Delgado* REHABILITATION OF FINANCIAL SECTOR – THE CASE OF SPANISH BANKS The economic crisis in Spain exposed significant vulnerabilities in the financial sector. Around 70% of the Spanish banking sector has proven to be healthy but the remaining part have needed public support. The number of agents in the sector has decreased from 50 in 2009 to 15 in 2013. The capital needs detected and not covered through private means have been addressed with public money injections (53.5 billion euros), burden sharing exercises and with the transfer of real estate assets to an Asset Management Company. In order to finance the public support in 2012 Spain required an EU financial assistance for the weakest financial institutions. The result – most analysts agree- is a much sounder and resilient financial sector. JEL G01 G18 G21 G28 O ver the last few years, the Spanish financial sector has gone through a substantial restructuring process. The economic crisis derived from the international financial turmoil and from the bursting of the construction bubble in Spain impacted across the economy, leading to surging unemployment, deficit and public debt. It has also exposed significant vulnerabilities in the financial sector. Most analysts agree that the financial sector is now considerably sounder than a few years ago, but this has required substantial efforts both from the private and the public sector. 1. Introduction Several main aspects could be highlighted from the bank restructuring in Spain: • The financial crisis in Spain has been systemic, but not all the industry was equally affected. Around 70% of the banking sector – including 100% of commercial banks – has proven to be healthy1 -and have not needed public financial support in the form of capital or Cocos. The crisis was mostly focused on savings banks, and not even on all of them; certain saving banks have coped well with it. • The number of banks has decreased from 50 in 2009 to 15 in 2013 (not counting cooperatives, two minor saving banks and foreign branches). *Antonio Carrascosa, FROB, Director General, and Mario Delgado, FROB, Head of International Coordination. September 2013. 1 Banco de Valencia and Banco Gallego needed support but they were controlled by Saving Banks. 40 BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION • The FROB (“Fund for the Orderly Resolution of the Banking Sector” or “Fondo de Reestructuración Ordenada Bancaria” in Spanish) was set up in 2009 to channel the public financial support to banks and was enhanced in 2012 as Spanish resolution authority, sharing responsibilities with the Bank of Spain. • Since 2009, 53.5 billion euros of public money from budgetary sources has been injected through capital instruments2 into the banking sector (into 12 banks which were former savings banks or were controlled by savings banks) and another 7.9 billion has been injected from the Deposit Guarantee Scheme (“Fondo de Garantía de Depósitos”; fully financed with private contributions). Additionally, banks have strengthened their capital position through capital increases in the market and through internal generation of capital (using the buffers accumulated in the boom times, for example countercyclical provisions). • In 2012 a comprehensive and independent stress test exercise was conducted in order to estimate the capital needs of the banking sector. To ensure there would be a sufficient backstop for any level of capital needs, EU financial assistance was requested in 2012 for the recapitalisation of the financial sector for a maximum amount of 100 billion euros (of which slightly more than 41 billion euros has been drawn down). • Management of the crisis has been consistent with the guidelines of the FSB in terms of effective banking resolution. In order to minimize public support, the private sector has borne part of the burden through the absorption of losses by shareholders BV 11/2013 and holders of hybrid capital. Senior debt and deposits have not been affected by this burdensharing. • The process has also involved the creation of an Asset Management Company (SAREB, “Sociedad de Gestión de los Activos de la Reestructuración Bancaria”) for the orderly disposal of the real estate-related assets of banks in need of public capital. • Entities receiving public funds have undertaken restructuring or resolution plans aimed at refocusing their businesses in retail activities in their region of origin. • The restructuring process is now close to being complete – the main task remaining would be the disinvestment of FROB’s participations in banks – but challenges remain for the future of the banking sector, especially related to its adaptation to the new environment (low interest rates in a deleveraging scenario). In this article we overview the steps of the process and analyse the remaining challenges. We will focus on the vulnerabilities in the Spanish financial sector, without addressing other dimensions of the Spanish economy or, more broadly, the impact of the international financial crisis. 2. Pre-crisis vulnerabilities Traditionally, the Spanish Banking Sector comprised three types of credit entities: commercial banks, savings banks (Cajas de ahorros) and credit cooperatives. Prior to the crisis, commercial banks and savings banks had very similar market shares accounting for more than 90% of the sector, while Cooperatives had a much smaller share. During the years of expansion several vulnerabilities built up in the financial sector and, when the crisis hit, important structural weaknesses 41 were exposed. They were concentrated mostly in the “Cajas de Ahorros”. Most of the mounting vulnerabilities were linked to the financing of the housing bubble and can be summarised as follows. 1. Oversizing. In the pre-crisis years, credit grew at very significant rates (18% CAGR3 between 2002 and 2008). Growth during that period was very credit intensive (because so is construction) and the number of branches and employees in the banking sector increased significantly (the number of employees jumped from 243,743 in 2000 to 278,301 in 2008, while the number of branches swelled from 39,391 in 2000 to 46,167 in 2008). 2. Balance sheets accumulated assets linked to real estate which became impaired when the bubble burst. The Spanish banking sector was not an active dealer or trader of the complex financial products that were at the root of the international financial crisis but it did finance assets which turned out to be problematic, namely real estate assets. As a consequence, doubts arose about the quality of the balance sheets of the financial sector, with a clear impact on wholesale financing availability. 3. Transparency and corporate governance. Information disclosure was not complete for agents to analyse how affected by impaired assets of the banks were, increasing uncertainty on their situation. In addition, high quality corporate governance was not guaranteed in savings banks, which were subject to 2 This figure does not include liquidity support, guarantees to debt issuance, asset protection schemes, public participation in SAREB (Spanish’s Asset Management Company) or contributions from the Spanish Deposit Guarantee Scheme. 3 Cumulative annual growth rate SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION political influence and to lack of professional management in some cases. 4. When recapitalisation needs emerged, the savings banks were faced with structural problems to raise capital. The Cajas de Ahorros have a special ownership structure with no shares capital and thus, they rely mostly on retained earnings to increase their capital or on preferred shares – which, in general, were sold to retail customers. 5. Finally, the legal framework revealed certain gaps and deficiencies, for example: the banking resolution framework did not have enough tools to allow swift action and consumers of financial products were not sufficiently protected. These deficiencies combined with the macroeconomic downturn since 2008 led to a weakened banking sector in need of a restructuring and rationalisation. This process has required significant efforts both from the private and the public sector including a request for financial assistance to the EU (for the financial sector), the setting-up of an Asset Management Company (SAREB), the imposition of haircuts on privately held shares and hybrid instruments, public recapitalisation of certain entities and the strengthening of financial regulation. The result is a much sounder and resilient financial sector. Nevertheless, it is worth noting that although the financial crisis in Spain was a systemic crisis, it did not affect the entire industry in the same way. Around 70% of the banking sector did not need public capital support. In fact, the most severe impact of the crisis has been felt in the savings banks sector, and not equally by all Cajas. All the traditional banks and several savings banks have been able to cope with the crisis without having to tap public capital. 3. Restructuring of the Spanish banking system The restructuring of the Spanish financial sector is very much under way, but it has required significant efforts. Here we review those efforts with a special focus in the last few years. 3.1. Liquidity support Like most of the developed countries suffering from the crisis, the Spanish government set up liquidity measures to support their financial system when the international crisis led to a sharp deterioration of liquidity conditions in financial markets. In 2008, a special fund was created in Spain (FAAF, “Fondo para la Adquisición de Activos Financieros” in Spanish, or “Fund for the Acquisition of Financial Assets”) to inject liquidity in banks in exchange of high quality financial assets. Additionally, the Treasury guarantees for debt issuance by banks were made available. 3.2. The FROB In June 2009, the FROB was created as a Fund to provide public financing to banks in financial distress. The establishment of the FROB follows the realisation that specific structures and legislation were needed to address the problems that appeared likely to materialize in the financial sector. In this period, the first intervention of a Caja had been “Caja Castilla la Mancha” in March 2009 – using resources of the Deposit Guarantee Scheme – and it had shown the deficiencies in the system for dealing with these kind of issues (for example, despite the injection of public money, the control of decisions was not granted). The creation of the FROB sought to overcome those shortcomings. In the first years of the process the efforts were mainly addressed to try to untangle the legal obstacles that, especially regarding Saving Banks, made it very difficult to recapitalize them or to rationalize them through mergers. Originally, the capital injections by the FROB came under the form of preferred shares, usually in the context of a merger (most of the merging processes take place in this period). The summary of the initial activity of the FROB (2010) is presented in table 1. Table 1: Phase one of FROB’S financing: consolidation in the savings bank sector 1 CatalunyaCaixa (Catalunya, Tarragona, Manresa) 2 Unnim (Manlleu, Sabadell, Terrassa) 3 CEISS (Caja España-Duero) 4 Nova CaixaGalicia (Galicia, Caixanova) 5 BFA-Bankia (Madrid, Bancaja, Laietana, Insular, Ávila, Segovia y Rioja) 6 Banco Mare Nostrum (Murica, Penedés, Sa Nostra, Granada) 7 Banca Cívica (Navarra, Cajasol-Guadalajara, General de Canarias, Burgos) TOTAL Date March 2010 FROB aid (M€) 1,250 June 2010 380 March 2010 525 June 2010 1,162 June 2010 4,465 June 2010 915 December 2010 977 9,674 Source: FROB 42 BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION In 2011, capital requirements were increased up to 8-10% (depending on the financing structure of the bank). In addition, FROB’s financing took the form of ordinary shares, which required Saving Banks to change their nature into banks if they were to receive FROB aid. As a result, most savings banks transferred their activities to commercial banks which could then be recapitalised more easily. In fact, nearly 100% of savings banks have transferred their banking activity to banks4, and not only the savings banks, which have needed public money but also the healthy ones. Some of the new banks derived from former Saving Banks went listed, which qualified them for the 8% capital requirement. In this new form the financial support of the FROB is presented in table 2. Additionally, the Deposit Guarantee Scheme provided support to other Saving Banks to other Saving Banks (CAM, Caja Castilla La Mancha and Unnim) for around 7.8 billion euros as a way to make the financial sector itself to take on part of the burden of the restructuring. The Deposit Guarantee Scheme also guaranteed some of the “Asset Protection Schemes” that were granted to facilitate the sale of some of the institutions in which the FROB had intervened. Both in 2010 and 2011, the stress tests were coordinated at the European level and the capital needs detected and not covered privately, were covered by the FROB (they are included in table 1 and 2). In August 2012, with the approval of the Royal Decree Law 24/2012 (later approved as Law 9/2012), the FROB took on extensive resolution powers in close implementation of the October 2011 FSB “Key Attributes of Effective Resolution Regimes for Financial Institutions”. It thus became the Spanish banking resolution authority, sharing responsibilities with the Bank of Spain, and keeping its holding company competences. In this new format the FROB has implemented new banks capitalizations which will be described in paragraph 3.5.5. Currently, the FROB is a 100% state owned-company with a Governing Committee chaired by the Deputy Governor of the Bank of Spain and comprising representatives from the Bank of Spain, the Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness, the Ministry of Finance, a representative from ICAC (“Instituto de Contabilidad y Auditoría de Cuentas” or the Institute of Accounting and Accounts Auditing) and (without voting rights) a State Attorney, and a representative of the General Controller Department of the State Administration (IGAE). The Law 9/2012 enables the FROB to act in the key stages of a bank recovery and resolution. It allows for an early intervention, for a restructuring in which public financial sup- port is necessary in order to ensure viability and for resolution as an alternative to ordinary insolvency procedures. The law also foresees the possibility of setting up an “Asset Management Company” and of private sector involvement in the absorption of losses (“Burden sharing”). The burden sharing foreseen affects shares and hybrid instruments (that is to say, no bail-in of senior debt or deposits is foreseen). In order to exercise its functions, the FROB has at its disposal the ordinary mercantile faculties that every shareholder has and it also counts on significant administrative faculties to facilitate its work, for example: it can require the transmission of equity instruments, hybrid capital or subordinated debt instruments and/or assets and liabilities of the credit entity, it can carry out capital increases/ reductions (even with exclusion of preferential subscription rights) or it can implement Subordinated Liabilities Exercises (burden sharing). The FROB also has protocols for the detection of possible illegal operations or with no economic or financial justification. The FSB, in its first peer review of the implementation of the key attributes, concluded that the level of compliance of the Spanish regime is very high. In any case, the Spanish regime will have to be adapted when the forthcoming EU Directive on Banking Recovery and Resolution is approved. Table 2: Phase two of FROB’S financing: improving solvency 1 CatalunyaBank (Catalunya, Tarragona, Manresa) 2 Unnim (Manlleu, Sabadell, Terrassa) 3 Nova CaixaGalicia (Galicia, Caixanova) 4 Banco de Valencia Date FROB aid (M€) September 2011 1,718 December 2011 568 September 2011 2,465 May 2012 998 TOTAL As stated, a significant number of mergers and acquisitions has taken place since 2009 especially among Cajas de Ahorros, leading to a huge reduction in the number of agents 5,749 4 Only two minor Cajas maintain financial activity, Caixa Pollença y Caixa Ontinyent. Source: FROB BV 11/2013 3.3. Rationalisation of the banking sector 43 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION in the sector. The number of banks has decreased from 50 in 2009 to 15 in 2013 (not counting cooperatives, two minor saving banks and foreign branches). This number may even decrease further in the near term after the likely sales of some of the FROB participated entities and as a result of the likely integration of Unicaja and CEISS. The number of branches and employees has also adjusted, dealing with the problem of oversizing. 3.4. Cleaning up of balance sheets In early 2012, despite the restructuring and recapitalisation efforts, significant doubts remained among agents about the quality of balance sheets, in relation to real estate portfolios. Real estate assets linked to loans to developers in the whole Spanish banking system amounted to 323 billion euros by the end of June 2011, of which 175 billion euros was considered problematic. This was damaging for the whole financial sector and it explained banks’ difficulty to access wholesale financial markets. That is why two Royal Decree Laws (February and May 2012) were passed aimed at imposing on banks additional clean-up measures through new provisions and capital buffers for real estate assets. The required increase in provisions and capital buffers amounted to around 80 billion euros, which would result in a more realistic valuation of real estate assets. The goal was to dispel any doubts on the proper valuation of the asset side. 3.5. EU financial assistance As a result of these provisioning efforts and of the deteriorating macroeconomic context capital needs arose in some entities. In an effort Table 3: Adjustment in number of branches and employees: Number of employees (2000) 243.743 (2008) 278.301 (2012) 236.503 Number of branches (2008) 46.167 (2000) 39.391 (2013; Q2) 36.407 Source: Bank of Spain to ensure that, whatever the capital needs were, there would be enough public capital to deal with them, the Spanish Government announced in June 2012 that it would request European financing for the recapitalization of its weakest financial institutions for a maximum amount of 100 billion euros. The upper limit of 100 billion euros was set as a credible backstop, sufficient to cover the system’s eventual capital needs in the most stressed hypothetical scenarios. This marked the first time that EU financial assistance was requested for the support of a financial sector (up to that point all EU financial supports to euro countries –Greece, Portugal, Ireland- had been macroeconomic programs covering all financial needs of the country and not only those related to the financial sector). A Memorandum of Understanding (MoU) was signed in July 2012 including horizontal conditionality in the form of regulatory requirements (such as the strengthening of the banking resolution framework) and individual conditionality in the form of requirements for individual banks in need of public support. 3.5.1. The stress test exercise The 2012 recapitalisation process began with a comprehensive stress test. In order to ensure credibility the stress tests were conducted by two independent consultants (Oliver Wyman and Roland Berger) and it involved a Top-down and a Bottomup exercise (the latter conducted by Oliver Wyman and including on-the-ground portfolio reviews by several external auditors). Addition44 ally, the stress tests were monitored by international institutions: the European Commission and the ECB, since it was carried out in the context of a European Financial Assistance. It was also monitored by the IMF which provided technical assistance (but not financial resources). The first stage of the Tests was the Top-Down approach conducted by Oliver Wyman and Roland Berger. The objective was to offer an estimate of the aggregate capital needs for the Spanish banking system as a whole under a baseline and a stressed scenario. The time horizon of the analysis was three years: 2012, 2013 and 2014 and the core Tier 1 threshold for the base scenario was 9% and 6% for the adverse scenario. The exercise applied to 14 Spanish banking groups accounting for almost 90% of the Spanish financial system. The aggregate capital needs detected were between 51 billion euros and 62 billiuon euros. The second stage was the bottomup exercise conducted by Oliver Wyman and finalized in September. The analysis performed included a thorough review of the valuation and accounting treatment of the assets of Spanish banks, carried out by four audit firms and six appraisal companies – again, to reinforce the credibility of the exercise. The capital needs identified were around 55.8 billion euros (which was consistent with the results of the first phase). As a result of the exercise, the banks analyzed were classified in 4 different groups: • Group 0 included the banks with no capital needs even under the BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION Table 4: Key assumptions in the baseline and stressed scenario of the Spanish Stress Test GDP Unemployment Price evolution Real estate prices Interest rates FX rates Credit to other resident sectors Stocks Real GDP Nominal GDP Unemployment Rate Harmonised CPI GDP deflator Housing Prices Land prices Euribor, 3 months Euribor, 12 months Spanish debt, 10 years Ex. rate/USD Households Non-Financial Firms Madrid Stock Exchange Index 2011 0.7% 2.1% 21.6% 3.1% 1.4% -5.6% -6.7% 1.5% 2.1% 5.6% 1.35 -1.7% -4.1% -9.7% Base case 2012 2013 -1.7% -0.3% -0.7% 0.7% 23.8% 23.5% 1.8% 1.6% 1.0% 1.0% -5.6% -2.8% -25.0% -12.5% 0.9% 0.8% 1.6% 1.5% 6.4% 6.7% 1.34 1.33 -3.8% -3.1% -5.3% -4.3% -1.3% -0.4% 2014 0.3% 1.2% 23.4% 1.4% 0.9% -1.5% 5.0% 0.8% 1.5% 6.7% 1.30 -2.7% -2.7% 0.0% 2012 -4.1% -4.1% 25.0% 1.1% 0.0% -19.9% -50.0% 1.9% 2.6% 7.4% 1.34 -6.8% -6.4% -51.3% Adverse case 2013 -2.1% -2.8% 26.8% 0.0% -0.7% -4.5% -16.0% 1.8% 2.5% 7.7% 1.33 -6.8% -5.3% -5.0% 2014 -0.3% -0.2% 27.2% 0.3% 0.1% -2.0% -6.0% 1.8% 2.5% 7.7% 1.30 -4.0% -4.0% 0.0% Source: Bank of Spain stressed macroeconomic scenario (Santander, BBVA, CaixaBank, Kutxabank, Banco Sabadell, Bankinter and Unicaja). These banks did not require additional capital. • Group 1 was comprised by the banks, which were already majority-owned by the FROB: BFA-Bankia, Catalunya Banco, NCG Banco and Banco de Valencia, all of which needed further capitalisations according to the exercise. This group accounts for 18% of the sector but for 86% of the entire capital shortfall detected. • Group 2 included the rest of the banks with capital needs that could not be satisfied trough the market (Banco Mare Nostrum, Liberbank, Caja3 and CEISS). • Group 3 was composed of banks with capital needs that could be met through private means (Banco Popular and Ibercaja) The banks in groups 1, 2 and 3 should submit recapitalisation plans in October 2012 for their approval BV 11/2013 by the Banco de España and by the European Commission. On the basis of these plans, the need for State aid was to be determined. The Spanish Stress Tests have become a benchmark because of their focus on independence as a means to ensure the credibility of the results. The tests confirmed that the core of the Spanish banking sector was sound and that problems were focused on a group of institutions (limited, both in terms of quantity and size). The capital needs detected were well below the maximum amount requested from Europe (100 billion euros). 3.5.2. Restructuring and resolution plans The MoU required all the banks in need of public support to formulate a restructuring or a resolution plan (depending on whether the objective was to restore viability or to orderly liquidate the bank). Those plans included the measures that the banks were to undertake with a view to 45 avoid distortions to competition: focusing new production in retail and SME, lending in their historical core region (Real Estate Development and wholesale financing is forbidden), reducing capacity (employees and branches), divestment of non-core participations and ensuring the re-balancing of balance sheets (limitations on total asset growth, credit growth and a decrease of the loan to deposits ratios were imposed). 3.5.3 Transfer of assets to the SAREB A second requirement for the entities that needed public support was the transfer of their real estate-related assets to an Asset Management Company. To this effect the SAREB was created in 2012 (SAREB stands for “Management Company for the Assets Stemming from the Bank Restructuring” or “Sociedad de Gestión de Activos de la Reestructuración Bancaria” in Spanish). SAREB’s objective is to segregate and manage the orderly disposal of SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION Table 5: Assets transferred to SAREB Asset class Land RED foreclosed Finished housing assets Unfinished developments Finished projects Loans to RE Developers Urban land Average haircut 79.5% 54.2% 63.2% 32.4% 53.6% Gross Net Gross Assets Net Gross Total Net Loans Group 1 54.520 28.313 24.358 8.397 78.878 36.710 Group 2 20.071 11.056 7.172 2.967 27.243 14.023 Total 74.591 39.369 31.530 11.364 106.121 50.733 Source: FROB the assets related to the real estate sector, for which it has a time-horizon of 15 years. According to the restructuring and/ or resolution plans, the assets to be transferred to SAREB are those classified by the participating entities as real estate (owned and not for use) subject to an individual minimum threshold (100,000 euros), loans to real estate and development firms that meet certain eligibility criteria and above a minimum borrower net book value exposure (250,000 euros) and controlled real estate development equity investments. Assets were transferred at a transfer price composed of two elements, the “Real Economic Value” (“REV”) referred to in the MoU, calculated in the Oliver Wyman bottom up stress test exercise, using the base case scenario and an additional haircut to cover managing costs. The objective was to ensure that transfer prices were clearly conservative as one of the keys for the success of SAREB and therefore to facilitate the attraction of private capital. Assets transferred to SAREB have totalled 106.1 billion euros in book value and the transfer price has been 50.6 billion euros, so the average discount has been around 53% (with different discounts depending on the type of asset and the transferring bank). To fund the transfer, SAREB has issued securities (1-, 2- and 3-year FRNs) which are guaranteed by the Spanish Government and are therefore discountable at the Eurosystem. SAREB’s capital (a combination of pure equity and subordinated debt) is 45% public (channelled through the FROB) and 55% from private investors (who are most of the Spanish Banks with no public funds and most of the Insurance Companies). SAREB’s capital is 45% public and 55% from private investors. The creation of SAREB entails significant managerial challenges, since its time horizon is pre-fixed (15 years) and its social objective is to dispose all of its assets. SAREB is now completely operational. It has already completed its first sales and structured its first funds together with private investors. 3.5.4. Burden sharing The MoU required that part of the costs of the restructuring process would be borne by the private sector, in line with the FSB key attributes on effective resolution regimes which state that taxpayer involvement in crisis management should be minimised. In application of this principle, shareholders and holders of hybrid 46 instruments (preferred shares and subordinated debt) have suffered a haircut in their holdings. In the case of shareholders5, the entities were valued by three independent experts and in those where net value was negative shareholders were completely wiped out. This was the case of CatalunyaCaixa, NovaCaixaGalicia, Banco de Valencia, Bankia6, CEISS and Banco Gallego7. The haircut to hybrid instruments was a function of the present value of the security (calculated by discounting its expected future cash flows) and the economic value of the company. Effective burden-sharing costs have depended on the characteristics (seniority, maturity…) of the instrument, the economic value of the bank and the final shareholder structure imposed by State aid Decisions. After the haircut, the security was transformed into pure capital instruments (mostly ordinary shares and in some cases into Cocos; dated subordinated debt could, in some cases, be transformed into zero-coupon fixed-income instruments – senior debt or deposits – with lower face value). Thus, many of the holders of hybrid instruments became shareholders. 5 The shareholders were, mainly, the original Saving Banks that had transferred the activities to the Banks. In the cases of listed banks (e.g. Bankia) there were also other private shareholders. 6 In the case of Banco de Valencia and Bankia the wiping out was close to 100% but not 100% due to technical reasons, as they were quoted (the share price was reduced to 1 cent). 7 Banco Gallego was controlled by NovaCaixaGalicia and initially It was not dealt with individually. BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION In the case of non-listed entities (NovaCaixaGalicia and Catalunya Caixa) the new shareholders could not easily cash-in their shares so a voluntary liquidity mechanism was set up by the Government aimed at retail investors, allowing the Deposit Guarantee Scheme to acquire those shares with a discount (fixed by an independent expert based on liquidity parameters). More than 90% of the addressees of this option (retail shareholders formerly holders of hybrid instruments) have taken advantage of that possibility and sold their shares. Consequently, the Deposit Guarantee Scheme has become a shareholder of those banks. Many of the holders of hybrid instruments were retail investors. Since it has become apparent that the sale of those products had not been transparent in all cases (there were investors that acquired those securities without fully understanding their nature) an arbitrage procedure has been set up, with the participation of an independent expert. The arbitrage process was chosen in order to make the process more agile. In it, holders of hybrid instruments could prove that they had not been properly informed or that they did not fit the adequacy criteria for buying those instruments and earn the reimbursement of their money. Senior debt was not affected by the burden sharing. According to the current draft of the forthcoming Banking and Recovery Resolution Directive bail-in of senior debt will be introduced in 2018. 3.5.5. Recapitalisation Finally, capital needs were covered by the FROB. The FROB injected 38.8 billion euros in nine banks. These new injections come on top of the ones realized in 2010 and 2011 already described.8 This amount is lower than the estiBV 11/2013 Table 6: Phase three of FROB’s financing: capital needs detected in the Stress Tests 1 CatalunyaBank (Catalunya, Tarragona, Manresa) 2 CEISS (Caja España-Duero) 3 Nova CaixaGalicia (Galicia, Caixanova) 4 BFA-Bankia (Madrid, Bancaja, Laietana, Insular, Ávila, Segovia y Rioja) 5 Banco Mare Nostrum (Murica, Penedés, Sa Nostra, Granada) 6 Banco de Valencia 7 Liberbank (Grupo Cajastur, Caja Extremadura, Caja Cantabria) 8 Caja3 (CAI, Caja Círculo, Caja Badajoz) TOTAL Date Type of Aid FROB aid (M€) December 2012 Shares 9,084 March 2013 Cocos 604 December 2012 Shares 5,425 December 2012 Shares 17,959 December 2012 Shares 730 December 2012 December 2012 Shares Cocos 4,500 124 December 2012 Cocos 407 38,833 Source: FROB mated capital needs in the report by Oliver Wyman. The differences stem from several sources: • Disposal of assets by entities. • Raising of capital privately on the markets. • Burden sharing, which reduces the capital needs through the direct absorption of losses by those instruments and also through their transformation into equity (in more than 13 billion euros). • Transfer to SAREB, which produces two effects on the transferring banks. The first one is an increase in losses, due to the discounts incorporated in the transfer prices. This first effect increases capital needs. However, due to the disposal of those assets, RWA decrease and thus capital needed decreases too. The total net effect is a reduction in capital needs (in more than 1 billion euros). This 38.8 billion euros plus the 2.3 billion euros injected by the FROB in SAREB makes up a total of 41.1 billion euros which is the total amount 47 disposed from the European credit line (well below the agreed maximum of 100 billion euros). 3.10. Regulatory measures In compliance with the MoU, a significant strengthening of the financial regulatory environment has been conducted. Some reforms can be highlighted. • The resolution framework has been reinforced, as already described, transforming the FROB in a real resolution authority and adopting many of the FSB guidelines on effective resolution. • Corporate governance in savings banks has been strengthened with more stringent requirements of professional management. • Capital requirements were set at 9% of Core Tier 1 for all the entities (using EBA definition). 8 This Press Release by the Bank of Spain provides a summary of all the capital injections and CoCos provided by the FROB since 2009. SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION • Disclosure requirements have been enhanced and harmonised for all entities on areas such as restructured and refinanced loans, NPLs, asset quality across asset classes and sectorial concentration. • The marketing of financial products has been revised, requiring tougher tests to ensure the adequacy of the buyer of financial products. 4. Challenges ahead The restructuring process of the Spanish financial sector is significantly advanced and the progress is recognised by external analysts; however there are several challenges ahead. • The FROB has already sold its stakes in CAM, Banco de Valencia, Unnim and Banco Gallego and it now has to proceed with the sale of the remaining banks in resolution (NovaCaixaGalicia and CaixaCatalunya). In the medium term, the FROB must also sell its participation in BMN and Bankia (banks in restructuring). As for the CoCos the FROB currently holds, they should be recovered through their ordinary maturities. • The macroeconomic context is mentioned by some analysts as a vulnerability of the financial sector. However, it should be noted that economic performance is being broadly better than what was considered in the adverse scenario of the Oliver Wyman Stress Test (except for unemployment). • In the context of the building-up of the European Banking Union an Asset Quality Review and the Stress Test exercise are going to be conducted. Spain is well prepared for that exercise after the very detailed and thorough Stress Test of 2012 and the subsequent recapitalisations. It could be even said that the Spanish experience shows the importance of conducting demanding bank stress tests, exhaustive and with the widest possible scope, in order to ensure their effectiveness. • The latest recommendations from the IMF and the European Commission also refer to: 1. The need to strengthen the quality and quantity of capital, including through prudent dividend policies. In this regard, the Bank of Spain has already issued a recommendation to limit cash dividends to 25 % of profit. 2. Ensuring the cleaning up of balance sheets, including refinanced credits. As with the previous issue, the Banks of Spain has tightened the conditions for banks refinancing, which will have to be treated as substandard risks. 3. Overcoming credit supply constraints. The final goal of having a healthy financial sector is to provide sustainable credit to the real economy. The government is also implementing measures to support credit in the short term such as reinforcing ICO’s (“Instituto de Crédito Oficial” or Official Credit Institute) credit lines and by promoting non-banking financing. The main international observers endorse these conclusions. The European Commission highlighted in 30th September that: “The process of restructuring of banks having received State aid is well underway, guided by the restructuring plans as adopted by the European Commission. The foreseen burden-sharing exercises with banks´ shareholders and junior bond holders are virtually completed. Compliance with the horizontal policy requirements in the Memorandum of Understanding is nearly complete, and, thereby, the governance, regulatory and supervisory framework of the Spanish banking sector has been strengthened, which translates into higher shock resilience of the banking sector going forward.” In 30th September the IMF said that “Nearly all measures specified in the program have now been implemented, as envisaged under its front-loaded timetable. Of note, capital-augmentation measures arising from last year’s stress test are now essentially complete, as is SAREB’s organizational development.” It also adds that: “Actions under the program since its inception have bolstered the financial system’s capital, liquidity, and efficiency.” In sum, the banking sector is now better placed to fulfill its mission: to provide credit to the real economy in sustainable terms. This is the final objective underlying all the reforms conducted. 6. Conclusion The transformation experienced by the Spanish financial sector has a historic dimension and is now practically finished. The resulting financial sector is structurally different from its starting point. Financial entities are sounder; the number of entities and branches has reduced down to more efficient levels and their corporate structures are more suitable now to sustainable value creation. 48 References: FSB: Key Attributes of Effective Resolution Regimes for Financial Institutions (October 2011). EU Directive the Recovery and Resolution of Credit Institutions and Investment Firms Spanish Law 9/2012 on Banks Restructuring and Resolution EU-Spanish “Memorandum of understanding on financial-sector policy conditionality (july 2012)” Banco de España website on the financial sector restructuring Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness information on the financial sector restructuring BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION UDK 336.71(497.4):347.7 Kapital in lastništvo bank z vidika bančne sanacije pri nas Ivan Ribnikar* BANK CAPITAL AND OWNERSHIP IN LIGHT OF BANK REHABILITATION IN SLOVENIA Necessary rehabilitation of banks in Slovenia that includes the establishment of a bad bank is in fact the need to recapitalise the banks in which the government has an important or a dominant stake in their ownership structure. The government is reluctant to fulfil its duty as the majority shareholder of those banks. The bad bank seen as a priority is in fact not necessary. It may only increase the costs of bank rehabilitation, unless non-performing loans, which are supposed to be transferred to the bad bank, are not really worthless. What we have now is just the latest problem with bank ownership in Slovenia. Since the times before the transition, there have been problems with bank ownership and the paper gives a short historical overview of the situation. It seems that the only viable bank ownership is foreign ownership in the sense that Slovenian banks become subsidiaries of foreign banks. JEL G21 G 28 G32 P roblemi bank pri nas, ne samo sedanji, so problemi njihovega kapitala in za njim lastništva. Podobno sicer velja tudi za nefinančna podjetja, vendar o njih samo najpotrebnejše. Ti problemi se vlečejo iz časov pred začetkom tranzicije. Zato bomo pogledali najprej, kako je bilo s tem pred začetkom tranzicije, zatem po začetku tranzicije in kako je danes. Sanacija bank ima poleg svoje tehnične plati tudi vsebinsko. Zato na koncu še o tem in o kapitalu in lastništvu bank v prihodnje. 1. Kapital podjetij in bank pri nas pred začetkom tranzicije Kapital nefinančnih podjetij pri nas na začetku tranzicije, če z njim začnemo, je nastal, kot je znano, z odpravo družbene lastnine teh podjetij. Tako nastalega kapitala, del tega kapitala je prišel v lastništvo države, je bilo relativno precej več kot v netranzicijskih državah. Podjetja so namreč začela kot kapitalska podjetja z relativno majhno zadolženostjo. Zasluge za to ima permanentna prvobitna akumulacija kapitala1 ali premoženja v podjetjih z družbeno lastnino, ki je bila očitno zelo učinkovita. Tako akumulirano premoženje pri podjetjih se je preoblikovalo v (lastniški) kapital. Druga stran ali zrcalna slika, vendar zelo pomanjšana, tega akumuliranega kapitala v podjetjih se je kazala v premoženjskih bilancah bank kot (kumulirana) nepokrita izguba. Dr. Ivan Ribnikar, zaslužni profesor Ekonomske fakultete Univerze v Ljubljani. S tako imenovano prvobitno akumulacijo kapitala je s krajo, nasiljem in tudi z umori, če je bilo potrebno, nastajal prvi kapital. Zatem se je kapital večal zakonito z dobički podjetij. Ker je bila pri nas ves čas akumulacija kapitala, večanje trajnih virov sredstev podjetij, nezakonita, pomeni, da smo imeli permanentno prvobitno akumulacijo kapitala in družbeno nestabilnost, značilno za ta čas. Govorili so o permanentni revoluciji, vendar niso imeli v mislih te akumulacije kapitala. * 1 BV 11/2013 49 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION Imenovala se je evfemistično »negativne tečajne razlike« in ne izguba. Vendar je bilo teh izgub precej manj kot pri podjetjih akumuliranega premoženja. Del tega prenesenega premoženja na podjetja, čeprav se je prav tako dogajalo prek bank z njihovimi posojili, ni puščal sledov v premoženjskih bilancah bank. To so bila posojila, ki so jih dobila podjetja na osnovi bančnih vlog v domačem denarju. Premoženje bančnih deponentov se je zaradi negativne realne obrestne mere prenašalo z bančnimi posojili na podjetja in tega ni bilo videti v premoženjskih bilancah bank. Banke so bile že zaradi tečajnih razlik vsaj skoraj insolventne. Če pa k temu dodamo še potencialne izgube zaradi posojil, čeprav so bila posojila na pol darila, so bile insolventne. Imele so manj premoženja kot dolgov. Njihova neto aktiva so bila negativna. V začetku je bil lastniški kapital nefinančnih podjetij poceni. Lastništvo je bilo zelo razpršeno, lastniki so bili vsi državljani Slovenije. Nevedni in nezainteresirani lastniki naj ne bi vedeli, kaj lahko zahtevajo. Tako je marsikdo mislil. Vendar moramo vedeti, da so bili mnogi od teh lastnikov nekdanji ali sedanji delavci teh podjetij. Lastniki na primer niso bili niti investicijski skladi iz eksotičnih držav niti menedžerji podjetij, ki so jih kupili z velikimi bančnimi posojili in jih odplačevali z dividendami prevzetih podjetij. Finančniki, ki so poznali poslovne finance ali »corporate finance«, ali so vsaj tako mislili, in s tem optimalno kapitalsko in finančno strukturo podjetja, niso mogli kar tako prepričati podjetij, da so premalo zadolženi. Vendar pa verjetno to ne pomeni, da so bili v podjetjih nevedneži. V podjetjih so se kljub temu racionalno obnašali. Dolžniški kapital je bil namreč precej dražji od lastniškega in optimalna kapitalska struktura podjetja je tista, ki zagotavlja podjetju najcenejše financiranje. Tako kljub razpršenemu lastništvu in celo de facto diskreditiranemu delavskemu samoupravljanju ni bilo nič narobe z racionalnostjo na mikro ravni. Optimalna kapitalska struktura verjetno ni kakšno določeno razmerje med dvema vrstama kapitala, ki so ga enkrat za vselej in za povsod izračunali in ga najdemo v knjigah. To je preprosto tista struktura, ki zagotavlja podjetjem najcenejše financiranje. Podjetja so imela dosti kapitala in zaradi tega je bilo tudi dosti skomin, kako se ga polastiti. Vzrok prilaščanja, kot ga poznamo, ni namreč ostal samo pri skominah, je bil najprej že Banke so bile pred začetkom tranzicije insolventne. v načinu odprave družbene lastnine nefinančnih podjetij. Razdelitvi certifikatov ljudem je sledila tako imenovana druga faza privatizacije, kot se je reklo. Ta naj bi bila šele prava. Kmalu se je začelo lastništvo podjetij koncentrirati v rokah manjše skupine podjetij in posameznikov. Glavni val je seveda prišel precej pozneje, in sicer po letu 2004, ko ni bilo več tveganja spremembe vrednosti tolarja nasproti evru. Vendar nas to pot ne zanima, kako so prišla podjetja do današnjega stanja, ko so preveč zadolžena.2 Zanimajo nas banke in njihov kapital. Najprej pred začetkom tranzicije ali neposredno pred njenim začetkom. Banke niso imele enakih problemov s kapitalom, da bi ga bilo dosti ali celo preveč in bi ta kapital postal cilj 50 pohlepnežev. Banke ga sicer imajo na splošno mnogo manj kot nefinančna podjetja, vendar ne mislimo na to. Imele so ga manj kot drugod ali pa ga sploh niso imele. Imele so negativna neto aktiva ali neto premoženje. Bile so drugačne, kar zadeva kapital, ker pri njih ni bilo družbene lastnine3 in s tem tudi zelo učinkovite prvobitne akumulacije kapitala njim v prid. Banke so sicer bile pri tej permanentni prvobitni akumulaciji kapitala pomembne, vendar so bile na drugi strani. Prek njih se je premoženje ali kapital akumuliralo v nefinančnih podjetjih. Deloma so bile banke pri tem prenosu premoženja na podjetja samo posredniki in deloma so bile one tiste, ki so premoženje izgubljale. Ker banke niso bile v družbeni lasti, so lahko imele trajno vložena sredstva svojih ustanoviteljev. Ta sredstva so bila podobna kot delniški kapital delničarjev. Če poiščemo podobno institucijo drugod, so bile podobne kapitalskim finančnim institucijam z neomejeno odgovornostjo lastnikov. Ustanovitelji so odgovarjali za obveznosti bank z vsem svojim premoženjem. Zaradi tega tudi ni bilo pomembno, koliko imajo banke s strani svojih ustanoviteljev trajno vloženih sredstev. Navadno je bilo tega zelo malo. Neomejena odgovornost sama po sebi ni bila nekaj nenavadnega. Dandanes je še vedno v Evropi in 2 Pri vzrokih moramo začeti z načinom odprave družbene lastnine in končati s finančno in ekonomsko krizo. Vmes je vmešavanje politike v vodenje podjetij, to je obnašanje države, in poskus vodstev podjetij obraniti se tega vmešavanja na način, da so poskusila postati večinski lastnik. Dosegljivost poceni denarja je kazala, da bo to mogoče. Bila je tudi grabežljivost, vendar grabežljivost sama ne bi bila zadosti, saj kapitalizem temelji na grabežljivosti. Ne sicer neomejeni, ampak omejevani. Tako je vsaj v današnjih normalnih državah. 3 V bankah ni bilo samoupravljanja in s tem družbene lastnine, ker delo v bankah ni bilo produktivno. Ni ustvarjalo vrednosti. Seveda v skladu z marksizmom, kar pa seveda ni imelo nobene zveze z Marxom. BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION ZDA kar nekaj finančnih institucij z neomejeno odgovornostjo lastnikov. Poleg tega je neomejena odgovornost, vsaj tako je videti, še vedno ali ponovno aktualna. Zaradi propada mnogih zasebnih bank se razmišlja in piše o kapitalu in se v zvezi s tem ponovno omenja neomejena odgovornost lastnikov.4 Če bi pri tej krizi propadle banke v državni lasti, bi bil odgovor preprost. Edina prava rešitev je privatizacija. Tako pa ni preprostega odgovora.5 Sicer pa si v začetku razvoja bančništvo ni moglo zamisliti, da ne bi bilo neomejene odgovornosti. Kdo bi zaupal denar komu, če ne odgovarja neomejeno z vsem svojim premoženjem. Da bi ta neomejena odgovornost ne bila samo papirna, so bili lahko delničarji samo bogati. Neomejena odgovornosti pri naših bankah se je pred začetkom tranzicije jemala kot nekaj čudaškega in nepomembnega, ker naj bi se zaradi stalnega razvrednotevanja bančnih posojil zaradi inflacije le malokrat zgodilo, da bi podjetja ne mogla servisirati svojih bančnih dolgov in bi se posojila bank spremenila v slaba. Vendar se je izkazalo, da neomejena odgovornost bank ni bila nekaj nenavadnega, ampak pomembnega. To se je pokazalo pred začetkom tranzicije, ko so se banke spremenile v delniške družbe. Če bi bilo po zakonu, bi namreč morali lastniki, ali de facto lastniki, s svojim premoženjem pokriti kumulirane izgube bank in jih ustrezno rekapitalizirati. Šele tako bi ustvarili pogoje za njihovo spremembo v delniške družbe. Banke so se, kot vemo, brez tega spremenile v delniške družbe in država je bila tista, ki jih je pozneje sanirala. Zaradi tega je bilo lahko v podjetjih toliko več kapitala, ko so se preoblikovala v delniške družbe, in s tem premoženja za razdelitev ter potešitev skomin grabežljivih. BV 11/2013 2. Podjetja in banke po začetku tranzicije in sanacija bank Omenili smo že, kar je sicer tudi znano, da gospodarski sistem z družbeno lastnino (in delavskim samoupravljanjem) ne bi mogel delovati, če ne bi banke omogočale, da pri podjetjih nastajajo na desni strani njihove premoženjske bilance postavke, če povemo tehnicistično, ki niso dolgovi. To pomeni postavke, kot so sicer pri podjetjih trajno vložena sredstva, to je lastniški kapital. To se ni moglo dogajati normalno s trajno vloženim denarjem ali premoženjem posameznikov in institucij. Ustavno je bilo namreč prepovedano, da bi imel kdorkoli v podjetju trajno vložena sredstva. Ker pa so takšna sredstva bila, pomeni, da so nastala na neustaven način. Lahko sicer rečemo, samo na pol neustavno, ker ta sredstva niso pripadala nobeni fizični ali pravni osebi, kot na primer pri bankah ustanoviteljem, ampak so pripadala »družbi« in od tod družbena lastnina. Našel se je izhod iz zagate. Zaradi permanentne prvobitne akumulacije kapitala pri nefinančnih podjetjih prek bank so bile banke pred začetkom tranzicije insolventne. Treba jih je bilo sanirati. Če so ostale insolventne po začetku njihove sanacije tudi potem, ko je država pokrila izgube, imenovane »tečajne razlike«, in takšne so bile v začetku tri in zatem dve banki, so šle v tako imenovano individualno sanacijo. Drugačno obravnavanje »negativnih tečajnih razlik« od drugega dela izgub bank je posledica tega, da so »negativne tečajne razlike« nastajale v bankah, ker so morale sprejemati vloge v tujem denarju, medtem ko niso smele dajati posojil v tujem denarju. Zaradi zmanjševanja vrednosti bančnih posojil v dinarjih nasproti bančnim vlogam v tujem denarju, pri katerih tega ni bilo, je nastajala pri 51 bankah izguba. Lahko rečemo, da je bila ta izguba bankam vsiljena s strani oblasti in bilo je prav ali vsaj manj narobe, da to pokrije država, čeprav se je tudi s temi bančnimi posojili prenašalo premoženje na posojilojemalce. Lahko bi na primer tudi za ta del izgub poklicali lastnike bank, da te izgube pokrijejo, saj so, kot je bilo rečeno, neomejeno odgovarjali za obveznosti bank. Država je pri sanaciji bank s svojimi obveznicami pokrila izgube bank, tudi potencialne zaradi njihovih slabih posojil. V zameno za slaba posojila so banke dobile državne obveznice. S tem je prešlo lastništvo teh bank v celoti v roke države. Tehnično je to šlo prek institucije, ki je bila dejansko »slaba banka«. Ker je bila ta banka samo za državni banki, država je bila njuna edina lastnica, je bila ta slaba banka podobna slabi banki, ki jo ustanovi, kot je edino smotrno in brez problemov, posamezna banka. Ni bilo na primer pomembno, kako se vrednotijo slaba posojila, ki so se prenesla na slabo banko. Vendar pa je bilo pri tej sanaciji pomembno, da so se slaba bančna posojila prenesla po nominalni vrednosti. Tako je lahko namreč država pokrila (potencialne) izgube bank sorazmerno velikosti teh izgub. Vendar to ni bilo zadosti. Če bi namreč banki dobili od države prek slabe banke samo toliko, ne bi bili več insolventni, kar bi sicer bilo pomembno, vendar bi kljub temu dobili premalo. Bankam je bilo na- 4 Nihče seveda ne predlaga neomejene odgovornosti, vendar se omenja (Goodhart, 2010), objavljajo se razprave o britanskih bankah v devetnajstem stoletju, kako se je postopoma zmanjševal delež lastniškega kapitala (Turner, 2009). 5 Večina meni, da se mora pri bankah delež lastniškega kapitala povečati (Miles in drugi, 2011; Haldane 2012 in 2012a, Lanchester, 2013, Turner, 2013) in da se mora določiti relativno visok »leverage ratio« in opustiti ali vsaj ne zaupati toliko »risk weighted assets«, ko gre za določitev velikosti potrebnega kapitala. Izkazalo se je namreč, da ne smemo preveč zaupati v »risk weighted assets«. So pa tudi nasprotna mnenja (DeAngelo in Stulz, 2013). SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION mreč treba dati še nekaj več papirjev države, da bi bilo vsaj nekaj neto premoženja bank in s tem njihovega kapitala. Namen slabe banke, ki jo praviloma ustanovi sama banka, ni priti do daril od koga razen seveda od svojih lastnikov. Slaba banka naj bi bila finančna institucija, ki je sposobna reševati probleme podjetij, ki ne morejo servisirati svojih bančnih dolgov. In slaba banka iz začetka devetdesetih let je bila podobna slabi banki, ki jo ustanovi posamezna banka. Ker je lastnik takšne slabe banke dobra banka, lahko poljubno pomaga slabi banki. Na primer pokriva njene izgube, ki so zaradi njenih slabih terjatev pričakovane. Pri nas je bila lastnica, ali vsaj de facto lastnica obeh bank država, in ne banke, in zato je država lahko pokrivala zgube slabe banke, ki so bile dejansko izgube njenih bank, ki sta se očistili slabih posojil. To je bilo seveda smotrno s strani države, saj bi bili stroški propada teh bank zagotovo večji kot stroški sanacije, to je pokrivanja izgub in rekapitalizacije bank. Takrat seveda ni bilo zunanjih omejitev za to. Bila pa je tudi kakšna banka, ki ni potrebovala državne pomoči, vendar kljub temu ni bilo kakšne posebne diskriminacije. Lastništvo dveh bank je bilo v celoti državno. Tehnično je bilo tako, če ostanemo še pri slabi banki, da so se slaba posojila prenesla na slabo banko po njihovi nominalni vrednosti. Z razliko med nominalno in dejansko vrednostjo prenesenih slabih posojil je država subvencionirala svoji banki, to je pokrila izgube zaradi slabih bančnih posojil. Tega seveda ne bi bilo, če se slaba posojila ne bi prenašala po njihovi nominalni, ampak po dejanski vrednosti. Banka se namreč sanira samo tako, da dobi od koga dodatni kapital, če ga ima premalo, banka je na primer solventna, če kdo še pokrije kumulirane izgube, če je banka insolventna. Ker pa je z ustanovitvijo slabe banke, kot smo jo poznali, in sicer agencijo za sanacijo bank in hranilnic, šlo za dva posla, prenos slabih terjatev in pokritje izgub bank ter njuno rekapitalizacijo, se je menda ustvarilo mnenje, da je slaba banka tudi sedaj potrebna zato, da dobijo banke darila (pokritje izgub) in dodatni kapital. Od tod verjetno pričakovanja, da bo slaba banka napravila banke dobre in da bodo lahko potem te na veliko dajale posojila. Slaba banka, ki se pripravlja, je nekaj drugega kot slaba banka na začetku tranzicije. 3. Podjetja, banke in slaba banka dandanes Že nekaj časa se pri bankah povečuje obseg slabih posojil, ki izčrpavajo bančni kapital. Zaradi tega se morajo banke rekapitalizirati. Videli smo sicer, da se s slabo banko ne more povečati bančni kapital, če niso takšne razmere, kot so bile pri nas v začetku devetdesetih let. Vendar pa se dandanes kljub temu, da gre za bančni kapital, javnosti zavajajoče oznanja kot najpomembnejše, kdaj se bodo slaba posojila prenesla na slabo banko. Ali pa se ne pove, za kaj gre. Zato je videti, da je od tega odvisna rekapitalizacija bank. Ni jasno, ali se misli, da se s prenosom slabih posojil banka že rekapitalizira ali pa lahko rekapitalizacija sledi 52 šele prenosu slabih posojil. Vztrajanje na časovnem zaporedju, in sicer najprej prenos slabih posojil na slabo banko in s tem ali za tem rekapitalizacija, lahko pomeni, da so slaba posojila kužna in ne pomenijo samo ustreznega zmanjšanja kapitala, ampak negativno delujejo tudi na druge naložbe bank in zato morajo čim prej iz bilance bank. Slaba banka, ki se pripravlja, je nekaj drugega kot slaba banka na začetku tranzicije. Ni niti slaba banka posamezne banke niti bank, ki imajo istega lastnika. Država bo gotovo za njo, vendar so v treh bankah še drugi lastniki. To seveda precej zaplete prenos slabih posojil. Še posebej pomembno je, da slaba banka in prek nje država ne bosta nikomur nič podarili. Banke so namreč pri sanaciji iz devetdesetih let dobile za na slabo banko po nominalni vednosti prenesena slaba posojila državne obveznice, ki so bile denominirane v nemških markah in so prinašale bankam obresti po osemodstotni letni obrestni meri. Zdaj bodo seveda obveznice, najbolje bi bilo, kot bomo videli, da jih sploh ne bi bilo, v domači valuti in ne morda v kakšni zelo močni tuji valuti, ki bi stalno pridobivala vrednost glede na evro. Tudi z obrestmi za te obveznice bo drugače. Tudi prek obresti, ki naj bi jih slaba banka plačevala bankam, ne sme država subvencionirati bank. Zaradi tega bo slaba banka smela dati bankam v zameno za slaba posojila samo pretočne obveznice (»pass-through bonds«)6. Vendar upamo, da je to samo hipotetično, to je, kako bi bilo, če bi bilo narobe in ne bi bila prenesena na slabo banka resnično samo ničvredna posojila. Slaba banka se je pojavila pred nekaj časa, čeprav se jasnovidci hvalijo, da so jo predlagali že pred 6 Nekaj besed o tej obveznici je mogoče najti v kratkem besedilu iz leta 1996 (Ribnikar, 1966). BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION leti, zaradi problemov s kapitalom treh bank, kjer je država večinska ali pomembna lastnica. Zaradi zunanjih okoliščin in tudi razmer v teh bankah bi jih morala država ponovno rekapitalizirati, kar ni tako nenavadno za lastnika, čeprav je lahko formalno zapleteno, ker je država lastnica in smo v EU. V obtok je prišla slaba banka. Vendar pa, ko gre za slaba bančna posojila, je edino prav, če vsaka banka, ki ima dosti takšnih posojil, ustanovi svojo slabo banko, če posebni oddelek banke, ki bi se ukvarjal samo s slabimi posojili, ne bi bil zadosti. Bodisi da gre za posebni oddelek v banki ali za slabo banko, ki jo ustanovi banka, je njen namen zagotoviti boljše gospodarjenje s tem izdvojenim premoženjem banke. Postaviti podjetja na noge, če je mogoče, in jih prodati, če so banke (in država) njegove pomembne lastnice. To je tudi lahko edini smisel tudi slabe banke, ki se načrtuje in nestrpno pričakuje. V posebnem oddelku, ki ga ustanovijo posamezne banke, ali pa v slabi banki, če je oddelek premalo, je pomembno, da so v njem ljudje z bančnimi izkušnjami in izkušnjami reševanja podjetij različnih dejavnosti, ki se na to bolje spoznajo kot drugi bankirji ali kot bankirji nasploh. 4. Problemi kapitala pri nas Problemi kapitala bank, ki so dejansko problemi njihovega lastništva, se vlečejo že od začetka tranzicije. Še posebej so postali pereči v zadnjem času, ko je lastnik, mislimo seveda na državo, namesto rekapitalizacije »svojih« ali »skoraj svojih« bank odkril, verjetno s pomočjo Bruslja, slabo banko. Kakor koli obračamo, je problem nezadostnost kapitala. Ker pa je pri nas očitno to problem lastništva bank, nas zanima, kako je s tem lastništvom. Problemi lastništva in kapitala so tudi pri nefinančnih podjetjih in drugih finančnih instituciBV 11/2013 jah, vendar jih puščamo ob strani. Za tranzicijske države se v začetku postavlja zasebno lastništvo nasproti še vedno državnemu. Pri nas verjetno ne moremo postavljati državnega lastništva podjetij nasproti zasebnemu. Ne morda zaradi tega, ker pri nas pred začetkom tranzicije ni bilo državne lastnine, nastala je šele z odpravo družbene lastnine in s sanacijo bank. Pri nas namreč navadno pomeni privatizacija, in to ne samo bank, ampak tudi nefinančnih podjetij, ne Problemi kapitala naših bank so dejansko problemi njihovega lastništva. samo prodaje tujcem, ampak precej več in/ali nekaj drugega. Pomeni namreč navadno prevzem banke ali podjetja s strani kakšne tuje banke ali tujega podjetja, kar se navadno označuje kot strateško partnerstvo, čeprav ni nikakršnega partnerstva. To velja še posebej za banke. Če kdo govori o privatizaciji bank na primer v Nemčiji, to ne pomeni, da bodo tujci prevzeli banke. V Nemčiji je namreč več kot dovolj domačih potencialnih bančnih lastnikov, in sicer različnih finančnih institucij. Med njimi bodo seveda tudi tuje finančne institucije, vendar to ni nič posebnega. Lahko so tudi pretežno ali celo samo tuje, vendar je pomembno, ali ostaja banka samostojna in da ne postane hči druge banke. Čeprav verjetno nima v Nemčiji 53 skoraj nihče nič proti privatizaciji, je gotovo drugače, ko gre za to, da bi tuja podjetja prevzela nemška in jih spremenila v svoje hčere. Zato gre med nami in tujci, ko se govori in piše o privatizaciji, za »double talking«. Za kaj gre, tega ne vedo niti tisti, ki pri nas neprenehoma govorijo, naj se čim prej vse privatizira, niti tujci. Ne vedo, da nam pravijo, da moramo banke in podjetja čim prej prepustiti tujim bankam in podjetjem, da jih prevzamejo in spremenijo v svoje podružnice ali hčerinska podjetja. Vendar vse to ni argument za to, da se država ne umakne iz lastništva bank in nefinančnih podjetij, če se ona ne more spremeniti. Žal ni videti, da bi naša država postala podobna drugim, kjer lastništvo države ni nič nenavadnega. Vendar nam posebnost, kaj pomeni pri nas privatizacija, morda razloži, zakaj toliko obotavljanja pri privatizaciji. Privatizacija je, kot smo videli, pri nas nekaj drugega kot v večjih evropskih državah. In glede na državo, kakšno imamo, se moramo zato osvoboditi iluzij, kakšna podjetja in kakšno gospodarstvo bomo imeli. Ker nas zanimajo banke, še nekaj besed o kapitalu in lastništvu bank. V nasprotju z nefinančnimi podjetji, pri katerih je lahko lastnik kdor koli, za banke ni dobro, da je lastništvo razpršeno in da se skupina, ki ima odločilni lastniški nadzor v banki, pogosto spreminja. Pogosto spreminjanje večinskega lastništva, kar je lahko pri razpršenem delničarstvu, pomeni namreč za banko nestabilnost. Zato je v tej zvezi najpomembnejše, da so večinski lastniki finančne institucije. Pri finančnih institucijah je skoraj vse njihovo premoženje finančno in delnice bank v njihovem portfelju so nekaj običajnega. Tega ne moremo reči za nefinančna podjetja. Zanje je praviloma finančno premoženje samo nekaj začasnega. Pri njih ne moremo pričakovati, da bodo ostali SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION lastniki na dolgi rok. S tem imamo tudi mi kar nekaj izkušenj. Če pogledamo pri nas finančne institucije po številu in velikosti kot potencialne lastnice bank, vidimo, da takšno lastništvo bank ni mogoče. Koketiranje s pokojninskimi skladi je na primer bila neumnost, čeprav je bil to eden od argumentov za njihovo ustanovitev. Vsak sklad, in zato tudi pokojninski, mora razpršiti svoje premoženje in v takšnem skladu ne bi moglo biti več kot nekaj delnic kakšne naše večje banke. Kakor koli obračamo, ne moremo najti ustreznih potencialnih lastnikov bank. Poleg države ostane samo tujina. Navadno je seveda alternativa državi kot lastnici bank, in tudi nefinančnih podjetij, to, da banke, tudi nefinančna podjetja, izgubijo samostojnost in postanejo hčere tujih bank ali tujih (nefinančnih) podjetij. Če država ne more biti lastnica bank ali to ni dobro, ker je slab lastnik, kar je pri nas splošno sprejeta resnica, kar pa seveda ne velja za državo na splošno, je edina rešitev privatizacija v tistem smislu, kot je pri nas edino mogoča. Dopustiti moramo, da banke postanejo na splošno hčere tujih bank. Tako izgubijo svojo samostojnost. Verjetno je ekonomska samostojnost, seveda omejena, podobno pomembna kot politična, vendar pa v zvezi s politično samostojnostjo nihče ne govori omalovažujoče, da gre za izmišljeni nacionalni interes. Država očitno že nekaj časa kaže, da ne želi biti lastnica bank, če ostanemo samo pri njih. Ne želi na primer rekapitalizirati bank. Slaba banka, ki naj bi bila odkritje, lahko privede samo do tega, da če ne bodo prenesena nanjo samo resnično ničvredna posojila, bodo stroški sanacije bank mnogo večji in tako vse skupaj še bolj grozno. Rekapitalizacija se šteje, ne glede na Bruselj, za pomoč, za nekaj, kar bodo spet plačali davkoplačevalci in podobno. Država bo morala prepustiti banke, da jih prevzamejo tuje banke in jih spremenijo v svoje hčere. In videti je, če pomislimo na slabo banko, da to želi napraviti hitro, čeprav v škodo državljanov in ne samo davkoplačevalcev. Sanacija bank in slaba banka sta namreč tako zamišljeni, vsaj kot je videti, da bo vsakomur neizpodbitno dokazano, da se to mora zgoditi. To so, upajmo, čeprav je tega upanja verjetno malo, samo želje. Država se mora sicer v celoti umakniti iz bank, če ne želi imeti večinskega lastniškega deleža. Manjši delež, na primer 25 odstotkov in še ena delnica, kar naj bi bila strateška odločitev, je neumnost. S kakršnim koli deležem, ki je manjši od nekaj nad 50 odstotkov, ne more preprečiti, da banka ne bi izgubila samostojnosti. Sprijazniti se bomo morali, da ekonomska samostojnost ne bo samo deloma omejena, kot je nujno v današnjem svetu, ampak da bo zelo omejena, kot tudi dandanes ni ravno nujno. Videti je, da je pri nas zaradi države, kakršno imamo, to nujno. *** Banke, ki so v večinskem lastništvu države, so zaradi finančne in ekonomske krize ter še česa drugega, kar nas ne zanima, v težavah in država jih noče rekapitalizirati.7 Ponuja slabo banko, na katero naj bi bila prenesena slaba bančna posojila teh bank. Že ves čas se vse vrti okrog te banke in vrednotenja slabih posojil. Videti je, da država želi prenesti na slabo banko slaba posojila po vrednosti, ki seveda ne bo nominalna, kot je bila nekoč, in prav je tako, vendar tudi ne bo dejanska, ampak bo nič ali vsaj blizu tega. Stroški bi bili v tem primeru s slabo banko manjši, to je, ne bi bilo nepotrebnih dodatnih stroškov, vendar tega država ne more napraviti. Ni edina lastnica treh bank, saj bi to bila kraja in seveda nasprotje sanacije bank. Poleg tega, 54 kar je verjetno pomembnejše, bi po tem prenosu imele banke še manj kapitala, ker bi se s prenosom tako vrednotenih slabih posojil prenesel na slabo banko tudi del njihovega premoženja. Zaradi tega bi bilo treba za rekapitalizacijo bank še več kapitala, vendar pa tega kapitala očitno država ne bi mogla zagotoviti. Zato bi bila nujna hitra privatizacija teh bank. Premoženje, vzeto bankam, ko bi se slaba posojila nasilno kot ničvredna prenesla na slabo banko, čeprav posojila ne bi bila takšna, bi postalo premoženje slabe banke. Ko bi se podjetja, ki so dolžniki pri prenesenih slabih posojilih, prodajala, bi slaba banka dosegala zanje ugodno ceno. Prek prodajne cene podjetij bi namreč unovčila vsaj delno tudi premoženje, ki je bilo prek slabih posojil kot ničvredno preneseno nanjo. Zaradi ugodnih cen bi bilo treba podjetja kar se da hitro prodati. Zasluga za privatizacijo in dober izkupiček bi šla upravi slabe banke in seveda njeni zamisli. Ker pa je vse to hipotetično, nasilnosti si pri vrednotenju slabih posojil slaba banka kljub morebitni podpori Bruslja verjetno ne bi mogla privoščiti, ni mogoče videti racionalnega razloga za slabo banko. Če država in verjetno Bruselj, kljub temu, da ni racionalnega razloga zanjo, želita ostati pri slabi banki, to očitno želi uprava te banke, saj se kregajo za mesto v njej. Zato je edini način, da se zaradi prenosa slabih posojil nanjo ne bodo povečali stroški za državo, ta, da se prenesejo na slabo banko samo resnično ničvredna posojila. Pričakovana vrednost teh 7 Ker država ne more rekapitalizirati bank s svojimi obveznicami, to je s stvarnim vložkom, in to ni samo naša iznajdba, ampak menda tudi Bruslja, mora za potreben denar iti na trg. To bo ali bi podražilo rekapitalizacijo bank s strani države, če pustimo ob strani, kaj vse se šteje kot državna pomoč. Tudi to je tako lepo narejeno, da bo privatizacija nujna in je igra s slabo banko in z vrednotenjem slabih posojil morda sploh nepotrebna. BV 11/2013 SYSTEMIC ASPECT OF BANKING SECTOR REHABILITATION posojil mora biti nič. Prenos kakršnih koli drugih posojil, ki niso ničvredna in slaba banka plača zanje toliko, kolikor so vredna, se za ta znesek po nepotrebnem, namreč samo za to, da se spremeni lokacija slabih posojil, povečajo stroški sanacije, če ostanemo pri besedi sanacija. Če bodo prenesena tudi druga posojila, ki niso dejansko ničvredna, po njihovi dejanski vrednosti, bo to pomenilo, da državi, in s tem davkoplačevalcem, o katerih toliko govori, stroški niso pomembni. Ne pride verjetno v poštev, kot je bilo že rečeno, da se prenašajo posojila, ki niso ničvredna, kot da bi bila takšna, in da zato banke zanje ne dobijo nič. Zato je edino racionalno v iracionalnosti, da se na slabo banko, na katero stavijo ne samo država, ampak tudi gospodarstvo in strokovnjaki, prenesejo samo resnično ničvredna bančna posojila.Tako država ne bi imela nobenih dodatnih stroško, ne bi izdala nobenih obveznic, ali ne bi jamčila za nobene obveznice, ki BV 11/2013 bi jih bankam dala slaba banka. Za državo bi bili stroški sanacije bank samo stroški rekapitalizacije bank, če seveda rekapitalizacijo imenujemo strošek.8 Pri tem puščamo ob strani sicer za mnoge zelo pomembne verjetno kolateralne koristi od slabe banke, na primer možnost odkriti, kdo je dajal posojila, ki so zdaj slaba. Verjetno tudi posojila, ki so bila ob odobritvi dobra. Tako ne bi šlo samo za zapravljanje denarja, kar se ne sme kar tako dopustiti, ampak tudi za blamažo Slovenije, kako se namreč odkriva morebitno fravdulentno obnašanje bankirjev. LITERATURA IN VIRI/REFERENCES: DeAngelo, H. & R. M. Stulz, 2013, »Why high leverage is optimal for banks«, NBER Working Paper 19139, 20 str. Goohart, C., 2010, »How should we regulate bank capital and financial products? What role for 'living wills'?, objavljeno v: R. Adair Turner in drugi, »The Future of Finance«,LSE, str. 165 – 186. Haldane, A., 2012, The doom loop«, 55 London Review of Books, 23. Februar, 8 str. Haldane, A., 2012, »The dog and the frisbee«, Razprava na 36. Simpoziju Federal Reserve Bank of Cansas City »The changing policy landscape«, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, 31, avgusta, 36 str. Lanchester, J., 2013, »Let's consider banks: can we tame the banks«, London Review of Books, 8. Julij, 15 str. Miles, D., J. Yang & G. Marcheggiano, 2011, »Optimal bank capital«, Bank of England, Discussion Paper No. 31, 52 str. Ribnikar, I., 2009, »Listinjenje«, Bančni vestnik, št. 1-2, str. 48-51. Turner, J. D., 2009, » 'The last acre and sixpence': view on bankliability management in nineteenth century Britain«, Financial History Review, str. 111- 127. Turner, A., 2013, »Debt, Money and Mephistopheles: how we get out of this mess?«, Cass usiness School, str. 43. 8 Strošek za državo in s tem za državljane in ne samo za davkoplačevalce, kot neprestano slišimo in beremo, je namreč strošek za tiste, ki neto dobivajo od države, je v izgubi »njenih« bank, če ostanemo pri bankah.Gre samo za izgubo, ki je posledica nevestnega ali celo fravdulentnega obnašanja uprav in nadzornih svetov bank. Običajna izguba ni nekaj kriminalnega. Kot pravi P. Samuelson, kapitalizem ne temelji na dobičku, ampak temelji na dobičku in izgubi. Rekapitalizacija bank, ki je morda enaka izgubi bank v lastništvu države, ni strošek ampak naložba države. Če morda Bruselj in tudi strokovna javnost doma mislita drugače, ne spremeni dejstva, da je rekapitalizacija bank kot vsaka druga naložba in se o njej odloča podobno. Strošek za državo je namreč z izgubo že bil narejen. L E GA L E N V I R O N M E N T A N D L E G I S L AT I V E F R A M E WO R K O F C O M PA N Y R E S T R U C T U R I N G UDK 338.124.4:336.71 Zakonodaja o sistemskem razdolževanju Andrej Simonič* SYSTEMIC DELEVERAGING LEGISLATION As Slovenia is facing a severe financial and banking crisis, and a severe downturn in the corporate sector, it is of great importance that we introduce new rules to facilitate the survival of businesses, banks, jobs and people. The main goal of the new act on systemic deleveraging of companies is to make it easier for creditors and debtors to reach out-of-court settlements and quicker debt-to-equity conversions, which would lead to rescue and restructuring of businesses. The new rules should allow creditors to step in the process sooner, thus contributing to the company’s survival more efficiently than they can now in the compulsory settlement proceedings, which are run and controlled by irresponsible owners. Compulsory settlements often occur too late and the creditors get too little out of them. New out-of-court settlements of debt-to-equity swaps would be faster, controlled by creditors and would only be possible if the benefits for the creditors were larger in comparison with bankruptcy proceedings. Z akon o finančnem poslovanju podjetij in postopkih zaradi insolventnosti in prisilnem prenehanju (ZFPPIPP) – poenostavljeno obstoječa insolvenčna zakonodaja – se uporablja od 1. oktobra 2008. Z rezultati uporabe ne moremo biti zadovoljni. 1. Stečajna zakonodaja ne daje dobrih rezultatov Stroški stečaja so med najvišjimi na svetu, hitrost postopka pa je med najpočasnejšimi na svetu. Obstoječa zakonodaja ne omogoča ohranjanja zdravih jeder v stečaju. Gre za čisto razprodajo premoženja. Zaradi dolgotrajnosti postopkov je premoženje v postopkih prodaje v ekonomskem pogledu neaktivno. Dolžnik ga ne more uporabljati, kupec pa ne kupiti ne ekonomsko aktivirati. Tudi postopki prisilne poravnave so se izkazali kot večinoma neuspešni. Večina podjetij kljub zaključku prisilne poravnave ostane prezadolžena. Količnik med dolgom in EBITDA ostaja mnogo previsok. Če k temu dodamo še splošno poslabšanje ekonomskih razmer v državi, dolžniki iz potrjene prisilne poravnave kmalu vnovič zaidejo v insolventnost. V ekonomskem pogledu torej rezultat prisilne poravnave ni dosti drugačen od stečaja. V obeh primerih dolžnik že na srednji rok preneha poslovati, pred tem pa posluje na robu likvidnosti, ni razvoja in počasi umira. JEL G01 G31 G33 * Andrej Simonič, univ. dipl. iur. 56 BV 11/2013 L E GA L E N V I R O N M E N T A N D L E G I S L AT I V E F R A M E WO R K O F C O M PA N Y R E S T R U C T U R I N G 2. Razlogi za slabe rezultate Poglavitni problem v Sloveniji je nerešeno konceptualno vprašanje, kaj pomeni prisilna poravnava na podlagi izkazane insolvence. Po teoriji naj bi se v insolvenčnih postopkih, kot posledici insolvence , dogajala »generalna izvršba« za poplačilo vseh upnikov. In če je restrukturiranje boljši način poplačila le-teh, lahko upniki pristanejo nanj, drugače gre za razprodajo premoženja dolžnika in njegovo ukinitev kot poslovnega subjekta . V obeh poznanih načinih izvedbe insolvenčnega postopka, kot enoten postopek (npr. Nemčija) ali dva ločena postopka (npr. ZDA), imetniki udeležb (lastniki) postanejo razred upnikov, restrukturiranje in ohranjanje delujočih podjemov je mogoče v obeh primerih. Slovenski ZFPPIPP vzpostavlja dva med seboj ločena postopka. Prvič, prisilno poravnavo, ki jo v celoti obvladujejo stari lastniki in uprava, ki jo ti imenujejo. In drugič, stečajni postopek, ki ne omogoča ohranitve delovanja podjetja. Obe poti sta neustrezni. Poleg previsokih stroškov v stečaju praviloma ne ostane nič za poplačilo navadnih upnikov, to je zlasti delavcev in dobaviteljev. S prodajo premoženja se praviloma poplačajo zgolj zavarovani upniki, pa še ti ne nujno v celoti. Zaradi nastanka sistemske nelikvidnosti so cene dosežene v stečajnih prodajah nizke. Zakon ne omogoča razdelitve neprodajljivega premoženja med upnike. Neustrezno je zastavljena tudi prisilna poravnava. Načrt finančnega prestrukturiranja v prisilni poravnavi pripravijo uprava in stari lastniki, kar zbuja nezaupanje upnikov. V obstoječi ureditvi prisilne poravnave ni upoštevano načelo absolutne prioritete. V predlogu finančnega prestrukturiranja ni mogoče oblikovati razredov in tako upoštevati različen pravni in ekonomski položaj različnih skupin upnikov. Na primer, BV 11/2013 prisilna poravnava posega v pravice malih dobaviteljev, ki bi jih bilo, gleda na ekonomske okoliščine, edino smiselno v celoti poplačati, pa zakon tega ne omogoča. Mali in veliki dobavitelji, banke, ki posojajo obratni kapital, in banke, ki dajejo investicijska posojila, so enako obravnavani, kar je popolna deformacija. Stari lastniki, ki bi morali prvi vse izgubiti, ohranjajo svoje deleže. O potrditvi prisilne poravnave glasujejo navadni upniki, ki v primeru stečaja sploh ne Obe poti, prisilna poravnava in stečajni postopek, sta trenutno neustrezni. bi bili poplačani, zavarovani upniki, ki bi morali biti najmanj prizadeti, pa sploh ne glasujejo. Posledica opisane deformirane situacije je tudi deformiran tipičen rezultat prisilne poravnave. Prevladujoča rešitev je maksimalen reprogram dolga in čim manj konverzije dolga v kapital. Posledično s potrditvijo prisilne poravnave dolžnik ni niti finančno niti poslovno prestrukturiran. 3. Dodaten vpliv finančne krize na vodenje insolvenčnih postopkov Po začetku svetovne finančne krize je že leta 2010 postalo očitno, da je poglaviten vir ekonomske krize v Sloveniji prezadolženost nefinančnega sektorja. Posojilni bum pomeni krizo tudi v bankah. Nelikvidnost 57 se je najprej pojavila pri najbolj izpostavljenih dolžnikih, potem pa je po sistemu domin hitro prerasla v sistemsko nelikvidnost. Glede na položaj v slovenskem gospodarstvu je tako v tem trenutku skoraj nemogoče izvesti finančno prestrukturiranje s hkratno dokapitalizacijo. Tako se ponuja rešitev: konverzija dolga v kapital. V tem okviru lahko pričakujemo, da bodo banke takšnemu dolžniku zagotovile posojila za obratni kapital, s tem da bo zaradi razdolžitve potreba po bančnem financiranju obratnega kapitala manjša. Investicijska vlaganja pa se bodo odložila na čas po izvedenem poslovnem prestrukturiranju. Poslovno prestrukturiranje pa bodo morali izvesti novi lastniki, za kar bo potrebno več časa od časa za samo konverzijo. 4. Način reševanja obstoječih razmer Uporabiti je treba splošno načelo: pravila o sistemski razdolžitvi omogočijo sklepanje krovnega sporazuma tako, da se omogoči rešitev, ki je enaka, kot bi bil pogodbeni dogovor med strankami v svetu popolnih informacij in z ničelnimi transakcijskimi stroški. Upnikom se v okviru maksimalne možne pogodbene svobode omogoči sklepanje krovnih sporazumov na način, da se izvede uspešno finančno prestrukturiranje dolžnikov, ob predpostavki, da vsi upniki dobijo v primeru sklenitve krovnega sporazuma večjo vrednost, kot bi jo dobili v primeru razprodaje premoženja v stečajnem postopku. S sklenitvijo krovnega sporazuma si upniki med seboj v skladu z dogovorom razdelijo pozitivno razliko vrednosti delujočega podjetja v razmerju do likvidacijske mase. Če ni tako, krovni sporazum ne bo sklenjen in začel se bo stečaj. Zgoraj opisana dodana vrednost L E GA L E N V I R O N M E N T A N D L E G I S L AT I V E F R A M E WO R K O F C O M PA N Y R E S T R U C T U R I N G za upnike se bo realizirala zgolj pod pogojem, da bo razdolženo podjetje sposobno dolgoročno pozitivno poslovati v boju s konkurenco. Navedeno pa pomeni, da bo treba doseči vzdržno razmerje med dolgom in EBITDA, ki se bo moralo gibati nekje blizu količnika 3. Novi predpis seveda takšnega razmerja ne more omogočiti neposredno. Lahko pa sklepanje razumnih dogovorov omogoči tako, da odpravi deformacije obstoječega ZFPPIPP, to pa je zlasti pravilno upoštevanje načel absolutne prioritete in razrešitev vprašanja posega v pravice zavarovanih upnikov. Le tako bo vsem pogajalcem omogočeno jasno in enoznačno razumevanje postopka razdolžitve in primerjava le-tega z alternativno možnostjo, to je s stečajem. Tako sklenjeni krovni sporazumi bodo logični in ekonomsko vzdržni. 5. Koncept zakona o sistemski razdolžitvi (v nadaljevanju ZSR) Praksa kaže, da se upniki vključitvi v formalne postopke po ZFPPIPP izogibajo. Dolžniki in banke sklepajo sporazume o moratoriju ter se pogajajo o sklenitvi krovnega sporazuma. Do končne sklenitve tega pa pogosto ne pride zato, ker ni mogoče doseči 100-odstotnega soglasja vseh upnikov. V takšnem primeru bi seveda moral biti upnik, ki ne želi skleniti sporazuma, 100-odstotno poplačan v skladu s pogodbo, kar pa je nesprejemljivo za preostale upnike. ZSR bi tako uredil način, kot se zdaj dogaja v praksi. To je, da bi omogočil sklenitev moratorija in krovnega sporazuma z večino glasov in ne s stoodstotnim soglasjem. Zaradi pravila o preglasovanju je potrebna sodna potrditev predhodno že sklenjenega oziroma izglasovanega krovnega sporazuma. 6. Dileme ZSR • Načelo absolutne prioritete Načelo absolutne prioritete v principu pomeni, da mora biti zagotovljena prednost poplačila zavarovanih terjatev pred navadnimi terjatvami in pred podrejenimi terjatvami in na koncu pred terjatvami družbenikov. Ob upoštevanju absolutne prioritete mora krovni sporazum zagotavljati ugodnejše poplačilo vseh upnikov od poplačila v primeru stečaja. V zvezi Praksa kaže, da se upniki formalnim zakonodajnim postopkom izogibajo. s podrobnejšo izvedbo pa so odprta številna strokovna vprašanja. V vrstnem redu od najbolj prednostnih upnikov proti manj prednostnim upnikom imamo naslednje vrste upnikov: 1.Zavarovani upniki (finančna in nefinančna zavarovanja) 2.Navadni upnik DURS (davki in prispevki) 3.Navadni upniki delavci 4.Navadni upniki veliki dobavitelji 5.Navadni upniki mali dobavitelji 6.Navadni finančni upniki 7.Podrejeni upniki (obveznice CoCo) 8.Lastniki Zgoraj so navedene le nekatere najpogostnejše skupine upnikov. V primeru stečaja se takšni upniki poplačajo po še kar jasnem vrstnem redu prioritet, kot jih določa ZFPPIPP. V idealiziranem primeru se iz enotne 58 mase denarja pridobljene s prodajo dolžnikovega premoženja poplačajo najprej zavarovani upniki, nato se poplačajo stroški stečaja in šele s preostankom se poplačajo navadni upniki, med njimi delno prednostno delavci. V primeru finančnega prestrukturiranja in s tem nadaljevanja poslovanja dolžnika pa stvar ni več tako enostavna. Vir za poplačilo ni več denar iz likvidacijske mase, ampak pozitiven denarni tok finančno saniranega podjetja in/ali vrednost podjetja pri »debt zo equity swap-u«. Gledano znotraj prvega leta je višina prostega denarnega toka praviloma nižja od likvidacijske vrednosti, ob upoštevanju diskontirane vrednosti bodočega denarnega toka pa je vrednost podjetja seveda večja od likvidacijske vrednosti. Upnike je v skladu z načeli prioritete možno izplačati le v ustrezno določenem časovnem obdobju. Pri tem pa je z vidika zagotovitve uspešnega sprejetja finančnega prestrukturiranja ter nadaljnjega poslovanja podjetja treba nekatere upnike poplačati celo 100-odstotno v skladu s pogodbami, kar je več, kot bi jim šlo v skladu z načelom prioritete. Praviloma so tako prednostno poplačani mali dobavitelji in delavci. Vprašanje je, kje so v tem primeru terjatve države iz naslova davkov in prispevkov. Na tem mestu pa ne gre več le za strokovno vprašanje, temveč tudi za politično. Mogoča je rešitev, da krovni sporazum posega le v pravice finančnih upnikov in se nefinančni upniki 100-odstotno poplačajo, kar pa je velik poseg v načelo prioritete. Obravnavano načelo absolutne prioritete je mnogo pomembnejše, kot se zdi na prvi pogled. Bistvo načela je, da ne posega v obstoječa pogodbena razmerja. Pri tem gre za pogodbena razmerja, ki so nastala v času, ko je bil dolžnik solventno podjetje. Takšna pogodbena razmerja so se izvrševala in BV 11/2013 L E GA L E N V I R O N M E N T A N D L E G I S L AT I V E F R A M E WO R K O F C O M PA N Y R E S T R U C T U R I N G ob zapadlosti tekoče poplačevala. Lastniki so si izplačevali dividende. Navedena obligacijska in korporacijska razmerja pa so v sebi vsebovala pravila o tveganjih. Ravno ta pravila o tveganjih se po nastopu insolventnosti spremenijo v pravila absolutne prioritete. Pri tem je pomembno, da v času sklepanja pogodb pogodbene stranke zaupajo, da bodo v primeru nastanka insolventnosti tveganja, kot so vgrajena v pogodbe, realizirana skladno z načeli prioritete. Takšno zaupanje pomembno znižuje stroške financiranja delujočih podjetij in tako povečuje konkurenčnost nacionalne ekonomije. In nasprotno, dvom v spoštovanje načela absolutne prioritete v okviru delujočega podjetja povzroča deformacije, ki se kažejo v neobičajnih načinih financiranja. V slovenskih razmerah je to v praksi pomenilo, da so v nasprotju z evropsko prakso skoraj vse banke, kot finančni kreditodajalci, zahtevale zavarovanje s hipoteko na nepremičnini, ker jim je edino to zagotavljalo jasno določeno prioriteto oziroma zavarovanje pred tveganji. Ob pripravi nove insolvenčne zakonodaje je nujno treba pripraviti jasen, razumljiv in razumen sistem absolutnih prioritet, ki bo utemeljen na spoštovanju pogodbenih določil ter ustrezno modificiran glede na ekonomsko nujnost zagotovitve nadaljnjega poslovanja finančno prestrukturiranega dolžnika. Glede obojega navedenega pa bo treba najti tudi ustrezno politično soglasje, kajti zainteresirane institucije predstavljajo različne skupine upnikov (npr. finančni in nefinančni upniki), zato so njihovi interesi nasprotni. Pri tem je pomembno, da potrebno politično soglasje ne bo preveč deformiralo sistema. Vsaj delavci in mali dobavitelji bi se morali zavedati, da so v pogledu prioritet v najslabšem položaju, vendar pa je ravno njihov interes glede nadaljnjega poslovanja dolžnika in s tem možnosti novih poBV 11/2013 slov s finančno saniranim dolžnikom močnejši od interesa po čim večjem poplačilu iz naslova starih poslov, vendar z dvomom nadaljnjega poslovanja dolžnika. • Poseg v pravice zavarovanih upnikov. Slovenska posebnost je, da so praviloma vsi finančni upniki hkrati tudi zavarovani upniki. Zlasti zaradi sistemske nelikvidnosti ob nastopu insolventnosti likvidacijska masa ne zadošča niti za poplačilo zavarovanih upnikov. To pomeni, da je v številnih primerih za potrebe vzdržnega načrta finančnega prestrukturiranja Zagotovljena mora biti prednost poplačila zavarovanih terjatev pred drugimi terjatvami. dolžnika treba najti razumen način, kako poseči v pravice zavarovanih upnikov. Pri tem bo treba razlikovati med upniki s finančnimi zavarovanji in upniki z nefinančnimi zavarovanji. Osnutek ZSR zaenkrat predvideva le obveznost glasovanja zavarovanih upnikov v posebnem razredu, pri čemer je odločitev v takšnem razredu sprejeta s 75-odstotno večino nominalne vrednosti terjatev. Vsebina takšne odločitve pa še ni jasna. Ena od možnosti je, da se oblikuje poseben pool zavarovanj in določi delež posameznega zavarovanega upnika 59 v tem poolu. • Cenilci in upravitelj Vsi primerljivi postopki zunajsodnih prestrukturiranj v drugih državah predvidevajo posebno vlogo administratorja. Osnutek ZSR namenja funkcijo administratorja stečajnim upraviteljem, imenovanim na podlagi določb ZFPPIPP. Vprašanje je, ali je to najboljša rešitev, zlasti ker je v postopku finančnega prestrukturiranja potreben finančni svetovalec, kar upravitelj ni. Osnutek ZSR dopušča to vprašanje pogodbeni svobodi upnikov in dolžnika. Osnutek ZSR prav tako ne predvideva obveznega imenovanja cenilca. V okviru pogodbene svobode si lahko ustreznega izvedenca najame vsak upnik za potrebe lastnega odločanja o načinu glasovanja glede potrditve krovnega sporazuma ali pa tudi dolžnik, da si zagotovi verodostojnost predlogov. Tudi zahtevana vsebina krovnega sporazuma je v osnutku ZSR navedena le na ravni načel, konkretizacija pa je prepuščena pogodbeni svobodi. Vprašanje je, če vse navedeno zadošča za odločanje sodišča glede sodne potrditve krovnega sporazuma. Menim, da bi bilo treba glede navedenega vprašanja zunaj določb zakona pripraviti posebne smernice oziroma uzance, ki bi jih pri pripravi krovnega sporazuma upoštevali pogajalci in potem tudi upravitelj pri pripravi mnenja. Tako izdelan krovni sporazum in priloženo mnenje upravitelja bi morala zadoščati za učinkovito sodno odločanje o potrditvi krovnega sporazuma. Predpostavka za izdelavo smernic bi moral biti jasen odgovor na vprašanje podrobnosti glede izvajanja načela absolutne prioritete in načina posega v pravice zavarovanih upnikov. • Sodna potrditev Osnutek ZSR predvideva potrditev predhodno sklenjenega krovnega sporazuma s strani sodišča. Posto- L E GA L E N V I R O N M E N T A N D L E G I S L AT I V E F R A M E WO R K O F C O M PA N Y R E S T R U C T U R I N G pek sodne potrditve je smiselno podoben načinu odločanja sodišča v postopkih o predlogu za začasno odredbo. Navedeno pomeni, da sodišče vloženi predlog za potrditev javno objavi s pozivom upnikom, da v osemdnevnem roku vložijo odgovor na predlog. V okviru trditvenih podlag iz predloga za potrditev in morebitnega odgovora na predlog sodišče po načelu verjetnosti krovni sporazum potrdi in ta začne s pravnomočnostjo veljati glede izvedbe finančnega prestrukturiranja. Vsak upnik, ki je vložil odgovor, lahko naknadno vloži tožbo, s katero zahteva, da krovni sporazum nanj nima pravnega učinka. V pravdi, ki sledi vloženi tožbi, odloča sodišče o spornih vprašanjih po načelu gotovosti, kar lahko vključuje tudi izvajanje dokazov z izvedenci. • Razmerje do ZFPPIPP Osnutek ZSR uvaja hiter in enostaven postopek finančnega prestrukturiranja dolžnika ob bistvenem načelu, da večina lahko preglasuje manjšino in potem sprejeta odločitev velja tudi za tistega upnika, ki je glasoval proti. Pri tem je seveda treba upoštevati načelo poštenega in enakega obravnavanja upnikov in načelo, da vsi dobijo več, kot pa bi dobili v stečaju. Če takšnega dogovora ni mogoče doseči, lahko vsak upnik ali dolžnik zahteva uvedbo insolvenčnega postopka na podlagi določb ZFPPIPP. Zato osnutek ZSR ne nadomešča določb ZFPPIPP, ampak ponuja dodatno, bolj fleksibilno, hitrejšo pot do normalno delujočega podjetja. Glede na to hkrati s sprejemanjem osnutka ZSR ni nujno treba novelirati še ZFPPIPP. Če pa bi do novele ZFPPIPP v tej fazi kljub temu prišlo, potem bi bilo edino smiselno v ZFPPIPP vnesti naslednje bistvene spremembe: ◦◦ Razmisliti o uvedbi enotnega sistema. To pomeni, da se v primeru predloga za začetek prisilne poravnave ali v primeru predloga za stečaj začne isti insolvenčni postopek z vsemi pravnimi posledicami, z edino razliko, da v primeru predloga za prisilno poravnavo dolžnik nadaljuje poslovanje. ◦◦ Korporacijske pravice lastnikov se po reorganizaciji ohranijo v višini, ki predstavlja realni preostanek vrednosti podjetja pred reorganizacijo. Če se ugotovi, da ta obstaja, lahko nekdanji lastniki, kot podrejeni upniki, pridobijo/ohranijo proporcionalno ustrezen delež v osnovnem kapitalu dolžnika. ◦◦ Če je predlagana prisilna poravnava, upravitelj lahko pooblasti staro upravo za nadaljnje delo pod njegovim nadzorom. ◦◦ V postopku prisilne poravnave je treba uvesti načelo absolutne prioritete. ◦◦ Načrt finančnega prestrukturiranja pripravi upravitelj, pri tem mu stara uprava lahko pomaga. 7. Pričakovani rezultati sprejetja ZSR Osnutek ZSR ponuja orodje za razdolžitev gospodarstva, njegova uporaba pa je zlasti odvisna od načina izvedbe sanacije bank. Če bodo banke to orodje uporabljale, lahko pričakujemo hitro finančno prestrukturiranje slovenskega gospodarstva. Posledično bo sproščeni denarni tok pri dolžniku zmanjšal potrebe po bančnem financiranju obratnega kapitala. Šele tako bo postavljen temelj za kasnejšo poslovno sanacijo slovenskega gospodarstva, ki je prvi pogoj za nove investicije in rast ter na koncu za izstop bank iz lastništva podjetij, v katerega bodo vstopile, ne da bi si to zares želele. 60 8. Posledica ZSR za bančni sistem Predlagana razdolžitev gospodarstva je nujno povezana z vprašanjem sanacije bank. Zaenkrat je predvidena sanacija bank po načelu bail out. Zelo poenostavljeno to pomeni, da bodo banke v zameno za slabo aktivo prejele obveznice Republike Slovenije, ki jih bodo nato pri ECB zastavile za evre. Predvidevam, da bo ECB za likvidnostne potrebe bank odkupovala obveznice Republike Slovenije izdane zaradi sanacije bank le v primeru, če bo verjela v solventnost izdajatelja obveznic, v to pa bo verjela le, če proračun ne bo več v prevelikem primanjkljaju oziroma bo mogoče potreben celo presežek. Povsem možno je, da se poenostavljeno opisani model ne bo izšel. V nasprotnem primeru se lahko zgodi prestrukturiranje bank po načelu bail in, kar pa pomeni bolj ali manj kontroliran stečaj bank z obsežnim hair cut-om. Če se to zgodi, se bodo tudi na ravni bank odprla ključna vprašanja absolutne prioritete, ki zaenkrat niso ustrezno razrešena v sistemu bančništva. S tem v zvezi je že v pripravi novela zakona o bančništvu, ki ureja položaj podrejenih terjatev do bank za primer sanacije banke. Takšen razplet v bankah pa bi nedvomno povzročil nov val stečajev v realnem sektorju in pravočasna ter smiselna ureditev sistemske razdolžitve bi postala še bolj pomembna. LITERATURA IN VIRI/REFERENCES: Zakon o finančnem poslovanju podjetij in postopkih zaradi insolventnosti in prisilnem prenehanju, Uradni list RS, 31. 12. 2007. Osnutek Zakona o sistemski razdolžitvi, delovna gradiva. BV 11/2013 L E GA L E N V I R O N M E N T A N D L E G I S L AT I V E F R A M E WO R K O F C O M PA N Y R E S T R U C T U R I N G UDK 336.71:346.62(497.4) Bančna zakonodaja in ukrepi za prestrukturiranje bank Mojca Trstenjak* BANKING LEGISLATION AND BANK REHABILITATION MEASURES In the last year, the Banking act has been enhanced in order to introduce more efficient supervisory tools, tailored to meet the requirements for efficient restructuring of credit institutions as an alternative to regular winding down procedures, such as insolvency or administrative liquidation. The financial stability has been put forward as a prevailing principle of bank’s supervision and, if threatened, triggers the use of extraordinary supervisory tools (such as special administration, purchase and assumption transactions, selling bank’s shares, increase of bank’s capital, bail-in of equity and qualified liabilities), to implement bank restructuring measures and to achieve the long term viability of the bank or allow for orderly wind-down of nonviable institution. When designing the supervisory toolbox to comply with the restructuring purposes, the state aid rules have been taken into account in order to establish a framework that will allow a state participation in the restructuring process in compliance with state aid rules. JEL G18 G21 G28 BV 11/2013 D anes govorimo o prestrukturiranju bank oziroma bančnega sistema v kontekstu bančne in širše gospodarske krize, ki je sooblikovala vzroke za nastanek težav v bankah in je po drugi strani tudi pomemben dejavnik pri oblikovanju rešitev in ukrepov prestrukturiranja, ki bodo v danih razmerah zagotovili ponovno vzpostavitev uspešnega poslovanja bank in posredno tudi delovanje celotnega bančnega sistema v svoji osnovni funkciji – podpori gospodarstvu. 1. Pomen prestrukturiranja bank Poenostavljeno lahko povzamemo, da prestrukturiranje bank vključuje ukrepe (notranje) reorganizacije poslovanja in prilagoditve poslovnega modela glede na spremenjene razmere na trgu. Za učinkovito prestrukturiranje banke je vsekakor nujno pravočasno prepoznavanje težav in načrtovanje ustreznih ukrepov za njihovo odpravljanje, glede na pravne in dejanske možnosti, ki so na voljo. Uspešno reševanje nastalih težav v okviru prestrukturiranja banke nikakor ni odvisno od osamljenih dejavnikov, ampak od prepletenosti in součinkovanja različnih zunanjih in notranjih dejavnikov. Po eni strani gre za fleksibilnost in odzivnost notranje poslovne in upravljalske (vključno z lastniško) strukture, po drugi strani je reševanje teh težav odvisno tudi od splošnega gospodarskega položaja. * Mojca Trstenjak, univ. dipl. prav., zaposlena v Banki Slovenije kot specialist pravni svetovalec banke. Stališča, izražena v tem članku, ne predstavljajo stališč institucije, v kateri je avtorica zaposlena. 61 L E GA L E N V I R O N M E N T A N D L E G I S L AT I V E F R A M E WO R K O F C O M PA N Y R E S T R U C T U R I N G Uspešno reševanje težav je odvisno tudi od usklajenosti področnih predpisov s cilji prestrukturiranja (npr. splošna insolvenčna zakonodaja, prevzemna zakonodaja pa tudi uveljavljanje teh predpisov, zlasti glede finančne discipline in poslovne etike), pa tudi od učinkovitosti delovanja državnih institucij in nadzornih organov pri izvajanju teh predpisov, če navedemo le nekaj od pomembnejših dejavnikov. Ko zaradi težav v bankah nastajajo motnje v delovanju bančnega sistema kot celote, je usklajenost navedenih dejavnikov še toliko pomembnejša. Vzpostavitev učinkovitega okvira za prestrukturiranje bank je v tem primeru nujna za zagotavljanje pravilnega delovanja bančnega sistema kot celote in za zagotavljanje stabilnosti finančnega sistema. Zaradi učinkov finančne krize in pomanjkanja potrebnih finančnih sredstev splošni pravni okvir, ki določa okvire in pogoje (instrumentarij) za prestrukturiranje gospodarskih subjektov, ob predpostavkah delujočega trga (kot so bile podane pred nastankom krize), ne ustreza več potrebam in ciljem (učinkovitega) prestrukturiranja bank. Zaradi sistemskih razsežnosti prestrukturiranja bank se posamični (zasebni) interesi oziroma cilji umikajo javnemu interesu s ciljem zagotavljanja stabilnosti finančnega sistema. V zadnjih letih so številne države, ki so se soočale s podobnimi (sistemskimi) težavami v delovanju bančnega oziroma finančnega sistema, sprejele ukrepe, ki posredno ali neposredno usmerjajo oziroma vzpodbujajo procese prestrukturiranja bank ter sooblikujejo novo podobo bančnega sistema v državi. Ukrepi za doseganje tega cilja so bili različni, odvisni od konkretnih vzrokov za nastanek krize, od družbenopolitičnega in pravnega okvira, širšega gospodarskega okolja in nenazadnje tudi od uveljavljenih nadzorniških praks. Tudi v Sloveniji je prodrlo spoznanje, da je prestrukturiranje bank v okviru sanacije bančnega sistema proces, ki presega okvire neposrednega nadzora nad bankami in notranjega prestrukturiranja poslovnega modela. Spremembe prevzemne zakonodaje, spremembe postopkov unovčevanja zavarovanj na nepremičninah (notarska prodaja), napovedana reforma insolvenčne zakonodaje s poudarkom na prestrukturiranju dolžnikov, aktivne politike države na področju prestrukturiranja gospodarstva in državne pomoči gospodarstvu ter nenazadnje tudi uveljavitev okvira za sanacijo bank so dejavniki, ki bodo v prihodnjem obdobju odločilno Viri financiranja so v finančni krizi omejeni. vplivali na proces prestrukturiranja bank v Sloveniji. V tem prispevku se omejujemo na predstavitev ukrepov, ki jih v zvezi s prestrukturiranjem bank v okviru nadzora in sanacije bank na podlagi zakona o bančništvu izreka Banka Slovenije. Pri tem je že uvodoma nujno pojasnilo, da so ukrepi nadzora kot (prisilni) instrument za prestrukturiranje banke utemeljeni šele, ko ciljev prestrukturiranja ni mogoče zagotoviti z drugimi (zasebnimi, prostovoljnimi) rešitvami, hkrati pa je prestrukturiranje banke oziroma razrešitev njenih težav nujna za ohranjanje stabilnosti banke in zavarovanje deponentov oziroma v končni posledici za ohranitev stabilnosti bančnega oziroma (širšega) finančnega sistema. 62 2. Prestrukturiranje bank kot cilj nadzora Banka Slovenije je v zadnjem letu s spremembami zakonodaje na področju nadzora in sanacije bank pridobila pomembne nove pristojnosti, ki omogočajo oziroma zahtevajo njeno aktivno vlogo pri načrtovanju in izvajanju ukrepov prestrukturiranja v posameznih bankah. Z novelo zakona o bančništvu, ki je bila sprejeta decembra 2012 (ZBan-1J),1 je bil izveden prvi del reforme na področju nadzora nad bankami, s katero se zagotavljanje stabilnosti finančnega sistema jasno opredeli kot eden od najpomembnejših ciljev nadzora, pristojnosti Banke Slovenije pri izvajanju nadzora pa se razširijo z novimi ukrepi in pooblastili pri načrtovanju in izvajanju prestrukturiranja banke tako, da se ohranja stabilnosti finančnega sistema. Drugi del reforme na področju ukrepov nadzora bo novela ZBan-1L,2 ki bo z jasno opredelitvijo ciljev izrednih ukrepov še dodatno utrdila razumevanje izrednih ukrepov v vlogi prestrukturiranja banke zaradi ohranjanja stabilnosti finančnega sistema. V predlogu novele ZBan-1L se namreč kot cilj izrednih ukrepov izrecno opredeljuje reorganizacija banke, tako da se z ukrepi prestrukturiranja (reorganizacije) bodisi ponovno vzpostavijo pogoji za dolgoročno uspešno poslovanje banke bodisi da se izvedejo postopki za urejeno (postopno, nadzorovano) prenehanje banke, ki vključuje delno ali popolno prenehanje poslovanja.3 Izredni ukrepi se tako uveljavljajo 1 Uradni list RS, št. 105/2012. Predlog zakona o spremembah in dopolnitvah zakona o bančništvu je Vlada RS potrdila na seji dne 10. 10. 2013. 3 V zvezi s tem je pomembno sporočilo predloga novele, da je postopno prenehanje banke utemeljeno predvsem takrat, ko je zaradi nemotenega delovanja sistema nujno, da se ohranjajo določene dejavnosti banke v težavah in se v okviru prestrukturiranja prenesejo na druge izvajalce bodisi postopoma ukinjajo, brez pomembnejših učinkov na delovanje sistema kot celote. 2 BV 11/2013 L E GA L E N V I R O N M E N T A N D L E G I S L AT I V E F R A M E WO R K O F C O M PA N Y R E S T R U C T U R I N G kot alternativa oziroma dopolnitev rednih postopkov prenehanja banke (prisilna poravnava oziroma stečaj), ki se uporabijo z namenom, da se odvrnejo negativni učinki prenehanja banke. Pri tem pa je v vsakem posameznem primeru treba presoditi, ali je uporaba tega okvira upravičena glede na učinke, ki bi jih redno prenehanje banke oziroma stečaj banke lahko povzročila glede na vsakokratne zunanje ter notranje dejavnike stabilnosti finančnega sistema. Prestrukturiranje banke na način, da se ohrani ali ponovno vzpostavi dolgoročno uspešno poslovanje banke, je predvsem odgovornost banke, njenega menedžmenta in lastnikov. Če ukrepi za vzpostavitev uspešnega poslovanja banke zaradi notranjih ali zunanjih dejavnikov niso uspešni in banka posledično ne zagotavlja več pogojev za ohranitev dovoljenja za opravljanje bančnih storitev, bi bilo treba zoper banko uvesti ustrezne postopke za prenehanje banke – odvzem dovoljenja za opravljanje bančnih storitev ter prisilna likvidacija oziroma stečaj banke. Stečaj banke kot oblika prenehanja v finančni krizi zaradi učinkov na druge subjekte finančnega trga in na širše gospodarstvo nikakor ni ustrezna oblika prenehanja banke.4 Ukrepi nadzora za prestrukturiranje bank se tako uveljavljajo z namenom, da se odvrnejo morebitni negativni učinki uvedbe stečaja banke tako, da se zagotovi ohranitev ključnih funkcij in dejavnosti banke, ohranja zaupanje uporabnikov in posledično ohranja stabilnost finančnega sistema.5 Stabilnost finančnega sistema in merila, po katerih se ocenjuje njegova ogroženost, so opredeljena v zakonu o bančništvu,6 s tem pa je zakon zagotavljanje stabilnosti finančnega sistema z ukrepi nadzora jasno opredelil kot osrednje načelo izvajanja nadzora nad bankami. BV 11/2013 Kot je poudarjeno že uvodoma, je vloga Banke Slovenije v procesu prestrukturiranja oziroma stopnja omejevanja upravičenj obstoječih lastnikov pri upravljanju in prestrukturiranju banke s prisilnimi ukrepi nadzora odvisna tako od stopnje tveganj v banki7 kot tudi od sposobnosti in pripravljenosti lastnikov, da zagotovijo pogoje za učinkovito prestrukturiranje banke.8 Praviloma je slednje vedno povezano z vprašanjem finančnih zmožnosti lastnikov, da banki zagotovijo potrebna sredstva za povečanje osnovnega kapitala, saj so viri financiranja v finančni krizi omejeni, naraščajoče težave pa zahtevajo takojšnje ukrepanje z vplačilom dodatnega kapitala, da se zagotovi zahtevana kapitalska ustreznost in prepreči propad banke. Z novelo ZBan-1J so se določile konkretne pristojnosti Banke Sloveni- je pri izvajanju ukrepov za prestrukturiranje banke, vključno z izrecno določenimi pristojnostmi, da upravi banki izda konkretna navodila glede oblikovanja predloga skupščinskih sklepov v zvezi s povečanjem osnovnega kapitala banke. Zakon zaradi lažjega sprejemanja odločitev, ki so potrebne za povečanje osnovnega kapitala, določa veljavnost odločitev, ki so sicer sprejete na nižjo večino, kot bi bila zahtevana po splošnih prepisih, odpravljena pa so tudi nekatera druga varovala, ki so sicer uveljavljena zaradi varovanja manjšinskih delničarjev (glede sklica skupščine od izpodbijanja skupščinskih sklepov). S tem zakon v primeru prestrukturiranja banke omejuje pravice delničarjev, ki niso sposobni ali pripravljeni podpreti procesov prestrukturiranja banke pri odločanju o ukrepih prestrukturiranja (povečanje osnovnega kapitala), pri čemer so te omejitve utemeljene z dejstvom, da z dosedanjimi ukrepi delničarji oziroma banka ni uspela odpraviti nastalih težav in izvesti ukrepov za prestrukturiranje banke. Kot pomembna vzpodbuda procesom prestrukturiranja s povečanjem osnovnega kapitala banke so v zakonu določene tudi oprostitve glede obvezne prevzemne ponudbe, če bi posamezni investitor zaradi sodelovanja pri povečanju osnovnega kapitala, kadar je povečanje posledica zahtev Banke Slovenije, pridobil delež nad prevzemnim pragom, kot ga določa 4 Odvzem dovoljenja banki bi namreč pomenil takojšnjo izključitev banke iz vseh pomembnih finančnih infrastruktur (kreditne linije, plačilni in poravnalni sistemi, ...), zaradi česar banka dejansko ne bi bila več sposobna servisirati uporabnikov, posledično pa bi se njeno premoženje znatno razvrednotilo ter pripeljalo do insolventnosti banke. Učinki insolventnosti banke na druge finančne subjekte (zaradi prepletenosti poslovanja, obveznosti izplačila zajamčenih vlog) oziroma na širše gospodarstvo (zaradi ustavitve poslovanja, zamrznitve nezajamčenih vlog) bi torej v vseh negativnih razsežnostih nastopili takoj. O tem vidiku tudi Mathias Dewatripont and Xavier Freixas v »The Crisis Aftermath: New Regulatory Paradigms«. 5 Temeljna načela učinkovitega mehanizma reševanja podrobneje obravnava Financial Stability Board v dokumentu »Key Attributes of Effective Resolution Regimes for Financial Institutions«. 6 Glej 254. člen zakona. Določba je bila uveljavljena z novelo ZBan-1J. 7 V prvem odstavku 253.a člena ZBan-1 je kot eden od razlogov, ki mora biti izpolnjen za izdajo izrednega ukrepa, ugotovljeno povečano tveganje v banki. Takšno tveganje je glede na drugi odstavek istega člena podano zlasti v primeru, če banka ne izpolnjuje ali v naslednji šestih mesecih verjetno ne bo zagotavljala minimalnega kapitala ali ustreznega likvidnostnega položaja in so ali verjetno bodo s tem podani pogoji za odvzem dovoljenja za opravljanje bančnih storitev. 8 Kot drugi razlog za izdajo izrednega ukrepa, ki mora biti izpolnjen hkrati s pogojem povečanega tveganja, je tudi dejstvo, da banka z drugimi ukrepi ni uspela odpraviti tveganj in torej ni izvedla potrebnih ukrepov za prestrukturiranje banke. Stabilnost finančnega sistema je dobrina v javnem interesu, ki se varuje (tudi) z ukrepi nadzora, ki jih s ciljem prestrukturiranja banke lahko izreče Banka Slovenije in tako prevzame upravljanje banke. Ogrožanje stabilnosti finančnega sistema se za namene izrednih ukrepov torej presoja za katero koli banko, glede na konkretne okoliščine povezane z banko ter okoljem, v katerem deluje. 3. Ukrepi nadzora za prestrukturiranje bank 63 L E GA L E N V I R O N M E N T A N D L E G I S L AT I V E F R A M E WO R K O F C O M PA N Y R E S T R U C T U R I N G zakon o prevzemih. Navedeni ukrepi so v zakonu urejeni kot dodatni ukrepi nadzora, ki jih Banka Slovenije izreče banki zaradi ugotovljenih kršitev glede obvladovanja tveganj. Ob upoštevanju načela sorazmernosti ukrepov nadzora, ki s svojimi učinki posegajo v položaj delničarjev, je poseg upravičen zlasti, če stopnja tveganja v banki ogroža stabilno poslovanje banke. Z dodatnimi ukrepi nadzora lahko Banka Slovenije daje nadaljnja navodila upravi banke glede načrtovanja ukrepov prestrukturiranja, pri čemer je poglavitni cilj takšnega usmerjanja, da banka čim bolj učinkovito zmanjša tveganja in zagotovi pogoje za varno in zanesljivo poslovanje (za zavarovanje vlagateljev). V primeru, ko niti z dodatnimi ukrepi ni mogoče odpraviti tveganja in izpeljati ukrepov za prestrukturiranje banke, se v primeru povečanega tveganja, ko banka ne izpolnjuje več minimalnih pogojev za ohranitev dovoljenja za opravljanje bančnih storitev, banki lahko izrečejo izredni ukrepi, kjer upravljanje banke prevzame Banka Slovenije.9 Z novelo ZBan-1J je reforma ukrepov nadzora v pomembnem delu temeljila prav na preoblikovanju in dopolnitvi izrednih ukrepov, tako da ti ukrepi Banki Slovenije omogočajo, da odvrne negativne učinke propada (stečaja) banke in kot skrajni ukrep prevzame upravljanje banke z namenom, da izvede potrebne ukrepe za ohranitev stabilnosti finančnega sistema. ZBan-1J je tako uredil štiri izredne ukrepe: (1) imenovanje izredne uprave, (2) prodajo delnic banke obstoječih delničarjev novemu investitorju, (3) povečanje osnovnega kapitala banke z vložkom novega investitorja in (4) prenos premoženja banke na prevzemno družbo. Z novelo ZBan-1L pa bo uveljavljen še dodaten izredni ukrep, in sicer (5) ukrep prenehanja in konverzije kvalificiranih obveznosti. Ko so izpolnjeni pogoji za uporabo izrednih ukrepov, je odločitev o izdaji posameznega ukrepa oziroma o kombinaciji različnih ukrepov predmet presoje Banke Slovenije, ki bo morala za dosego ciljev prestrukturiranja upoštevati tako notranje dejavnike (vzroke za nastanek povečanega tveganja v banki) kot tudi zunanje dejavnike, ki vplivajo na uspešno izvedbo prestrukturiranja (ponovno vzpostavitev poslovanja banke oziroma postopno prenehanje banke). Že pri opredelitvi ciljev prestrukturiranja kot tudi pri izbiri določenih Izredna uprava lahko predlaga ukrepe za postopno prenehanje banke. ukrepov mora biti odločitev utemeljena z analizo ekonomske upravičenosti, ki potrjuje bodisi ugotovitev, da bo banka z določenimi ukrepi prestrukturiranja sposobna zagotoviti dolgoročno uspešno (dobičkonosno) poslovanje, bodisi ugotovitev, da tega cilja v razumnem času ni mogoče doseči. Ob tem je za odločitev pomembna tudi pripravljenost morebitnih investitorjev oziroma prevzemnikov, da se pod določenimi pogoji vključijo v proces prestrukturiranja – bodisi država prek mehanizmov državnih pomoči bodisi zasebni investitorji, ki vstopijo v banko s svežim kapitalom oziroma prevzamejo del poslovanja banke. Zakon sicer določa okvire za uporabo posameznih izrednih ukrepov, 64 vendar pa hkrati določa široko diskrecijo Banke Slovenije, da izdela načrt prestrukturiranja z izrednimi ukrepi tako, da bodo ukrepi kar najbolj zagotavljali uresničitev ciljev prestrukturiranja in bodo prilagojeni konkretnim okoliščinam, ki bodo vplivale na uspešnost celotnega procesa. V zvezi z ukrepom imenovanja izredne uprave v banki bo novela ZBan-1L predvsem jasneje opredelila vlogo izredne uprave pri načrtovanju in pri izvajanju prestrukturiranja banke. Predlog novele tako izrecno določa, da izredna uprava pripravi oceno glede možnosti, da se v banki v razumnem roku vzpostavijo razmere za uspešno poslovanje in predlaga ustrezne ukrepe prestrukturiranja, vključno s predlogom in oceno učinkov drugih izrednih ukrepov, npr. prenehanja in konverzije kvalificiranih obveznosti, prenosa premoženja in obveznosti banke, povečanja osnovnega kapitala banke in prodaje delnic banke. Če izredna uprava oceni, da ukrepi za vzpostavitev dolgoročno uspešnega poslovanja v banki ne bodo uspešni ali jih ne bo mogoče izvesti v razumnem roku, predlaga ukrepe za postopno prenehanje banke, vključno z ukrepi za postopno unovčitev premoženja banke in poplačilo upnikov banke. Podlaga za delo izredne uprave je torej načrt reorganizacije, ki ga potrdi Banka Slovenije glede na cilje prestrukturiranja v konkretnem primeru. Pomembna novost v zakonu je vsekakor ukrep prenosa premoženja in obveznosti banke na prevzemnika. Predmet prenosa je lahko katero koli premoženje oziroma obveznosti banke, razen kvalificiranih obveznosti, ki predstavljajo osnovni 9 Na podlagi 255.a člena ZBan-1 z vročitvijo odločbe o izrednih ukrepih prenehajo pooblastila in pristojnosti skupščini in nadzornemu svetu banke, pristojnosti skupščine in nadzornega sveta banke izvaja Banka Slovenije. BV 11/2013 L E GA L E N V I R O N M E N T A N D L E G I S L AT I V E F R A M E WO R K O F C O M PA N Y R E S T R U C T U R I N G kapital banke, in obveznosti banke do upnikov iz naslova kapitalskih instrumentov in drugih podrejenih obveznosti banke. S tem ukrepom se lahko na prevzemnika prenesejo bodisi določene perspektivne skupine premoženja in obveznosti, ki so vezane na opravljanje določene dejavnosti banke, bodisi se iz banke izloči problematično premoženje oziroma obveznosti tako, da se banka razbremeni tveganj in se (ob drugih dejavnikih) zagotovijo razmere za ponovno uspešno poslovanje. Prenos premoženja banke v okviru izrednega ukrepa se opravi odplačno tako, da prevzemnik zagotovi ustrezno nadomestilo bodisi v denarju, z vrednostnimi papirji prevzemnika ali s prevzemom obveznosti banke v sorazmerni višini glede na prevzeto premoženje. Ker se z ukrepom prenosa premoženja in obveznosti (avtoritativno) neizogibno posega tudi v pogodbena razmerja banke s tretjimi osebami (tako upniki kot dolžniki), določa zakon tudi učinke takšnega prenosa za tretje osebe. Ker je namen ukrepa, da premoženje, ki se prenaša, tudi po prenosu opravlja svojo funkcijo in tako ohranja vrednost za prevzemnika, zakon za namene takšnega prenosa poenostavlja nekatera (splošna) pravila pogodbenega prava v zvezi s prenosom premoženja oziroma obveznosti in hkrati omejuje pravice tretjih oseb, da bi zaradi prenosa premoženja na prevzemnika lahko odpovedale že sklenjene pogodbe oziroma uveljavljale morebitne kršitve pogodbe v razmerju do banke. Prevzemnik premoženja na podlagi izrednega ukrepa je lahko kateri koli subjekt, ki nastopa na trgu in lahko v skladu s predpisi opravlja dejavnost, s katero je povezano premoženje. Premoženje oziroma obveznosti so glede na ureditev v ZBan-1 lahko z izrednim ukrepom prenesene tudi na (državno) slabo BV 11/2013 banko oziroma posebno namensko družbo, ki jo ustanovi banka z izločitvijo neperspektivnega ali problematičnega premoženja banke. Pri tem zakon ne ureja izrecno niti prenosa na slabo banko niti na posebno namensko družbo, ampak se ta vprašanja z vidika možnih učinkov na javne finance rešujejo v okviru zakona o ukrepih za zagotavljanje stabilnosti bank. Kot pomembno novost med izrednimi ukrepi je v zvezi s prestrukturiranjem banke vsekakor treba omeniti tudi ukrep prenehanja in konverzije kvalificiranih obveznosti (bail-in), ki se bo uveljavil z novelo ZBan-1L. Bail-in je kot instrument za uporabo zasebnih sredstev pri prestrukturiranju in sanaciji bank že uveljavljen v nekaterih državah EU – države so za uveljavitev teh mehanizmov že spremenile svojo nacionalno zakonodajo, predvsem zaradi potrebe, da se v okviru ukrepov sanacije bank z državno pomočjo zmanjšajo zahteve po dodatnem kapitalu za potrebe pokrivanja izgub z dokapitalizacijo bank in tako razbremenijo javne finance. Pomen ukrepa prenehanja in konverzije kvalificiranih obveznosti v zvezi z reševanjem bank je v zadnjih letih sprožil številne razprave v EU, v katerih so bile poudarjene tako prednosti kot slabosti ukrepa z vidika učinkov na položaj upnikov kot tudi na delovanje finančnih trgov (zaradi zmanjšanega zanimanja investitorjev, da bi sredstva nalagali v instrumente, ki bi lahko bili v procesu reševanja banke predmet prenehanja oziroma konverzije). Ugotovimo lahko, da so bili v ome- njenih razpravah očitno uspešnejši zagovorniki uporabe tega ukrepa, saj je prenehanje oziroma konverzija predvidena kot eden od ukrepov za reševanje bank tudi v predlogu direktive,10 ki naj bi bila sprejeta konec tega leta. Podpora uporabi ukrepa prenehanja in konverzije se je uveljavljala tudi v praksi nekaterih držav članic, ki so torej že pred sprejetjem direktive v svojih nacionalnih zakonodajah uredile tudi ukrepe prisilnega prenehanja oziroma konverzije določenih obveznosti banke do upnikov z namenom, da se stroški reševanja banke vsaj delno razporedijo na zasebne investitorje in se tako razbremeni proračun. V zadnjem obdobju se je v okviru reševanja bank ukrep prenehanja in konverzije že uveljavil kot učinkovit ukrep, ki nadomešča oziroma dopolnjuje druge (javne) vire financiranja reševanja bank. Kot posledico tega dejstva je evropska komisija temu novemu trendu prilagodila tudi pravila, po katerih se presoja dopustnost državnih pomoči za sanacijo bank.11 Tako je evropska komisija kot obvezen element državne pomoči določila, da morajo delničarji banke in investitorji, ki so vlagali sredstva v tvegane instrumente banke, maksimalno prispevati k pokrivanju izgub banke in k pokrivanju stroškov za ponovno vzpostavitev kapitalske ustreznosti banke. Prenehanje oziroma konverzija kvalificiranih obveznosti v delnice banke je torej nujna, preden se uporabijo javna sredstva za sanacijo bank, da bi se državna pomoč za sanacijo posamezne 10 Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing a framework for the recovery and resolution of credit institutions and investment firms and amending Council Directives 77/91/EEC and 82/891/EC, Directives 2001/24/EC, 2002/47/EC, 2004/25/ EC, 2005/56/EC, 2007/36/EC and 2011/35/ EC and Regulation (EU) No 1093/2010 - General approach (Brussels, 15 July 2013, 2012/0150 (COD)) (http://register.consilium.europa.eu) 11 Sporočilo Komisije o uporabi pravil o državni pomoči za podporne ukrepe v korist bank v okviru finančne krize od 1. avgusta 2013 dalje (Uradni list EU C 216, 30. 7. 2013, str. 0001–0015). Sporočilo glede presoje državnih pomoči za sanacijo bank, ki je veljalo pred 31. 7. 2013, ni eksplicitno določalo zahteve glede uporabe bail-in v zvezi z državno pomočjo bankam, ampak le splošno zahtevo, da se »bremena reševanja ustrezno porazdelijo tudi na lastnike in upnike«. 65 L E GA L E N V I R O N M E N T A N D L E G I S L AT I V E F R A M E WO R K O F C O M PA N Y R E S T R U C T U R I N G banke lahko štela kot dopustna. Pri tem je komisija določila, da mora prenehanje oziroma konverzija vključevati najmanj osnovni kapital banke ter tiste obveznosti banke do upnikov, ki bi jih v primeru prenehanja (z upoštevanjem prednostnega vrstnega reda poplačila, kot ga določa insolvenčna zakonodaja) banka poplačala šele po popolnem poplačilu navadnih terjatev upnikov. Breme reševanja banke torej najprej trpijo delničarji banke, nato pa po vrstnem redu tisti upniki banke, ki bi v primeru prenehanja banke lahko uveljavljali poplačilo svojih podrejenih terjatev do banke. Obseg prenehanja oziroma konverzije je v vsakem posameznem primeru odvisen od obsega izgub v banki in od višine dodatnega kapitala, ki ga potrebuje banka za zagotavljanje kapitalske ustreznosti. Pristojnost evropske komisije, da določa zahteve glede državne pomoči, je utemeljena neposredno na pogodbi o delovanju EU, saj presoja državnih pomoči sodi v okvir ukrepov na področju varstva konkurence.12 Ukrepi in pristojnosti komisije v zvezi s tem so opredeljeni neposredno v pogodbi o EU, zato tudi določanje smernic in zahtev glede pogojev za državne pomoči sodi v okvir avtonomnih pristojnosti komisije, upravičenost njenih zahtev pa se lahko izpodbija pred Sodiščem EU v okviru posameznih postopkov v zvezi z dodelitvijo državne pomoči. Z uveljavitvijo novele ZBan-1L bo Banka Slovenije v okviru načrtovanja prestrukturiranja banke lahko uporabila tudi ukrep prenehanja in konverzije kvalificiranih obveznosti. Kot kvalificirane obveznosti se v predlogu novele določajo poleg osnovnega kapitala tudi tiste obveznosti banke, ki bi se v primeru stečaja banke poplačale z vrstnim redom podrejenih terjatev, torej šele po poplačilu vseh navadnih terjatev upnikov.13 Ukrep prenehanja in konverzije je tako v predlogu novele omejen le na točno določene kategorije obveznosti, zato tega ukrepa ni mogoče uporabiti za prenehanje ali konverzijo drugih (navadnih) obveznosti banke – depozitov in obveznosti banke iz naslova izdanih (navadnih) obveznic ali drugih finančnih instrumentov banke, ki nimajo lastnosti podrejenih instrumentov (v primeru stečaja banke), tako ni mogoče odpisati ali konvertirati v okviru izrednega ukrepa. Predlog novele določa, da učinki prenehanja oziroma konverzije za banko in za upnike kvalificiranih Breme reševanja banke bodo odslej najprej prevzeli delničarji banke. obveznosti banke nastopijo z izdajo odločbe o izrednem ukrepu. Izredni ukrep je glede učinkov, ki jih ustvarja za položaj upnikov kvalificiranih obveznosti banke, primerljiv z učinki prisilne poravnave, kot jo sicer določa splošna insolvenčna zakonodaja in ki je bila pred novelo ZBan-1L v primeru bank izrecno izključena. Tudi sicer se ukrep prenehanja oziroma konverzije izreče z upoštevanje osnovnih načel insolvenčnih 12 Poročilo komisije je izdano na podlagi 107. člena Pogodbe o delovanju Evropske unije. 13 V novem tretjem odstavku 253.člena zakona predlog novele ZBan-1L določa kvalificirane obveznosti banke, ki so: 1. osnovni kapital banke (obveznosti prvega reda), 2. obveznosti do imetnikov hibridnih finančnih instrumentov iz 4. točke prvega odstavka 133. člena tega zakona (obveznosti drugega reda), 3. obveznosti do imetnikov finančnih instrumentov, ki se po 134. členu tega zakona upoštevajo pri 66 postopkov, zlasti načelo, da noben upnik kvalificirane obveznosti zaradi prenehanja ali konverzije ne sme utrpeti večjih izgub, kot bi jih utrpel v primeru prenehanja banke.14 Ob tem je ponovno treba izpostaviti dejstvo, da so izredni ukrepi in s tem povezano prestrukturiranje dopustni le, če se z njimi prepreči propad banke (tj. odvrnejo razlogi za odvzem dovoljenja banki in s tem prepreči stečaj banke, ki bi sicer sledil kot edina realna posledica odvzema). V zvezi z ukrepom prenehanja in konverzije bo tako ključna predvsem ocena pričakovanih učinkov stečaja banke na položaj upnikov kvalificiranih obveznosti – torej ocena višine poplačila teh obveznosti v primeru stečaja banke, ki bo hkrati tudi podlaga za prenehanje teh obveznosti in podlaga za določanje vrednosti pri konverziji teh obveznosti v delnice banke (tj. vrednost stvarnih vložkov pri povečanju osnovnega kapitala banke)15. Ukrep prenehanja in konverzije se bo glede na nova pravila evropske komisije o državnih pomočeh v primeru sanacije bank predvidoma vedno uporabil v primerih, ko bo za prestrukturiranje banke potrebna državna pomoč. Vendar novela ZBan-1L uporabe tega ukrepa ne omejuje le na primere državnih pomoči, ampak omogoča uporabo tudi v drugih primerih, kjer ni predvidena uporaba javnih sredstev (tj. za namene urejenega prenehanja brez sredstev državne pomoči). izračunu dodatnega kapitala banke, razen če so te obveznosti že zajete v 1. ali 2. točki (obveznosti tretjega reda), 4. obveznosti, ki niso zajete v 1., 2. ali 3. točki, in bi se v primeru stečajnega postopka nad banko poplačale po poplačilu navadnih terjatev do banke (obveznosti četrtega reda). 14 Glej peti odstavek 261.a člena predloga novele ZBan-1L. 15 V zvezi s tem glej 261.b in 261.d člena predloga novele ZBan-1L. BV 11/2013 L E GA L E N V I R O N M E N T A N D L E G I S L AT I V E F R A M E WO R K O F C O M PA N Y R E S T R U C T U R I N G 4. Sklep Izredni ukrepi, kot jih ureja zakon o bančništvu, so sicer oblikovani z namenom, da bi omogočili hitro in učinkovito prestrukturiranje bank, ki je potrebno za pravilno delovanje bančnega sistem kot celote. Vendar pa izredni ukrepi po drugi strani pomenijo skrajni poseg oziroma ukinitev pravic lastnikov in upnikov, ki so v primeru izrednih ukrepov izključeni iz procesa odločanja in načrtovanja ukrepov prestrukturiranja. Ob tem se je treba zavedati tudi dejstva, da bo okvir reševanja, kot ga določa zakon o bančništvu z dodatnimi in izrednimi ukrepi nadzora za prestrukturiranje banke, glede osnovnih rešitev glede prestrukturiranja in sanacije bank v relativno kratkem času s sprejetjem in implementacijo direktive o vzpostavitvi skupnega okvir za prestrukturiranje in sanacijo bank uveljavljen v vseh državah članicah EU. Danes torej ni več vprašanje, ali bo tak okvir, BV 11/2013 vključno s prenehanjem (write down) in konverzijo obveznosti banke kot ukrepom prestrukturiranja bank, na ravni EU uveljavljen ali ne, ampak se postavlja predvsem vprašanje, kako v okviru posamezne nacionalne zakonodaje opredeliti pogoje za uporabo teh ukrepov, da bo poseg v pravice delničarjev in upnikov sorazmeren. Zakon o bančništvu in zlasti izredni ukrepi, kot so zasnovani v zakonu, vključno s predlogom novele ZBan-1L, bodo morali ta preizkus sorazmernosti prestati prej, kot bo to primer v drugih državah ob sprejemanju omenjene direktive. S sprejetjem omenjene direktive pa čaka slovenskega zakonodajalca še tretji del reforme ukrepov nadzora, ko bo ukrepe prestrukturiranja in sanacije moral v celoti prilagoditi zahtevam iz direktive. Predlog zakona o spremembah in dopolnitvah Zakona o bančništvu (ZBan1J), Poročevalec DZ z dne 30.11.2013. LITERATURA IN VIRI/REFERENCES: Mathias Dewatripont and Xavier Freixas: The Crisis Aftermath: New Regulatory Paradigms, Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) 2012, London (www. voxeu.org) Zakon o bančništvu, Uradni list RS, št. 99/10 - uradno prečiščeno besedilo, 9/11 - ZPlaSS-B, 35/11, 59/11, 85/11, 48/12, 105/12, 56/13 in 63/13 - ZS-K (ZBan-1) 67 Predlog zakona o spremembah in dopolnitvah Zakona o bančništvu (ZBan1L), Vlada RS, (EVA 3013-1611-0146) (www. http://www.dz-rs.si/). Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing a framework for the recovery and resolution of credit institutions and investment firms and amending Council Directives 77/91/EEC and 82/891/EC, Directives 2001/24/EC, 2002/47/EC, 2004/25/ EC, 2005/56/EC, 2007/36/EC and 2011/35/EC and Regulation (EU) No 1093/2010 - General approach (Brussels, 15 July 2013, 2012/0150 (COD)) (http:// register.consilium.europa.eu). Sporočilo Komisije o uporabi pravil o državni pomoči za podporne ukrepe v korist bank v okviru finančne krize od 1. avgusta 2013 dalje (Uradni list EU C 216, 30. 7. 2013, str. 0001–0015) Key Attributes of Effective Resolution Regimes for Financial Institutions”, oktober 2011, Financial Stability Board (www. financialstabilityboard.org) Dirk Schoenmaker, Banking Supervision and Resolution: The European Dimension, January 2012, DSF Policy Paper, No. 19 (www.dsf.nl) MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING UDK 336.71:061.1EU Macroeconomic trends and EU banking crisis Holger Schmieding* MACROECONOMIC TRENDS AND EU BANKING CRISIS The eurozone crisis has exposed serious banking problems in some eurozone member countries. After a long period of trial and error, the eurozone has managed to contain the systemic risks which these national problems pose to the eurozone as a whole. Since the ECB stepped forward as the de facto lender of last resort for reform-oriented governments in July 2012, tensions have receded. The toxic link between banks and sovereigns has been weakened. As a result, sorting out banking problems is largely a task for the national sovereigns. The faster and the more decisively they do so, the better for these countries. Rapid progress towards a full banking union would be helpful for the euro countries hit by the crisis. But the available evidence shows that a full banking union is not essential for the crisis to go away. JEL G01 G21 G28 T he eurozone crisis has exposed serious banking problems in some eurozone member countries including Ireland, Spain, Italy and Slovenia. For a while, some countries even fell victim to a vicious circle. Doubts about the ability of the national sovereign to backstop its major banks raised the funding costs for banks to such an extent that the resulting credit crunch exacerbated the recession and the fiscal problems of the sovereign. KEY CONCLUSIONS In this paper, we take a fundamental look at the euro crisis and the toxic link between sovereigns and banks. Our major conclusion is that, after a long period of trial and error, the eurozone has managed to contain the systemic risks to the eurozone as a whole. Between them, the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) and the European Central Bank (ECB) now have the means and the instruments for two key tasks: (1) they can back up the national sovereigns to such an extent that these sovereigns can deal with their banking problems if they choose to do so. (2) The ESM and ECB can contain the risk of contagion from small crisis countries to bigger less problematic members and to the eurozone as a whole. As a result, sorting out banking problems fast and decisively is largely a task for the national sovereign. * Holger Schmieding, Chief Economist, Berenberg. 68 BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING A lack of courage to deal with national banking problems poses a serious risk to the respective country but less so to the eurozone as a whole. An immediate and full banking union with common rules, a common supervisor, a joint resolution regime and common deposit insurance would be useful. But it is not essential. National sovereigns themselves can take all the decisive steps to defuse their national banking problems, even if some of them may request European support to speed up the process. I. TOUGH LOVE: THE NATURE OF THE EURO CRISIS Crises are handmaidens of change. Some 30 years ago, Margaret Thatcher slayed an inflation dragon and crushed the power of irresponsible trade unions in Britain, turning the then “sick man of Europe” into a modern service economy. Twenty years ago, Sweden and Denmark transformed soft socialism into a welfare system that works. Ten years ago, Germany cut social benefits and loosened labour market rules by enough to turn Europe’s worst-performing economy into the continent’s new growth engine. Two years ago, the three small Baltic countries emerged from a dramatic post-bubble crisis in better shape than they had been before. In all these cases, the initial results of tough reforms were record unemployment, social unrest and howls of protests from many economists. In all cases, history proved the hard-nosed reformers right, as it did in the even more traumatic transformation of post-communist Europe in the 1990s. Over the last three years, the countries of the eurozone have struck a grand bargain. The strong support the weak and the weak accept the tough conditions attached to such BV 11/2013 help. They need to make their fiscal positions sustainable by reining in their current budget deficits and by raising their long-term growth potential through structural reforms. In the eurozone, support from the strong to the weak takes the form of highly conditional credits. “Tough love” is the rule of the game.1 As a result, there is much less risk of moral hazard in the mutual support systems between eurozone countries than the usual transfer systems within nation states. In the eurozone, the donors can and do set the terms at which they grant support to the recipients. Put simply: Germany (as a donor) Eurozone has managed to contain the systemic risks to the eurozone as a whole. can be much tougher on Spain (as a recipient) than it ever could be on its own destitute regions such as Bremen and the Saar. Whereas Spaniards do not vote in the national election of the donor country (Germany), the citizens of Germany’s problem regions vote in the elections to the German parliament. On static criteria of an optimum currency area, the lack of major automatic and unconditional transfers between member countries counts against the eurozone. But on the more important dynamic criterion as to whether the institutional setting provides the right incentives, this counts as an advantage: those who need to be protected against market turmoil have to make their economies 69 more dynamic and hence less likely to require aid in the future. No easy escape routes The euro denies its members the easy escape routes: they can no longer devalue or inflate their way out of trouble. Instead, they have to take the hard route of fundamental reforms. Inflation or devaluation does not solve any structural problems. These macroeconomic gimmicks merely postpone the day of reckoning. The common currency forces its weaker members to choose between the chaos that would ensue from a euro exit and the painful reforms needed to improve their lot for good. The big call for the economic future in Europe is whether this tough love approach will work. In our view, it probably will. In the OECD’s league table for actual structural economic reforms2, Greece takes the top spot of all OECD members for 2011 and 2012, followed by Ireland, Estonia, Portugal and Spain. All four countries that had received external assistance by the end-2012 cut-off date for the analysis are among the five top reformers. Confusing dreams with reality In analysing the euro crisis, many observers make a simple mistake: they confuse their dreams of what would be a perfect world with reality. The world does not have to be perfect in order to work. For example, Germany would be much better off if it had a simple flat tax and a deregulated labour market. But in real life, a complex tax system and an overregulated labour market have 1 See Holger Schmieding, Tough Love: the true nature of the euro crisis, Berenberg, 20 August 2012. 2 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Economic Policy Reforms 2013: Going for Growth, Paris 2013, MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING not prevented Germany from turning itself into the economic powerhouse of Europe. The same holds for the eurozone crisis. Many observers believe that the region needs a full political union, a full fiscal union, an immediate banking union, a full German/ ECB guarantee for sovereign debt or the realisation of some other pipedream to get out of its crisis. Some of the arguments such observers make are not wrong. Yes, some kinds of financial tensions could be contained by a full-scale mutualisation of public debt or other variants of fiscal or even political union. And yes, an immediate banking union or any other way to end the credit crunch for small and medium-sized enterprises in parts of the euro periphery in one fell swoop could be quite helpful. But discussing what may or may not be desirable is very different from analysing what is strictly necessary for the euro crisis to fade. The bare essentials Stripping it to the bare essentials, the eurozone needs four ingredients for its crisis to fade. All four are in place. 1. A reliable mechanism to contain contagion. The problems of small countries must not endanger the region as a whole. Since the ECB president Mario Draghi’s announcement of 26 July 2012 that the second most powerful economic institution in the world, the ECB, would not commit suicide but would instead do all it takes to preserve the euro and its own existence, this ingredient is in place. The eurozone now has a lender of last resort. 2. The right incentives so that places like Greece fix their underlying problems. With the tough love approach pursued by Germany and the ECB, this ingredient is there as well: Europe helps places like Greece or Ireland with serious amounts of money if the recipients meet harsh reform conditions.3 Despite occasional hiccups, the reform process is well entrenched and well advanced.4 3. The political will to stick to the grand bargain: the strong help the weak while the weak accept the strings attached. All German mainstream political parties back chancellor Merkel’s euro policies. At the periphery, the will to do what it takes to stay part of the euro family has survived numerous challenges including elections and changes in government in Greece, Ireland, Portugal, Italy and Spain. 4. Some growth in key export markets. To export their way out of their domestic adjustment recession, the euro periphery needs some increase in global demand and in core European domestic demand. So far, external demand remains suitably resilient. For the euro periphery, good news from Germany, the US, the UK, China and Switzerland more than offsets the wobbles in a number of emerging markets. Of course, past performance is no guarantee for the future. But it does hold lessons. Euro-sceptics underestimate the capacity of the eurozone to contain and overcome its crisis at their own peril. II. BANKING CRISIS – THE FUNDAMENTAL VIEW Banks are a vital part of any modern economy. They intermediate between savers and investors and transmit the monetary policy of the central bank to the real economy, that is, to households and companies. Banks and capital markets pool resources and risks. They thus help to change the risk profile of 70 an economy: funds deposited by risk-averse savers can finance the promising projects of risk-taking entrepreneurs. Banks and financial markets have a network function like no other sector of the economy. No sector of an advanced economy can function without financial services. A serious problem in the car industry is bad news for the car industry and all its stakeholders. A serious banking problem can paralyse an entire economy. One of the most robust lessons of financial history is that serious banking problems need to be tackled fast and decisively to limit the damage. Among the many examples from which that lesson can be drawn are those of Sweden (1992-1993),5 the post-Lehman US (2009-2010) and, as part of the euro crisis, even Ireland (2010-2012). One of the reasons why the US is now rebounding faster from the Great Financial Crisis of the last five years and why Ireland enjoys a more promising economic outlook and lower bond yields than other countries on the euro periphery is that they dealt rather energetically with their banking problems. Countries which let their banking issues fester, including Spain, Cyprus and Slovenia, are finding it harder to escape recession. Nonetheless, we have not included comprehensive bank rehabilitation in the crisis countries and a eurozone banking union among the bare essentials needed to let the eurozone crisis fade further. Why is that so? The answer is simple: the pace of progress on sorting out banking problems is crucial for individual 3 We explain this approach in detail in Tough Love: the true nature of the euro crisis, Berenberg, 20 August 2012. 4 See for example our Euro Plus Monitor, Spring 2013 Update, Berenberg and Lisbon Council, 7 March 2013. 5 See for instance Ingves and Lind (2009), also Kanaya nd Woo on the case of Japan in the 1990s. BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING countries. If they act fast and forcefully, their adjustment recessions will be brief and their subsequent recoveries will be rapid; if they fail to do so, the recessions will be longer and deeper and the recoveries will initially be shallower. But this is largely a problem for those individual countries themselves. It is less of a systemic issue for the eurozone as a whole. Slovenia’s progress on banking issues, or the lack of it, has been shaping its own economic fate. But it is of limited importance for the eurozone as a whole. The roots of the problem The pervasive banking problems in some eurozone member countries have three different roots. 1. In Ireland and Spain, credit-fuelled real estate booms turned into bust after 2007, as they did in the US and the UK. In Slovenia, undisciplined lending practices by some institutions also stored up trouble for the future. 2. In Greece and Cyprus, the de facto default of Greece on its sovereign bonds wiped out the capital of almost all major banks, triggering a need to recapitalise these banks largely at the expense of eurozone taxpayers. 3. Across the eurozone periphery, the deep double-dip recession caused (i) by the post-Lehman global financial collapse, (ii) by severe austerity and (iii) by the collapse of economic confidence from mid-2011 to mid-2012 amid widespread anxiety about a perceived risk of the eurozone break-up led to a surge in non-performing loans. As a result, even Italy is now struggling with a credit-crunch for smalland medium-sized enterprises although Italy did not suffer from a real estate boom-bust cycle. BV 11/2013 The vicious circle The eurozone crisis added a special complication to banking issues. In countries with their own national currency, the national central banks and the national sovereigns are the usual backstops for troubled banking systems. But eurozone members no longer have a central bank that could intervene at its own discretion. More importantly, the eurozone crisis started with worries about public debt. This limits the ability of national governments to support their banking systems. Transferring debt from the balance sheets of banks to that of the eurozone crisis. Once markets started to worry about individual countries, driving up the funding cost for sovereigns and banks alike, these countries seemed to be sucked ever deeper into the malaise. And seeing a major slide in asset prices in small countries with big problems such as Greece, investors turned away from bigger countries such as Spain and Italy as well, just to be safe side. When the de facto default of Greece on its public debt, announced in July 2011, confirmed some of the worst fears of investors about Greece, contagion spread like wildfire to Spain and Italy. Containing the contagion risks The eurozone crisis started with worries about public debt. the national sovereign adds to the debt mountain. The result has been a toxic link between banks and their sovereign. In a vicious circle, concerns about sovereign debt erode the value of the sovereign bonds which banks hold as assets while the short-term pain of austerity hurts bank earnings. The perceived need for the sovereign to support banks, in turn, fuel worries about an ever-rising debt burden, making it more difficult for the sovereign to fund itself while further depressing the value of the bonds held by banks. This vicious circle, or the mere risk that there might be such a vicious circle, has been at the heart of 71 After some dithering, the eurozone has successfully reacted to those problems. By setting up the temporary and then the permanent rescue shields (European Financial Stability Facility EFSF and European Stabilisation Mechanism ESM), the parliaments of the eurozone members willed sufficient funds to back up all small euro crisis countries up to and including Spain. The ECB announcement of 26 July 2012 to do all it takes to preserve the euro, and to buy sovereign bonds of reform countries if need be as long as those countries abide by the terms of an EFSF/ESM programme, de facto added the funds to keep Italy out of harm’s way as well. The ECB stepped forward as the eurozone’s lender of last resort. The ECB promise had two major effects. Firstly, it virtually put an end to contagion risks within the eurozone. If one country were to hit the wall, perhaps by hypothetically losing access to bailout funds because it has refused to meet the conditions, the ECB could credibly protect all other countries against the fallout from such an incident. Secondly, the bailout funds can lend the national MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING sovereigns the money needed to recapitalise banks, de facto weakening the toxic link between national sovereigns and the banks under their jurisdiction. The mechanisms to contain contagion risks and to support the weaker sovereigns have a major consequence for the analysis of banking problems within the eurozone. They have reduced the risks that banking problems in one country can spread to other countries and the eurozone as a whole. If a country cannot raise funds to recapitalise banks on its own, it can ask the ESM for help, as Spain has done. If trouble in one country were to endanger other countries or if markets were to worry that the ESM would not have the means to support a large eurozone member country, the ECB could activate its OMT programme. As a result, banking problems have turned largely into issues to be dealt with on the national level, possibly with European support. A full eurozone banking union, while useful, is not required to protect the eurozone as a whole from the potential fallout from banking problems on the national level. Put differently: instead of waiting for a solution within the framework of a future eurozone banking union, countries such as Spain and Slovenia ought to address their banking problems at home. The faster and more decisively they do so, the better for these countries. Accepting the strings attached The eurozone has the instruments to contain contagion risks and to help countries that have lost - or are at risk of losing - access to funding markets. Of course, any outside support comes with strings attached. The ECB has explicitly tied its programme for potential “Outright Monetary Transactions“ (OMT) to the ESM conditionality. Countries that ask for help expose themselves to troika supervision and tough conditionality. Politically, that can be very painful. Seen just from the standpoint of ending the crisis in individual countries fast, this conditionality is a severe handicap. Avoiding such conditionality for the sovereign, for instance by asking the ESM to directly recapitalise banks without dealing with and through the national sovereign, would be much more convenient for national governments. No wonder than most of the weak euro mem- Countries such as Spain and Slovenia ought to address their banking problems at home. bers are very much in favour of that. The tough conditionality attached to European support is one of the key reasons why crisis countries are not cleaning up their bank balance sheets as fast and thoroughly as they should. But seen from the vantage point of other countries and the region as a whole, the calculus is very different. Lending support without conditions would incur a moral hazard problem. Countries might be encouraged to continue with ultimately unsustainable policies if the risks of such policies can be partly shifted onto foreign taxpayers. Also, by allowing a direct bank recapitalisation or through other ways of virtually 72 unconditional support, the donor countries would lose the useful leverage to promote pro-growth structural reforms in the crisis countries. While avoiding such painful reforms may feel good near-term, it would mean to let slip an opportunity to strengthen the fundamental health of countries. As a result of the tough conditionality attached to actually accessing support funds, euro crisis countries have to strike their own balance between chance of faster resolution and hence a faster return to economic growth and the risk of a loss of sovereignty. It may not be a bad thing that countries are forced into a national public discourse about such a choice. Tackling banking problems: better to be bold The gradual fading of tensions in the eurozone since August 2012 has opened up a chance for countries with troubled banking sectors. In an environment of improving sentiment, markets may be ready to allow countries a little more leeway than they had before. Markets are starting to look at opportunities for growth instead of just focussing on the risks inherent in high levels of public debt. If countries choose to forcefully tackle their banking problems, using national funds to recapitalise or wind down problem banks if need be, such resolve may impress markets. In other words, chances are that, with a credible programme, countries may be able to raise the required funds on the capital markets, especially if the programmes bear the stamp of approval of the EU Commission and eurozone finance ministers. Amid improving sentiment, countries such as Spain and Slovenia may avoid having to ask for a (full) ESM support programme if markets see that they are heading in the right direcBV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING tion. The chance that bold action can improve future growth prospects can outweigh the need to borrow more near-term to clean up bank balance sheets. Whether or not such an attempt would really be successful remains unclear. It crucially depends on still fickle market sentiment. But it is worth a try. If raising the required funds on the market turned out to be too difficult, the country could still apply for European help. With a credible programme to resolve its banking issues, it would already have met much of the likely conditions that would be attached to such official support. III. BANKING UNION – USEFUL BUT NOT ESSENTIAL A full banking union for the eurozone could help to ease tensions further and allow the euro crisis countries to return to satisfactory growth fast. It would break the link between banks and the national sovereign. It could spread the costs of winding down problem banks and strengthen confidence in the banking systems of problem countries. For example, capital adequacy tests run by the European Central Banks could be much more credible than the previous stress tests that were heavily influenced by national regulators who are often seen as biased. A stamp of approval from the ECB could improve access of banks to funding markets and strengthen the confidence of depositors in that bank. But while rapid progress towards a full banking union would be helpful for euro crisis countries, the available evidence shows that it is not essential for the crisis to fade. Financial tensions in the eurozone have already subsided significantly since the ECB announced its readiness to do what it takes to preserve the euro and hence its own existence. Right after the ECB unveiled its programme for potential BV 11/2013 “Outright Monetary Transactions” in August 2012, leading economic indicators started to turn up in the periphery as well as in core Europe. Monetary policy usually works with a lag of some three quarters. Exactly on cue, the eurozone economy returned to modest growth in the second quarter of 2013, three quarters after the decisive shift in ECB policy. The leading indicators available at the time of writing project further gradual gains in momentum. Whereas the periphery is still lagging behind the core, the leading indicators suggest that most peripheral countries will leave recession in the third quarter. In Portugal and Greece, GDP started to expand again in the second quarter already according to provisional data. The economic recovery has started despite a serious credit crunch for small and medium-sized enterprises in some peripheral eurozone countries such as Spain and Italy. In the eurozone as a whole, loans to non-financial corporations fell by 3.7% year-on-year in July 2013. But how can economies expand when credit to companies is contracting? Doesn’t the eurozone have to fix its major financial problems first before the economic outlook can brighten for good? The answer is simple: in the eurozone, bank credit to companies is a lagging indicator of the business cycle. Turning points in bank credit tend to follow turning points in the real economy with a variable lag of around two quarters. Companies only ask for a credit, and banks only grant a new credit, when the economy is already clearly on the way up. Banks do not finance the first phase of an economic turnaround. Unlike bank credit to companies, money supply is a leading indicator of the economic cycle. That holds at least for the eurozone where monetary policy is largely transmitted through the banking system to the real economy. As Chart 1 shows, major turning points in real M1 money supply tend to lead the eurozone business cycle by roughly three quarters. Real M1 consists of the liquid balances (cash and overnight deposits) of households and non-financial companies adjusted for the increase in consumer prices. In times of crisis, companies and households try to raise their liquid balances. Central banks make that easy through an Chart 1: Money supply and GDP growth in the eurozone Yoy changes in %, M1 deflated by consumer prices, advanced by three quarters. Source: ECB, Eurostat, Berenberg calculations. 14 6 12 5 10 4 8 3 6 2 4 1 2 0 0 -1 -2 -2 -4 -6 Jan 92 Eurozone real M1,3q fwd, lhs Jan 95 Jan 98 73 Jan 01 -3 GDP, rhs Jan 04 Jan 07 Jan 10 Jan 13 -4 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING appropriately accommodative monetary policy. When households and companies have raised their reserves – and when their worst fears fail to materialise – they eventually end up with more liquidity than they want to hold in the long run. They gradually start to spend some of these liquid balances. Put differently, companies in the eurozone tend to finance the first phase of an economic recovery out of liquid balances which they have accumulated during the crisis. Bank credit only kicks in when the upswing is well on its way. Of course, companies will eventually need bank credits to put an economic recovery on a sound footing. This may well be happening soon. Chart 2 shows that financing cost for some of the worst-hit companies in the eurozone, the small and medium-sized companies in Italy and Spain, have started to fall modestly from very elevated levels in late 2012. We expect this trend to continue as overall financial tensions recede further and – after some quarters of economic growth – banks become less hesitant to grant new credits. However, the turnaround in bank credit to corporates will probably be later and shallower than in previous economic upturns as banks continue to prioritise balance sheet repair over the expansion of their businesses. Until the European Central Bank has concluded its forthcoming asset quality review, probably in early Chart 2: Financing cost for small and medium-sized enterprises Loans to non-financial corporations, up to € 1mn, maturity 1-5 years, new business, annualised agreed rate (AAR), in %. Source: ECB SME financing costs 7 6 Germany Spain Italy 5 4 3 Jan 2003 Jan 2005 Jan 2007 2014, many banks may be especially reluctant to take on new risks. The banking problems in the eurozone, including the lack of a full banking union with a joint supervisor, a joint resolution mechanism and a joint deposit guarantee fund, are likely to restrain the unfolding economic upswing. We expect the economic upturn to remain slightly below trend in the eurozone until these issues are resolved. But we do not expect the banking problems to prevent the economic upswing in the first place. The more individual countries manage to repair their banking systems on their own initiative, the faster they may lift their GDP growth to their trend rate or beyond. 74 Jan 2009 Jan 2011 Jan 2013 REFERENCES: Holger Schmieding and Christian Schulz, Euro Plus Monitor, Spring 2013 Update, Berenberg and Lisbon Council, 7 March 2013. Holger Schmieding, Tough Love: the true nature of the euro crisis, Berenberg, 20 August 2012. Stefan Ingves and Göran Lund, Is the Swedish Model for Dealing with a Banking Crisis still Valid?, in: Lessons Learned from Previous Banking Crises: Sweden, Japan, Spain, and Mexico, Group of Thirty, Occasional Paper No. 79, Washington, DC, 2009. Akihiro Kanaya and David Woo, The Japanese Banking Crisis of the 1990s: Sources and Lessons, International Monetary Fund, IMF Working Paper, Washington, DC, January 2000. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Economic Policy Reforms 2013: Going for Growth, Paris 2013. BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING UDK 336.71:338.124.4(497.4):061.1EU Razdolževanje bank v EU in Sloveniji Marko Simoneti in Božo Jašovič* BANK DELEVERAGING IN EU AND SLOVENIA The purpose of this paper is to analyze the possibilities for "good" deleveraging of banking and corporate sector in Slovenia. Many banks that are dependent on wholesale funding are facing strategic decision to change their business plans. Quintessential ingredient of these changes is de-leveraging and less dependence on unstable financing due to uncertainties which arise from time to time in financial markets. The process of deleveraging can be implemented either through recapitalisation or retrenchment of assets. The latter can contribute to contraction of credits to non-financial sectors and ensuing contraction of economic activity. The negative feedback loop thus feeds back through the worsening economic activity on banks’ balance sheets. The Slovenian enterprise sector is among most dependent on bank financing; therefore, the process of deleveraging is likely to have negative consequences on supply of credit to the economy. Due to a high level of non-performing loans, the deleveraging process should go hand in hand with cleaning up banks’ balance sheets and enterprise restructuring. JEL G01 G21 BV 11/2013 G lobalno bančno razdolževanje (de-leveraging, de-risking) je posledica nevzdržnega procesa kreditiranja v obdobju pred finančno krizo. V tem obdobju so ogromne količine kapitalskih tokov v obliki kreditov dobesedno »zalile« nekatere nacionalne ekonomije. Zaradi obilice razpoložljivih sredstev so bili tudi kreditni standardi bank temu primerno sproščeni, ta sredstva pa so pogosto končala v tveganih finančnih instrumentih, manj donosnih ali celo nasedlih investicijah gradbenega sektorja in kreditih zadolženim podjetjem in posameznikom, ki bi v normalnih okoliščinah težko dobili kredit na podlagi slabe bonitete. V bilancah finančnih (bančnih) institucij se je močno povečala zadolženost, kapital lastnikov pa je bil neznaten in s tem tudi varnost upnikov bank. 1. Uvod Banke niso uspele zbrati dovolj depozitov za take obsege kreditiranja, zato so zadolžitev povečale z najemanjem grosističnih virov na mednarodnih finančnih trgih. Posledica takega ravnanja je bila, da je postal finančni sistem zelo kompleksen in medsebojno prepleten. Z izbruhom finančne krize se je najprej začel sesuvati ta del trga in banke so bile prisiljene v nasprotni proces – razdolžitev, ki naj bi bančne bilance tolikanj razgradil, da bodo postale dolgoročno vzdržne in stabilne. Proces razdolževanja ni samo posledica razmer na finančnih trgih, deloma so ga povzročili tudi regulatorji oziroma spremembe, ki so jih sprejeli za zagotavljanje dolgoročne vzdržnosti bank in finančne stabilnosti (Basel III oziroma CRD IV in CRR, ki ga implementirata). * Dr. Marko Simoneti, izredni profesor Pravne fakultete Univerze v Ljubljani, in mag. Božo Jašovič, svetovalec uprave, Gorenjska banka d.d., Kranj. 75 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING Glede na spremenjeno regulativo in spremenjeno poslovno prakso bank se zastavlja vprašanje, kolikšen je obseg potrebnega razdolževanja bank, da pridemo do dolgoročno vzdržne ravni. Enoznačnega odgovora na to vprašanje ni, saj je odvisen od več dejavnikov. Na potrebo po razdolževanju banke vplivajo strukturni dejavniki: spremenjeni poslovni modeli, potreba po povečanju kapitala zaradi izgub na portfelju, zmanjšanje odvisnosti od grosističnih virov oziroma virov ECB in prestrukturiranje (zmanjšanje) zaradi prejete državne pomoči. Poleg strukturnih dejavnikov pa na razdolževanje bank vplivajo tudi ciklične značilnosti določenega ekonomskega okolja: kreditna sposobnost države, splošne finančne razmere, dinamika gospodarske aktivnosti in kreditno tveganje nefinančnega sektorja. Negativne ciklične razmere še dodatno pritiskajo na razdolževanje bank tako prek ponudbe kot tudi povpraševanja po kreditih. Proces razdolževanja bank ima več merljivih končni ciljev, ki so zapisani v bančni regulativi ali pa so postali nekakšen splošno sprejemljiv standard. Med slednjimi je najbolj poznan kazalnik med krediti in depoziti (LTD, loan to deposit ratio), ki ni predpisan, vendar pa je pogosto predstavljen kot indikator odvisnosti bank od grosističnih virov financiranja in kot kazalnik, v kolikšnem obsegu so banke že prilagodile svoje poslovne modele novim razmeram. Varno naj bi bilo razmerje, pri katerem krediti dosegajo zbrane depozite od bančnih komitentov. Najpomembnejši kazalniki, ki so predpisani z regulativo in vplivajo na proces razdolževanja bank, so: delež temeljnega kapitala v tvegani aktivi, razmerje med sredstvi in kapitalom (leverage ratio) in količnik stabilnega financiranja (NSFR, net stable funding ratio), ki predstavlja razmerje med razpoložljivimi dolgo- ročnimi viri in zahtevanim stabilnim financiranjem. Banke bodo morale postopoma doseči ciljne vrednosti opisanih količnikov. Že bežen pogled na količnike daje nedvoumen odgovor, da jih je mogoče doseči na dva načina: s povečanjem lastniškega kapitala ali pa z zmanjšanjem sredstev (naložb) bank oziroma s kombinacijo obeh. Tehnično gledano obstajajo številne variacije, kako proces razdolževanja izpeljati v praksi, bolj kot to pa je pomembno vprašanje, kakšen bo vpliv tega procesa na primarno funkcijo bank – zagotavljanje kreditov nebančnemu sektorju. Vsaki finančni krizi nujno sledi razdolževanje bank pa tudi njenih komitentov. Vsaki finančni krizi nujno sledi razdolževanje bank, pa tudi njenih komitentov – prezadolženih nebančnih sektorjev gospodarstva. Podatki kažejo, da se je proces razdolževanja tudi tokrat najprej začel v finančnem sektorju ter šele z določenim časovnim zamikom tudi v realnem sektorju, pri čemer pa Slovenija zelo zaostaja za drugimi državami članicami EU.1 Ta proces razdolževanja je torej neizogiben, vendar je od intenzivnosti in načina tega procesa odvisno, kakšne so negativne posledice na gospodarsko aktivnost v posamezni državi. V primeru prehitrega zmanjševanja kreditne aktivnosti bank lahko pride do povratne negativne zanke, ko upad ekonomske aktivnosti povzroči dodatno poslabšanje 76 bančnih bilanc, kar vodi v nov krog zmanjševanja kreditiranja in gospodarske aktivnosti. Kot »dobro« razdolževanje bank bi tako lahko načeloma označili vse procese in ukrepe, ki ne povzročajo še dodatnih in nepotrebnih omejitev na strani ponudbe kreditov na gospodarsko aktivnost. Povečanje kapitala v bankah je gotovo najbolj neposreden ukrep, ki omogoča bankam po finančni krizi, da se soočijo z izgubami v svojih bilancah brez škodljivega omejevanja kreditiranja tistih komitentov, ki so še kreditno sposobni. Tudi krčenje bančnih bilanc zaradi odpisov nima nobenih negativnih posledic za ekonomsko aktivnost, saj se obseg dejanskih kreditov s tem ne spreminja. Japonska izkušnja kaže prav nasprotno: skrivanje bančnih izgub, odlašanje z dokapitalizacijami in odlašanje z aktivnostmi za prestrukturiranje slabih kreditov (NPLs, non performing loans) so lahko pomembni vzroki za dolgoročno gospodarsko stagnacijo.2 Kot »dobro« zmanjšanje bilanc univerzalnih bank lahko opredelimo tudi odprodajo sredstev in aktivnosti, ki niso neposredno povezane s komercialnim bančništvom: naložbe v različne finančne instrumente, investicijsko bančništvo, upravljanje premoženja, zavarovalništvo in podobno. Pri bančnih skupinah, ki poslujejo v številnih državah, se pojavlja tudi možnost, da se večji del razdolževanja opravi na tujih trgih in tako omeji negativne posledice na domačo ekonomsko aktivnost (home bias in deleveraging). Razdolževanje bank, ki je »dobro« za domačo ekonomijo in »slabo« za ekonomijo gostitelja, je aktualna tema tako na globalni ravni kot v okviru EU. 1 Glej na primer Košak & Košak (2012). Več o delovanju »zombi« bank na Japonskem in posledicah za ekonomsko aktivnost, če se odlaša s priznanjem izgub in dokapitalizacijo bank po finančnih krizah, je pojasnjeno v R. Caballero et. al. (2008) in Tang G. & Upper C. (2010). 2 BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING Možnosti za »dobro« razdolževanje bank so večinoma odvisne tudi od stopnje prezadolženosti osnovnih sektorjev domačega gospodarstva: prebivalstva, podjetij in države ter od pomena, ki ga imajo domače banke za financiranje teh sektorjev glede na alternativne možnosti prek trga kapitala in tujine. Namen tega članka je analizirati možnosti za izvedbo »dobrega« razdolževanja bank v Sloveniji. V prvem delu predstavljamo pomembna pravila in ukrepe na ravni EU, ki jih mora Slovenija kot članica EU in evrskega območja upoštevati v tem procesu. Pri tem opozarjamo predvsem na primere, ko so ti zunanji pogoji oblikovani oziroma se dinamično spreminjajo na podlagi razmer, ki prevladujejo v večjih državah članicah, razmere v Sloveniji pa so povsem drugačne zaradi njenih strukturnih značilnosti ali pa zaradi njenih zamud pri odzivu na krizne razmere. V drugem delu analiziramo strukturne posebnosti problema prezadolženosti v Sloveniji in vlogo bank pri njegovem nastanku in reševanju. V nadaljevanju sistematično prikažemo na ravni posamezne banke »dobre« in »slabe« načine razdolževanja, ki v Sloveniji poteka po spontanem scenariju od začetka krize do danes. Na koncu podamo oceno načrtovanega programa Vlade RS za sanacijo bank ter podamo nekatera priporočila za izvedbo »dobrega« razdolževanja bank v razmerah, ki trenutno prevladujejo v Sloveniji in njenem širšem evropskem institucionalnem okolju. 2. Pregled razdolževanja v bankah EU po krizi Vsaki finančni krizi sledi proces zmanjševanja dolga v razmerju do BDP, ki ga ekonomska politika poskuša uravnavati tako, da bi bila prilagoditev čim bolj postopna in posredna prek rasti BDP, ter tako omejiti BV 11/2013 potrebo po manj prijetnih alternativah za zmanjšanje bremen dolga: fiskalna konsolidacija, odpisi ali prestrukturiranje javnega in zasebnega dolga, odprodaja premoženja ter inflacijsko razvrednotenje v primeru lastne valute. Zmanjšanje obsega zadolženosti večinoma poteka prek bank, ki opravljajo posredniško vlogo pri prenosu prihrankov med sektorji. Predstavimo nekaj dejstev iz zadnje krize: finančni vzvod velikih evropskih bank je ob koncu leta 2008 znašal 30-kratnik kapitala in se je zmanjšal ob koncu leta 2012 na Finančni vzvod velikih evropskih bank je ob koncu leta 2008 znašal 30-kratnik kapitala. 22-kratnik kapitala.3 Večina tega zmanjšanja je treba pripisati povečanju kapitala in le manjši del zmanjševanju naložb bank. Tako visok finančni vzvod še vedno predstavlja visoko tveganje za nestabilnost bank, zato je proces nadaljnjega razdolževanja neizbežen. Doslej se celotna sredstva evropskih bank, v nasprotju z ameriškimi, niso pomembno zmanjšala. Vzrokov za bolj intenzivno krčenje ameriškega bančnega sektorja od evropskega je več: obsežne odprodaje finančnih naložb na račun prevladujoče tržne narave finančnega sistema, manjša odvisnost podjetij od bančnega financiranja in ustaljen mehanizem prenosa hipotekarnih kreditov na državno sponzorirane agencije. 77 Dodatno je treba pojasniti, da evropske banke v povprečju zagotavljajo precej več kot polovico vseh kreditov podjetjem in prebivalstvu, medtem ko je ta delež za ameriške banke zgolj 30 %. Na podlagi nanizanih dejstev je mogoče ugotoviti, da se je razdolževanje ameriških bank izvedlo z odprodajo finančnih naložb in zmanjšanjem zadolžitve na finančnih trgih. Evropske banke so bolj kot ameriške odvisne od grosističnih virov financiranja, izkazujejo višji finančni vzvod in bodo zato v naslednjih obdobjih pod večjim pritiskom glede razdolževanja. Tudi anketna preverjanja evropskih bank4 potrjujejo omenjeno tezo: večina bank je vgradila razdolževanje med ključne strateške cilje zaradi zmanjševanja tveganj (de-risking) in višjih kapitalskih zahtev regulatorja oziroma trgov. V zvezi s tem se zastavlja vprašanje, ali je mogoče ta proces kontrolirati tako, da bo potekal brez negativnih posledic na ponudbo kreditov podjetjem in prebivalstvu. Dilema ni navidezna, saj so tveganja na obeh straneh. Hitro razdolževanje je ob dani strukturi portfelja evropskih bank možno le z zmanjševanjem kreditne aktivnosti, ki vodi do kreditnega krča in povezanih negativnih posledic. Da to ni nemogoče, nakazujejo že podatki o dalj časa zaostrenih standardih kreditiranja, ki v povezavi z zmanjševanjem povpraševanja po kreditih lahko vplivajo na kreditni krč. Po drugi strani pa odlašanje s procesom razdolževanja lahko sproži vprašanja o ustreznem vrednotenju sredstev v bančnih bilancah in posledično sproža nezaupanje vlagateljev v banke ter slabi njihovo posredniško funkcijo. Proces razdolževanja japonskih bank je trajal predolgo in je zato povzročil 3 Financial Stability Review, ECB, May, 2013, str. 56. 4 Glej Risk Assessment of the European Banking System, EBA, July 2013, str 16. MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING dodatne ekonomske stroške zaradi prepočasnega prilagajanja. Prehitro in nekontrolirano razdolževanje pa prav tako lahko povzroči škodo podjetjem in prebivalstvu, ki so odvisni od bančnih kreditov. Povsem drugačno dinamiko ima razdolževanje bank v državah, ki imajo finančne težave ali gospodarsko nazadujejo. V teh primerih ciklični dejavniki dajejo takt razdolževanju, ki vključuje nujno in hitro čiščenje bančnih bilanc kot prvi pogoj, da bi bančni sektor lahko zopet opravljal svojo primarno funkcijo. Vsako odlašanje razdolževanja (de-riskinga) pomeni akumuliranje visokih stroškov končne sanacije bančnega sistema. Če je bilo do sredine leta 2012 razdolževanje v EU (merjeno s finančnim vzvodom) predvsem na račun povečevanja kapitala, poteka v zadnjem času z zmanjševanjem tveganjem prilagojene aktive (TPA), medtem ko so celotna sredstva bank ostala stabilna. Na prvi pogled gre za protisloven proces, ki po razmisleku navaja na to, da so se evropske banke osredotočile na »izkoriščanje prostora«, ki ga dovoljuje regulativa v zvezi z določanjem uteži za izračun kapitalske ustreznosti bank. Tu so prakse bank raznolike: od tistih, ki uporabljajo napredne metode in izračunavajo uteži z uporabo lastnih modelov (in praviloma izračunavajo najmanjšo porabo kapitala), do drugih, ki še vedno uporabljajo standardni model, vendar se prisojene uteži razlikujejo po državah. Slovenski bančni sistem v povprečju uporablja visoke uteži (razmerje med tvegano aktivo in knjigovodsko vrednostjo naložb – gostota tvegane aktive – je med najvišjimi) in zato regulativno »porablja« veliko kapitala. Po drugi strani pa slovenski bančni sistem po finančnem vzvodu (razmerje med sredstvi in kapitalom) sodi med povprečje evropskih bank. V obdobju 2010–2012 so evropske banke intenzivno spreminjale uporabo kapi- Slika 1: Finančni vzvod bank v evrskem območju (sredstva/kapital) Vir: ECB talskih uteži, ki naj bi zagotavljale na tveganjih temelječ izračun kapitala. To je vzbudilo dvom o konsistentni uporabi regulative tako pri nadzornikih kot tudi pri številnih kritikih uporabe kreditnih uteži, ki je nepregledna in zato težje preverljiva.5 Evropske banke ocenjujejo, da bodo do konca leta 2014 zmanjšale sredstva za 800 milijard EUR.6 Analitiki menijo, da je razpon ocen zmanjšanja sredstev, upoštevajoč ključne dejavnike (ciklične, strukturne, kapitalske), lahko tudi precej večji, po drugi strani pa relativizirajo te ocene z blažilnimi dejavniki. Med najpomembnejšimi omenjajo povečanje kapitala bank, prevzem sredstev s strani drugih bank in definirano zaporedje skupin naložb, ki jih bodo prioritetno zmanjševale (pecking order). Možnosti za povečanje kapitala bank so zelo negotove zaradi dinamičnih okoliščin, ki so povezane z bankami: postavljanje enotnega evropskega nadzora in mehanizma prestrukturiranja problematičnih bank, harmoniziranega sistema zavarovanja vlog, napovedanih strukturnih sprememb v bančništvu.7 Potencialni investitorji bodo pri investiranju v bančne delnice vključili opisane negotovosti v diskontne stopnje in vprašanje je, kakšna bo ponudba bančnih delnic ob takšnih pričakovanjih. Alternativa 78 je agresivno zmanjševanje tistih sredstev, ki so kapitalsko najbolj potratna oziroma imajo najmanjši vpliv na matična okolja bank. Podatki kažejo, da so evropske banke doslej najbolj zmanjševale izpostavljenosti do drugih držav in nestrateške naložbe. Več kot polovica tega zmanjšanja se nanaša na države znotraj evrskega območja, kar postavlja omejitve pri zagotavljanju kreditov v državah, ki so odvisne od tujih virov. Spremenjene poslovne politike mednarodnih bank preusmerjajo svoje izpostave na zbiranje depozitov na lokalnih trgih perifernih držav, kar povzroča dvig obrestnih mer in dodaten negativen impulz za kreditiranje. Razne iniciative za blaženje preveč agresivnih politik mednarodnih bank do perifernih držav so bolj moralno prepričevanje kot pa učinkovit ukrep proti regionalno selektivnemu zmanjševanju sredstev. V sedanjih kriznih razmerah v državah EU so tako povsem razumljivi trendi umika zahodnoevropskih bank iz financiranja drugih svetovnih regij 5 Več o tem glej v Haldane, (2012). Financial Stability Report 2013, ECB, May 2013, str. 57. 7 Gre za poročila različnih komisij, ki so jih ustanovili v ta namen: Liikanenovo poročilo, Vickersovo poročilo in Volckerjevo poročilo. Več o tem glej v Vinals et. al., (2013). 6 BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING Slika 2: Delež bančnih kreditov v vseh kreditih podjetij (vodoravna os, v %) in delež kreditov podjetjem v vseh kreditih nebančnemu sektorju (pokončna os, v %) Slovenija 30 Spain Greece 25 Italy Portugal 20 Large domestic corporate loan book Austria 15 France Germany 10 Ireland Belgium United States United Kingdom Small domestic corporate loan book 0 20 40 60 80 5 100 0 1 Vir: Global Financial Stability Report, IMF, April 2012. in iz financiranja drugih držav v okviru EU, saj se želi čim večji del razpoložljivih finančnih virov uporabiti za prehodno financiranje domačih deficitov. Takšno pristransko delovanje bank pri razdolževanju vodi k dezintegraciji enotnega evropskega bančnega trga in še dodatno destabilizira države uvoznice kapitala v okviru EU. Po nekaterih ocenah naj bi tako iz Italije in Španije v zadnjih dveh kriznih letih prek tujih bank odtekla sredstva v višini kar približno 35 % BDP.8 Nestandardne ukrepe dolgoročnega refinanciranja ECB je tako treba razumeti tudi kot način, da se iz javnih virov začasno nadomesti zasebne bančne vire financiranja obrobnih evrskih držav. Vzpostavitev evropske bančne unije pa naj bi že na srednji rok ustvarila razmere za zagotavljanje finančne stabilnosti celotnega evrskega območja in za odpornost evropskega modela čezmejnega bančništva na gospodarske cikle v posameznih državah. BV 11/2013 V začetku krize se je ocenjevalo, da bodo zaradi pristranskega razdolževanja mednarodnih bančnih skupin najbolj ogrožene države centralne in vzhodne Evrope (CEE deleveraging problem), kjer je pretežni del bančnega sektorja v lasti bank iz zahodne Evrope.9 Tuje banke so bančnim sistemom teh držav v obdobju pred krizo zagotavljale znanje, kapital in dodatno financiranje iz tujine, ki se za razdobje 2000–2008 ocenjuje na približno 100 % BDP te regije. V Sloveniji je prevladala nekoliko drugačna bančna kombinacija z domačim (predvsem državnim) kapitalom, domačim znanjem in dodatnimi tujimi viri. Po drugi strani pa je za približno tretjino našega bančnega sektorja značilna kombinacija CEE: tuj kapital, tuje znanje in dodatni tuji viri. Z vidika obsega slabih kreditov, možnosti refinanciranja obveznosti do tujine in zagotavljanja kapitalske ustreznosti brez pomoči države razlika med domačimi in tujimi bankami 79 pri prenosu tujih prihrankov v Slovenijo skoraj ne bi mogla biti večja.10 Kako so se tuje banke odrezale po finančni krizi na Sloveniji podobnih hitro rastočih trgih, kadar so imele prevladujoč delež? Predvsem so za kapitalsko ustreznost svojih bank v CEE poskrbele matične banke. V prvem obdobju krize se je pokazalo, da so bile tuje banke v nasprotju s pričakovanji celo dejavnik stabilnosti pri ohranjanju zunanjega financiranja teh držav.11 Po izbruhu krize evra in krize javnega dolga perifernih evrskih držav, ko so se pritiski po razdolževanju bank v celotni Evropi še dodatno povečali, pa se je to pokazalo tudi v zmanjšanju kreditne aktivnosti tujih bank v regiji CEE, vendar zelo različno po državah. V državah s pozitivno gospodarsko rastjo, nizkimi in stabilnimi deleži slabih terjatev in visokimi profitnimi stopnjami v bančništvu tuje banke celo širijo poslovanje, pri čemer pa se vedno večji del financiranja zagotavlja iz lokalnih virov. Trenutna ocena je, da poglavitne ovire za rast kreditiranja v teh državah niso na strani ponudbe, vendar se lahko razmere hitro spremenijo, če bodo ukinjeni nestandardni ukrepi financiranja s strani ECB.12 Pri tem velja omeniti, da so bili povprečni donosi na kapital tujih bank v 8 Glej v CEE Banking Sector Report, Raiffeisen Bank, (2013), str.10. 9 Številni analitiki so že ob začetku krize opozarjali, da bi pretiran in nenaden umik evropskih bank iz financiranja držav CEE zaradi regulatornih ali kratkoročnih tržnih pritiskov lahko imel uničujoče posledice za gospodarsko aktivnost teh držav. (Glej na primer S. Gardó and R. Martin (2010), Martin Brown et. Al. (2011), Erik Feyen et. al. (2012)). Za usmerjanje in spremljanje tega procesa razdolževanja v regiji CEE so na pobudo Avstrije mednarodne finančne organizacije skupaj z največjimi mednarodnimi bankami ustanovile celo posebno koordinacijo (Vienna Initiative). To je po svoje ironično, saj je avstrijski regulator med prvimi začel omejevati poslovanje avstrijskih bank v tujini na obseg sredstev, ki jih banke zberejo na lokalnih trgih. 10 Za Slovenijo je razliko v poslovanju domačih in tujih bank med krizo in po njej dobro dokumentirala Banka Slovenije v vsakoletnih Poročilih o finančni stabilnosti. 11 Glej na primer Berglöf E. et. al. (2009) in EBRD Transition Report (2009). 12 Glej CESEE Deleveregaing Monitor (2012). MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING tej regiji za leto 2012 približno 15 % do 16 %, donosi istih bank na trgih razvitega dela Evrope pa komaj pozitivni.13 Večina trgov CEE je torej za velike mednarodne bančne skupine še vedno zelo zanimivih, vendar Slovenije žal ni med njimi. Težko si je trenutno predstavljati, da bi bile mednarodne skupine zainteresirane za nakup slovenskih bank brez njihove predhodne sanacije in konsolidacije in dokler se ne izboljšajo obeti za gospodarsko rast. Na dinamiko procesa razdolževanja bank z zmanjševanjem sredstev bodo pomembno vplivali tudi postopki povezani s prejeto državno pomočjo in neugodne ciklične razmere v nekaterih perifernih državah, ki delujejo tako prek zmanjšane ponudbe kot tudi povpraševanja po kreditih. Kar zadeva postopke državne pomoči, lahko pričakujemo, da bo pomemben del sredstev, ki jih bodo morale banke dezinvestirati, pristal v portfeljih drugih bank. Zanimivo vprašanje je, koliko bodo taka nujna dezinvestiranja vplivala na zmanjševanje cen oziroma potrebo po prevrednotenju tudi v drugih bankah. Neugodne ciklične razmere predstavljajo za nadzornike in banke v teh okoljih največji izziv. Stagnacija ekonomske aktivnosti povzroča poslabševanje kvalitete in potrebo po prevrednotenju portfeljev bank, kapitalske omejitve in s tem tudi omejitve pri kreditiranju. Po drugi strani pa je zaradi ekonomske kontrakcije tudi povpraševanje po kreditih zmanjšano: podjetja in prebivalstvo se razdolžujejo in odlagajo investicijske odločitve. Gre za okoliščine »popolnega viharja«, ki zahtevajo odločno ukrepanje (dokapitalizacijo bank, prestrukturiranje podjetij) za izhod iz negativne spirale. Bojazen, da bo proces razdolževanja bank vplival na zmanjšano kreditno aktivnost bank, je upravičena predvsem zaradi pritiska finančnih trgov. Tržni udeleženci Slika 3: Delež kreditov nebančnemu sektorju v bilančni vsoti (v %) Vir: Global Financial Stability Report, IMF, April 2012. prav tako želijo poslovati z manj tveganimi institucijami in pri prilagajanju kapitalskih zahtev ne poznajo prilagoditvenega obdobja. Podobna je bila tudi reakcija Evropske bančne agencije (EBA), ki je konec leta 2011 zahtevala od sistemsko pomembnih bank najmanj 9 % prvovrstni kapital, da bi trgom demonstrirale stabilnost pred dodatnimi tveganji. Ta zahteva pomeni v okoliščinah, ko je potreba bank po razdolževanju očitna, še dodaten pritisk na omejevanje kreditiranja in zmanjševanje sredstev.14 Banke morajo sedaj v skladu z usmeritvami EBA na enoto sredstev vzdrževati več kapitala. Poenostavljeno bi bilo trditi, da je pičla kreditna aktivnost evropskih bank med drugim posledica zahtev EBA po višjem kapitalu, zagotovo pa ni le-ta prispevala k lajšanju pritiskov v procesu razdolževanja bank. Morda je tudi zato ECB intervenirala z dolgoročnima operacijama refinanciranja, da bi omilila sicer upravičeno zahtevo regulatorja, a sproženo v neprimernem trenutku. 3. Posebnosti razdolževanja bank v Sloveniji Geneza nevzdržne rasti slovenskega bančnega sektorja do leta 2008 je imela podobne vzroke kot v drugih 80 finančnih sistemih, dodaten pospešek pa so slovenske banke dobile zaradi nekaterih posebnosti, ki jih drugje ni bilo. Slovenski bančni sistem je bil že pred vključitvijo v EU in kasneje v evrsko območje najpomembnejši uvoznik tujih prihrankov, deloma tudi na račun tečajne politike centralne banke, ki je omogočala bankam zamenjavo presežkov tuje valute z rednimi operacijami zamenjave. Banke so tuje prihranke uvažale v obliki kreditov in jih v obliki kreditov tudi posredovale naprej podjetjem. Tuje direktne in portfeljske investicije so bile ob obilici kreditnih sredstev, ki so jih ponujale banke, za podjetja in njihove lastnike nezanimive, še posebej ob dejstvu, da je pri nas potekal drugi val privatizacij podjetij, ki je bil večinoma financiran prav s krediti. Če k temu dodamo še dodatno likvidnost, ki jo je naš bančni sistem dobil z zapadlostjo več kot 3 milijard blagajniških zapisov ob vključitvi v evrsko območje, in nizke oziroma negativno realne obrestne mere, potem lahko ugotovimo, da je bil scenarij »popolnega viharja« pri nas še bolj izpopolnjen. Posledica take- 13 Glej v CEE Banking Sector Report, Raiffeisen Bank, (2013), str. 10. 14 Več o tem v Jašovič (2012). BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING ga scenarija je, da imamo v Sloveniji opravka s podjetniškim sektorjem, ki je med bolj odvisnimi od bančnega financiranja, in na drugi strani bančni sektor, ki ima največji delež kreditov nebančnemu sektorju (podjetjem) v svoji bilanci (glej sliki 1 in 2). V takih razmerah ima gospodarska stagnacija uničujoč vpliv na kvaliteto kreditnih portfeljev bank. Slovenski bančni sektor ima nadpovprečen delež kreditov nebančnemu sektorju (65,4 % konec junija 2013), med katerimi prevladujejo krediti podjetjem. Razdolževanje slovenskih bank bo zato potekalo pretežno prek zmanjševanja kreditov nebančnemu sektorju, zato ne preseneča podatek, da se ta agregat krči že tretje leto zapored. Posledice negativne spirale so zato očitne: negativna ekonomska rast, slabšanje kreditnega portfelja bank, pritisk k razdolževanju in zmanjševanje kreditov podjetjem vodijo v vse slabše razmere v bančništvu, ki se kažejo v naraščajočem deležu nedonosnih terjatev. Prekiniti jo je mogoče z dokapitalizacijo bank in očiščenjem bančnih portfeljev, sočasnim prestrukturiranjem podjetij ter ponovnim zagotavljanjem kreditov nebančnemu sektorju. Za prvo razdobje razdolževanja slovenskih bank je značilno, da so bili sistemski ukrepi države relativno omejeni in da so bile banke pri reševanju tega problema bolj ali manj prepuščene same sebi in svojim lastnikom, ki so izkazali le omejen interes za dokapitalizacijo bank. Pri velikih državnih bankah je bila omejitev predvsem v začetnem podcenjevanju resnosti težav in v politični opredelitvi, da se ohrani domače lastništvo. Pri manjših zasebnih domačih bankah so se tudi lastniki sami znašli v velikih finančnih težavah, te banke pa zaradi majhnosti in tveganosti kreditnega portfelja niso zanimive za tuje vlagatelje. Pri tujih bankah pa so bile potrebe po BV 11/2013 dokapitalizacijah bistveno manjše, omejitve pri financiranju pa so izhajale iz razdolževanja matičnih bank in slabih perspektiv našega bančnega trga glede na alternativne geografske lokacije. Intervencija države je bila omejena in premalo odločna: lajšanje likvidnostnih pritiskov z depoziti državne zakladnice, ki so bili ponujeni vsem bankam, nezadostna in pozna dokapitalizacija državnih bank ter jamstvena shema za kredite podjetjem, ki ni bila pogojena z nujnim restrukturiranjem podjetij. Pritiski na refinanciranje domačih bank so bili sicer omiljeni, pretežno tudi s pomočjo dolgoročnega kredita pri ECB, zaradi katerega sodimo Evropske banke bodo do konca leta 2014 zmanjšale sredstva za 800 milijard EUR. med štiri najbolj zadolžene bančne sisteme pri centralni banki. Omenjeni ukrepi so zagotovili slovenskemu bančnemu sektorju potreben čas za nujno razdolžitev (de-risking), ki pa ni bil izkoriščen. V takšnih razmerah, ko so banke prepuščene same sebi, se problem kapitalske ustreznosti lahko rešuje predvsem z notranjimi ukrepi, ki zmanjšujejo TPA ali povečujejo kapital banke ali oboje hkrati. Pri tem posamezne banke delujejo predvsem kot delniške družbe, ki zasledujejo svoje lastne interese, širše posledice na ekonomsko aktivnost pa niso in ne morejo biti primarna skrb bančnih uprav niti v državnih bankah. V 81 stresnih finančnih razmerah tudi interesi lastnikov lahko postanejo zelo kratkoročno naravnani, uprave bank pa soočene z ultimatom, da prilagodijo obseg poslovanja zmanjšanemu obsegu kapitala zaradi slabitev. Večkrat gre tudi za ukrepe, ki škodijo dolgoročni uspešnosti banke in njeni sposobnosti zagotavljanja kapitala iz lastnega poslovanja v bodoče. Banke tako z agresivnim prilagajanjem poslovanja vse slabši kapitalski ustreznosti škodujejo ne le svojim komitentom in splošni gospodarski aktivnosti, ampak z nekaterimi ukrepi celo svojim lastnim dolgoročnim interesom. Problemi s kapitalsko ustreznostjo povzročijo, da začnejo banke bolj intenzivno iskati notranje rezerve prek znižanja operativnih stroškov, boljšega upravljanja s tveganji, opuščanja slabo donosnih produktov, storitev in aktivnosti ter sprememb v poslovnem modelu. Tovrstni ukrepi krepijo kapital prek tekočega rezultata ali pa znižujejo uteži pri ugotavljanju TPA, vendar glede na resnost razmer niso zadostni ali pa dajejo rezultate šele s časovnim zamikom. Zato so potrebni tudi takojšnji in odločni posegi v bilanco stanja. Možnosti za obsežna zmanjšanja naložb domačih državnih in zasebnih bank so bile že v izhodišču relativno omejene, saj je bilo v bilancah le malo primernih naložb, tržne razmere za njihovo prodajo pa neugodne. Najbolj učinkovite za izboljšanje kapitalske ustreznosti so prodaje odvisnih finančnih družb. Nekatere domače banke v težavah so tako uspele prodati svoje deleže v družbah za upravljanje in v zavarovalnicah, medtem ko so bili poskusi prodaje omejenega števila hčerinskih bank v Sloveniji in v tujini neuspešni. Tudi možnosti za prodajo tržnih naložb, zaseženega finančnega premoženja in nepremičnin ter zdravih bančnih terjatev so bile zaradi slabih tržnih razmer zelo otežene. Možnosti za nakup zavarovanj za obstoječi MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING kreditni portfelj na trgu ali pri državi pri nas, v nasprotju z drugimi bolj razvitimi in proaktivnimi državami v EU, praktično ni bilo. Kreditna in tržna tveganja so tako v času krize in upada ekonomske aktivnosti večinoma ostajala v bilancah bank in neposredno vplivala na zniževanje kapitalske ustreznosti. Ko postane poglavitni cilj poslovanja banke vzdrževanje kapitalske ustreznosti, v banki dokončno prevlada regulatorna logika nad ekonomsko logiko. Vsaka prodaja pod knjižno vrednostjo ima poleg vpliva na zmanjšanje TPA tudi vpliv na zmanjšanje kapitala in včasih je z vidika kapitalske ustreznosti bolje, da se s tako naložbo ne zgodi nič, kar bi pokvarilo trenutno sliko v bilancah. Po drugi strani je vsaka prodaja naložbe nad knjižno vrednostjo z vidika trenutne kapitalske ustreznosti ugodna, ker znižuje TPA in hkrati generira dodatni kapital, pa čeprav je moč pričakovati še višjo ceno že v bližnji prihodnosti. Podobna regulatorna logika prevlada tudi na strani obveznosti pri predčasnem odkupu podrejenih instrumentov z diskontom, ki so ga že izvedle največje domače banke. Realizirani enkratni dobički so tako z vidika trenutne kapitalske ustreznosti dobrodošli, saj povečajo najbolj kvalitetne sestavine kapitala, pa čeprav se obseg celotnega regulatornega kapitala pri tem zmanjšuje, »striženje« investitorjev pa tudi še dodatno zmanjšuje možnosti, da bi se take banke lahko v bližnji prihodnosti dokapitalizirale ali financirale na finančnih trgih. Pomemben način ohranjanja kapitalske ustreznosti je tudi odlašanje s slabitvami ter podaljševanje kreditov komitentom v težavah. Tako se reševanje nakopičenih finančnih težav le odlaga v prihodnost, ko bodo možne rešitve za banko in komitenta verjetno še bolj neugodne. V razmerah samosanacije bank ostane kot najpomembnejši način zmanjšanja TPA zmanjševanja kreditne izpostavljenosti do dobrih komitentov, ki so še sposobni vračati kredite. Gre torej za tipičen primer »slabega« razdolževanja bank, ko je večji del bančne bilance zamrznjen v težko prodajljivih naložbah in slabih terjatvah, kreditne omejitve pa občutijo predvsem finančno zdrava podjetja. Po drugi strani so takšne banke še naprej dejansko podkapitalizirane in izpostavljene velikim kreditnim, tržnim in likvidnostnim tveganjem, stroški njihovega vedno bolj omejenega financiranja so visoki, prihodki pri znižanem obsegu poslovanja pa upadajo hitreje, kot se lahko znižujejo operativni stroški. Ker gre za sistemsko pomembne banke Slovenski bančni sektor ima nadpovprečen delež kreditov nebančnemu sektorju. ali za sistemsko pomemben del bančnega sektorja, postane organizirana intervencija države kot varuha finančne stabilnosti le še vprašanje časa. 4. Sklepne misli Slovenija se je šele v letu 2012 odločila, da se bo sistematično lotila očiščenja sistemsko pomembnih bank s prenosom slabih terjatev na slabo banko in glede na potrebe zagotovila tem bankam dovolj dodatnega kapitala s strani države.15 Pri tem ji pozno ukrepanje nikakor ne bo v pomoč, saj se v EU po izhodu iz krize že vzpostavlja nov sistem 82 za reševanje bank, ki ga bo treba upoštevati tudi pri nas in je deloma že vgrajen v bančno zakonodajo.16 V okviru novih pravil za dodeljevanje državnih pomoči finančnim institucijam bo treba zagotoviti, da del bremen sanacije poleg lastnikov prevzamejo tudi podrejeni upniki.17 V pravice velikih deponentov in drugih nezavarovanih navadnih upnikov se torej zaenkrat še ne posega, medtem ko je položaj lastnikov zaradi državnega lastništva naših sistemskih bank dokaj nenavaden. Drugje v EU, kjer je država reševala predvsem zasebne banke, so vrednosti prenesenih slabih terjatev, ki določajo potreben obseg državne dokapitalizacije in tudi cene delnice ob dokapitalizaciji, odločilne z vidika državnih pomoči, pravičnosti porazdelitve bremen in skupnih stroškov intervencije za državo. Pri nas bo država v javnem interesu reševala sistemsko pomembne državne banke, pri tem pa »razlastila« predvsem sama sebe. V okviru nastajanja enotnega evropskega bančnega nadzora bo treba po večkratnih skrbnih pregledih aktive naših sistemskih bank, pred prenosom slabih terjatev, opraviti še standardizirane preglede kvalitete sredstev (AQR) in stresne teste, ki naj bi povečali mednarodno kredibilnost te operacije. Zamude, ki so povzročene tudi od zunaj, povzročajo dodatno škodo, saj se finančne razmere v bankah in podjetjih poslabšujejo, nihče pa ni v vmesnem času pripravljen sprejemati nobenih pomembnih odločitev. V času priprav na sanacijo sistemskih bank je bil sprožen še postopek nad- 15 Zakon o ukrepih Republike Slovenije za krepitev stabilnosti bank (ZUKSB) predvideva za sanacijo bank ustanovitev Družbe za upravljanje terjatev bank (DUTB) kot sistemske »slabe banke«. Bistvo sprejetega modela »slabe banke« je v prenosu »slabega« premoženja banke na DUTB, ki v zameno zagotovi banki nadomestilo v obliki obveznic, za katere jamči RS. 16 Več o tem glej v M. Simoneti, J. Radež (2013). 17 Glej European Commission (2013). BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING ziranega prenehanja dveh manjših bank z uporabo državnih sredstev, ki so bila sicer prvotno predvidena za sistemske banke. Ali so odgovorni ugotovili, da so razmere že tako resne in medsebojno prepletene, da je že vsaka banka sistemsko pomembna? Vprašanje, kakšen bo potem skupni fiskalni strošek sanacije bank in ali ga bo država sposobna financirati brez uradne prošnje za mednarodno pomoč, je tako še povsem odprto. Z vidika dobre izvedbe projektov sanacije bank in podjetij je to tudi precej vseeno. Ne glede na vse zaplete bo treba napovedani projekt sanacije bank zdaj izvesti do konca. Za njegov pozitiven učinek na gospodarsko aktivnost pa bo bistveno, kako hitro bodo prestrukturirane slabe terjatve bank do prezadolženih podjetij. V Sloveniji namreč velja visoka odvisnost poslovanja bank od poslovanja podjetij: brez sanacije podjetij ni dokončne sanacije bank in nasprotno. Komu bodo posojale očiščene in dokapitalizirane banke, če bodo podjetja z dobrimi programi ostala še naprej prezadolžena? Prenos slabih terjatev na DUTB bo sicer omogočil delno koncentracijo terjatev do velikih dolžnikov na tej instituciji, za katero veljajo tudi nekatere zakonske izjeme, kar naj bi omogočilo bolj učinkovito reševanje problema prezadolženosti podjetij. Toda velik del slabih terjatev bo ostal v bilancah drugih bank in za sanacijo posameznih podjetij bo treba doseči koordinirano ravnanje številnih bank upnic. Zato poleg individualnih ukrepov za posamične banke predlagamo tudi linearne ukrepe, ki bi bili vezani na pomembnejše dolžnike, s čimer bi nastale močne spodbude za aktiven nastop vseh bank v sistemu za aktivno prestrukturiranje prezadolženih podjetij. Odprle bi se tudi dodatne možnosti za uporabo regulatorno neugodnih konverzij bančnih terjatev z namenom poznejBV 11/2013 še prodaje dolžnika pod ugodnejšimi pogoji.18 Tudi prezadolžena slovenska podjetja potrebujejo kapital, ki ga na dolgi rok lahko v zadostnem obsegu zagotovijo le tuji investitorji, konverzije bančnih terjatev pa so le pragmatičen vmesni korak do tega cilja. Pri prenosih na slabo banko pa se je treba zavedati, da so sredstva države omejena. Če bodo predmet prenosa predvsem terjatve do podjetij, ki so že v stečajnih postopkih, bo pozitiven učinek za bančne bilance izbranih sistemskih bank večji, učinek na sanacijo podjetij pa zelo omejen. Če bodo predmet prenosa predvsem še »žive« terjatve do posameznih pomembnih dolžnikov iz celotnega bančnega sistema, pa bo neposredni pozitivni učinek na bančne bilance manjši, koristi za sanacijo podjetij pa večje. Dilema je velika, vendar čiščenje bančnih bilanc brez pozitivnih učinkov za razdolževanje podjetij za Slovenijo gotovo ni prava pot. Tuje banke, ki imajo vodilno vlogo pri prestrukturiranju podjetij v državah CEE, ki so nam po nastanku, globini in dolgotrajnosti gospodarske krize dokaj podobne, so izvedle široko medbančno konzultacijo o pridobljenih izkušnjah pri upravljanju s slabimi terjatvami. Nastala so priporočila za ravnanje bank in za vzpostavitev ustreznega institucionalnega okolja za hitro in učinkovito prestrukturiranje dolžnikov, ki so zelo zanimiva tudi za slovenske razmere.19 Predlaga se proaktiven, kooperativen in celovit način s številnimi ukrepi za odpravljanje različnih ovir za aktivno prestrukturiranje slabih kreditov: ustanovitev posebne skupine za koordinacijo projekta, realno ovrednotenje slabih terjatev in zavarovanj v bankah in odprava bančnih regulatornih ovir. Med slednjimi omenjajo možnosti za neposreden prevzem zastavljenega premoženja in korporacijske kontrole nad dolžniki, ustanavljanje posebnih družb za prestrukturiranje, izboljša83 nje postopkov izterjave, podpora zunajsodnemu prestrukturiranju, izboljšanje insolvenčnih postopkov, izboljšanje dela sodišč, odprava davčnih ovir in kolektiven pristop bank do dolžnikov v okviru bančnega združenja. Priporoča se tudi, da se država neposredno ne vmešava v prestrukturiranje slabih terjatev, ampak se omeji le na vzpostavitev ustreznega okolja za iskanje zasebnih rešitev med bankami in dolžniki. V Sloveniji bo zaradi državnega lastništva bank in prenosa slabih terjatev na osrednjo državno slabo banko pristop že v osnovi precej drugačen, vendar so glavne ovire v institucionalnem okolju za učinkovito izvedbo projekta prestrukturiranja dolžnikov verjetno zelo podobne. LITERATURA IN VIRI/REFERENCES: Banka Slovenije (2013). Poročilo o finančni stabilnosti. Ljubljana: Banka Slovenije. European Banking Authority (2013). Risk Assessment of the European Banking System., London: European Banking Authority. Berglöf, E., Korniyenko, Y., Plekhanov, A., & Zettelmeyer, J. (2009). Understanding the crisis in emerging Europe. EBRD Working Paper No. 109. London: EBRD. Brown, M., Lane, P. R. (2011). Debt Overhang in Emerging Europe? The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper 5784. Washington D.C.: The World Bank. Caballero, R., Hoshi, T., & Kashyap, A. (2008). Zombie lending and depressed restructuring in Japan. American Economic Review, No 98(5). CESEE Deleveraging Monitor, Vienna Initiative, November 9, 2012. European Commission (2013). Communication from the Commission on the Application, from 1 August 2013, of State Aid Rules to Support Measures in Favour of Banks in the Context of the Financial Crisis (»Banking Communication«). Brussels: European Commission. European Central Bank (2013). Financial 18 Več o ekonomsko smiselni institucionalni povezavi med sanacijo bank in podjetij glej v B. Jašovič, M. Simoneti (2013) in M. Simoneti, B. Jašovič (2013) 19 Glej Working Group on NPLs in Central, Eastern and Southestern Europe, Vienna Initiative, March 2012, in publikacije IMF in Svetovne banke: Yan Liu and Christoph B. Rosenberg, (2013) in Jose M. Garrido, (2012). MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING Stability Review. Frankfurt: European Central Bank. Feyen, E., Kibuuka, K., & Ötker-Robe, I. (2012). Bank Deleveraging: Causes, Channels, and Consequences for Emerging Market and Developing Countries. Policy Research Working Paper 6086. Washington D.C.: The World Bank. Gardó, S. & Martin, R. (2010). The impact of the global economic and financial crisis on central, eastern and southeastern Europe: A stock-taking exercise. ECB, Occasional Paper series No. 114. Frankfurt: ECB. Garrido, J. M. (2012). Out-of-Court Debt Restructuring. V A World Bank Study. Washington D.C.: World Bank. Haldane, A. (2012). The Dog and the Frisbee. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City's 366thEconomic Policy Symposium, Jackson Hole, Wyoming. International Monetary Fund (2012). Global Financial Stability Review. Washington: D.C.: International Monetary Fund. Jašovič, B., & Simoneti, M. (2013, 14. maj). Sanacija bank ter razdolževanje podjetij in bank. Ljubljana: Časnik Finance. Jašovič, B. (2012). Dokapitalizacija bank in kreditna aktivnost. Bančni vestnik, 61 (11), 69 – 76. Liu, Y. and Rosenberg, C. B. (2013). Dealing with Private Debt Distress in the Wake of the European Financial Crisis. A Review of the Economics and Legal Toolbox. IMF Working Paper. Washington D.C.: IMF. Raiffeisen Bank (2013). CEE Banking Sector Report. Vienna: Raiffeisen Bank. Ruscher, E., & Guntram, B. Wolff, G. B. (2012). Corporate balance sheet adjustment: stylized facts, causes and consequences. European Commission, Economic Papers 449. Brussels: European 84 Commission. Simoneti, M., & Jašovič, B., Prestrukturiranje podjetij s strani bank upnic: kako skupaj iz blokade? Bančni vestnik, letnik 62, št. 7-8, str. 9-17, julij-avgust 2013. Simoneti, M. & Radež, J. (2013). Krizni institucionalni okvir za prestrukturiranje bank in podjetij: kako naprej? Podjetje in delo, leto 39. Tang, G. & Upper, C. (2010). Debt reduction after crises. BIS Quarterly Review, Basel: BIS. Vienna Initiative (2012). Working Group on NPLs in Central, Eastern and Southestern Europe. Vinals, J., Pazarbasioglu, C., Surti, J., Narain, A., Erbenova, M., & Chow, Julian (2013). Act Local But Think Global: Can the Volcker, Vickers, and Liikanen Structural Measures Create a Safer Financial System? IMF Staff Discussion Note. Washington D.C.: IMF. BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING UDK 338.124.4(497.4):336.71 Zadolženost slovenske ekonomije in kreditna vrzel Marjan Hafner in Urška Lušina* INDEBTEDNESS OF SLOVENIAN ECONOMY AND CREDIT-TO-GDP GAP Slovenia is classified among the most affected Member States in the Euro Area by the last financial crisis, which according to our estimates is also a result of unfavorable financial structure of the Slovenian corporate sector. The corporate sector is above average dependent on debt financing. Since financial resources are highly limited, enterprises are forced to deal with financial difficulties connected with debt repayments instead of focusing on their core business, which further reduces economic activity. Limited access to finance even for the less indebted Slovenian enterprises due to the poor situation in Slovenian banks also significantly contributes to the poor economic situation. We find that the lending activity in Slovenia is highly pro-cyclical. In the period of economic expansion the privatesector credit-to-GDP gap was positive, whereas in the period of financial crisis, especially since the last quarter of 2009, it has been negative and more pronounced than in the euro area. S lovenija se v zadnji finančni krizi uvršča med bolj prizadete države članice evrskega območja, kar je po naši oceni tudi posledica neugodne finančne strukture slovenskega gospodarstva. To je namreč nadpovprečno odvisno od dolžniških virov financiranja. V času izredno omejenih virov financiranja se tako podjetja pretežno ukvarjajo le s finančnimi težavami poveznimi z odplačevanjem dolgov, medtem ko je njihova osnovna dejavnost potisnjena v ozadje, kar dodatno duši gospodarsko aktivnost. K slabim gospodarskim razmeram pa pomembno prispeva tudi slabo stanje v slovenskih bankah, z omejevanjem dostopa do virov financiranja tudi manj zadolženim gospodarskim subjektom. Ugotavljamo, da je bila kreditna aktivnost v Sloveniji izrazito prociklična. V času konjunkture je bila kreditna vrzel pozitivna, v času finančne krize pa je kreditna vrzel vse od zadnjega četrtletja leta 2009 negativna in bolj izrazita kot v evrskem območju. Slovenska podjetja in NFI so v primerjavi z EMU nadpovprečno zadolžena. Čeprav se je obseg kreditov, najetih pri domačih bankah, v obdobju od leta 2010 do leta 2012 precej znižal (za približno 12 %) in je le še za približno 5 % nad ravnijo iz leta 2007, je zadolženost slovenskega gospodarstva še vedno precej nad predkrizno ravnijo. To je v prvi vrsti posledica občutnejšega krčenja kapitala v podjetjih in NFI zaradi negativnih gibanj na kapitalskih trgih. Tudi poslovni rezultati podjetij niso več dopuščali krepitve kapitalske osnove slovenskega gospodarstva, kar je občutneje povečalo kazalnik zadolženosti slovenskega gospodarstva. JEL G01 G21 G28 O1 * Marjan Hafner in Urška Lušina, Urad RS za makroekonomske analize in razvoj. BV 11/2013 85 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING Slika 1: Zadolženost podjetij in NFI v Sloveniji in EMU 160 140 120 100 V% 80 60 40 2004 1 Podatki za druge države članice EMU se nanašajo na leto 2011. 2 Vključena so samo podjetja, ki so v obdobju od leta 2006 do leta 2011 imela finančne obveznosti do bank. Samo ta podjetja predstavljajo tveganje za slabšanje kakovosti bančne aktive. Preučevali smo jo na podlagi individualnih podatkov iz bilance stanja in izkaza poslovnega izida gospodarskih družb v Sloveniji, ki jih zbira Agencija Republike Slovenije za javnopravne evidence in storitve (v nadaljevanju AJPES) za obdobje od 2006 do 2011. Ta baza vključuje vse gospodarske družbe v Sloveniji, pri čemer so od leta prijave stečajnega postopka dalje iz baze izključene vse gospodarske družbe, ki so v stečajnem postopku, saj niso več zavezane k oddaji zaključnih računov. Iz baze smo izločili ekstremne vrednosti, pri katerih je bila rast finančnih obveznosti podjetij do bank več kot 50.000-odstotna, in holdinge, saj bi nam lahko ta podjetja popačila sliko dejanskega stanja na področju kreditiranja slovenskih podjetij. Končni vzorec za celotno bazo vsebuje 28.014 podjetij s povprečnim štiriletnim časovnim horizontom (kar pomeni 112.056 enot), ki so v obdobju 2006– 2011 v povprečju predstavljala 85,6 % finančnih obveznosti do bank vseh gospodarskih družb, ki so v bazi podatkov. 2006 2007 2008 Ostali dolg 2009 2010 EMU Slovenija EMU Slovenija EMU Slovenija EMU Slovenija EMU Slovenija EMU Slovenija EMU Slovenija 2005 Krediti 2011 2012 Dolžniški vrednostni papirji Vir: BS, Eurostat, preračuni UMAR. Slika 2: Delež dolga v virih sredstev (v %), razmerje med dolgom in EBITDA ter donosnost sredstev (ROA) podjetij zasebnega sektorja, v obdobju 2006–2011 7 60 64.1 61.3 67.5 66.7 66.9 65.7 ROA (desna os) 6 50 5 40 4 30 3 20 8.0 10 9.8 8.6 12.5 12.5 11.4 2 1 0 0 -10 V% 70 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Delež dolga v virih sredstev Dolg na EBITDA -1 Vir: AJPES, preračuni UMAR. Slika 3: Delež finančnih obveznosti do bank in poslovne obveznosti do dobaviteljev v virih sredstev podjetij zasebnega sektorja, v obdobju 2006–2011 40 30 33.7 34 35 33.6 34.5 30.8 27.7 25 V% Zadolženost podjetniškega sektorja v Sloveniji, ki ima finančne obveznosti do bank, merjena kot razmerje med dolgom in obveznostmi do virov sredstev, se v času krize ni bistveno znižala. Dolg je tako predstavljal približno dve tretjini vseh obveznosti do virov sredstev. Več kot polovico celotnega dolga podjetniškega sektorja pa so predstavljale finančne obveznosti do bank, ki so v času krize znašale okrog 34 % vseh obveznosti do virov sredstev. Pomembne so tudi obveznosti do dobaviteljev, a se je njihov delež v zadnjih letih nekoliko znižal, kar je po naši presoji posledica manjšega obsega poslovanja. V strukturi finančnih odhodkov podjetij, ki imajo finančne obveznosti do bank, prevladujejo odhodki iz posojil, prejetih od bank (v letu 2011 EMU Slovenija 0 EMU 20 Zadolženost podjetij,2 ki so imela finančne obveznosti do bank Slovenija Celotna zadolženost podjetij, merjena kot razmerje med celotnim dolgom in kapitalom, je bila tako leta 2012 na ravni okrog 130 %, kar je sicer za približno 10 o. t. manj kot leta 2011. Bolj zadolžena od slovenskih so le še podjetja in NFI v Grčiji, Italiji in Španiji.1 20 15 14.4 14 13 12.1 12.3 11.7 10 5 0 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Finančne obveznosti do bank v virih sredstev Poslovne obveznosti do dobaviteljev v virih sredstev Vir: AJPES, preračuni UMAR. 86 BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING Analiza zadolženosti podjetij po velikosti4 Najbolj so zadolžena mikro, najmanj pa velika podjetja. Pri mikro podjetjih zadolženost, merjena kot delež dolga v virih sredstev, presega 80 % in se v času krize ni občutneje znižala. Mala in srednja podjetja so nekoliko manj zadolžena, delež dolga v virih sredstev se giblje okrog 70 %. Prva so svojo zadolženost v času krize konstantno zniževala. Ta je bila leta 2011 za 3,3 o. t. nižja kot pred krizo. Srednja podjetja pa so zadolženost v prvem letu krize najprej povišala, nato pa so jo začela zmanjševati. Njihova zadolženost je bila leta 2011 za 3,5 o. t. nižja kot pred krizo. Daleč najmanj so zadolžena velika podjetja, pri katerih delež dolga dosega le dobro polovico njihovih virov sredstev in je v času krize upadel za 1,3 o. t. Glede na razmerje med dolgom in EBITDA so bila najbolj zadolžena mikro podjetja, ki so imela vrednost kazalnika 26, najmanj pa velika podjetja, ki so imela vrednost kazalnika na ravni okrog 7. BV 11/2013 Slika 4: Delež finančnih obveznosti do bank v virih sredstev po ročnosti in njihova rast po velikostnih razredih v podjetjih zasebnega sektorja, v letih 2008 in 2011 2008 2011 Delež zadolževanja po ročnosti KR DR Skupaj KR DR Skupaj KR Srednja p. (51–250) Velika p. (>250) DR Skupaj KR Mikro p. (<5) Mala p. (6–50) DR 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 -5 -10 -15 Skupaj V% so imela podjetja 1,9-odstotni delež teh odhodkov v prihodkih), precej manj pa je odhodkov povezanih z drugimi viri financiranja (posojila, ki jih prejmejo od družb v skupini in z izdajanjem obveznic). Delež odhodkov od posojil, prejetih od bank, se je sicer v času krize nekoliko znižal, a je bilo znižanje precej skromno in bi po naši presoji lahko bilo večje glede na intenzivnost zniževanja osrednje obrestne mere ECB. Finančni odhodki od posojil, prejetih od bank, so tako dosegali okrog 2 % prihodkov od podjetij, kar je za približno 0,5 o. t. manj od najvišje ravni iz leta 2008. Visoko ostaja tudi razmerje med dolgom in EBITDA,3 ki kaže na (ne)sposobnost podjetij za odplačevanje dolgov, ki je bilo v letu 2011 na ravni 11,4. 2008 2011 Rast dolga po ročnosti Vir: AJPES, preračuni UMAR. Mikro, mala in srednja podjetja so najbolj odvisna od bančnih kreditov in ravno te skupine imajo močno omejen dostop do tovrstnega načina financiranja. V teh treh skupinah predstavljajo finančne obveznosti do bank v povprečju 38 % virov sredstev, medtem ko je pri velikih podjetjih ta delež v povprečju 25-odstoten. V času krize so mikro, mala in srednja podjetja znižala delež zadolževanja prek bank, medtem ko se je le-ta pri velikih podjetjih še celo za malenkost okrepil (za 0,4 o. t.). Slednje je posledica upada obsega virov sredstev, ki je bil leta 2011 malenkost višji od upada finančnih obveznosti do bank (ta je bil skoraj pol nižji kot pri drugih podjetjih). Še naprej se krepi delež dolgoročnih finančnih obveznosti5 do bank. Po letu 2008 je v vseh skupinah podjetij prišlo do krepitve dolgoročnih finančnih obveznosti do bank. To je po naši presoji predvsem posledica prestrukturiranja kratkoročnega dolga v dolgoročnega. Banke so tako blažile likvidnostne pritiske na podjetja. 87 Analiza zadolženosti podjetij po izvozni usmerjenosti6 Analiza zadolženosti podjetij, merjena kot razmerje med dolgom in obveznostmi do virov sredstev, glede na njihovo izvozno usmerjenost, je pokazala, da so podjetja, ki so usmerjena na domači trg, bolj zadolžena. V obdobju krize se je sicer znižala zadolženost tako neizvoznim (za 1 o. t.) kot tudi izvoznim podjetjem (za 2,8 o. t.), vendar je bila dinamika različna. Pri izvoznikih se 3 EBITDA je določen kot dobiček/izguba iz poslovanja, povečan za amortizacijo. 4 V nadaljevanju prikazujemo rezultate analize zadolženosti slovenskih podjetij, ki so imela finančne obveznosti do bank po velikosti. Mikro podjetja imajo do 5 zaposlenih, mala od 6 do 50, srednja od 51 do 250, velika pa nad 250 zaposlenih. V celotni bazi imamo 58 % mikro, 34 % malih, 6 % srednjih in 2 % velikih podjetij. Vseh zaposlenih je v povprečju 316.276, in sicer jih je v mikro podjetjih v povprečju 13.815 (4 %), v malih podjetjih okrog 68.456 (22 %), v srednjih podjetjih okrog 81.440 (26 %), v velikih podjetjih pa 152.565 (48 %). 5 Obseg dolgoročnih finančnih obveznosti do bank se je sicer v letu 2011 zniževal, a je bilo znižanje manjše kot pri kratkoročnih obveznostih. 6 Izvozno usmerjene so družbe, v katerih prihodki od prodaje na tujih trgih presegajo prihodke od prodaje na domačem trgu. V celotni bazi imamo 10 % izvozno usmerjenih in 90 % na domači trg usmerjenih družb, slednje pa predstavljajo okrog 65 % dodane vrednosti vseh gospodarskih družb, ki so imele finančne obveznosti do bank. MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING Slika 5: Delež finančnih obveznosti do bank v virih sredstev in rast dolga po izvozni usmerjenosti podjetij zasebnega sektorja, v letih 2008 in 2011 40 Izvozniki Neizvozniki 30 V% 20 10 0 2008 2011 2008 Delež zadolževanja po ročnosti KR DR Skupaj KR DR Skupaj KR DR Skupaj KR DR -20 Skupaj -10 2011 Rast dolga po ročnosti Vir: AJPES, preračuni UMAR. Slika 6: Delež finančnih obveznosti do bank in poslovnih obveznosti do dobaviteljev v virih sredstev, v obdobju 2009–2011 45 Predelovalne dejavnosti Gradbeništvo Trgovina Nepremičnine 40 35 30 V% je zadolženost v letih 2010 in 2011 že nekoliko okrepila, kar povezujemo predvsem z oživljanjem izvoznih trgov. Rast zadolženosti pri izvoznikih je pretežno posledica prirasta obveznosti do dobaviteljev, medtem ko so podjetja v celotnem obdobju krize zmanjševala obseg bančnih posojil. Zadolženost neizvoznikov se je v prvih dveh letih krize najprej krepila (za skoraj 1 o. t.) in se šele v letu 2011 znižala (za skoraj 2 o. t.). Zniževanje zadolženosti pri neizvoznikih je tako posledica manjšega obsega bančnih posojil kot tudi manjšega obsega obveznosti do dobaviteljev. Zadolženost, merjena kot razmerje med dolgom in EBITDA, se je pri izvoznikih že leta 2010 znižala na predkrizno raven (7,2), leta 2011 pa se je še za malenkost znižala (6,9). Pri neizvoznikih je še vedno za dobro četrtino višja kot leta 2008, ko je bila na ravni 11,2. Neizvozniki so tudi bolj odvisni od bančnega financiranja. Delež finančnih obveznosti do bank je tako za dobrih 8 o. t. višji kot pri izvoznikih. V letu 2011 se je zaustavilo tudi dolgoročno kreditiranje neizvoznikov, medtem ko so pri izvoznikih dolgoročne finančne obveznosti do bank še vedno naraščale, a je bil njihov delež kljub temu precej nižji kot pri neizvoznikih. 25 20 15 10 5 0 2009 2010 2011 Fin. obv. do bank v virih sredstev 2009 2010 2011 Obv. do dobaviteljev v virih sredstev Vir: AJPES, preračuni UMAR. Analiza zadolženosti podjetij po dejavnostih7 Analiza zadolževanja zasebnega sektorja po dejavnostih kaže, da so bila v obdobju 2006–2011 najbolj zadolžena podjetja v dejavnostih finančnega posredništva, gradbeništva, trgovine in poslovanja z nepremičninami, najemom in poslovnimi storitvami (v nadaljevanju nepremičnine).8 Delež dolga v virih sredstev se je v obdobju pred krizo (2006– 2008) povečeval v vseh panogah, v letih 2009–2011 pa je bilo gibanje zadolženosti precej neenotno. Znižala se je v dejavnostih nepremičnin, gradbeništva, predelovalnih dejavnostih, medtem ko so se v drugih dejavnostih prirasti zadolženosti precej umirili. Eden izmed vzrokov za zniževanje zadolženosti v najbolj zadolženih dejavnostih je tudi propadanje podjetij iz teh dejavnosti (prijava stečajnega postopka), zaradi česar ta podjetja od začetka stečajnega postopka niso več oddala zaključnih računov in od tega leta dalje niso zajeta v bazi podatkov. To ne pomeni manjšega pritiska teh 88 podjetij do bank, saj terjatve do teh podjetij ostajajo v bančnih bilancah, obenem pa banke zanje okrepljeno oblikujejo dodatne oslabitve in rezervacije. Banka Slovenije tako v Poročilu o finančni stabilnosti (2013, 7 Zaradi večje konsistentnosti vzorca so podatki razvrščeni po SKD 2002. 8 Poleg teh bolj zadolženih dejavnosti smo nekoliko podrobneje analizirali tudi predelovalne dejavnosti, ki predstavljajo pomemben del slovenskega gospodarstva. Delež zajema v finančnem posredništvu je izredno skromen, saj v bazi ni podatkov za banke niti za zavarovalnice, ki predstavljajo pretežen del dejavnosti. Zaradi tega finančnega posredništva nismo podrobneje analizirali. BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING BV 11/2013 15 150 10 100 5 50 0 0 V% Slika 7: Razmerje med dolgom zasebnega sektorja in BDP in njegov trend za Slovenijo (levo) ter primerjava dolžniških vrzeli za Slovenijo in EMU Q1 12 Q1 11 Q1 10 Q1 06 Q1 09 -100 Q1 08 -10 Q1 07 -50 Q1 05 -5 Q1 04 V o.t. str. 65) ugotavlja, da med nedonosnimi terjatvami bank z velikim in naraščajočim deležem izstopajo nedonosne terjatve do podjetij v stečajnih postopkih. Teh terjatev je bilo marca za 2,6 mrd EUR oziroma 48 % vseh nedonosnih terjatev do nefinančnih podjetij v primerjavi z 38 % v decembru 2011. V vseh razvrščenih terjatvah do nefinančnih podjetij predstavljajo podjetja v stečaju 11,7-odstotni delež. Razmerje med dolgom in EBITDA, ki kaže na sposobnost podjetij za odplačevanje dolgov, se je v času krize predvsem v najbolj zadolženih dejavnostih močno povečalo, kar kaže na njihove povečane težave z odplačevanjem zapadlih obveznosti. Krepitev je posledica tega, da se je v obdobju 2009–2011 obseg prostega denarnega toka znižal skoraj za petino.9 Leta 2011 se je razmerje med dolgom in EBITDA v nekoliko podrobneje analiziranih dejavnostih gibalo na ravni med 7 (predelovalne dejavnosti) in 56 (gradbeništvo). Med izpostavljenimi dejavnostmi imata največji delež finančnih obveznosti do bank v virih sredstev dejavnosti gradbeništva in nepremičnin. V gradbeništvu se je še celo nekoliko povečal, medtem ko se je celotna zadolženost v tej dejavnosti zaradi manjšega deleža obveznosti do dobaviteljev10 znižala. Večji delež finančnih obveznosti do bank pa je predvsem posledica močnega krčenja virov sredstev, medtem ko je bilo znižanje obsega finančnih obveznosti do bank nižje (približno 15-odstotno).11 Struktura ročnosti zadolževanja se je v vseh izpostavljenih dejavnostih s krizo začela spreminjati v prid dolgoročnega zadolževanja razen v gradbeništvu, kjer še naprej prevladujejo kratkoročni krediti, kljub stalni rasti deleža dolgoročnih kreditov. V nasprotju s preteklimi leti pa je v letu 2011 prišlo tudi do zniževanja Razmerje med dolgom ZS in BDP – SLO (desna os) Trend – SLO (desna os) Dolžniška vrzel – SLO (leva os) Dolžniška vrzel – EMU (leva os) Vir: BS, ECB, SURS, preračuni UMAR. Opomba: ZS - zasebni sektor. obsega dolgoročnih finančnih obveznosti do bank, kar je po naši presoji posledica tega, da so banke zelo omejile prestrukturiranje kratkoročnih kreditov v dolgoročne; njihovo znižanje pa je še vedno na precej nižji ravni kot pri kratkoročnih. Dolžniška vrzel zasebnega sektorja Dolžniška vrzel zasebnega sektorja (angl. credit-to-GDP gap) je instrument makrobonitetnega nadzora12 nad finančnim sistemom posamezne države ali skupine držav. Prikazuje spreminjanje sistemskega tveganja v času (angl. time-varying systemic risk) in je pomemben z dveh vidikov. Prvi je zgodnje odkrivanje morebitnih kopičenj neravnovesij in ranljivosti, tako da bi lahko že v obdobju gospodarske in finančne ekspanzije vzpostavili mehanizme in sprejeli določene ukrepe, ki bi preprečili pretirano krčenje v času finančnih in gospodarskih kriz. Drugi vidik pa je 89 povezan z nakazovanjem, kdaj naj bi se kriza končala in se bo tako v gospodarstvo kot tudi na finančne trge vrnila določena vzdržna rast ter ne bo več potrebe po različnih preventivnih mehanizmih in ukrepih. Raziskave kažejo,13 da so kazalniki, ki prikazujejo prekomerno rast dolga, dober napovedovalnik prihodnjega tveganja nezmožnosti poplačila kredita s strani posojilojemalcev. Bank of England (2011) v svoji študiji sicer opozarja, da se ti kazalniki izkažejo kot dober napovedovalnik prihodnjih gibanj v času konjunkture, 9 Obseg EBITDA se je v prvih dveh letih krize zniževal (predvsem leta 2009), v letu 2011 pa se je zvišal za skoraj 6 %. 10 Njihov pomen je v primerjavi z drugimi dejavnostmi še vedno razmeroma velik. 11 Krčenje vseh vrst virov sredstev je po naši oceni tudi posledica propada nekaterih večjih gradbenih podjetij, ki zato niso več vključena v bazo podatkov. 12 Makrobonitetni nadzor (angl. macroprudential supervision) preprečuje finančno nestabilnost kot posledico makroekonomskega razvoja in razvoja v celotnem finančnem sistemu. 13 Borio in Lowe, 2002 in 2004; Derehmann, M., Borio, C., Gambacorta, L., Jiménez, G., Trucharte, C., 2010; Schularick in Taylor, 2012. MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING medtem ko se nagibajo k zaostajanju v času krize, tako da je treba biti previden pri njihovi uporabi. Kljub temu pa je baselski odbor za bančni nadzor predlagal uvedbo rednega spremljanja dolžniške vrzeli zasebnega sektorja kot osnovnega vodila za kalibracijo in uvedbo proticikličnih kapitalskih blažilnikov v skladu s sporazumom Basel III. Dolžniška vrzel zasebnega sektorja je razlika, izražena v odstotnih točkah, in sicer med kazalnikom, ki meri razmerje med dolgom zasebnega sektorja in BDP, ter njegovim dolgoročnim trendom. Za izračun slednjega je baselski odbor za bančni nadzor priporočil uporabo enostranskega Hodrick-Prescottovega filtra14 s parametrom za glajenje v višini 400.00015 (za podrobnosti glede izračuna glej Basel Committe on Banking Supervision, 2010). Na ravni EU pa je začel izračunavati dolžniško vrzel tudi evropski odbor za sistemska tveganja (angl. European Systemic Risk Board, ESRB), ki jo uporablja kot enega izmed kazalnikov pri ocenjevanju makroekonomskih tveganj. Njihovi rezultati se razlikujejo od naših zaradi razlik pri opredelitvi mere za dolg, kjer oni uporabljajo ožjo opredelitev (tj. dolžniške vrednostne papirje in posojila nefinančnih družb), ter zaradi uporabe različnega filtra za izračun dolgoročnega trenda (za podrobnejšo razlago uporabljenega filtra glej Alessi in Detken, 2011). Kljub temu pa tudi rezultati ESRB kažejo pozitivno dolžniško vrzel v Sloveniji, a je ta manjša. Ocenjujemo, da je v Sloveniji prišlo do prekomernega kopičenja dolga predvsem v obdobju od drugega četrtletja leta 2007 do vključno tretjega četrtletja leta 2009. Razmerje med dolgom zasebnega sektorja in BDP je bilo v povprečju za približno 3,8 o. t. nad dolgoročno trendno oziroma »vzdržno« ravnijo. K pozitivni dolžniški vrzeli v letu 2009 je največ prispevalo izrazito realno krčenje gospodarske aktivnosti (-7,8 %), saj je bil kreditni tok v tem letu že precej skromen. Prekomerna kreditna aktivnost je bila značilna predvsem za leti 2007 in 2008, ko smo tudi presegli mejno vrednost za kazalnik zadolževanja zasebnega sektorja (15 % BDP), ki jo je določila evropska komisija in jo le-ta uporablja za ugotavljanje makroekonomskih neravnovesij. V omenjenih letih je prihajalo predvsem do prekomernega kreditiranja nefinančnih podjetij, za katera se je kasneje izkazalo, da niso bila sposobna servisirati takega obsega dolga, ki Bolj zadolžena od slovenskih so le še podjetja v Grčiji, Italiji in Španiji. je bil predvsem v primeru na domači trg usmerjenih podjetij marsikdaj ekonomsko neutemeljen. Za slovenska gospodinjstva pa je bilo značilno, da so le zmerno sodelovala pri napihovanju kreditnega balona (največ leta 2007, pa še takrat le za okrog 5 %). Ugotavljamo, da se je v letu 2012 negativna dolžniška vrzel ohranila na visoki ravni, kar je posledica še ostrejšega kreditnega krča (leta 2012 je bila rast kreditov -4,3 %) in nizke gospodarske aktivnosti. To močno vpliva tudi na investiranje dobro stoječih izvozno usmerjenih in tehnološko zahtevnejših podjetij ter s tem na nadaljnje poglabljanje gospodarske in finančne krize. Naši izračuni tudi nakazujejo, da je dolžniška vrzel v Sloveniji v 90 tem obdobju presegala povprečje EMU, kjer je prišlo do prekomernega kopičenja dolga predvsem v obdobju od tretjega četrtletja leta 2005 do vključno tretjega četrtletja leta 2009. Razmerje med dolgom zasebnega sektorja in BDP je bilo v tem obdobju v povprečju za približno 2 o. t. nad dolgoročno ravnijo. Tudi v EMU je bila v letu 2009 pozitivna dolžniška vrzel zaradi skromne kreditne aktivnosti in krčenja gospodarske aktivnosti, ki sta bili realno za skoraj polovico manjši kot v Sloveniji (-4,4 %). Sklep Prezadolženost slovenskega gospodarstva in slabo stanje v slovenskem bančnem sistemu sta dva izmed ključnih razlogov za pričakovanje nadaljnjega krčenja gospodarske aktivnosti, ki je med najizrazitejšimi v evrskem območju.16 Ugotavljamo, da so slovenska podjetja na eni strani prezadolžena, a na drugi strani je v zadnjih letih zabeležena negativna kreditna vrzel, kar kaže, da je kreditna aktivnost v Sloveniji tudi glede na trenutne gospodarske razmere preskromna in si rezultati na prvi pogled celo nasprotujejo. Avtorja meniva, da bi bila za normalnejše funkcioniranje gospodarstva potrebna takšna kreditna aktivnost, ki bi bila usmerjena predvsem v tista manj zadolžena podjetja, ki tudi v tej krizi vidijo poslovne priložnosti, a jih zaradi omejenih virov financiranja ne morejo izkoristit v celoti, kar še dodatno duši gospodarsko aktivnost. Na izredno pomembno vlogo dolžniškega financiranja v prihodnje 14 Enostranski Hodrick-Prescottov filter za izračun enostranskega dolgoročnega trenda uporablja samo podatke, ki so na voljo do določene točke v času, ko se odločimo za izračun samega trenda. 15 Implicitno se predpostavlja, da je dolžina kreditnega cikla štirikrat daljša od dolžine poslovnega cikla. 16 Več glej UMAR (2013) in European Commission (2013). BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING pa kaže tudi struktura slovenskega gospodarstva, kjer prevladujejo mala in srednja podjetja, ki imajo dostop do drugih virov financiranja precej omejen. Z uveljavitvijo ukrepov za sanacijo slovenskega bančnega sistema in vzpostavitev normalnejše finančne in lastniške strukture slovenskega gospodarstva že močno zamujamo. Ugotavljamo, da se zadolženost slovenskega gospodarstva v zadnjih letih ni bistveno znižala kljub temu, da so podjetja in NFI od konca leta 2009 do julija 2013 zmanjšala obseg kreditov pri domačih bankah za okrog 3,6 mrd EUR, prav tako pa se še naprej izrazito poslabšujejo razmere v slovenskem bančnem sis- BV 11/2013 temu, kar močno poglablja težave v slovenskem gospodarstvu. Zato brez hitre izvedbe predvidenih ukrepov za sanacijo bančnega sistema, v okviru tudi drugih strukturnih reform, ne moremo pričakovati trajnejšega in trdnejšega okrevanja slovenskega gospodarstva. Literatura in viri/References: Alessi, L., Detken, C.. (2011). Quasi real time early warning indicators for costly asset price boom/bust cycles: a role for global liquidity. European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 27, No. 3. Banka Slovenije (2013). Poročilo o finančni stabilnosti. Ljubljana. Bank of England (2011). Instruments of macroprudential policy. A Discussion Paper. London. Basel Committe on Banking Supervision 91 (2010). Guidance for national authorities operating the countercyclical capital buffer. Basel. Borio, C. in Lowe, P. (2002). Asset prices, financial and monetary stability: exploring the nexus. BIS Working Paper no.114. Borio, C. in Lowe, P. (2004). Securing sustainable price stability: should credit come back from the wilderness?. BIS Working Paper no.157. Derehmann, M., Borio, C., Gambacorta, L., Jiménez, G., Trucharte, C. (2010). Countercyclical capital buffers: exploring options. BIS Working Paper no. 317. European Systemic Risk Board (2013). ESRB Risk Dashboard. Frankfurt. European Commission (2013). European Economic Forecast-Spring 2013. Schularick, M. Taylor, A. (2012). Credit booms gone bust: monetary policy, leverage cycles and financial crises, 18702008. American Economic Review. UMAR (2013). Jesenska napoved gospodarskih gibanj 2013. Ljubljana. MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING UDK 336.71:347.738:330.101.54 Macroeconomic implications of banks and corporate sector deleveraging MACROECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF BANKS AND CORPORATE SECTOR DELEVERAGING This paper reviews the overall balance sheet adjustments in the corporate and banking sectors in the euro area during the current crisis and addresses their macroeconomic and policy implications. The strong reversal of crossborder flows in the euro area and policy response to the crisis has led to financial fragmentation. Leveraged balance sheet positions in banking and non-financial corporate sectors in the euro area members are unwinding with different degree. The ECB policy has been partly successful in easing the overall deleveraging pressures, but the effect on asset prices and economic recovery has been uneven among euro area members. The most affected are peripheral countries, which are undergoing a process of internal macroeconomic adjustment mainly visible in depressed domestic demand and assets prices and fall in employment. This is taking place in an unfavourable context of the mal-functioning interbank market, weak external demand and fiscal consolidation pointing out to a slow and credit-less recovery. JEL E2 G01 G21 G28 T Gonzalo Caprirolo* he post dot-com bubble burst period leading to a crisis was characterised by a rapid credit expansion and private debt accumulation in developed economies. The intensity of the process and the sectors leading it has varied among countries but in general private indebtedness has risen to historically high levels. The crisis has resulted in a massive financial retrenchment and reappraisal of risk. Liquidity shortages, mounting losses and increasing refinancing risk have triggered early government intervention in banking systems. The post-crisis period in the euro area is characterised by non-functioning interbank market, massive outflow of capital from vulnerable to the core euro area members and financial fragmentation. Debt was reappraised in light of the change in financial conditions and the policy response at the euro area level which turn the crisis into systemic. Liquidity provision, low interest rates, banks refinancing (LTROs) and the recent ECB policy of “do whatever it takes” have eased overall financing conditions and risks as they intensified. The timing and broad macroeconomic effect from these measures is still to be debated as well as their effect on different member states. In some the economy has rebounded and asset prices recovered or their fall mitigated. Other member states are still struggling to emerge from recession while price of assets continues on a downward path. * Gonzalo Caprirolo, IMAD. The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the author and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of IMAD. 92 BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING While monetary policy is a key instrument to offset the risk of unwinding leverage positions, there are other relevant policies. However, in the euro area the broad policy response has led to contagion and systemic crisis and, in particular, the policy of pursuing private solutions to debt problems amidst an unprecedented crisis of confidence. In such a context pursuing an orderly deleveraging process of adjusting excessive debt without depressing price of equity and hinder permanently productive capacity seems particularly challenging for some euro area members. Not only exchange rate policy is not available, but interest rates in some member states are high, price of equity is low, the role of local central banks and government in facilitating restructuring financial systems and enterprises is strongly constrained by EU rules and the support of EU institutions can vary according to the relative size of the countries. In such a set-up, a relevant question to address is the likely macroeconomic implications of deleveraging of the corporate sector and banks. Such an issue is of particular relevance to Slovenia since leverage ratios of both sectors are relatively high. Deleveraging in the non-financial corporate sector (corporate sector) Deleveraging of banks and corporate sector can have different implications for economic activity. Since banks are the primary source of external finance of the corporate sector in the euro area and this generates feedback loops between the two deleveraging process, it is relevant to look at their interaction and macroeconomic implications. In this regard, the analysis of credit dynamics, the evolution of asset price and economic activity can shed light BV 11/2013 on what drives the credit market conditions and business cycle, the feedback loop among these variables and on policy options to pursue orderly deleveraging and economic recovery. Regarding credit dynamics, the crisis in 2008 brought a dramatic change in banking funding and financial conditions in the euro area. The share of interbank borrowing in total liabilities, which was the main source of financing before the crisis shrunk. This and banks’ losses triggered balance sheet adjustment and change in asset positions, the so-called bank lending channel (Bernanke and Gertler, The size of corporate debt in the euro area was 50% bigger in 2008 than in 2001. 1995). It is estimated that credit supply conditions accounted for almost one third of the contraction in real GDP in the euro area in the first half of 2009 (ECB, 2011). In the aftermath, also banks’ risk perception about the impact of macroeconomic developments on creditworthiness of the borrower increased (i.e. borrowers’ balance sheet channel) (ECB, 2010-2013). In the case of corporate sector demand for loans remained negative with exception of the second half of 2010 until first half of 2011. While the change in banks’ funding conditions and worsening of their balance sheets constrained credit supply, it is less clear to which extent the macroeconomic outlook or 93 the drop in value of assets restrained supply, but mostly demand for credit as borrowers’ credit constraints tightened resulting from the gap between debt and capacity to serve it. An empirical issue to disentangle is the trigger of the corporate sector deleveraging. Was caused by banking sector deleveraging or by collapse in economic activity and equity prices? According to Gorreti and Souto (2013), the current corporate adjustment follows those in the past and is triggered by banking sector deleverage. Yet, the dynamic of asset prices and economic outlook seem critical in explaining corporate credit demand and the deleveraging process. According to Ruscher and Wolff (2012), macroeconomic downturns and equity price shocks triggered past corporate balance sheet adjustment periods. In Japan it was the collapse in asset prices which triggered corporate deleveraging (Koo, 2003) and also in Germany contributed to explain the corporate deleveraging during the dot-com bubble (Ruscher and Wolff, 2012). More broadly, stock market crashes are usually followed by recession (Farmer, 2013). In the current crisis changes in banking funding conditions, stock market crashes and collapse of economic activity have resulted in reappraisal of risk and have triggered, in relatively indebted countries, balance sheet adjustment and negative feedback loops. In disentangling the relation between credit activity, growth and corporate deleveraging it is important to highlight the high and positive correlation between lags of credit growth rate (three quarters) and the economic cycle (ECB, 2013). Furthermore, stylised facts concerning big five financial crisis involving the non-financial corporate sector and current one in the euro area suggest that the ratio of bank loans to the corporate sector-to-GDP, and thus MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING leverage, continue increasing after the start of the crisis and then with at least two years of lag credit starts to fall (ECB, 2013). This suggests an order of causation from economic activity, including asset prices, to credit activity and leverage. Adverse shocks to economic activity can lead to reassessment of creditworthiness in light of risks and trigger balance sheet adjustment. Two issues in this regard seem relevant: the timing when those risks are reassessed, which can further worsen economic conditions, and the adjustment triggered when actual borrowers risk is reappraised. With credit and leverage overshooting business cycle turning points, this suggests a lagged change in risk attitude or that it feeds in only gradually on credit dynamics. Yet, in a crisis and its aftermath corporate leverage indicators do not only reflect the impact of shocks but also the underlying adjustments to them that needs to be disentangled. Thus, in assessing the deleveraging process in itself, given that indebtedness exhibits pro-cyclical fluctuations caused by the underlying shock that drives business cycle, the emphasize should be on the relative size of the Figure 1. Share price indices (rebased); 2007=100 and change 2007-2012 120 Association of Stock Exchanges 100 Athens Stock Exchange general index 80 Irish Stock Exchange Equity Overall Index 60 FTSE MIB Index 40 Portuguese Stock Index 20 Slovenian blue chip index 20 0 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Source: Eurostat Figure 2. Change in debt-to-equity ratio (Q3 2008 - Q4 2012) 50 40 30 20 Change owing to valuation effects 10 0 -10 Change owing to transactions -20 Overall change -30 -40 -50 LU MT IT PT FI SI EL AT FR ES EA CY EE SK DE BE IE NL Source: ECB (2013) 94 debt in light of the evolution of asset price and economic activity. According to Farmer (2013), the magnitude of the drop in stock market and ensuing recession in the US in 2008 was different than in the Great Depression due to Federal Reserve (FED) policy of Quantitative Easing (QE). Such a policy underpinned stock market price recovery and eased deleveraging. The importance of asset price evolution in corporate balance sheet adjustment is also highlighted in the case of Germany in which it played a less supportive role at the beginning of the 2000s (Ruscher and Wolff 2012) than in the aftermath of the 2008 crisis which might be also explained by flight to safety resulting from the euro area crisis. In the euro area stock market indexes fell in 2008 but their recovery has been uneven among members. In 2012, the average index in Germany reached a similar level than in 2007 (7 p.p. lower) but the recovery was weaker than the US Dow Jones Industrial average. In countries more affected by the crisis the average indexes remained low or continued falling in 2012. In the case of Slovenia the average index level fell by 74 % between 2007 and 2012 (Figure 1). The value of equity with few exceptions also remains below the 2007 level in most countries. Changes in equity valuation are critical for assessing indebtedness and deleveraging pressures as they contribute to changes in debt-to-equity ratio (Figure 2). They have adversely affected most peripheral countries in the aftermath of the crisis. In the case of Slovenia the positive valuation effects that mitigated the strong debt build-up in the pre-crisis period turned negative in the post crisis period increasing relative indebtedness and exacerbating deleveraging pressures. The fall and downward trend price BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING BV 11/2013 a process will ensue as they depend on overall economic conditions and sustainability of asset price dynamics. This was the case during pre-crisis period when debt was not perceived as major issue. It is the change in underlying conditions and policy to cope with them that change the risk perception of debt which triggers balance sheet adjustment. Of particular importance in this regard is the type of shock affecting asset prices, economic activity and the degree of involvement of the financial sector. Nevertheless, the literature rate with the intensity of corporate debt accumulation prior to the crisis but also with the severity of the downturn (Jorda et al., 2010). The trend evolution of debt since 2008 differs among members. Debt started to decrease only more recently in some countries including Slovenia, Spain, Portugal and Greece. In other countries it continues increasing. Although enterprise balance sheet ratios can have important signalling effect about deleveraging pressures (Ruscher and Wolff, 2012), they does not necessarily imply that such Figure 3. Debt-to-gross operating surplus ratio 1000 800 600 Average Q1 2000- Q2 2008 400 Average Q3 2008- Q4 2012 200 Change 0 IE PT SI FI ES IT FR BE AT EA EL NL DE -200 Source: ECB (2013) Figure 4. Non-financial corporations: Liabilities (Index 2001=100) 290 270 250 EA 230 DE IE 210 EL 190 ES 170 FR 150 IT 130 PT 110 SI Source: Eurostat. Own calculation 95 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 90 2001 of equity and other assets in the aftermath of the crisis in peripheral countries suggest strong deleveraging pressures. The fact that asset prices, with the exception of Germany, have not recovered points out to financial market fragmentation. An alternative ECB’s monetary policy focused on direct purchases of targeted asset classes in secondary market could help alleviating the overall deleveraging process in the common currency area while targeted policies are continue being implemented to address specific sector leverage issues. Since a euro area common asset does not exist, banks could swap their existing holdings of euro governments bonds with bonds issued for this purpose by European Stability Mechanism. This could also reduce overall euro area systemic risk. The US experience with QE resulting in significant deleveraging of corporate and households against a background of equity price recovery is of high relevance. Corporate gross operating surplus is another variable to benchmark and gauge deleveraging pressures. With the onset of the crisis it worsened in most euro area countries but on average it improved to a similar level than in the pre-crisis period. There are some exceptions, including Slovenia. Nevertheless, corporate debt with respect to gross operating surplus has worsened in most countries suggesting worsening in debt repayment capacity (Figure 3). Looking at nominal corporate sector debt dynamics per se suggests an intense period of debt accumulation in the euro area during 2004-2008 (Figure 4). The size of corporate debt in the euro area was 50% bigger in 2008 than in 2001. The degree of debt accumulation intensity varied and was particularly high in Spain and Slovenia. According to past deleverage episodes, the fall in investment and output is commensu- MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING in Germany, has clearly a different implication in terms of deleveraging pressures. Similarly, the increases in the size of debt-to-GDP ratio in the countries where debt has declined or its pace of increase has decelerated also suggest deleveraging pressures. In summary, taking into account the increase in corporate debt with respect to equity and GDP and the increase of interest payments-to-profit ratios (ECB 2013) this suggests that indebtedness will continue depressing investment and growth in vulnerable countries. An important dimension in the overall also suggests that debt levels can have important effect on growth (e.g. Cecchetti et al., 2011 and Goretti and Souto, 2013). Based on various indicators and available policy tools, we can assume that euro area countries face different intensity of deleveraging pressures. Since the onset of the crisis, the debt-to-equity ratios have increased primarily due to valuation changes in more vulnerable countries while in the core countries is the opposite (Figure 5). From that perspective the debt-to-equity ratio in vulnerable countries close to that Figure 5. Debt-to-GDP and Debt-to-Equity ratios (Average Q3 2008 - Q4 2012) 300 Debt-to-GDP ratio 250 Debt-to-Equity ratio 200 150 100 50 0 GR ES MT CY IE IT SI DE AT FI PT EA NL EE SK BE FR LU Source: ECB (2013) Figure 6. Loans to gross value added (Average Q3 2008 - Q4 2012) 500 All sectors 450 Industry 400 Construction and real state sectors 350 Wholesale and retail trade 300 Services other than real state 250 200 150 100 50 0 LU CY MT ES IE PT NL SI IT AT EL EA EE FR Source: ECB (2013) 96 DE FI BE SK deleveraging process is the relative indebtedness of various sectors of economic activity. In the period leading to the crisis, the construction and the real estate sectors together became the most indebted sectors across the euro area countries as reflected in the ratio of banks’ loan to gross value added (Figure 6). Before the crisis in 2008 the exception was Slovenia. In the period following the outburst of the crisis in 2008, indebtedness has continued increasing across all sectors in most countries and the construction and real estate sector experienced the largest increase across countries. In the case of Slovenia the substantial increase is largely explained by the collapse in gross value added in the construction sector. While the indebtedness of the two sectors remains below the euro area average, they have become the most indebted sectors of the economy followed by the manufacturing sector which relative indebtedness increased. The relatively high indebtedness in the real estate and construction in the euro area in general indicates substantial adjustment needs affecting banks’ balance sheet and economic activity. The issue regarding indebtedness in real estate and housing sectors is that they affect price in housing which is the variable most correlated with intensity of recessions and length of the crisis (Claessens et al., 2008). According to the literature corporate deleveraging can be lengthy and the impact on macroeconomic conditions severe. This depends on the macroeconomic channels, the state of banks’ balance sheet, overall policy response and external environment. The adjustment period in which corporations improve their financial performance (i.e. improved their net financial position) in a sample of developed countries lasted between 5 and 10 years with severe impact on economic activity (Ruscher BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING Deleveraging in banking sector The rapid increase in private debt in the run to financial crisis was caused by low interest rates, financial liberalization and innovation, globalization of financial flows and financial integration in euro area. Banks played a pivotal role in this process as their balance sheets expanded based on wholesale and cross border funding. In many euro area member’s banking systems the loan-to-deposit ratio, a proxy for leverage, increased or remained high before the crisis. The average loan-to-deposit ratio for large banks in Europe increased BV 11/2013 ties in total assets in some members reached 40% in 2008. With the financial crisis in 2008 banks’ deleveraging process begun. Besides financial disintegration in euro area other drivers include the overall policy approach to the crisis, the negative feedback loop between banks and sovereign balance sheets, worsening of economic outlook affecting the private sector, regulatory requirements and state-aid rules underlying bank restructuring. Government intervention in the banking systems has been massive. But, the models put forward to tackle balance sheet problems in euro from 115% in 2002 to close to 150% in 2008 (Deloitte, 2012b). In most of banking systems in euro area loans to corporate-to-total deposit ratios were above 100% in 2008 (Figure 8). Cross border financing increased in all euro area banking systems in the period 2003-2008. In most members the levels of foreign financing more than doubled those at the end of 2003 (Figure 9). In some countries, included Slovenia, the increase of bank’s foreign funding was substantial although the share of bank assets in GDP remains lower compared to those other euro area countries. The share of foreign liabili- Figure 7. Net financial position percentage of GDP 4.0 Ireland Spain Slovenia Portugal Italy 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 1.0 -2.0 2012Q4 2012Q2 2012Q3 2012Q1 2011Q3 2011Q4 2011Q2 2011Q1 2010Q4 2010Q3 2010Q1 2010Q2 2009Q4 2009Q2 2009Q3 2009Q1 2008Q3 2008Q4 -4.0 2008Q2 -3.0 2007Q4 and Wolff, 2012). Event study on 10 past corporate crises episodes suggest that the process of corporate deleveraging last from 7 to 8 years with an adjustment in leverage ratio of about 8% of assets for the median country (Gorreti and Souto, 2013). Sutherland et al. (2012) indicate that large debt reduction episodes last 6 1/2 years for the households and non-financial sectors on average across OECD countries. Looking at progress made so far on corporate deleveraging (Figure 4), including balance sheet adjustment as reflected in the evolution of corporate net financing needs (Figure 7) suggests that the length of corporate sector deleveraging will be still long and felt during the next five-year period. While corporate net financial positions have improved in various euro area countries (Figure 7), such improvement is still small compared to those experienced by corporate sector in Japan and Germany. In the case of Japan corporate net lending as percentage of GDP averaged 5% during 2001-2007 and in Germany around 2% in the period 20042007. In both cases balance sheet improvement was underpinned by economic recovery at global level. Source: Eurostat Figure 8. Banking system: External debt stocks (2003=100) 2.5 2008 2013 (Jul) 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 EE IE SI FI Source:IMF 97 PT IT FR NL ES EA AT CY MT DE GR SK BE LU MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING area differ more substantially than in previous crisis. The approaches chosen have different implications for the overall economic and debt evolution of various sectors in the economy including the government sector. A review of approaches followed regarding asset relief measures indicates that at euro area level individual bank measures have been preferred than schemes at member state level. Similarly, there is preference for asset guarantee measures and capital increase rather than asset purchase measures (Table 1). Such an approach can be explained by the complexity involved in the design, implementation, and valuation of asset relief measures (Boudghene and Maes, 2012a). Similarly, the fiscal impact is minimized in the case of guarantees and capital increases and provides flexibility in handling assets and result in different set of incentive structures. The main exceptions have been Ireland and later Spain which set up national schemes in which asset purchase are pursued by a “private entity”. Slovenia is the only country in euro area in which a state owned scheme will directly purchase banks’ assets and thus explicitly impact the government’s accounts. Yet, there are plans to enable private investment in the scheme to minimize the accounting burden of the process. The choice of the approach chosen to deal with impaired asset and their valuation have implications that go beyond technicalities as it can have important bearing in the overall deleveraging process and Table 1. Public interventions in the EU banking sector in the year 2008-2010 Used amounts % GDP 2.4 Approved amounts % GDP 4.6 Guarantees on banks liabilities 9.1 26.4 Relief of impaired assets 1.0 3.4 Capital injection Liquidity and bank funding support 0.7 1.3 Total 13.1 35.7 Source: Boudghene and Maes (2012b) Figure 9. Banking system: External debt stocks (2003=100) 800 2008Q4 2012Q4 2003Q4=100 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 SK SI EE EL FI IE FR ES AT IT NL BE Source: IMF 98 PT DE LU pace of economic recovery. Since 2008 banks’ cross border funding collapsed restricting overall supply of credit. European banks’ cross border lending fell by 41% between 2008 and 2011 (BIS 2012). The level of foreign funding decreased in absolute amount and as share of total assets (Figure 9). The cross-border bank deleveraging process has been particularly strong in some countries, including Slovenia, where the share of foreign funding of the banking system decreased by half and only between Q3 2011 and Q2 2012 it was reduced by more than 10% of GDP. A disorderly deleverage of banks in the euro area has been prevented so far in particular by the ECB policy. Refinancing of the first tranche of LTRO maturing in December 2015 will be important in this regard as euro area’s cross border banking activity came to historic lows in 2012 and has continued in 2013. In addressing multiple challenges, banks’ capital has increased (Figure 10). This process started already early in 2009 linked to sub-prime bonds losses. Since then trend increase in tier 1 capital ratios is observed in most euro area countries to cope with bursting bubbles, balance sheet uncertainty and negative feedback loop between sovereigns and banks. The increase in capital has been underpinned by regulatory requirements and market pressure to achieve the new BASLE III capital ratios sooner. In the case of Slovenia the increase in capital has been modest (Figure 10). It has been underpinned by regulatory pressure but, since the onset of the crisis successive governments have been reluctant to increase capital in state largely owned banks beyond minimum regulatory requirement. Future sizable capital increases will be needed, particularly at the time of transferring assets to the bad bank. BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING The impact of the crisis on corporate sector balance sheets is also pressing banks to further deleverage creating a negative feedback loop on economic activity (i.e. increase in non-performing loans (Figure 11). This and the need to break the negative interaction between banks and sovereigns risk led to the decision of setting up a banking union. Yet its effective impact on reducing sovereign risk and mitigating the deleveraging pressures on sovereigns is still far from reality and seem questionable, especially due to reluctance to use European Stability Mechanism funds to directly recapitalize ailing banks. Banks deleverage process seems to persist over the next years. Euro area banks are confronting excess of non-core and non-performing assets in excess of € 1.7 trillion (Deloitte, 2012a). The drivers will continue to be: market pressure and supervisory capital requirements; liquidity constraints and reversal of cross-country capital flows; state aid rules on banking restructuring and weak economic recovery. This will exert pressure on the corporate sector balance sheet. A survey on large financial institutions in euro area with assets worth € 11 trillion (Deloitte, 2012b) indicates that banks expect to re-size their balance sheets through run-offs of loans more than through divestment. This is because of the uncertainty surrounding asset valuation. Banks indicate that a high proportion of divestitures should be assets in Western Europe. Loan books with commercial real estate will be sold as a priority. They estimate that the process of deleveraging will take at least five years to complete although they expect it to be modest (7.5% of total assets) compared with the increase in banks’ balance sheet before the crisis. Banks have identified the determination of price of assets as the key challenge ahead. So far (2009-2013), the pace of BV 11/2013 12). Bank credit-to-GDP ratios in Scandinavian countries and Japan fell on average by 27 p.p. over a period of seven years and then returned to the pre-boom levels. In Slovenia the ratio has slightly fallen in 2013 but with the planned transfers of impaired assets to the asset management company (bad bank) the process of deleveraging should accelerate. To the extent that deleveraging reestablishes stability in the banking sector and conditions for sustained recovery, the speed of the process might be important. Yet, the means, bank deleveraging (i.e. reduction in loan-to-deposit ratio) in some euro area members seems to be slow compared to other episodes. In Scandinavian countries loan-todeposits ratios fell strongly in the first three years following the crisis which is quite a shorter period than in Japan (7 years) which is regarded as a lengthy process. The evolution of bank credit to private sector-to-GDP, also suggest slow pace of deleveraging in vulnerable countries with the exception of Ireland (64 p.p.) and Spain (30 p.p.), which nevertheless started from very high levels (Figure Figure 10. Tier 1 Capital 25 2008 2012 20 Change 15 10 5 0 EE IE LU FI BE SK DE FR AT NL PT IT MT SI ES EL CY Source: ECB Figure 11. Non-performing loans, % 25 2008 2012 20 15 10 5 0 EL IE CY SI Source: IMF 99 IT PT MT ES SK FR BE NL DE AT EE LU MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING strategy, as well as framework conditions, are of outmost importance for success. In this context selling troubled assets or the creation of bad banks can speed up the process. This was the case of Sweden which however at that time enjoyed the benefits of: independent monetary policy; exchange rate depreciation; strong external demand and the possibility to set its own domestic rules for asset valuation. Following the path of Sweden in establishing a bad bank under current conditions seems challenging for the euro area members in absence of independent monetary policy, lack of exchange rate and state aid rules for valuing assets. One of the most important risks being the cleaning up banks’ balance sheets at fire sale prices (i.e. price liquidation level). Such an outcome would magnify losses in the banking system generating significant and immediate negative macroeconomic externalities. Pushing down asset prices from already depressed levels can further increase relative indebtedness, weaken corporate and banks’ balance sheets, worsen government fiscal position, hinder potential output and lengthen the recovery process. This risk is higher given the uncertainty of broad economic recovery of euro area and for vulnerable countries that face relative high interest rates. In the case of Slovenia where there seems no alternative approach to the bad bank due to build-up of market expectation and its pressure, the key policy issue will be a careful determination of value of assets. At the euro area level it will be important to review state aid rules on asset valuation in light of their impact on overall deleveraging process or its consistency with the overall policy set up and broad economic recovery. Macro implications of corporate and bank deleveraging To understand the macroeconomic implications of the deleveraging process in some EU peripheral countries, largely triggered by change in funding conditions and massive reversal of capital flows from core countries, as for example reflected in Target 2 transactions, it is relevant to review the stylised facts of the literature dealing with episodes of sudden stops and credit-less recoveries. A sudden stop is a sharp and sudden reversal in international capital flows. It is followed by strong deteriora- Figure 12. Loans to private sector % GDP 200 2004 2008 2012 2013 (June) 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 IE ES BE DE AT EA PT SI FR IT FI NL EL tion of macroeconomic aggregates, sharp changes in exchange rate and declines in asset prices in equity and housing markets (Calvo et al., 2006 and Korinek and Mendoza 2013). Credit-less episodes occur when output reverts to its pre-crisis level without any significant recovery of domestic or external lending (Calvo et al., 2006). The probability of a credit-less recovery increases after a banking crisis and it is preceded by large declines in economic activity and financial stress. In particular when private sector indebtedness is high and the country is reliant on foreign capital inflows (Bijsterbosch and Dahlhaus, 2011). In such events, recoveries tend to be relatively weak with output and investment growth lower that in events where credit grows or is not constrained (Abiad et al, 2011). The literature of the sudden stop is relevant to peripheral countries to the extent that they have experiences such episodes since the onset of the crisis in 2008 (Merler and Pissani, 2012). It is less relevant with respect to the macroeconomic adjustment in which the sharp depreciation of the nominal exchange rate (and thus the real exchange rate) is a key variable in explaining the “v” shape type of recovery which is not available to euro area members. Nevertheless, the absence of exchange rate adjustment points out to the magnitude of the pressure and adjustment the nominal prices have to undergo or in their absence the effect on economic activity and employment. The episodes of credit-less recovery are relevant to euro area members to the extent that they hint to the type of economic recovery they can also go through: a recovery not underpinned by credit activity and therefore at a slower pace than otherwise. In episodes of credit-less recovery, including the case of the Great De- Source: ECB and Eurostat. Own calculation 100 BV 11/2013 MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING pression, the nominal exchange rate depreciates and consequently the real exchange rate contributing to the economic rebound (Calvo et al., 2006). To the extent that some euro are countries are likely to experience credit-less recovery and the exchange rate is not available this also points out to macroeconomic adjustment taking place through internal devaluation or loss in output and employment. With financial systems still to deleverage and nominal rigidities in economies this hints to a slow and credit-less recovery process in some euro area members. This process is likely to be more painful given that interest rates remains substantially higher in some members and have to still undergo fiscal consolidation. On the corporate side the balance sheet adjustment affecting aggregate demand is taking place through reduction in investment, improvement in corporate net borrowing position (Figure 7) and increase in savings, but a lesser extent through disposal in financial assets, probably due to depressed prices (Deloitte, 2012b), and increase in equity. Deleveraging is proceeding only gradually in highly indebted corporate sectors which are less able to diversify their funding sources and that have been exposed to large assets losses from the crisis (Goretti and Souto, 2013). Another channel through which deleverage is taking place is through bankruptcy, affecting directly banks’ balance sheet. With depressed external demand, corporate investment has fallen significantly and saving ratios have increased, affecting unemployment and reducing wages. Economic activity is slow and banks’ balance sheets are adversely affected. In addressing negative feedback loops, effort is being centred on the banking system. Although credit activity is not likely to be a key driver in the recovery, addressing banks’ balance sheets problems enhances BV 11/2013 their resiliency and thus creditworthiness of institutions and sovereigns. In the case of Slovenia the high yield on government debt is most often attributed to the uncertainty of banks’ balance sheet problems. At the euro area level the approach has been to increase capital, issuance of guarantees rather than selling assets due to valuation issues in a decentralized set up. In general the issue of asset valuation is not trivial as it can increase the leverage, generate wealth effects and contribute to a downward economic spiral. This is reflected in deleveraging strategies based In some countries the increase of bank’s foreign funding was substantial. on capital increases, run offs rather than divestures of largest banks located in core euro area which have also benefited the most from ECB policy and inflows of capital (flight to safety). But the issue of shocks to asset prices is particularly relevant to peripheral countries in which a centralized approach (bad bank) to deal with bank assets is pursued and for countries, such as Slovenia, where leverage in corporate sector is relatively high in relation to equity, but not in terms of GDP (Figure 5). In particular, in such institutional set up the bad bank becomes the market maker and thus pricing decisions can have enormous macroeconomic impact. The critical issue is that some 101 peripheral countries are undergoing an internal adjustment process that is likely to take time. In such conditions, transferring or selling bank assets at fire sale levels can trigger an additional massive shock. For euro area peripheral countries that chose a centralized approach to deal with banks’ assets, the risk of additional shock to asset prices contributing to a protracted recession is quite high. This is because of the institutional set up of the approach, its incentive structure, and the context of already depressed asset prices. In such an environment the entity in charge of valuing assets has the incentive to ensure that they are priced in such a way that do not loose further value to preserve its reputation. State aid rules aiming at an appropriate return to investors push for attractive prices in already depressed conditions. The aim of the institution handling the selling of assets is to maximise profit and thus exerts downward pressure on the assets transfer price. Finally, government under the pressure of investors to swiftly remove impaired assets might be willing to accept “fire sale” transfer prices. Such a scenario points out to the major risks facing the pace of economic recovery and to strong adverse effect for the government’s balance sheet. In such a case, the adverse fiscal impact will not result only from a large frontloaded capitalization to cover the losses of transfer of assets at “fire sale” level but the assets when sold will not recover the cost of the overall fiscal intervention. To some extent similar risk might be present in the context of the forthcoming euro area Asset Quality Review (AQR) with important impact on backstop financial support. Thus, as part of the policy effort of supporting and orderly deleverage process and internal macroeconomic adjustment in some countries, it will be important MACRO-FINANCIAL ASPECTS OF BANK REHABILITATION AND COMPANY RESTRUCTURING to revise state aid rules with a view of mitigating their potential adverse impact of an additional external shock on prices when countries are undergoing internal adjustment. Refinancing maturing ECB’s LTROs could ease deleveraging pressures as well as ECB purchase of assets, (preferable assets issued by the ESM in exchange of government assets currently held by banks), could also contribute to orderly deleveraging and, diminishing sovereign risk and systemic risk of the common currency area. At a national level the risk of selling assets at “fire sale” level on the government’s balance sheet should be minimised. An approach in this regard could be to put the assets in custody for a given time period and then only gradually proceed to their disposal as the economy improves. Equally important to the economic recovery is to pursue an orderly deleveraging of the corporate sector. This is particularly relevant for countries which do not receive fully the stimulus of the common monetary policy, have to undergo fiscal consolidation and lack of sources of alternative investment and funding than banks. In such cases, corporate restructuring (financial and organisational), could facilitate the viability of those enterprises under stress but with a long-term viable business model. In other cases liquidation should be pursued to reduce the drag on growth and improve allocation of resources. The recent change in corporate bankruptcy legislation in Slovenia is a step in such direction. Given, banks credit constrains alternative source of funding to SMEs should be pursued. In the concrete case of Slovenia, in addition to the mentioned measures and active involvement of bad bank in restructuring viable enterprises, privatisation and FDI should be pursued to enhance the speed and sustainability of recovery. As in the case of banks, the increase in capital of enterprises is of utmost importance to avoid negative impact on employment and growth. Careful attention should be given to asset pricing when cleaning banks’ balance sheets. In this regard a supportive role of the European Commission and the ECB are of outmost importance to facilitate and ensure a positive outcome. American Economic Review 96 References: Korinek, A., and Mendoza, E (2013), “From Sudden Stops to Fisherian Deflation: Quantitative Theory and Policy Implications”. NBER. Working Paper 19362 Abiad, A., Dell’Ariccia, G. and Li, B. (2011), “Credit-less recoveries”, Working Paper 11/58, IMF. Bernanke, B.S. and Gertler M. (1995), “Inside the Black Box: the Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 9. Bijsterbosch, M. and T Dahlhaus (2011). “Determinants of Credit-less Recoveries”, European Central Bank, Working Paper Series, No 1358 BIS Quarterly Review, March 2012 Boudghene,Y. and Maes, S. (2012a), “Empirical review of EU asset relief measures in the period 2008–2012” (n 2). European State Aid Law Quarterly 4/2012 Boudghene,Y. and Maes, S. (2012b), “Relieving Banks from Toxic or Impaired Assets: The EU State Aid Policy Framework” Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 2012 Bouis, R., Christensen, A. K. and Cournède, B (2013), “Deleveraging: Challenges, Progress and Policies”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1077, OECD Calvo, G., Izquierdo, A., and Talvi, E. (2006), “Sudden Stops and Phoenix Miracles in Emerging Markets.” The 102 Cecchetti, S.G.,. Mohanty, M.S., and Zampolli, F. (2011), “The Real Effects of Debt”, BIS Working Papers 352 Claesens, S., Kose, M., and Terrones,E. (2008), “What happens during recessions, crunches and busts?” IMF, WP nº 08/274. Deloitte (2012a), “ Managing non-core assets: critical success factors for banks” Deloitte (2012b), “Capital gain, asset loss: European Bank deleveraging”. The Deloitte Bank Survey 2012. ECB (2011), Monthly Bulletin, January 2011 ECB (2013), “Corporate Finance and Economic Activity in the Euro Area: Structural Issues Report”. Occasional paper No 151 ECB (2010-2013), “Banking Lending Survey Jordà, O., Schularick, M. and Taylor, A.M. (2010), “Financial Crises, Credit Booms, and External Imbalances: 140 Years of Lessons”, NBER Working Papers, No 16567, The National Bureau of Economic Research. Koo, R. C. (2003), Balance Sheet Recession; Japan”s struggle with unchartered economics and its global implications, John Wiley and Son, Hoboken, USA Garrote, D., Llopis, J., and Valles X. (2013), “Los canales del desapalancamiento del sector privado: una comparación internacional”. Documentos ocacionals 1302. Banco de Espana Goretti, M., and Souto, M (2013), “MacroFinancial Implications of Corporate (De) Leveraging in the Euro Area Periphery”. IMF Working Paper WP/13/150 Pisani-Ferry, Jean and Silvia Merler, S., and Pisani-Ferry, J (2012), “Sudden stops in the euro area”. Bruegel Policy Contribution Ruscher, E. and G. Wolff (2012), “Corporate Balance Sheet Adjustment: Stylised Facts, Causes and Consequences”, Bruegel Working Paper, No. 3. Sutherland, D., P. Hoeller, R. Merola and V. Ziemann (2012), “Debt and Macroeconomic Stability”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1003. BV 11/2013 BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS UDK 336.71:347.952:347.925 Problematika zunajsodnih prodaj in težave bank v insolvenčnih postopkih Boštjan Kavčič in Andraž Kotolenko* INSOLVENCY PROCEEDINGS – LEGAL CONCERNS AND BANK EXPERIENCE In the article we look into the main cause for extensive decrease in prices of shares used as collateral for bank claims on their clients and the level of indebtedness of Slovenian companies, including the most common difficulties faced by banks in sale procedures of assets used as collateral for their claims, initiated by banks under Consortium Sale Agreements in order to recover claims on their clients. Furthermore, we describe difficulties of banks – creditors in insolvency procedures by focusing on questions regarding necessity of approval of mortgage creditor for transfer of a proprietary right of the debtor on a real estate (serving as collateral of creditor’s claim) to a third party and the potential consequences incurred by the creditor in event of such transfer (when the debtor at commencement of the bankruptcy procedure has not been recorded in the public records as the owner of the mortgaged real estate) due to failure to file for the right to separate settlement. JEL G21 G32 G33 BV 11/2013 D ne 15. septembra leta 2008, nekaj pred eno uro popoldan (po newyorškem času), je družba Lehman Brothers Holdings objavila vest, da bo pri stečajnem sodišču Južnega okrožja države New York (Southern District of New York) vložila predlog za uvedbo stečajnega postopka1 oziroma zaprosila za t .i. varstvo po določbah 11. poglavja Stečajnega zakona Združenih držav Amerike2. V času vložitve predmetnega predloga za uvedbo stečajnega postopka je imela družba Lehman Brothers več kot sto tisoč upnikov, katerim je dolgovala prek sto petdeset tisoč milijard dolarjev3 (največja upnika sta bila družbi Citigroup Inc. in Bank of New York Mellon Corp., s skupaj več kot 138 milijardami terjatev iz naslova komercialnih oziroma blagajniških zapisov – t. i. »senior notes«). Stečaj družbe Lehman Brothers je bil največji stečaj v zgodovini Združenih držav Amerike in je, zaradi posledičnega padca tečajev svetovnih delniških trgov, zamajal celotni svetovni finančni trg, ameriško in evropsko gospodarstvo pa je, zaradi t. i. »domino učinka«, začelo drseti v recesijo. * Boštjan Kavčič, univ. dipl. prav., višji pravnik, bostjan.kavcic@nlb.si, NLB d.d., Center za pravne zadeve, Pravna pisarna za svetovanje; Andraž Kotolenko, univ. dipl. prav., višji pravnik, andraz.kotolenko@nlb.si, NLB d.d., Center za pravne zadeve, Pravna pisarna za izterjavo. 1 Lehman Brothers Press Release (Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc. Announces It Intends to File Chapter 11 Bankruptcy Petition« (PDF). Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc. September 15, 2008. Retrieved 2008-09-15.. 2 Poglavje 11 Stečajnega zakona ZDA ureja obliko stečajnega postopka, ki predstavlja kompleksno in eno izmed dražjih oblik finančnega prestrukturiranja aktive in pasive prezadolženega dolžnika. (http://www.investopedia.com/terms/c/ chapter11.asp; http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Chapter 11, Title 11, United States Code;) 3 »Lehman folds with record $613 billion debt«. Marketwatch. September 15, 2005. Retrieved 2008-09-15. 103 BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS Problematika zunajsodnih prodaj premoženja 1. Kratek opis vzrokov za nastanek položaja bank prodajalk delnic V danih razmerah tudi slovenskemu gospodarskemu prostoru ni bilo prizaneseno. V tistem času so bila slovenska podjetja4 že močno prezadolžena. Po nekaterih podatkih naj bi konec leta 2011 razmerje med dolžniškim in lastniškim financiranjem (t. i. »leverage ratio«) slovenskih gospodarskih družb dosegalo že do 143 odstotkov lastniškega kapitala.5 Zaradi takšnega stanja v slovenskih podjetjih in vse večje gospodarske recesije se je začel hitro poslabševati tudi položaj bank, ki so imele svoje terjatve do slovenskih gospodarskih družb in podjetnikov zavarovane z zastavnimi pravicami na delnicah teh družb, pri čemer so bile tudi same visoko kreditno izpostavljene do svojih kreditodajalcev. Ob koncu leta 2011 je namreč razmerje med krediti in depoziti nebančnega sektorja za slovenski bančni prostor znašalo 137 % in je bilo višje od povprečja bank evrskega območja, ki je znašalo 113 %.6 S padcem tečajev delnic na Ljubljanski borzi vrednostnih papirjev, ki je povzročilo padanje vrednosti zavarovanj za bančne kredite, in s sočasnim kontinuiranim poslabševanjem stanja v realnem gospodarstvu, se je finančna kriza začela seliti tudi v slovenski bančni sektor, kjer so njeni negativni učinki na kapital bank vidni še danes.7 2. Organiziranje bank upnic v obliki prodajnih konzorcijev V takšnih razmerah so se banke v Sloveniji, da bi čimprej poplačale svoje terjatve do insolventnih komitentov ter da bi reševale lastne bilance, začele medsebojno povezovati v obliki konzorcijskih prodajnih pogodb, ki so rabile kot osnova za izvedbo prodajnih postopkov večjih paketov delnic. Banke upnice so se v konzorcijskih pogodbah dogovorile zlasti o (i) skupnem nastopanju pri prodaji delnic, ki prepoveduje prodajo delnic zunaj konzorcija,8 (ii)vodji prodajnega postopka (praviloma tuj finančni svetovalci), (iii)koordinatorju prodaje, (iv)prodajnih aktivnostih, ki jih bodo izvedle za potrebe prodaje, (iv)prepovedi unovčevanja zastavnih pravic (razen za potrebe prodaje končnemu kupcu), (v)obveščanju uprave in nadzornega sveta družbe glede oblikovanja konzorcija in poteka prodajnega postopka (skupaj z zaprosilom za angažma in podporo zlasti pri izvedbi skrbnih pregledov poslovanja družb s strani potencialnih kupcev), (vi)načinu izbora zunanjih izvajalcev (finančnih in pravnih svetovalcev ter ocenjevalca vrednosti delnic družbe) in podelitvi mandata za njihov angažma, (vii)stroških prodajnih aktivnosti, (viii)načinu določitve najnižje prodajne cene delnice, (ix)fazi sprejema končne ponudbe in sklenitve kupoprodajne pogodbe ter (x)posledicah opustitve ali kršitve pogodbenih obveznosti. S sklenitvijo konzorcijskih prodajnih pogodb so banke upnice zasledovale skupni cilj po čim hitrejši prodaji deležev po čim višji ceni, saj vsakršno držanje teh deležev v bilancah bank izpostavlja banke padcu vrednosti delnic. Posledično so te banke zavezane k izvedbi ustreznih prevrednotenj in oblikovanju slabitev, posredno pa tudi k sprejemanju odločitev v zvezi z upravljanjem teh družb v okviru njihovih delničarskih upravičenj, za kar pa banke niso specializirane. Usklajeno ravnanje bank pri reševanju prezadolženih podjetij, ki so v finančni stiski, je v letu 2012 priporočila tudi Banka Slovenije v svojih priporočilih.9 Priporočila se (podobno kot konzorcijski prodajni dogovori) nanašajo na ravnanje bank v primeru podjetij v finančnih težavah. Na tej podlagi Banka Slovenije, kot regulator, priporoča bankam zlasti tudi, (i)da se dogovorijo o vseh aktivnostih, ki naj bodo usmerjene k skupnemu cilju – finančnemu prestrukturiranju podjetij v težavah, da bi se zagotovila njihova dolgoročna gospodarska uspešnost, (ii)da obravnavajo vse upnike pošteno in enakovredno in da se dajanje prednosti posameznemu upniku s strani dolžnika obravnava kot diskriminacija, proti kateri lahko ukrepa posamezni upnik ali skupina upnikov, (iii)da skupina imenuje vodilno banko (koordinatorja) in celo poseben odbor upnikov, ki ga vodi koordinator, za pogajanja s podjetjem, (iv)da vzpostavijo moratorij na odplačevanje dolgov (t. i. »standstill dogovori«), ki onemogočijo posameznim upnikom (strankam takšnih dogovorov) aktivnosti, ki bi izboljšale njihov položaj na škodo položaja drugih upnikov, (vi)imenovanje pooblaščenega revizorja za pridobitev neodvisne ocene družbe, (vii)zagotovijo oziroma omogočijo kratkoročno likvidnost podjetja in podobno. 4 Slovenske gospodarske družbe, njihove odvisne družbe in samostojni podjetniki posamezniki. 5 Članek Sanacija bank ter razdolževanje podjetij in bank, Božo Jašovič in Marko Simoneti, Finance 14. maj 2013. 6 Članek Sanacija bank ter razdolževanje podjetij in bank, Božo Jašovič in Marko Simoneti, Finance 14. maj 2013. 7 Najpogostejši bančni posli, ki so predstavljali podlago za ustanovitev in vpis zastavnih pravic na delnicah družb, so bili bančni krediti, dani večjim gospodarskim družbam v obliki sindiciranih kreditov in večjih bilateralnih kreditov. Velik delež kreditov so predstavljali gradbeni krediti in krediti dani finančnim holdingom, ki so svoja sredstva plasirali naprej v nakup delnic slovenskih gospodarskih družb. Določen odstotek kreditne izpostavljenosti pa predstavljajo tudi nekoliko bolj »eksotični«, a še vedno vrednostno izredno veliki posli z delnicami v obliki delniških terminskih poslov in opcijskih poslov. 8 Izjeme predstavljajo zlasti prodaje delnic s strani investicijskih skladov, ki se zaradi zakonskih omejitev ne morejo zavezati prepovedi prodaje svojih naložb, do katere lahko pride v primeru, kadar npr. vlagatelj zahteva odkup svojih investicijskih kuponov. 9 Priporočila Banke Slovenije za usklajeno postopanje bank upnic v primeru podjetij v finančnih težavah (september 2012) . 104 BV 11/2013 BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS 3. Težave z določanjem prodajne cene in pritiski tretjih na prodajni postopek Če pustimo ob strani običajno dolgotrajno odločanje vseh organov bank pri sprejemanju potrebnih sklepov za izvedbo prodaje delnic, nastanejo v fazi sklepanja konzorcijskih dogovorov prve težave zlasti v delu, ki se nanaša na način določitve cene, po kateri so pogodbene stranke zavezane prodati delnice končnemu kupcu. Problem nastane zaradi različne višine terjatev posameznih strank konzorcija, ki so zavarovane z delnicami, ki so predmet prodaje, in zaradi odsotnosti morebitnih drugih dodatnih zavarovanj. Posledično banke upnice z višjimi terjatvami (in slabšim zavarovanjem slednjih) zahtevajo višjo ceno za delnico, saj bodo le tako lahko prišle do poplačila in se izognile izgubi, ki bi sicer prizadela njihov kapital. Zaradi nevarnosti odtekanja informacij (žal pogost pojav v slovenskem finančnem prostoru) je sporazum o višini prodajne cene v fazi sklepanja konzorcijskega dogovora izredno tvegano početje, zato nekateri v dogovore vključujejo pravilo, po katerem se zahtevane najnižje cene razkrijejo šele v fazi, ko je na mizi že zavezujoča ponudba potencialnega kupca. V povezavi z določanjem prodajne cene je treba izpostaviti tudi občasne pritiske javnosti in politike ter medijev, zlasti glede očitkov o razprodaji državnega premoženja in varovanju nacionalnega interesa. Določena nasprotovanja posameznim prodajam pa so izražali tudi sindikati prodajanih družb, slednji največkrat iz utemeljenih razlogov, saj v tovrstnih prodajah kupci običajno izvedejo prestrukturiranje družbe in racionalizacijo poslovanja, vključno z znižanjem števila ali plač zaposlenih zaradi znižanja stroškov poslovanja in povečanja donosa na vloženi kapital. BV 11/2013 4. Problem dualizma v prodajnem postopku zaradi položaja bank prodajalk kot imetnic delnic in položaja bank prodajalk kot zastavnih upnic Kreditni posli, ki so jih banke sklepale s svojimi komitenti, so bili običajno zavarovani tudi z zastavnimi pravicami na delnicah, ki so bile ustanovljene in vpisane v centralni register KDD10 po določilih zakona o nematerializiranih vrednostnih papirjih11 (ZNVP) ali po določilih Stečaj družbe Lehman Brothers je bil največji stečaj v zgodovini ZDA. zakona o finančnih zavarovanjih12 (ZFZ). Banke so zastavne pravice na delnicah pridobile tudi v postopkih izterjav, ki so jih sprožile zoper tiste komitente, pri katerih terjatve predhodno niso bile zavarovane. Na tem mestu opisana kategorija bank–prodajalk sodi v kategorijo zastavnih upnikov, ki so v prodajnih postopkih bistveno bolj omejeni z razpolaganji z delnicami, ki so predmet prodaje, kot imetniki takšnih delnic. Druga kategorija bank–prodajalk so banke, ki so delnice pridobile v imetništvo zaradi poslovanja za svoj račun,13 pri čemer sodijo slednje v kategorijo imetnikov navadnih delnic z vsemi razpolagalnimi upravičenji, do katerih jih takšno imetništvo 105 upravičuje po zakonu o gospodarskih družbah14 (ZGD–1), torej do pravice do udeležbe pri upravljanju družbe, pravice do dela dobička (dividenda) in pravice do ustreznega dela preostalega premoženja po likvidaciji ali stečaju družbe.15 V takšnem položaju so imele banke prodajalke delnic, ki so imetnice delnic, pravico v prodajnih konzorcijskih pogodbah nastopati z vsemi zakonskimi razpolagalnimi upravičenji, kar pomeni, da so lahko (odvisno od velikosti svojega deleža) sklicale skupščino družbe in na njej predlagale in glasovale o predlogih sklepov (dokapitalizacije, statusna prestrukturiranja), se izrekale o predlogih uprave glede finančnega prestrukturiranja družbe (od katerega je bilo odvisno povečevanje ali nižanje vrednosti cene delnice), od uprav, v okviru zakonske pravice do informiranosti, zahtevale pojasnila o posameznih poslih, vključno z informacijami o angažmaju uprave v prodajnem poslu, ki so ga vodile oziroma v katerem so sodelovale same kot stranke prodajne konzorcijske pogodbe, pri čemer banke– zastavne upnice takšnih pravic in upravičenj niso imele. Imetništvo delnic (v primerjavi s položajem zastavnega upnika) je bilo še posebej pomembno v primerih, kadar takšen delež predstavlja 25 % premoženja družbe ali več (aktualen primer pro- 10 KDD – Centralna klirinško depotna družba, d.d., Ljubljana, Tivolska 48, Ljubljana, Slovenija. 11 Zakon o nematerializiranih vrednostnih papirjih (Ur.l. RS, št. 23/1999, s spremembami in dopolnitvami). 12 Zakon o finančnih zavarovanjih (Ur.l. RS, št. 47/2004 s spremembami in dopolnitvami). 13 Po določbi 3. odst. 8. člena (Investicijske storitve in posli) zakona o trgu finančnih instrumentov (Ur.l. RS, št. 67/2007 s spremembami in dopolnitvami) je poslovanje za svoj račun poslovanje v breme lastnega kapitala, katerega izid je sklenitev posla za lasten račun z enim ali več finančnimi instrumenti. 14 Zakon o gospodarskih družbah (Ur.l. RS, št. 42/2006 s spremembami in dopolnitvami). 15 Omenjene pravice se nanašajo zgolj na imetnike navadnih delnic po določbah 176. Člena ZGD–1 (navadne in prednostne delnice). Položaja in pravic imetnikov prednostnih delnic zaradi svojevrstnih specifik posebej ne obravnavam. BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS daje delnic družbe Mercator d.d.16). V takšnih primerih namreč ZGD–1 kot pogoj za sklenitev prodajnih pogodb za takšne deleže zahteva sklep skupščine družbe, ki je sprejet z večino najmanj treh četrtin pri sklepanju zastopanega osnovnega kapitala.17 V svojstvu imetnic delnic so banke za izpolnitev svojih obveznosti iz kupoprodajnih pogodb lahko delnice same prenesle neposredno na kupca z enostavnim nalogom za preknjižbo delnic18 in niso imele težav zastavnih upnic, ki so v ta namen praviloma morale podati nalog za unovčitev zastavne pravice na delnicah, saj bi se v nasprotnem primeru izpostavile različnim tveganjem. Prvo v vrsti tveganj predstavljajo morebitni ugovori ali celo odškodninske tožbe imetnika delnic ali dolžnika zaradi netransparentne prodaje delnic (ki kotirajo na borzi) oziroma prodaje delnic v nasprotju z ZNVP,19 ki določa, da lahko zastavni upnik v primeru, kadar dolžnik ob zapadlosti ne poravna terjatve, zavarovane z zastavo vrednostnega papirja, s katerim se trguje na organiziranem trgu, proda zastavljeni vrednostni papir na organiziranem trgu po osmih dneh od dneva, ko je opozoril dolžnika, pa tudi zastavitelja (če to ni ista oseba), da bo tako ravnal. Iz tega sledi, da mora zastavni upnik pred samo prodajo zastavljenih delnic sprva izvesti postopek obveščanja, nato pa delnice obvezno prodati prek organiziranega trga in ne na primer z neposredno preknjižbo na ime kupca mimo organiziranega trga,20 kot je to običajno pri prodajah večjih paketov delnic končnemu znanemu kupcu. Po določbah ZTFI sodi med organizirane trge finančnih instrumentov21 borzni trg,22 ki ga po določilih pravil borze23 upravlja borza. Zaradi navedenih značilnosti organiziranega trga je vsakršno unovčevanje zastavne pravice zunaj borznega trga, po poslovni praksi, že vnaprej izpostavljeno tveganju ugovorom tretjih zaradi domnevne netransparentnosti prodaje in kršitev dolžne skrbnosti prodajalcev pri prodaji zastavljenega premoženja. Poseben primer tveganja za imetnike zastavne pravice na delnicah so prodaje zastavljenih delnic zastavnega dolžnika, ki je v stečaju. Takšni zastavni upniki imajo namreč po določilih ZFPPIPP v stečajnem postopku položaj ločitvenih upnikov24 z ločitveno pravico25. Po splošnem zakonskem pravilu26 začetek stečajnega postopka ne vpliva na ločitveno pravico in terjatev, zavarovano s to ločitveno pravico. Posledično daje ZFPPIPP, v okviru posebnih pravil za ločitvene pravice, ki se lahko uveljavijo zunajsodno, takšnim imetnikom zastavnih pravic na delnicah pravico opraviti zunajsodno prodajo premoženja, ki je predmet ločitvene pravice.27 Iz navedenega sledi, da imajo banke–zastavne upnice pravico same zunajsodno prodajati delnice, vendar se v tem primeru pri prodaji dodatno izpostavljajo tudi ugovorom oziroma odškodninskim tožbam, ki bi jih v zvezi s takšno prodajo imel oziroma bi jih zoper prodajalce vložil stečajni upravitelj ali drugi upniki stečajnega dolžnika, zlasti tudi v primeru, če prodaje ne bi izvedli prek borze. Osnovni »problem« ugovorov dolžnika ali stečajnega upravitelja ali drugih upnikov dolžnika, ki se nanašajo na prodajni postopek oziroma na način prodaje (če je bila ta izpeljana prek zunajborznega posla), je namreč v tem, da bi, kolikor bi zastavni upniki–prodajalci prodajo zastavljenih delnic obvezno izvedli prek organiziranega trga s prodajo tržnega naročila v borzni trgovalni sistem (po določbah ZNVP), zaradi velike količine delnic, ki so običajno predmet takšnih pogodb, in velike nelikvidnosti borznega trga, nedvomno potisnili tečaje teh delnic navzdol, s tem pa bi bistveno zmanjšali možnost poplačila svojih terjatev. S takšnim ravnanjem bi najverjetneje nastala tudi škoda dolžniku oziroma stečajni masi. Sicer tudi v takšnih primerih obstaja možnost, da se kupec paketa delnic s svojim nakupnim nalogom postavi v borzni trgovalni sistem, vendar pa v tem primeru nastane tveganje konkurenčnih nakupnih nalogov špekulantov ali drugih dobrovernih udeležencev borznega 16 instrumentov je večstranski sistem, ki ga vodi oziroma upravlja določena oseba in ki ima naslednje značilnosti (i)v tem sistemu in v skladu z vnaprej določenimi pravili se povezuje ali omogoča povezovanje interesov glede prodaje ali nakupa finančnih instrumentov številnih tretjih oseb tako, da se sklenejo pravni posli v zvezi s finančnim instrumentom, ki je uvrščen v trgovanje po njegovih pravilih oziroma sistemih tega trga, (ii) ima dovoljenje pristojnega nadzornega organa (kar pomeni, da je nadzorovan), (iii)deluje redno in v skladu s pogoji določenimi v ZTFI. Slednji tudi določa, da je organiziran trg. 22 15. Člen ZTFI (borzni trg, borza, borzni posel in uradna borzna kotacija) Borzni trg je organiziran trg, katerega upravljavec ima sedež v Republiki Sloveniji. Borzni posel je posel s finančnimi instrumenti, sklenjen na borznem trgu. 23 1. Odst. 6. člena Pravil borze (Struktura borznega trga)(Pravila Borze, neuradno prečiščeno besedilo 26. marec 2013). 24 2. Odst. 19. člena ZFPPIPP (ločitvena pravica;ločitveni upnik) Ločitveni upnik je upnik, ki v postopku zaradi insolventnosti uveljavlja terjatev zavarovano z ločitveno pravico. 25 1. Odst. 19. člena ZFPPIPP (ločitvena pravica;ločitveni upnik) Ločitvena pravica je pravica upnika do plačila njegove terjatve iz določenega premoženja insolventnega dolžnika pred plačilom terjatev drugih upnikov tega dolžnika iz tega premoženja. 26 1. Odst. 179. člena ZFPPIPP (splošno pravilo). 27 1. člen 282. člena ZFPPIPP. V primeru prodaje delnic družbe Mercator d.d. je morala skupščina družbe Union d.d. odločati o sklenitvi pogodbe za prodajo delnic družbe Mercator d.d., katere pogodbena stranka je bila tudi družba Union d.d., saj je njen delež delnic, ki so bile predmet prodaje, predstavljal več kot 25 % njenega osnovnega kapitala. 17 330. Člen ZGD – 1 (prenos najmanj 25 % premoženja družbe). 18 Nalog za prenos delnic med računi različnih imetnikov. 19 47. člen ZNVP (Prodaja zastavljenega nematerializiranega vrednostnega papirja). 20 Tako imenovani OTC oziroma zunajborzni posel. 21 14. Člen ZTFI (organizirani trg in upravljavec organiziranega trga) organizirani trg finančnih 5. Poseben primer tveganja v primeru prodaje zastavljenih delnic stečajnih dolžnikov 106 BV 11/2013 BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS trga, ki utegnejo s svojimi nakupnimi nalogi pobrati celoto ali del prodajne količine tako konzorcijskih prodajalcev, posledično pa slednji tudi ne bi izpolnili osnovne obveznosti iz prodajne pogodbe, to je prenosa vseh delnic, ki so predmet prodaje, na kupca, ki je bil izbran kot končni kupec v prodajnem postopku. Zaradi takšnih tveganj so delnice, ki so zastavljene v korist bank upnic, komercialno bistveno manj zanimive za prodajo strateškim ali finančnim investitorjem, saj se slednji zavedajo tu opisanih tveganj in zato praviloma ne želijo imeti opravka z obremenjenimi delnicami ali insolventnimi imetniki teh delnic, kar kažejo tudi izkušnje iz nekaterih dosedanjih prodajnih postopkov. 6. Problem konzorcijskih zavez bank zaradi ukrepov po ZUKSB ZUKSB, (ii)o razvezi ali spremembi pogodbe zaradi spremenjenih okoliščin, (iii)o čezmernem prikrajšanju in (iv)o oderuški pogodbi30. Iz tega sledi, da je takšna banka primorana v skladu z zakonom in pogodbo z DUTB prenesti svoje terjatve, ki so zavarovane z zastavno pravico na delnicah (vključno z zastavno pravico), ali delnice, ki so predmet prodajnega postopka, na DUTB, zaradi česar lahko s tem preostale stranke prodaj- Banke so lahko delnice prenesle na kupca z nalogom za preknjižbo delnic. Zaradi uvedbe ZUKSB28 so banke zaradi zavez, podanih v konzorcijskih sporazumih, postale izpostavljene tveganju nemožnosti izpolnitve teh zavez, saj v primeru prenosa slabih terjatev teh bank na DUTB29 (t. i. »slabo banko«) ali v primeru uvedbe drugih ukrepov po ZUKSB, banke ne bi bile več imetnice prenesenih terjatev in zastavnih pravic, vpisanih na delnicah za namen zavarovanja teh terjatev. Smiselno enako velja v primeru prenosov delnic na DUTB. Po določbah ZUKSB se namreč za pogodbe DUTB z bankami, ki so deležne ukrepov po ZUKSB, ne uporabljajo določbe zakona, ki ureja obligacijska razmerja, (i)o izpodbijanju pravnih dejanj dolžnika, če je dolžnik banka deležna ukrepov po nega konzorcija izgubijo pomemben delež v izdajatelju31 in posledično s tem tudi prodajno premijo. Sicer je v tovrstnih primerih pričakovati, da se bo DUTB pridružila prodajnemu konzorciju, vendar prakse s tega področja trenutno še ni, zato ni moč podati ocene v tej povezavi. Zaradi navedenih tveganj vsebujejo novejše konzorcijske prodajne pogodbe izjeme od obveznosti skupne prodaje delnic za primer prenosov terjatev in zastavnih pravic ali delnic na DUTB, pri čemer takšen položaj tudi ne predstavlja kršitve zavez takšne banke, podanih v konzorcijski pogodbi. 28 32 Zakon o ukrepih Republike Slovenije za krepitev stabilnosti bank (Ur.l. RS, št. 105/2012 s spremembami in dopolnitvami). 29 Družba za upravljanje terjatev bank ustanovljena v skladu s 4. členom ZUKSB. 30 29. člen ZUKSB (izjeme od uporabe drugih zakonov) 31 S prenosom terjatve se, zaradi akcesornosti, skupaj s terjatvijo na DUTB prenese tudi zastavna pravica na delnicah. BV 11/2013 373. člen ZTFI (notranja informacija) določa, da je notranja informacija vsaka informacija, ki ima naslednje značilnosti: 1. je natančna, 2. ni bila objavljena, 3. se neposredno ali posredno nanaša: (i)na enega ali več izdajateljev finančnih instrumentov ali (ii) na enega ali več finančnih instrumentov, in 4. bi, če bi postala javna, verjetno pomembno vplivala na cene teh finančnih instrumentov ali na cene z njimi povezanih izvedenih finančnih instrumentov (torej informacija, ki bi jo razumen vlagatelj uporabil 107 7. Problem posredovanja zaupnih podatkov v prodajnih postopkih v povezavi s trgovanjem na podlagi notranjih informacij V primeru prodaj večjih paketov delnic je običaj, da potencialni kupec izvede skrbni pregled poslovanja družbe, izdajatelja delnic, ki so predmet prodaje v okviru prodajnega konzorcija. To je tudi običajna zahteva potencialnih kupcev. S tem v zvezi trčimo na dilemo posredovanja zaupnih in cenovno občutljivih podatkov potencialnim kupcem. Zlasti so za družbo občutljive poslovne skrivnosti, do katerih utegne priti potencialni kupec v procesu izvedbe skrbnega pregleda, pri čemer je težava še večja, če gre za neposrednega konkurenta. Rešitev je obvezno sklepanje pogodb o varovanju zaupnosti podatkov, ki natančno določajo, kateri podatki sodijo v kategorijo zaupnih podatkov in ki takšnemu pregledovalcu (i)prepovedujejo uporabo zaupnih podatkov, ki so mu posredovani v postopku skrbnega pregleda poslovanja družbe, za kakršen koli drug namen kot zgolj za nakup delnic družbe, ter prepovedujejo trgovanje na podlagi tako pridobljenih informacij, še zlasti če imajo te informacije naravo notranjih informacij32, (ii)zavezujejo k vzpostavitvi ustreznih sistemov in preprek za potrebe varovanja pridobljenih zaupnih podatkov ter (iii)zavezujejo k uničenju vseh pridobljenih zaupnih podatkov na zahtevo družbe. Dodatna varovalka je tudi postopno posredovanje posameznih kategorij zaupnih podatkov potencialnemu kupcu, glede na fazo prodajnega kot del podlage za svojo naložbeno odločitev). Nadalje določa še, da se domneva, da je informacija natančna: 1. če označuje: – sklop okoliščin, ki obstajajo ali je mogoče razumno pričakovati, da bodo nastopile, ali – dogodek, ki se je zgodil, ali je razumno mogoče pričakovati, da bo nastopil, in 2. če je zadosti podrobna, da je na njeni podlagi mogoče sklepati o mogočih učinkih teh okoliščin ali dogodka na cene finančnih instrumentov ali z njimi povezanih izvedenih finančnih instrumentov. BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS postopka, torej bolj kot se približuje podpis kupoprodajne pogodbe za paket delnic, večji dostop ima potencialni kupec do pomembnih zaupnih podatkov o poslovanju družbe. Poseben problem predstavlja tudi striktna zakonodaja, ki ureja trgovanje na podlagi notranjih informacij. ZTFI namreč izrecno prepoveduje vsakršno trgovanje na podlagi notranjih informacij33 in takšno ravnanje opredeljuje kot prepovedano ravnanje zlorabe trga (kazenski zakonik pa ga klasificira tudi kot kaznivo dejanje)34, pri čemer pa ZTFI ne ureja tudi morebitnih izjem, ki jih predstavljajo zlasti tudi primeri pridobivanja takšnih informacij s strani končnega kupca delnic v okviru skrbnih pregledov poslovanja družb (izdajateljev teh delnic), kar bistveno otežuje razkrivanje cenovno občutljivih informacij potencialnim kupcem in s tem posledično tudi prodajo bančnih naložb oziroma premoženja, ki je namenjeno za poplačilo slabih terjatev bank. Aktualne težave bank upnic v insolvenčnih postopkih Čeprav naj bi po C. Warrenu veljalo, da je stečaj turobna in depresivna zadeva, stečajno pravo pa suhoparna in pogum jemajoča tema,35 je nesporno, da je insolvenčna zakonodaja pomemben del gospodarstva, pri tem pa praksa dokazuje, da gre vse prej kot za suhoparno področje. Problemov, ki so tako ali drugače 33 372. člen ZTFI (prepovedani ravnanji zlorabe trga). 34 243. člen KZ (Zloraba notranje informacije) Kdor notranjo informacijo, ki bi lahko pomembno vplivala na ceno vrednostnega papirja ali izvedenega finančnega instrumenta, uvrščenega na organizirani trg v Republiki Sloveniji ali v vsaj eni državi članici Evropske unije oziroma za katerega je bil vložen predlog za uvrstitev na tak trg, ne glede na to, ali se z njim trguje na tem trgu ali ne, pridobi v zvezi s svojim položajem pri izdajatelju vrednostnega papirja, z lastniškim deležem v kapitalu izdajatelja vrednostnega papirja, s svojo zaposlitvijo ali pri opravljanju dejavnosti, in jo izkoristi z nakupom ali prodajo tega vrednostnega papirja ali izvedenega finančnega instrumenta zase ali za koga drugega, povezani z insolventnimi postopki, je nedvomno veliko in njihovo število ter obseg presegata predmetni članek, zato bodo opisani in izpostavljeni (le) najbolj pereči. 8. Prenos lastninske pravice na s hipoteko obremenjeni nepremičnini na stečajnega dolžnika SPZ36 določa, da je prepoved odtujitve in obremenitve dovoljena le v točno določenih primerih, kar pomeni, da hipotekarni upnik, razen z izjemo določeno v četrtem odstavku navedenega člena, ne more doseči vknjižbe prepovedi odtujitve in obremenitve. V primeru, ko sta osebni in realni dolžnik različni osebi,37 lahko realni dolžnik lastninsko pravico na (s hipoteko obremenjeni) nepremičnini prenese na tretjo osebo (pridobitelj) brez dovoljenja in/ali soglasja hipotekarnega upnika. Stečaj dolžnika, ki je hkrati tudi zastavitelj, praviloma ne povzroča težav. Ločitvena pravica je pravica upnika do plačila njegove terjatve iz določenega premoženja stečajnega dolžnika pred plačilom terjatev drugih upnikov tega dolžnika iz tega premoženja, pri čemer je ločitveni upnik tisti, ki v postopku zaradi insolventnosti uveljavlja terjatev zavarovano z ločitveno pravico.38 Terjatve, ki so nastale do dneva začetka stečajnega postopka, mora upnik v stečajnem postopku prijaviti v zakonsko določenem roku, kolikor pa je ta terjatev na dan začetposredno ali neposredno, se kaznuje za zaporom do treh let. (2) Enako se kaznuje oseba, ki notranjo informacijo sporoči nepoklicani osebi ali na podlagi notranje informacije priporoči tretji osebi nakup ali prodajo vrednostnega papirja ali izvedenega finančnega instrumenta. (3) Enako se kaznuje oseba, ki nepooblaščeno pride do notranje informacije in jo izkoristi z nakupom ali prodajo tega vrednostnega papirja ali izvedenega finančnega instrumenta zase ali za koga drugega, posredno ali neposredno. (4) Če je bila z dejanjem iz prejšnjih odstavkov pridobljena velika premoženjska korist, se storilec kaznuje z zaporom do petih let. 35 Charles Warren: »Bankruptcy in United States Histroy 1«, 1935. 108 ka stečajnega postopka zavarovana z zastavno pravico upnika nasproti stečajnemu dolžniku, mora upnik v stečajnem postopku v istem roku (za prijavo terjatve) prijaviti tudi ločitveno pravico, saj zakon v nasprotnem primeru (če upnik v roku ne prijavi ločitvene pravice) določa, da le ta preneha.39 Postopek in navedene posledice verjetno niso sporne. Situacija pa se lahko zaplete (oziroma se je zapletla), ko stečajni dolžnik postane lastnik s hipoteko obremenjene nepremičnine po začetku stečajnega postopka in/ali po izteku roka za prijavo terjatve. Povsem življenjsko je, da lastnik lastninsko pravico na s hipoteko obremenjeni nepremičnini prenese na pridobitelja, s čimer hipotekarni upnik ni seznanjen; nad pridobiteljem se začne stečajni postopek, vendar pa pridobitelj ob začetku stečajnega postopka v zemljiški knjigi (še) ni vknjižen kot zemljiškoknjižni lastnik. Hipotekarni upnik je v konkretnem primeru v stečajni postopek nad stečajnim dolžnikom (pridobiteljem) prijavil vse svoje terjatve do stečajnega dolžnika, ki jih je imel na dan začetka stečajnega postopka, ne pa tudi ločitvene pravice, saj stečajni dolžnik lastninske pravice na nepremičninah, na katerih je imel hipotekarni upnik vknjižene hipoteke (v zavarovanje svojih terjatev), ob začetku stečajnega postopka (še) ni imel oziroma je lastninsko pravico na teh nepremičninah pridobil šele po začetku stečajnega postopka. Višje 36 Stvarnopravni zakonik 38. člen; Ur. l. RS, št. 87/2002 in spremembe. 37 Možni varianti: zastavitelj zastavi svojo nepremičnino za tuj dolg ali osebni dolžnik, ki je hkrati tudi realni dolžnik, odtuji s hipoteko obremenjeno nepremičnino tretji osebi (ki pa ne prevzame tudi osebnega dolga). 38 19. člen zakona o finančnem poslovanju, postopkih zaradi insolventnosti in prisilnem prenehanju (ZFPPIPP); Ur. l. RS, št. 126/2007 in spremembe. 39 Prvi odstavek 298. člena ZFPPIPP v povezavi s petim odstavkom istega člena. Posebna pravila o ločitvenih pravicah, ki se lahko uveljavljajo zunajsodno in jih ni treba prijaviti v stečajnem postopku, so določena v 282. členu ZFPPIPP. BV 11/2013 BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS sodišče je potrdilo sklep prvostopenjskega sodišča o zavrženju naknadne prijave ločitvenih pravic, pri čemer je višje sodišče zavzelo stališče, da »... je upnik prijavil ločitveno pravico v predmetnem stečajnem postopku po preteku prekluzivnega roka za prijavo ločitvenih pravic. Po določilu prvega odstavka 296. člena ZFPPIPP morajo upniki v stečajnem postopku prijaviti vse terjatve in tudi ločitveno pravico (prim. prvi odstavek 298. člena ZFPPIP) do stečajnega dolžnika, ki so nastale do začetka stečajnega postopka; razen če gre za terjatve iz drugega in tretjega odstavka 59. člena ZFPPIPP). Okoliščina, da stečajni dolžnik postane lastnik s hipoteko obremenjenih nepremičnin po preteku roka za prijavo ločitvenih pravic, ne opravičuje hipotekarnega upnika do podaljšanja roka za prijavo ločitvenih pravic, saj gre za prekluzivni rok40«. Že iz citiranega stališča izhaja dolžnost upnika, da mora v stečajnem postopku nad stečajnim dolžnikom prijaviti (le) tiste terjatve in ločitvene pravice, ki so nastale do dneva začetka stečajnega postopka. Dan začetka stečajnega postopka je namreč pomemben mejnik za presojo pravnih posledic.41 Popolnoma nasprotno stališče pa je isto sodišče zavzelo v drugi zadevi, kjer je zapisalo, da »rok za prijavo terjatve, zavarovane z ločitveno pravico, iz 2. odstavka 59. člena v zvezi s 1. odstavkom 298. člena ZFPPIPP, predpostavlja situacijo, ko je upnik terjatev in ločitveno pravico pridobil še pred začetkom stečajnega postopka. V obravnavanem primeru pa je – bo upnik ločitveno pravico zoper stečajnega dolžnika pridobil šele med stečajnim postopkom, saj je/bo premoženje, na katerem ločitveno pravico upnik uveljavlja, prišlo v stečajno maso stečajnega dolžnika šele, ko je/bo ta postal lastnik nepremičnin (na katerih upnik uveljavlja pravico do ločenega poplačila) z vknjižbo lastninske BV 11/2013 pravice stečajnega dolžnika na teh nepremičninah. Evidentno je, da v roku za prijavo terjatev in ločitvene pravice iz 2. odstavka 59. člena v zvezi s 1. odstavkom 298. člena ZFPPIPP upnik še ni mogel prijaviti svoje ločitvene pravice zoper stečajnega dolžnika, ker nepremičnine, na katerih uveljavlja upnik ločitveno pravico, še niso bile del premoženja stečajnega dolžnika. Na vprašanje,v kakšnem roku bi torej upnik moral prijaviti ločitveno pravico v obravnavani situaciji, ZFPPIPP ne daje Zakonodaja izrecno prepoveduje vsakršno trgovanje na podlagi notranjih informacij. eksaktnega odgovora.42 Vsebinsko enako stališče je sodišče zavzelo tudi v drugi zadevi, ko je odločilo, »da upnik še ni pridobil ločitvene pravice, ker nepremičnine, na katerih ima upnik zastavno pravico, še niso last stečajnega dolžnik«.43 V zvezi s tem se seveda postavi vprašanje, kdaj stečajni dolžnik (pridobitelj) na podlagi pravnega posla pridobi lastninsko pravico na nepremičnini, saj je treba poleg SPZ upoštevati tudi določbe (procesnega) ZZK-1,44 in sicer (vsaj) določbe v 5. 6., 7. in 10. členu. V zvezi z načelom začetka učinkovanja vpisov je treba opozoriti, da je tovrstna ureditev potrebna zaradi uresničitve prednostnega načela iz 6. člena SPZ45, zaradi katerega je potrebno, 109 da zakon varuje vrstni red predlog za vknjižbo stvarnih pravic v zemljiško knjigo. SPZ v 49. členu jasno določa, da se za pridobitev lastninske pravice na nepremičnini s pravnim poslom zahteva vpis v zemljiško knjigo. Tudi Višje sodišče v Ljubljani je zavzelo jasno in nedvomno stališče: »Za pridobitev lastninske pravice na nepremičninah s pravnim poslom se zahteva vpis v zemljiško knjigo (1. odstavek 49. člena SPZ). Zgolj s sklenitvijo pravnega posla torej kupec na nepremičnini ne pridobi lastninske pravice. Tudi ne zadošča, da je kupec vložil zemljiškoknjižni predlog za pridobitev lastninske pravice. Res bo, če bo njegovemu predlogu ugodeno, vpis pravice učinkoval od trenutka, ko je zemljiškoknjižno sodišče prejelo predlog za vpis (5. člen ZZK-1), vendarle pa še ni vpisan kot lastnik, ker o vpisu še ni odločeno.46« Nujna predpostavka za (uspešno) uveljavljanje ločitvene pravice za poplačilo terjatve v insolventnem postopku je tako dejstvo, da je premoženje, ki je predmet ločenega poplačila, v času prijave last stečajnega dolžnika. Če ni tako, upnik (na tem premoženju) ne pridobi ločitvene pravice, saj ne gre za premoženje, ki bi bilo v času prijave last stečajnega dolžnika. Šele če oziroma ko bo prišlo premoženje v stečajno maso stečajnega dolžnika, bo oziroma bi lahko upnik uveljavljal ločitveno pravico. Prav tako velja omeniti, da (previdnostne) prijave ločitvenih pravic pod odložnim pogojem – da bo premoženje, na katerem 40 Sklep VSL Cst, opr. št. 281/2011 z dne 17.11.2011. 41 244. člen ZFPPIPP. 42 Sklep VSL opr. št. III Cpg 142/2010 z dne 03. 03. 2010. 43 Sklep VSL opr. št. Cst 177/2012, z dne 04. 07. 2012. 44 Zakon o zemljiški knjigi; Ur. l. Rs, št. 58/2003 in spremembe. 45 Če obstaja na isti stvari več stvarnih pravic, ima prej pridobljena stvarna pravica iste vrste prednost pred pozneje pridobljeno stvarno pravico. 46 Sklep VSL opr. št. I Cp 1257/2006, z dne 09. 03. 2006. BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS ima upnik zastavno pravico, prišlo v premoženje stečajnega dolžnika – niso ustrezne, saj po ZFPPIPP ni vsak odložni pogoj razlog za prijavo terjatve in ločitvene pravice kot pogojne. Kot pogojno terjatev z odložnim pogojem ZFPPIPP, ki jo mora upnik prijaviti v stečajnem postopku, opredeljuje v tretjem odstavku 59. člena za primer, če je zoper upnika vložena tožba za izpodbijanje pravnih dejanj stečajnega dolžnika in če bo tožbenemu zahtevku pravnomočno ugodeno, ter v drugem odstavku 296. člena za situacijo, ko obstaja možnost, da bo upnik med stečajnim postopkom pridobil regresno terjatev zoper stečajnega dolžnika, torej v primeru, ko je upnik odgovoren za obveznost stečajnega dolžnika kot solidarni sodolžnik, porok ali zastavitelj in to obveznost po začetku stečajnega postopka izpolni. Že je bilo rečeno, da ZFPPIPP roka, v katerem naj upniki prijavijo pravico do ločenega poplačila (njihove pravočasno prijavljene terjatve) iz premoženja stečajnega dolžnika, ki ga bo ta pridobil po dnevu začetka stečajnega postopka, ne določa, kar pa ne pomeni, da kasnejše uveljavljanje ločitvenih pravic ni mogoče oziroma celo, da bi tovrstne ločitvene pravice »avtomatsko« prenehale. Glede na izpostavljena stališča menim, da je (bila) odločitev sodišča v zadevi Cst 281/2011 nepravilna, saj stečajni dolžnik ob vložitvi prijave ni bil lastnik nepremičnin, čeprav je zemljiškoknjižni postopek (pridobitev lastninske pravice) že bil sprožen. Četudi rok za naknadno prijavo ločitvene pravice res ni določen, bi moralo sodišče v takih primerih, ko stečajni dolžnik na podlagi pravnega posla postane zemljiškoknjižni lastnik s hipoteko obremenjene nepremičnine, hipotekarnemu upniku dopustiti naknadno prijavo ločitvenih pravic, saj ni nikakršnega razloga za npr. smiselno uporabo 4. odstavka 299. člena ZFPPIPP, po katerem upnik, ki v roku ne prijavi izločitvene pravice, izločitvene pravice ne izgubi, pač pa je prijava izločitvene pravice možna do prodaje premoženja oziroma za pravico do plačila denarnega zneska pridobljenega s prodajo do objave načrta prve splošne razdelitve. Ni razloga, da enaka logika ne bi veljala tudi v situaciji, ko stečajni dolžnik lastninsko pravico na s hipoteko obremenjeni nepremični pridobi po začetku stečajnega postopka in/ ali po izteku roka iz drugega odstavka 59. člena ZFPPIPP. 9. Odgovornost zastavitelja po izbrisu stečajnega dolžnika V povezavi z navedenim je treba opozoriti na tudi sicer zelo aktualno vprašanje, ali hipotekarni upnik od realnega dolžnika, ko osebni dolžnik kot pravna oseba zaradi zaključka stečajnega postopka preneha obstajati, lahko zahteva plačilo obveznosti. Navedena situacija je možna, če zastavitelj svojo nepremičnino zastavi za tuji dolg, ko torej osebni dolžnik že od samega začetka ni tudi realni dolžnik, ali pa če osebni dolžnik, ki je sprva bil tudi realni dolžnik, po ustanovitvi hipoteke lastninsko pravico na (s hipoteko obremenjeni) nepremičnini prenese na tretjo osebo. Temeljna posledica in značilnost zastave za tuji dolg je, da za eno obveznost odgovarjata dve osebi, pri čemer pa je odgovornost realnega dolžnik omejena na kupnino, ki je dosežena v (potencialnem) izvršilnem postopku. Vrhovno sodišče Republike Slovenije je zavzelo negativno stališče, saj »da ugasitev zavarovane terjatve hipoteko vsebinsko izvotli in ji odvzame ves smisel, zato bi bilo pripisovanje prevelikega pomena dejstvu, da hipoteka formalno sicer še obstaja, v nasprotju s samim bistvom akcesornosti tovrstnega zavarovanja«.47 Z zaključkom stečajnega postopka nad osebnim dolžnikom v celoti ugasnejo vse terjatve zoper 110 stečajnega dolžnika, ki so nastale do začetka stečajnega postopka, zato je bila hipotekarna tožba, ki je bila vložena več kot leto dni po zaključku stečajnega postopka, zoper realne dolžnike po mnenju vrhovnega sodišča neutemeljena. Tudi pri poroštvu gre za odgovornost za izpolnitev tuje obveznosti, pri čemer je tudi porokova obveznost odvisna od obstoja obveznosti glavnega dolžnika. Ni dvoma, da gre tudi poroštvu za enak namen, in sicer zagotoviti upniku poplačilo terjatve, kolikor je ne bo izpolnil glavni dolžnik. Sodna praksa je tu drugačna: »Zaradi začetka stečajnega postopka nad dolžnikom se izpolnitvena dolžnost poroka ne spremeni in je porok dolžan izpolniti obveznosti na način in v rokih, kot se je zavezal ob sprejemu poroštvene zaveze«48 in »Prenehal je le dolžnik glavne obveznosti. V primeru, ko glavni dolžnik preneha zaradi stečaja in ko torej ni pravnega nasledstva, ostaja porok zavezan za celotno obveznost.«49 Sodna praksa je torej enotna – zmanjšanje obveznosti glavnega dolžnika v stečajnem postopku ali postopku prisilne poravnave50 ne pomeni tudi sorazmernega zmanjšanja obveznosti poroka,51 pač pa, kot že citirano, porok ostaja zavezan za celotno obveznost. Navedeno mora smiselno veljati tudi za zastavno pravico, ko sta osebni in realni dolžnik različni osebi, saj ni utemeljenih razlogov za različno obravnavo poroštva in hipoteke, ko zastavitelj jamči le kot realni dolžnik za tuji dolg.52 Vrenčur53 tudi opozarja na nevarnost prenosa lastninske pravice na s hipoteko obremenjeni nepremičnini, saj le to, kot je že bilo ugotovljeno zgoraj, 47 Sodba VS RS II IPs 120/2007 z dne 14. 10. 2009. 48 Sodba VSL I Cpg 754/2009 z dne 10. 12. 2009. 49 Sodba VSK I Cpg 37/2005 z dne 20. 10. 2005. 50 Skladno z določbo 1022 člena Obligacijskega zakonika; Ur. l. RS, št. 83/2001 (OZ). 51 Ena od zakonsko določenih izjem glede akcesornosti. BV 11/2013 BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS praviloma ni onemogočeno, kar pa bi izvotlilo smisel realnega zavarovanja terjatev. Stališče, da prenehanje glavnega dolžnika ne vpliva na odgovornost zastavitelja za zavarovano obveznost, zato tudi ne povzroči prenehanja hipoteke, zastopa tudi dr. Plavšakova,54 ki opozarja, »da zastaviteljeva odgovornost za (tujo) obveznost ni odvisna (akcesorna) od odgovornosti (glavnega) dolžnika za to (z vidika dolžnika lastno) obveznost, temveč samo od obstoja te obveznosti. Zato s prenehanjem odgovornosti glavnega dolžnika za obveznost ne preneha tudi porokova oziroma zastaviteljeva odgovornost za to obveznost«. Avtorica sklene: »Ker s prenehanjem pravne osebe kot glavnega dolžnika njene obveznosti ne prenehajo, tudi po njenem prenehanju še vedno obstaja odgovornost poroka oziroma zastavitelja za to obveznost. Zato prenehanje pravne osebe kot glavnega dolžnika ne povzroči prenehanja hipoteke.« Ker je (glavni) namen poroštva in zastave za tuji dolg ravno v dodatnem varstvu upnika (upnik dobi jamstvo, da bo obveznost glavnega dolžnika, kolikor je ne bo poravnal glavni dolžnik sam, poravnala druga oseba), je stališče, da s prenehanjem pravne osebe prenehajo tudi njene obveznosti, s tem pa tudi dana zavarovanja, v popolnem nasprotju z logiko, namenom in pomenom tovrstnih institutov55 in zato, ter skladno z gornjimi argumenti, tudi nepravilno. Stališču, da obveznosti kapitalske gospodarske družbe, nad katero je bil opravljen postopek stečaja, z izbrisom iz registra na podlagi pravnomočnega sklepa o končanju stečajnega postopka ne prenehajo, je na(vse)zadnje pritrdilo tudi vrhovno sodišče.56 10. Sklep Zakonodaja seveda ne more predvideti vseh življenjskih situacij in potez dolžnikov, ki so nemalokrat BV 11/2013 v škodo upnikov, zato je pri iskanju rešitev treba uporabiti tudi zdravo logiko in upoštevati namen institutov zavarovanja. Zlasti sodišča bi si morala prizadevati za enotno sodno prakso, ki lahko bistveno pripomore k izboljšanju pravne varnosti vseh deležnikov v pravnih razmerjih. Upoštevaje trenutno stanje v slovenskem bančnem sektorju lahko ugotovimo, da bi bilo, podobno kot sanacijo slovenskih bank, smiselno tudi prodajo bančnega premoženja izvesti bolj organizirano in z večjo podporo politike, zlasti v pogledu prilagoditve zakonodaje v obsegu, ki bi olajšal prodaje večjih paketov delnic in tako omogočil razbremenitev bančnih bilanc slabih terjatev, sočasno pa tudi kupcem omogočil hitrejši prihod na slovenski trg, slovenski državi pa s tem tudi dostop do še kako potrebnih neposrednih tujih investicij. LITERATURA IN VIRI/REFERENCES: RS, št. 105/2012 s spremembami in dopolnitvami). Pravila borze (Pravila Borze, neuradno prečiščeno besedilo 26. marec 2013). Priporočila Banke Slovenije za usklajeno postopanje bank upnic v primeru podjetij v finančnih težavah (September 2012) . Kazenski zakonik (KZ-1) Ur.l. RS, št. 55/2008 (s spremembami in dopolnitvami) Sklep VSL Cst, opr. št. 281/2011 z dne 17. 11. 2011. Sklep VSL opr. št. III Cpg 142/2010 z dne 03. 03. 2010. Sklep VSL opr. št. Cst 177/2012, z dne 04. 07. 2012. Zakon o zemljiški knjigi; Ur. l. Rs, št. 58/2003 in spremembe. Sklep VSL opr. št. I Cp 1257/2006, z dne 09. 03. 2006. Sodba VS RS II IPs 120/2007 z dne 14. 10. 2009. Sodba VSL I Cpg 754/2009 z dne 10. 12. 2009. Sodba VSK I Cpg 37/2005 z dne 20. 10. 2005. Obligacijski zakonik; Ur. l. RS, št. 83/2001 (OZ). Vrenčur Renato, Usoda akcesornih zavarovanj v primeru prenehanja insolventnega dolžnika, Podjetje in delo, št. 5/2012, str. 774 in dalje. Lehman Brothers Press Release (Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc. Announces It Intends to File Chapter 11 Bankruptcy Petition” (PDF). Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc. September 15, 2008. Plavšak Nina, Učinek prenehanja glavnega dolžnika na hipoteko za tujo obveznost, Pravna praksa, št. 22/2012, str. 22. Marketwatch. September 15, 2005. “Lehman folds with record $613 billion debt”. Posvetovanju sodnikov o nekaterih problemih v zvezi s stečaji v Ljubljani (28. 11. 1996 in 29. 01. 1997), Podjetje in delo, 1997, št. 3, stran 408 in nadaljnje. Članek: Sanacija bank ter razdolževanje podjetij in bank, Božo Jašovič in Marko Simoneti, Finance 14. maj 2013. Charles Warren: “Bankruptcy in United States History 1”, 1935. Stališča in pravna mnenja Vrhovnega sodišča Republike Slovenije z dne 06. 04. 2012. VS RS Sodba III Ips 22/2009, z dne 28. 02. 2012. Stvarnopravni zakonik 38. člen; Ur. l. RS, št. 87/2002 in spremembe. Zakon o gospodarskih družbah (Ur.l. RS, št. 42/2006 s spremembami in dopolnitvami). Zakon o nematerializiranih vrednostnih papirjih (Ur.l. RS, št. 23/1999, s spremembami in dopolnitvami). Zakona o trgu finančnih instrumentov (Ur.l. RS, št. 67/2007 s spremembami n dopolnitvami) Zakon o finančnih zavarovanjih (Ur.l. RS, št. 47/2004 s spremembami in dopolnitvami). Zakona o finančnem poslovanju, postopkih zaradi insolventnosti in prisilnem prenehanju (ZFPPIPP); Ur. l. RS, št. 126/2007 in spremembe. Zakon o ukrepih Republike Slovenije za krepitev stabilnosti bank (Ur.l. 111 52 Vrenčur Renato, Usoda akcesornih zavarovanj v primeru prenehanja insolventnega dolžnika, Podjetje in delo, št. 5/2012, str. 774 in dalje. 53 Ibidem. 54 Plavšak Nina, Učinek prenehanja glavnega dolžnika na hipoteko za tujo obveznost, Pravna praksa, št. 22/2012, str. 22. 55 Glede vprašanja, ali mora zastavitelj, ki za zavarovano terjatev upnika do glavnega dolžnika jamči s hipoteko in kot porok, dopustiti poplačilo iz zastavljene nepremičnine, kadar je glavni dolžnik gospodarska družba, ki je prenehala zaradi zaključka stečajnega postopka in bila izbrisana iz sodnega registra, je bila dopuščena revizija, o kateri pa po javno dostopnih podatkih še ni bilo odločeno. 56 Stališča in pravna mnenja Vrhovnega sodišča Republike Slovenije z dne 06. 04. 2012; dostopno na http://www.sodisce.si/znanje/sodna praksa/ pravna mnenja in stalisca/42640/. BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS UDK 336.71:338.124.4:347.738:061.1EU Reševanje bank z zasebnimi sredstvi Maja Koritnik in Peter Merc* BAIL-IN TOOL FOR BANK RESOLUTION The approach for the rescue of ailing banks in the EU has switched over the recent years from the initial bail-out measures, backed by public finances, to the bail-in measures, which ensure the minimisation of the taxpayer costs by means of contributions the shareholders and certain creditors give to the bank. The bail-in measures have developed in the course of the adaptations of the state aid regime for banks and have been adopted as one of the resolution tools within the forthcoming EU framework for the recovery and resolution of banks. This major change in the rules of the game is likely to affect the capital structure of banks as well as their costs of funding. JEL G01 G21 G34 S anacija bank v težavah poteka v več državah članicah EU že več kot pol desetletja. Ukrepi za reševanje bank so sprva temeljili na finančni pomoči zagotovljeni iz javnih sredstev (t. i. »bail-out« ukrepi); ob tem je evropska komisija (EK) oblikovala vrsto pravil in ukrepov, s katerimi je postavila regulatorni okvir za sheme državnih pomoči, namenjene bankam v težavah. Regulativa EU pa se je postopoma vedno bolj nagibala v smer ukrepov, ki breme reševanja bank prenašajo z ramen davkoplačevalcev na ramena delničarjev bank, podrejenih upnikov in v skrajnem primeru v določenem delu tudi na nekatere nepodrejene upnike (t. i. »bail-in« ukrepi). V članku predstavljava razvoj teh ukrepov, ki je vzporedno potekal po dveh »frontah«, in sicer (i) v okviru režima podeljevanja državnih pomoči za banke in (ii) skozi oblikovanje širšega okvira EU za sanacijo in reševanje bank. Sanacija in reševanje evropskih bank Po začetku finančne krize so banke v težavah najprej reševale države z javnimi sredstvi. V EU so se tako v okviru režima podeljevanja državnih pomoči, ki temelji na določbah pogodbe o delovanju EU, oblikovala posebna pravila za banke na podlagi sporočil, ki jih je EK izdajala od leta 2008 naprej.1 Gre za sistem pravil, ki sledi sprotnim spremembam razmer v bančnem sektorju in se posledično postopoma spreminja, dopolnjuje in razvija. * Mag. Maja Koritnik (LL.M.), Sektor za poslovanje s finančnimi institucijami v Novi Ljubljanski banki d.d., in mag. Peter Merc, Center za skladnost poslovanja v Novi Ljubljanski banki d.d. Predstavljena so stališča avtorjev, ki niso nujno tudi stališča družbe, v kateri sta avtorja zaposlena. 1 Postopek pred EK sta avtorja predstavila v članku Postopek ugotavljanja dovoljenosti državne pomoči pred evropsko komisijo, Bančni vestnik, leto 62, št. 5, maj 2013. 112 BV 11/2013 BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS Hierarhija bančnih sredstev in kategorije kapitala Opisani ukrepi za reševanje bank temeljijo na hierarhiji sredstev gospodarske družbe, ki izhaja iz insolvenčnih postopkov. V primeru stečaja se iz stečajne mase najprej poravnajo vse nepodrejene (senior) obveznosti; ko so te poplačane v celoti, se poravnajo podrejene obveznosti in šele po njihovem celotnem poplačilu pridejo na vrsto delničarji. V primeru bank so podrejene obveznosti še nadaljnje hierarhično razporejene. Skladno z zadnjimi spremembami bančne regulative (CRR1) bančni regulatorni kapital sestavljata temeljni kapital (Tier 1) in dodatni kapital (Tier 2). Prvo kategorijo sestavljajo vplačani kapital, zadržani dobiček (skupaj temeljni kapital) in najkvalitetnejši hibridni instrumenti (dodatni temeljni kapital), ki so po svojih lastnostnih podobni navadnim delnicam. Za te kategorije lastniškega kapitala velja največja podre- Slika 1: Shematski prikaz kategorij kapitala T1 in T2 (glede na lastnosti iz naslova pokrivanja izgub) po dosedanji ureditvi in uredbi o bonitetnih zahtevah za kreditne institucije in investicijska podjetja (CRR1); going concern Podrejeni dolg dodatnega kapitala I (UT2) Hibridni instrumenti dodatnega kapitala I (UT2) Hibridni instrumenti temeljnega kapitala (T1) KAPITAL (Core T1) BV 11/2013 Vir: avtorja 113 CRR 1 Podrejeni dolg dodatnega kapitala (T2) Dodatni temeljni kapital (AT1) going concern gone concern dosedanja ureditev 2 Utemeljitev EK iz sporočila EK o bančništvu #2. 3 Prvi predlog direktive, ki ga je pripravila EK, je bil natančneje predstavljen v članku M. Koritnik: Predlog novega režima EU za reševanje krize v finančnem sektorju; Bančni vestnik, leto 60, št. 4, april 2011. jenost, kar pomeni dvoje, in sicer da instrumenti temeljnega kapitala absorbirajo največ izgube, ter da jo absorbirajo prvi, že tekom rednega poslovanja (ang. »going concern«). Tier 2 kapital pa sestavljajo datirani podrejeni dolžniški instrumenti, ki so v primeru stečaja banke nadrejeni instrumentom temeljnega kapitala in se poplačajo, ko so v celoti poravnane obveznosti do nepodrejenih upnikov (ang. »gone concern«). V okviru trenutnih reševanj bank pa so pomembni obstoječi kapitalski instrumenti bank, ki so bili izdani skladno z do sedaj veljavno bančno regulativo, v kateri je bila kategorija Tier 2 kapitala (»dodatni kapital 1«) razdeljena na (i) trajne hibridne instrumente dodatnega kapitala I (ang. »Upper Tier 2«, UT2), ki so namenjeni pokrivanju izgub banke v času njenega rednega poslovanja, in na (ii) datirane instrumente podrejenega dolga (ang. »Lower Tier 2«, LT2), ki pokrivajo izgube banke šele v primeru njene insolventnosti; izven stečaja gone concern Reševanje bank pa se je za marsikatero državo izkazalo za prevelik zalogaj, ki je nekatere privedel tudi do nevzdržnega javnofinančnega položaja, tako da so zaprosile za mednarodno pomoč (npr. Španija, Ciper). Poleg tega pa reševanje bank z javnimi sredstvi tudi ni primerno, saj bi ustaljeno načelo, da se tako rešuje banke, ki so se spuščale v preveč tvegane posle, lahko vodilo do moralnega tveganja njihovega vodstva.2 Zato se je na ravni EU pojavila ideja o vzpostavitvi regulatornega okvira oziroma sistema pravil za sanacijo ter reševanje bank. Prvi predlog je EK objavila že leta 2010 in je predvideval okrepljen nadzor bank, poudarek na preventivnih ukrepih in pripravah na morebitno krizo ter obsežnejše pristojnosti nadzornikov za zgodnje reševanje bank (v okviru katerih je predviden tudi instrument za reševanje z zasebnimi sredstvi, ang. »bail-in tool«).3 Predlog direktive o vzpostavitvi okvira za sanacijo ter reševanje kreditnih institucij in investicijskih podjetij je po nadaljnjem usklajevanju v juniju 2013 potrdil Svet EU (predlog direktive), trenutno pa je v postopku pred evropskim parlamentom. Gre za enega od elementov bančne unije, poleg, med drugim, nove bančne ureditve (CRR1 in CRD4) in predlogov za enotni mehanizem za reševanje ter enotno jamstveno shemo za bančne vloge. Cilj teh ureditev je, da se reševanje bank z nacionalne ravni prenese na evropsko ter da se tako prekine začaran krog med težavami bank in z njimi povezanimi višjimi stroški zadolževanja za države, kjer imajo te banke sedež (sporočilo za javnost). LASTNIŠKI KAPITAL (Common Equity T1) BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS pa so Tier 2 obveznosti enakovredne nepodrejenim obveznostim banke. Ukrep odpisa dolga Med instrumenti za zgodnje reševanje bank, ki jih predvideva predlog direktive, najbolj odmeva reševanje z zasebnimi sredstvi, ki je predvideno v okviru ukrepa odpisa dolga. Z namenom zmanjševanja kapitalskega primanjkljaja banke v težavah bodo namreč lahko organi za reševanje po odpisu terjatev delničarjev in podrejenih upnikov odpisali tudi nekatere terjatve nepodrejenih in nezavarovanih upnikov banke v težavah oziroma pretvorili dolžniške terjatve v delnice. O izboru instrumentov, ki bodo predmet odpisa oz. konverzije v kapital, bo odločal njihov vrstni red poplačila v primeru prenehanja banke (podrejenost). Bistven element predloga pa je, da lahko organi reševanja ukrep uporabijo ne le, ko je banka insolventna, ampak tudi že, ko ocenijo, da je zelo blizu insolventnosti in da je tak ukrep nujen za zagotovitev njenega nadaljnjega poslovanja. To v povezavi z možnim obsegom ukrepa pomeni, da bodo nepodrejene in nezavarovane naložbe v bankah naenkrat postale bistveno bolj tvegane, kot so bile do sedaj. Načelo porazdelitve stroškov sanacije v režimu za državne pomoči bankam Ukrep odpisa dolga, kot ga predvideva predlog direktive, se je v zadnjih letih ob reševanjih bank razvijal v okviru sistema EU pravil državnih pomoči in postal del enega njegovih bistvenih načel, tj. načelo porazdelitve finančnega bremena stroškov sanacije med javnim in zasebnim sektorjem (ang. »burden sharing«). Obseg načela se je razvijal postopoma: • v prvem izmed sporočil EK (sprejeto leta 2008) so bili postavljeni temelji omenjenega načela, in sicer je bilo kot eden od kriterijev za dovoljeno državno pomoč določeno, da mora biti višina državne pomoči omejena na najmanjšo potrebno. To naj bi se zagotovilo s prispevkom finančne institucije, ki je prejemnica pomoči, ter s prispevkom zasebnega sektorja (sporočilo EK o bančništvu); • sporočilo EK o oslabljenih sredstvih (2009) govori o nujnosti porazdelitve bremena stroškov iz naslova oslabljenih sredstev v bankah na državo, delničarje in upnike, vendar ga ne ureja Reševanje bank se je za marsikatero državo izkazalo za prevelik zalogaj. podrobneje; • vprašanje bolj podrobno opredeljuje sporočilo EK o prestrukturiranju (2009). Nujnost upoštevanja tega načela EK utemeljuje z omejevanjem moralnega tveganja in z zmanjševanjem izkrivljanja konkurence. V okviru zasebnega sektorja sporočilo EK porazdelitev bremena prestrukturiranja prenaša na banko in na njene delničarje, uporabo načela pa omejuje le na primere, ko s tako porazdelitvijo bremena v fazi reševanja banke ne bi bila ogrožena finančna stabilnost banke. V tem primeru sporočilo EK predvideva nadomestitev porazdelitve bremena s prispevkom banke na poznejši stopnji njenega prestrukturiranja. 114 V zadnjih letih so nekatere države EU pri reševanju svojih bank z mednarodno pomočjo, predvsem pod pritiski t.i. trojke, uporabile ukrep prisilne konverzije ali odpisa posameznih obveznosti bank. Opaziti je bilo vedno strožje ukrepe, četudi je bila njihova uporaba precej nekonsistentna: • Pri reševanju irske banke Northern Rock v letu 2008 so bili na primer odpisani samo nekateri instrumenti temeljnega kapitala. Pri reševanju banke Bradford & Bingley v istem letu so bili nato odpisani vsi Tier 1 instrumenti banke (Yu P. in Luu B. V.). • Pri sanaciji Banco de Valencia, ki je prejela finančno pomoč v višini 28% bilančne vsote, je prišlo do celotnega odpisa navadnih delnic, 90% odpisa prednostnih delnic in 85% odpisa datiranega podrejenega dolga. Preostanek je bil konvertiran v navadne delnice banke. V primeru Bankia je banka investitorjem v Tier 1 in UT2 instrumente ponudila naložila konverzijo v navadne delnice banke s 38% odpisom vrednosti, imetniki LT2 instrumentov pa so ob odpisu 13% vrednosti svoje instrumente lahko konvertirali v delnice ali pa jih zamenjali za nepodrejene obveznice z ničelnim kuponom, tudi s precejšnjim diskontom (1,5% od nominalne vrednosti za vsak mesec do dospelosti instrumenta, s čimer so želeli imetnike odvrniti od te možnosti) (FROB, press release). • Za uporabo ukrepa odpisa dolga se je februarja 2013 odločila tudi nizozemska vlada pri prestrukturiranju četrte največje banke SNS Reaal, ki je sicer državno pomoč prejela že v letu 2008. Z vladnim dekretom je odločila o celotnem odpisu kapitala, hibridnih instrumentov in podrejenega dolga banke ter njeni hkratni dokapitalizaciji (Evropska komisija, state aid decision). BV 11/2013 BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS Ukrep odpisa dolga v predlogu direktive Vzporedno z opisanimi različnimi pristopi k reševanju bank je EK leta 2010 začela pripravljati enoten okvir za sanacijo ter reševanje bank, ki v okviru reševalnih ukrepov predvideva širok obseg odpisov dolga, tudi nepodrejenih obveznosti, in sicer že pred nastopom insolventnosti banke. Obseg ukrepa BV 11/2013 sedem dni (medbančne obveznosti in obveznosti iz sistemov plačilnega prometa), ter obveznosti, ki so ključne za dnevne operacije banke. Poleg tega daje predlog direktive državam tudi diskrecijsko pravico, da iz uporabe ukrepa odpisa dolga izključijo določene instrumente, ki bi sicer bili predmet odpisa ali konverzije. Diskrecijsko pravico bo država lahko uporabila le v primeru izpolnjevanja vsaj enega izmed štirih razlogov in sicer, če odpis (i) ne bi mogel biti izveden v razumnem času, (ii) če bi imel za posledico širjenje negativnih vplivov, (iii) če bi ogrozil nadaljevanje opravljanja ključnih funkcij banke, ali (iv) če bi povzročil izgube ostalim upnikom. Diskrecijo države nadalje omejuje še pogoj, da lahko iz okvira ukrepa določene instrumente izključi le, če je z odpisom ali konverzijo dolga delničarjev in upnikov že zagotovljena njihova participacija pri pokrivanju izgub v višini vsaj 8% od vsote skupnih obveznosti in lastnih sredstev. V primeru uporabe diskrecijske pravice bo država lahko izgubo prenesla na ostale upnike banke (ob upoštevanju načela, da ti upniki ne smejo ne smejo utrpeti več izgub, kot bi jih utrpeli v primeru stečaja banke) ali pa razliko kompenzirala s prispevkom nacionalnega reševalnega sklada. Slika 2: Podrejenost kategorij instrumentov in vrstni red odpisa po predlogu direktive Delnice Hibridni instrumenti TK oz. instrumenti dodatnega temeljnega kapitala (AT1) Podrejenost Upoštevati je treba, da ima prenehanje banke lahko tudi sistemske učinke, zato mora biti temu prilagojen sam insolvenčni postopek – predlog direktive tako z nekaterimi pravili posega v sistemsko ureditev insolvenčnih postopkov na način, da spreminja hierarhijo terjatev. Načelo, po katerem se terjatve istega reda obravnava enako (pari passu), bo v primeru uporabe ukrepa odpisa podrejenega dolga pri bankah lahko izključeno: v okoliščinah, ko bo to zahteval javni interes, se bodo upniki istega razreda lahko obravnavali različno. Predlog direktive tudi natančno določa vrstni red terjatev, ki bodo predmet uporabe ukrepa. Osnovno načelo je, da vrstni red odpisa oz. konverzije sledi splošno veljavni shemi, ki sicer velja za insolvenčne postopke: izgube bo treba najprej v celoti razporediti med delničarje in nato po hierarhiji po- drejenosti še na upnike. Za odpisom temeljnega kapitala (delnic), sledi odpis instrumentov dodatnega temeljnega kapitala (AT1) ali hibridnih instrumentov temeljnega kapitala (T1). Če izgube s popolnim odpisom instrumentov Tier 1 kapitala še ne bi bile pokrite, se nadalje pokrijejo z odpisom manj podrejenih instrumentov: instrumentov dodatnega kapitala (UT2), nato instrumentov podrejenega dolga (LT2) oziroma dodatnega kapitala (T2), ter v skrajnem primeru tudi še določenih terjatev iz naslova nepodrejenega in nezavarovanega dolga. V nasprotju z načelom enakovredne obravnave vseh nezavarovanih upnikov banke pa predlog direktive pri odpisu nadrejenega dolga v preferenčni položaj postavlja depozite fizičnih oseb, depozite malih in srednjih podjetij (SME) ter obveznosti do Evropske investicijske banke: v primeru odpisa so te obveznosti banke nadrejene obveznostim do ostalih nezavarovanih upnikov in depozitom velikih gospodarskih družb. Poleg tega naj bi bile določene kategorije obveznosti banke eksplicitno izključene iz okvira ukrepa. Gre za zajamčene vloge, zavarovane obveznosti (npr. krite obveznice), finančne obveznosti banke do zaposlenih, kratkoročne obveznosti z ročnostjo manj od Hibridni instrumenti dodatnega kapitala I (UT2) Instrumenti podrejenega dolga (LT2) Izbrani instrumenti nadrejenega dolga Vir:Barclays 115 Odpis • Še bolj radikalen je bil aprila 2013 pristop v primeru dveh največjih ciprskih bank, Bank of Cyprus in Laiki. Po odpisu celotnega kapitala, hibridnih instrumentov in podrejenega dolga so posegli tudi v nepodrejeni dolg. Del nezavarovanih depozitov je bil konvertiran v delnice, del je bil začasno zamrznjen kot kapitalska rezerva, del pa začasno zamrznjen za morebitne likvidnostne potrebe (Natixis in ESM). BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS Učinkovanje ukrepa Predlog direktive predvideva, da bodo imeli reševalni organi možnost, da uporabijo ukrep odpisa dolga še pred nastankom insolvenčnih razlogov,če bi bilo to potrebno zaradi javnega interesa. Ravno v tem premiku je glavna sprememba pravil igre: do sedaj je za prelomnico veljal stečaj, skladno s predlogom direktive pa bodo terjatve upnikov odvisne od bolj subjektivnega faktorja. Odvisne bodo od ocene organa za reševanje, da banka propada ali bo verjetno propadla in da bi alternativni ukrepi v razumnem roku takšen propad preprečili. S tem se tveganost bančnih naložb, ki so lahko predmet ukrepa, bistveno poveča. Ker gre za tako spremembo pravil igre je pomembno, da je pred uvedbo novosti predvideno dovoljšnje prehodno obdobje, ki akterjem omogoči ustrezne prilagoditve. Predlog direktive tako ob siceršnji predvideni veljavnosti okvira za sanacijo in reševanje bank, ki je načrtovana leta 2015, za ukrep odpisa dolga določa izjemo: zaradi pomiritve investitorjev naj se ne bi uporabljal pred letom 2018. Nova pravila EK v okviru režima državnih pomoči za banke Če se okvir za sanacijo in reševanje bank šele vzpostavlja, pa je EK s podobnimi ukrepi zelo pohitela pri vzporednem sistemu EU pravil za podeljevanje državnih pomoči bankam. Režim, vzpostavljen z opisanimi sporočili EK, je pri vprašanju porazdelitve bremena državam članicam po mnenju EK dopuščal preveč manevrskega prostora, kar je imelo za posledico različne stroške financiranja bank. Zato je EK z novim sporočilom, ki je začel veljati avgusta 2013 (sporočilo EK o bančništvu #2) postavila bistveno strožje minimalne standarde: • ustrezna porazdelitev bremena: po začetnem pokritju izgub z lastniškim kapitalom EK pričakuje še prispevke imetnikov hibridnega kapitala in imetnikov podrejenih dolžniških instrumentov, ki morajo kar najbolj prispevati k zmanjšanju kapitalskega primanjkljaja (v obliki pretvorbe instrumentov v navaden lastniški temeljni kapital ali pa v obliki odpisa glavnice instrumentov); denarni odlivi v korist imetnikov takih instrumentov morajo biti preprečeni v pravno sprejemljivem okviru. • omejitve: izvzetje je mogoče le, kadar bi izvajanje takih ukrepov Izguba banke iz poslovanja se bo morala kriti v breme razpoložljivega kapitala banke. ogrozilo finančno stabilnost ali povzročilo nesorazmerne rezultate; poleg tega je treba pri izvajanju ukrepov upoštevati načelo, da »noben upnik ne utrpi večjih izgub, kot bi jih sicer« (tj. podrejeni upniki z ekonomskega vidika ne bi smeli prejeti manj, kot bi bil njihov instrument vreden, če državna pomoč ne bi bila dodeljena). EK v sporočilu še določa, da je uporaba teh ukrepov predpogoj za uporabo katerih koli ukrepov državne pomoči, v prvi vrsti ukrepa za oslabljena sredstva (npr. mehanizem slabe banke) in dokapitalizacije. S tem sporočilom je EK za banke, 116 ki so prejemnice državne pomoči, dejansko že v letu 2013 uveljavila ukrepe odpisa dolga za vse podrejene instrumente, ki jih sicer predlog direktive za sanacijo in reševanje bank, kot že omenjeno, predvideva šele z letom 2018. Na možno destabilizacijo finančnih trgov zaradi hitrega sprejema ukrepa je EK v svojem pismu opozoril guverner ECB Mario Draghi. V pismu je predlagal odložitev uporabe ukrepa do dneva polne operativnosti bančne unije (Reuters). Uporaba ukrepa v primeru slovenskih bank Tako zadnje sporočilo EK kot tudi predlog direktive nalagata državam članicam, da vzpostavijo normativni okvir, ki bo omogočal uporabo ukrepa odpisa dolga. Kot omenjeno je v zadnjem sporočilu EK določeno, da je uporaba ukrepa predpogoj za uporabo katerih koli ukrepov državne pomoči. ZUKSB v tretjem odstavku 23. člena sicer predvideva, da mora banka pred povečanjem osnovnega kapitala z ukrepi po ZUKSB zagotoviti, da se izguba banke iz poslovanja krije v breme za to razpoložljivega kapitala banke. Vendar ta določba ni ustrezna glede na obseg zahtevanih ukrepov, kot so določeni v zadnjem sporočilu EK. Pravno podlago za uporabo ukrepa odpisa dolga vzpostavlja novela zakona o bančništvu, ki jo je vlada potrdila v oktobru in jo po nujnem postopku v obravnavo in sprejem posredovala Državnemu zboru (ZBan-1, novela L). Predlog med drugim širi nabor izrednih ukrepov, ki jih ima na voljo Banka Slovenije za reševanje banke, ki v naslednjih šestih mesecih verjetno ne bi izpolnjevala zahtev glede minimalnega kapitala ali likvidnostnega položaja. Banka Slovenije bi lahko v takem primeru z odredbo določila, da določene obveznosti banke (t.i. BV 11/2013 BEST PRACTICE CASES AND LESSONS kvalificirane obveznosti) prenehajo ali pa se konvertirajo v delnice.4 Kot kvalificirane obveznosti so določeni osnovni kapital in podrejene obveznosti banke. Glede na lastnosti posameznih instrumentov je taka ureditev najbolj sporna v primeru instrumentov podrejenega dolga (»LT2«), ki so v nasprotju z bolj podrejenimi instrumenti namenjeni za kritje izgub v primeru prenehanja banke. Tak poseg je lahko sporen z vidika več ustavnih določb: pravice do zasebne lastnine in dedovanja, načela prepovedi povratne veljave pravnih aktov, ter načela zaupanja v pravo. V obrazložitvi predloga Vlada RS utemeljuje dopustnost posega v ustavno varovano pravico do zasebne lastnine s t.i. strogim testom sorazmernosti. V zvezi s tem ocenjuje, da je poseg (i) nujen, ker cilja ni mogoče doseči brez tega ukrepa, oz. ga ni možno doseči z milejšim ukrepom, (ii) primeren, ker je z njim dejansko možno doseči cilj, ki mu ukrep sledi, in (iii) da je teža posledic uporabe ukrepa proporcionalna cilju ukrepa. Poseg v pravico do zasebne lastnine je zato po mnenju Vlade dopusten. Glede povratne veljave ukrepov pa Vlada navaja, da gre za t.i. nepravo retroaktivnost,5 ki načeloma ne pomeni kršitve prepovedi povratne veljave pravnih aktov. Lahko pa predstavlja kršitev načela zaupanja v pravo, vendar je tak poseg dopusten, če je skladen s testom sorazmernosti. Končno oceno skladnosti ukrepov pa lahko poda le Ustavno sodišče RS. Namesto sklepa Kot rečeno je bila uporaba ukrepa odpisa dolga zaradi svoje »revolucionarne« narave v predlogu direktive zamišljena šele nekaj let po uveljavitvi novega okvira za reševanje bank. Zadnje sporočilo EK pa ga je za vse podrejene instrumente banke, ki so v postopku pridobitve državne poBV 11/2013 moči, uvedlo že z avgustom 2013. S tem je akterjem onemogočen čas za prilagoditev; v tem pogledu so najbolj problematični izdani instrumenti podrejenega dolga (LT2), ki v svojih pogojih predvidevajo kritje izgub banke samo v primeru stečaja, EK pa njihov prispevek k zmanjševanju kapitalskega primanjkljaja zahteva že prej (ko banka prejme državno pomoč) – gre torej za poseg v pridobljene pravice njihovih imetnikov. Kar zadeva učinka opisanih sprememb na kapitalsko strukturo bank pa morda lahko rečemo, da bo predvideni okvir reševanja bank kategoriji dodatnega kapitala bank (Tier 2) takorekoč vdihnil novo življenje. Ta kategorija je namreč s prenovo kapitalske regulative (CRR 1 in CRD 4) in poudarkom na količnikih kvalitetnejšega kapitala (T1 in CT1) precej izgubila na pomenu, s predvidenimi mehanizmi reševanja bank pa ponovno pridobiva na pomenu, saj jo bodo nepodrejeni upniki banke verjetno šteli za svojo »varnostno blazino« v primeru reševanja banke, saj bodo skladno s predvidenim vrstnim redom njihovi instrumenti prišli v poštev šele potem, ko bodo podrejeni instrumenti v celoti odpisani. Verjetno lahko zato pričakujemo, da bodo banke zato še izdajale instrumente dodatnega kapitala (T2), kljub manjšemu pomenu kategorije za kapitalsko ustreznost, saj jim bo to omogočalo lažji dostop do (tudi cenejšega) zadolževanja. Nedvomno pa bodo opisani ukrepi imeli očitne posledice na ceno zadolževanja bank, saj postaja zaradi njih večina naložb v banke bistveno bolj tvegana, kot je bila do sedaj. Če se podobni ukrepi ne uveljavijo tudi po svetu, se bo to nedvomno odrazilo na dobičkonosnosti sektorja v regiji. LITERATURA IN VIRI/REFERENCES: Artus, P.: Bail-ins instead of bail-outs in Europe: Why, and what impacts?, economic research, Natixis, 2013. Direktiva o dostopu do dejavnosti kreditnih 117 institucij in bonitetnem nadzoru kreditnih institucij in investicijskih podjetij, spremembi Direktive 2002/87/ES in razveljavitvi direktiv 2006/48/ES in 2006/49/ES (CRD4), 2013/36/EU, Ur. l. EU št. 176 , 27. junij 2013. European Stability Mechanism (ESM): FAQ - Financal assistance for Cyprus. Evropska komisija: Odločitev o državni pomoči: Nizozemska - reševanje SNS Reaal, 2013/N, Bruselj, 2012. Evropska komisija: Sporočilo Komisije o uporabi pravil o državni pomoči za ukrepe v zvezi s finančnimi institucijami v okviru trenutne svetovne finančne krize (sporočilo EK o bančništvu), Ur. l. EU, št. C 270, 2008. Evropska komisija: Sporočilo komisije o obravnavanju oslabljenih sredstev v bančnem sektorju Skupnosti (sporočilo EK o oslabljenih sredstvih), Ur. l. EU, št. C 72, 2009. Evropska komisija: Sporočilo Komisije o ponovni vzpostavitvi uspešnega poslovanja in oceni ukrepov prestrukturiranja v finančnem sektorju v sedanji krizi na podlagi pravil o državni pomoči (sporočilo EK o prestrukturiranju), Ur. l. EU, št. C 195, 2009. Evropska komisija: Sporočilo komisije o uporabi pravil o državni pomoči za podporne ukrepe v korist bank v okviru finančne krize od 1. avgusta 2013 dalje (sporočilo o bančništvu #2), Ur. l. EU, št. C 216, 2013. FROB: Press release disclosing the resolutions adopted in the FROB steering committee; Madrid, marec, 2013. J.P. Morgan: The Dynamics of Burden Sharing, Europe Credit Research, London, 2012. Sporočilo za javnost o vrhu Sveta Evropske Unije junija 2013. Yu, P. in Luu, B. V.: Lessons from the Collapse in Hybrid Bank Capital Securities, University of East London Business School, London, 2010. Reuters: ECB‘s Draghi has asked to delay bank bail-in plans, 19. oktober 2013. Societe Generale: Spain Banks: Banco de Valencia haircut read across, februar 2013. Uredba o bonitetnih zahtevah za kreditne institucije in investicijska podjetja ter o spremembi Uredbe (EU) št. 648/2012 (CRR1), Ur. l. EU št. 176, 27. junij 2013. ZBan-1, novela L. 4 Prenehanje kvalificiranih obveznosti bi se določilo v obsegu, ki je potreben zaradi pokrivanja izgub banke, konverzija pa v obsegu, potrebnim za doseganje kapitalske ustreznosti banke. Predlog predvideva še, da posamezni upnik zaradi ukrepov ne sme utrpeti večjih izgub, kot bi jih utrpel v primeru stečaja banke. 5 V primerih neprave retroaktivnosti ima zakon učinek za naprej, saj posega v že oblikovana, a še ne zaključena pravna razmerja. SKLEPNE MISLI / CONCLUSION REMARKS The Slovenian banks between rock and hard place Emil Lah* The macroeconomic situation in which the Slovenian banks have been coping with the consequences of a long-delayed clean-up plan, has gone from bad to worse in 2013 after the last year’s vague promise of recovery. Slovenia’s economy remains in recession, the rate of unemployment is getting very close to 10 per cent, the general government deficit forecast to soar by the year-end from 3.8 per cent to 5.7 per cent of GDP, public debt is set to exceed the magic Maastricht convergence criterion of 60 per cent of GDP. The only star on the country’s dark macroeconomic sky is the positive balance of payments with the current-account surplus of around 2.5 per cent in 2012 and expected to soar to approximately 7 per cent of GDP at the end of 2013 fuelled more by ebbing imports than by swelling exports. Even a quick glance at the situation in the real sector reveals that during the period between 2010 and 2012, the volume of lending by the domestic banks fell by approximately 12 per cent, but the indebtedness of the national economy still remains at a level where deleveraging is “a bridge too far”. In addition, the net debt to EBITDA ratio stays high indicating that about one third of local companies are in dire straits when it comes to their ability to decrease their bank debt burden and take on the additional debt required to grow the business. It is no wonder that the local banks have found themselves in a vicious circle when after raising the bar for credit applicants their credit offering was reduced to a trickle leaving them with gross income posted for the first eight months of this year plunging by approximately 30 per cent. On the other hand, if the local banks had neglected “the prudent man’s rule” when lending to their corporate customers, the portion of non-performing loans would have grown to unmanageable proportions. Even though bank managers realise that for the credit institutions to restore soundness, their customers must first complete restructuring programmes and to do that, they need funding. The three biggest Slovenian banks are controlled by the state and no significant statefunded aid has been available so far. To illustrate the scope of state-funded aid poured by the EU countries on their ailing credit institutions there is the figure of 1,600 billion euros handed out until the end of 2011. On the other hand, the Slovenian government has bowed to the pressures of the European Banking Authority (EBA) and has allocated minimum amounts for the recapitalisation of the stateowned banks. There is a brain-twisting paradox that, in line with its position of the principal shareholder, the government would not only meddle on a daily basis with the credit policy of the three biggest banks under its wing, but it would nudge their management to lend even to the “lame ducks” of the Slovenian economy on the one hand, and to finance management buy-out constructed on a razor blade. The strategy backfired shaking the financial stability of the banking system in September 2013 to the point where the Bank of Slovenia was forced to take the extraordinary measure of the so-called controlled liquidation of two illiquid banks. The fact is that the exposure of the banking system to the risk of earning lower returns has been increasing; no process of bank consolidation is taking place, while the processes of bank restructuring or using internal rehabilitation tools still have to gain impetus. The whole banking system in Slovenia continues to suffer in 2013 and the cumulative loss keeps rising mostly as a consequence of swelling provisions and the fact that the national economy in recession1. What may also be a problem is the (dangerously) low capital adequacy ratio of most Slovenian banks in comparison with other credit institutions in the euro area. The question to be asked at this point is whether Slovenian banks will be able to keep pace with the capital regulatory framework for banks Basel III with ever more strict capital requirements. Should the socalled Asset-Quality Review (AQR) or due diligence of bank assets and the stress tests reveal that the Slovenian banks are too vulnerable to possible new macroeconomic shocks, it would be a serious blow. It is clear that to carve out bad assets from the banks’ balance sheets and transferring them to the so-called bad bank will be a very painful and highly demanding operation. It will strip the banks bare to show how much the banks’ total assets will decrease and what the price * Emil Lah, Chief Editor of Bančni Vestnik. The information and views set out in this article are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the official opinion of the Bank Association of Slovenia. 1 The loss accumulated by the Slovenian banking system for the period ended 31 August 2013, is 375 million euros, mostly as a consequence of net impairments and provisions totalling 677 million euros. 118 BV 11/2013 SKLEPNE MISLI / CONCLUSION REMARKS for the bank rescue will be so that the bills can be issued to the government, to the shareholders and to the large depositors to foot them. The European Commission agreed in August this year the new deal on bank rescue and resolution using public funds which introduces the socalled “bail-in” rule2. The bottom line of the new rule is that a bank rescue plan can kick off also before it is formally made bankrupt and the burden of its rescue falls first on the shoulders of its shareholders and then of its uninsured creditors before public funds (taxpayers’ money) can be used. By forcing losses on creditors, public finances will be supposedly relieved of the entire burden of footing the bill of bank failure. As far as the case of Slovenia is concerned, the bail-in model for a failed bank rescue is not bear much fruit since the Republic of Slovenia is the principal shareholders of the country’s top three banks and, in addition, figures as a holder of big chunks in the share capital of a number of state-owned enterprise, which, in turn, are formal owners of private banks. This means that to handle the cost of future bank bailouts, funds will be taken from Peter to give to Paul and, at the end of the day, Slovenian taxpayers will pick the tab. Clearly, we will be forced to participate in a dangerous game of imposing losses on junior bondholders in banks that need recapitalisation by taxpayers and these investors include important institutional investors such as insurance companies and pension funds. Hurting financially pension funds could be a fatal blow since pensions funds are still on wobbly legs and must get stronger as the population is aging. With pension funds in the line of fire, further pension system reforms would be futile exercise. There are voices arguing that the best solution for the Slovenian state-owned banks would be to use the option of asking for financial aid from the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) and to launch as soon as practicable a wide-reaching bank resolution plan, which will be complex and pains- BV 11/2013 taking. Slovenia is indeed in a tight corner but asking for an international bailout would be forcing its citizens to swallow a bitter pill. The treatment may be efficient but the suffering imposed in exchange for financial aid is seen by all recipients of such aid as excessive. Whatever the doctor’s orders will be, it is clear now that by sweeping the bank problems under the carpet, the Slovenian governments have not got rid of them as one of former prime ministers has recently admitted in public and by downplaying the leverage issue, they have ill served the country’s indebted real sector. The productivity level of the Slovenian companies and the output of certain sectors is too modest, and we will have to take steps in the right direction if we are to overcome the problem of struggling to raise the competitiveness level of the national economy in order to stay afloat. It does not mean that we are in a position to delay taking new austerity measures in the light of the further downside risk to GDP growth in 2014. The European Commission is expected to demand that the Slovenian government stays firmly on track of fiscal consolidation, and further belt-tightening will strip us of the chances we have to revive the economy. In plain language, should more funds be allocated to capital expenditure, we will have to cut even deeper into all segments of government spending. Since investors demand the eye-popping yield on ten-year government bonds of some 6.5 per cent, there is little room for manoeuvre should we wish to escape the iron handshake of Brussels3. This year’s developments in the euro zone will remain in our memory for quite a while with Cyprus taking the centre stage as a guinea pig to test whether the new bail-in principle for bank rescue and reach into the pockets of unsecured depositors of two Cyprian banks. The citizens of Slovenia will certainly remember the first pan-Slovenian protests against austerity measures, corruption and nepotism of the ruling elite. According to the published figures and forecasts, 119 most euro-zone countries are “out of the woods”. Sadly, Slovenia is not in that group and whatever imbalances are prolonging recession, a turnaround of the country’s growth prospects remains distant. The fact that the share of non-performing loans has soared to around 30 per cent of total loans must be rather painful for the executives in the state-owned banks. The government minister must feel bad about the general government debt shooting to over 60 per cent of GDP and the general government deficit rising in 2013 year-on-year. we should all brace for the day when the results of the Asset-Quality Review and of the stress tests are announced. There are legal experts in Slovenia who should at least feel uncomfortable for sabotaging back-loaded bank efforts to promulgate a law on the systematic deleveraging and providing a life raft to creditors instead of bailing out irresponsible owners of chronically indebted companies. Conventional wisdom tells us that for the Slovenian banks, companies and the government to go on, a growthfriendly policy is as necessary as preserving a sound fiscal position. The same applies to other less developed EU Member States. Choosing the model for re-trenching Slovenia’s economy is still in our hands4 but it also relies heavily on investors seeking to earn as much as possible in the international financial markets. References: European Commission, European Economy, Occasional Papers 142, April 2013. Banka Slovenije, Eurosystem, Macroeconomic Developments and Projections, October 2013. 2 The bail-in rule is not acceptable from the political and legal view since it is a retroactive measure affecting the rights of all bank creditors and jeopardises the financial stability of the Slovenian financial system. 3 The policy imposing spending cuts also called »austerity policy« as advocated by the European Commission has only exacerbated recession in Greece, as well as in other »problematic« member states of the euro area and has been counterproductive so far as argued both by the ECB and the IMF. 4 The serious problem of the Slovenian banking system and its regulator is that the insurance scheme for bank deposits is not in place yet. STATISTICAL APPENDIX / STATISTIČNA PRILOGA Selected macroeconomic indicators Luka Žakelj* Figure 1: Slovenia: projection of expenditure contributions to GDP growth rate 10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6 -8 -10 -12 -14 -16 -18 -20 in p.p. 4.4 4.0 7.0 5.8 1.3 3.4 1.4 0.7 -0.7 -2.6 -2.5 -7.9 households government gross fixed investment change in inventories net foreign trade GDP (proj. - Oct. 2013) GDP 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 Figure 3: Slovenia: projection of contributions to inflation by components 7 10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6 -8 -10 -12 -14 -16 -18 -20 6 current account current account (projection – Oct. 2013) 6.1 -5 -6 6.8 current account (projection – Apr. 2013) 5 4 3 2 1 0 -1 -2 -3 -4 7.7 3.3 0.4 -0.5 -0.1 -2.6 -1.7 -1.8 -4.2 -5.4 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 2 7 6 5 4 2.1 3 2.8 3 2.2 2.1 1.7 0.9 1.5 2 1 1 0 0 -1 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 -1 Sources: SORS, projection Bank of Slovenia. Note: Due to rounding, sums of components may differ from aggregate values. Figure 4: Projections of GDP growth in Slovenia's main trading partners for the year 2013 6 8 7 6 5 5 4 3 2 1 annual growth in % 6 Austria Germany Italy Croatia France Serbia Russia 5 4 4 3 3 2 2 1 1 0 -1 -2 -3 -4 0 0 -1 -1 -5 -6 -2 Sources: SORS, projection Bank of Slovenia. * 5.5 4 Figure 2: Slovenia: current account projection % BDP services non-energy industrial goods processed food unprocessed food energy HICP, y-o-y in % 5 Sources: SORS, projection Bank of Slovenia. 8 7 6 in p.p. 2012 2013 -2 Source: Consensus Economics. Luka Žakelj, Analitsko - raziskovalni center, Banka Slovenije 120 BV 11/2013 STATISTICAL APPENDIX / STATISTIČNA PRILOGA Figure 5: Projections of GDP growth in Slovenia's main trading partners for the year 2014 5 annual growth in % Figure 7: Differences in y-o-y growth rates of GDP components between Slovenia and the euro area - production side 5 20 20 *y-o-y growth rates for Slovenia minus y-o-y growth rates for the euro area 15 4 4 in p.p. 10 3 3 2 1 0 5 2 Austria Germany Italy Russia Croatia France Serbia 0 -5 -5 -10 -10 0 2013 -15 08 in p.p. GDP* gross investment* final consumption - households and NPISH* final consumption - government* difference in net foreign trade contribution -15 15 30 -10 10 20 -15 5 10 -20 0 -15 11 12 13 60 40 -10 *y-o-y growth rates for Slovenia minus y-o-y growth rates for the euro area 70 LFS unemployment rate - overall LFS unemployment rate - youth (15-29 years) share of long-term unemployed in total unempl. (rhs)* 20 -5 -25 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 Sources: SORS, Employment office of the Republic of Slovenia, Bank of Slovenia calculations. Note: *Based on data from registry of unemployed. Sources: Eurostat, ECB, Bank of Slovenia calculations. BV 11/2013 13 50 -5 10 12 25 0 09 11 in % 30 10 0 08 35 15 5 -25 10 Figure 8: Slovenia: selected unemployment figures 20 5 -20 09 Sources: Eurostat, Bank of Slovenia calculations. Figure 6: Differences in y-o-y growth rates of GDP components between Slovenia and the euro area - expenditure side 10 5 1 2012 15 10 0 Source: Consensus Economics. 20 15 GDP industry construction private services public services 121 0 STATISTICAL APPENDIX / STATISTIČNA PRILOGA Figure 9: Slovenia: contributions to y-o-y growth in the number of people in employment 5 4 3 2 in p.p. Figure 11: Nominal unit labour costs in Slovenia and the main trading partners from the euro area 14 5 public sector services private sector services construction industry agriculture, forestry, fishing people in employment, y-o-y in % 4 y-o-y growth in % 14 Slovenia Germany 12 3 10 2 12 France Austria Italy 10 8 8 0 6 6 -1 -1 4 4 -2 -2 -3 -3 2 2 -4 -4 0 0 1 1 0 -5 2010 2011 2012 2013 -2 -5 Figure 10: Slovenia: total wage bill and average gross wage per employee y-o-y in % nominal gross wage per employee real gross wage per employee* nominal wage bill real wage bill* 8 6 4 *HICP deflator 10 11 12 13 -2 -2 -4 -4 -6 -6 -8 -8 in mio EUR balance (rhs) exports imports 20 4 0 2013 y-o-y in % 6 0 2012 25 8 2 2011 10 Figure 12: Slovenia: international trade in goods and services 2 2010 09 Sources: Eurostat, Bank of Slovenia calculations. Source: SORS, Bank of Slovenia calculations. 10 -2 08 800 15 600 10 400 5 200 0 0 -5 -200 -10 -400 2010 Source: SORS, Bank of Slovenia calculations. Note: Wage bill is calculated as the product of average gross monthly wages for employees of legal persons who received pay and the total number of employees of legal persons. 1000 2011 2012 2013 Source: Bank of Slovenia. 122 BV 11/2013 STATISTICAL APPENDIX / STATISTIČNA PRILOGA Figure 13: Slovenia: current account components 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 -1 -2 -3 -4 -5 -6 in % BDP, 3-month moving sums 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 -1 -2 -3 -4 -5 -6 current account goods services factor income current transfers 2010 2011 2012 Figure 15: Slovenia: confidence indicators 2013 50 30 2009 2010 30 20 10 10 0 0 -10 -10 -20 -20 -30 -30 -40 -40 -50 -50 -60 -60 -70 2010 2011 2012 -70 2013 non-financial corporations government 2011 2012 2013 Figure 16: Slovenia: business tendency in manufacturing – limits to production 100 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6 -8 -10 -12 90 80 % of enterprises 90 80 70 60 60 50 50 40 40 30 30 20 20 10 10 07 08 Source: SORS. 123 100 uncertain economic conditions insufficient domestic demand insufficient foreign demand financial problems 70 0 Sources: Bank of Slovenia - consolidated financial accounts, SORS. BV 11/2013 40 Source: SORS. % GDP, 4-quarter moving sum of flows 2008 50 consumers retail trade construction 20 Figure 14: Slovenia: savings-investment gap rest of the world financial corporations households and NPISH total economy manufacturing activities services 40 Source: Bank of Slovenia. 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6 -8 -10 -12 points of balance, seasonally adjusted 09 10 11 12 13 0 STATISTICAL APPENDIX / STATISTIČNA PRILOGA Figure 17: Slovenia: business tendency in construction – limiting factors 90 enterprises in % 90 high cost of capital insufficient demand access to bank credits no limits 80 70 Figure 19: Slovenia: business tendency in services excluding retail trade – limiting factors 70 80 enterprises in % 70 financial constraints insufficient demand shortage of labour force none 60 70 60 50 50 50 40 40 40 40 30 30 30 30 20 20 20 20 10 10 10 10 60 60 50 0 0 0 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 Figure 18: Slovenia: business tendency in retail trade – limiting factors enterprises in % high cost of money low demand access to bank credits no obstacles 60 11 12 13 0 60 3 3 2 2 1 1 0 0 -1 -1 40 30 30 20 20 10 09 10 11 12 13 y-o-y growth in % 4 40 08 10 70 50 07 09 Figure 20: HICP growth rates in Slovenia and the euro area 50 0 08 Source: SORS. Source: SORS. 70 07 -2 10 -3 0 -4 4 Slovenia excluding energy, food, alcohol and tobacco euro area excluding energy, food, alcohol and tobacco 2010 2011 2012 2013 -2 -3 -4 Source: SORS, Eurostat, Bank of Slovenia calculations. Source: SORS. 124 BV 11/2013 6 ECB main refinancing rate S T A T I S T I C A L A P P E N D I X / S T A T I S T I Č N A P R I L3-m OEURIBOR GA 5 12-m EURIBOR 4 BANKING SECTOR INDICATORS 3 Franc Remšak* 2 1 0 Figure 1: Credit to nonfinancial enterprises and households 2007 2008 2009 rates 2010 for 2011 2012 approved 2013 Figure2006 3: Lending interest newly loans to corporates in Slovenia and in the euro area for loans of up to EUR 1 million (in %) (annual growth in %) 40 USA Euro area Slovenia 35 30 40 9 35 8 30 7 25 25 20 40 15 35 10 30 5 25 0 20 -5 15 -10 10 20 40 15 35 10 30 5 25 0 20 -5 15 -10 10 USA Euro area Slovenia 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 ECB main refinancing rate 5 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Figure 2: Comparison of the EURIBOR and 3-m EURIBOR 4 (in %) -10 ECB refinancing rate 12-m EURIBOR 6 5 5 4 4 3 3 2 2 1 1 0 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 -1 Source: ECB, Bank of Slovenia Figure 4: Lending interest rates for newly approved loans to corporates in Slovenia and in the euro area for loans of over EUR 1 million (in %) 9 ECB main refinancing rate 7 12-m EURIBOR 4 1 3 0 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2 1 8 Spread (right scale) 0 7 8 Slovenia 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Euro area 6 7 9 Source: ECB, Bank of Slovenia 6 5 5 9 4 8 Spread (right scale) 4 8 Slovenia Franc Remšak, Finančna stabilnost, Banka Slovenije Euro area 3 7 BV 6211/2013 Spread (right scale) Slovenia Euro area 8 3-m EURIBOR 5 2 1 5 7 -5 6 3 * 8 6 0 5 Source: ECB Statistical Data Warehouse (http://sdw.ecb. 5 europa.eu) and Economic Research Federal Reserve Bank of St. 0 0 Louis (http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/) -5 6 -10 Spread (right scale) Slovenia Euro area 1 5 0 4 5 4 4 3 3 2 2 1 1 0 190.0 170.0 125 6 5 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Source: ECB, Bank of Slovenia 2 6 7 6 0 3 7 8 150.0 130.0 Slovenia Euro area -1 Euro area 7 6 9 STATISTIC 5 8 4 7 6 5 8 Spread (right scale) ASlovenia L A P P E N D I47X Euro area 3 6 3 6 2 5 2 5 1 4 1 4 0 3 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2 -1 2 1 Figure 5: Ratio of loans to non-banking sectors to 1 0 deposits by non-banking sectors (in %) 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Slovenia Euro area -1 100% 170.0 80% 70% 150.0 Slovenia Euro area 190.0 130.0 60% 50% 170.0 110.0 100% 40% 150.0 90.0 90% 30% 70% 10% 110.0 50.0 60% 0% 90.0 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 H1 50% Source: 70.0 ECB Statistical Data Warehouse (SDW) 40% 50.0 25% 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 H1 Figure 6: Bank Nonperforming 2009 2010 Loans to Total Loans 2011 2012 (in %) 20% 2013 20% 10% 30% 20% 20%IMF, Financial Soundness Indicators, October 2013 Source: 10% 2008 http://fsi.imf.org/fsitables.aspx (See Notes under “Table 4. 18% 2009 Bank 0% Provisions to Nonperforming Loans”) 16% 14% 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 10% 20% 8% 18% 6% 10% 0% 14% 2% 16% 4% Source: IMF, Financial Soundness Indicators, October 2013 http://fsi.imf.org/fsitables.aspx (See Notes under “Table 3. Bank Nonperforming Loans to Total Loans” ) 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 12% 0% Austria Austria Belgium Belgium Cyprus Cyprus Czech Republic Czech Republic Denmark2 Denmark2 Estonia Estonia Finland3 Finland3 France4 France4 Germany5 Germany5 Greece Greece Ireland Ireland Italy9 Italy9 Netherlands Netherlands Norway13 Norway13 Portugal14 Portugal14 Slovak Republic Slovak Republic Slovenia Slovenia Spain Spain Sweden16 Sweden16 United States53 United States53 0% 2010 2011 2012 Figure 8: Capital adequacy in Slovenia and EU 12% (in %) 15% 5% 5% 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 80% 20% 130.0 70.0 25% 15% 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 90% Austria Belgium Cyprus Czech Republic Denmark1 Estonia France Greece Ireland Italy Portugal9 Slovak Republic Slovenia Spain10 United Kingdom United States 190.0 2008 Austria Belgium Cyprus Czech Republic Denmark1 Estonia France Greece Ireland Italy Portugal9 Slovak Republic Slovenia Spain10 United Kingdom United States 0 Figure 7: Bank Provisions to Nonperforming Loans (in %) 10% 8% 6% 30% 4% 2% 25% 0% 20% 15% Slovenia EU banks, EU banks, EU banks, EU banks, All Large Medium-size Small domestic domestic domestic institutions institutions institutions institutions 2008 2009 2010 2011 Slovenia 2012 EU banks, EU banks, EU banks, EU banks, Large Medium-size Small All domestic domestic domestic institutions institutions institutions institutions Source: Bank of Slovenia, ECB, Statistics on Consolidated 30% Banking Data2008 (Domestic banking groups and stand-alone 10%October 2013 banks), 2009 25% 5% 20% 126 0% 15% 2010 2011 2012 BV 11/2013 Austria Belgium Cyprus Germany Estonia Spain Finland France ece (GR) Ireland Italy embourg Malta therlands Portugal Slovenia Slovakia 0 3 / STATISTIČNA PRILOGA 15% 12% STATISTICAL APPENDIX / STATISTIČNA PRILOGA 10% 25% 10% 8% 6% 2% 15% 0% Austria Belgium Cyprus Germany Estonia Spain Finland France Greece (GR) Ireland Italy Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Portugal Slovenia Slovakia 0% Slovenia EU banks, EU banks, EU banks, EU banks, All Large Medium-size Small Figure 9: Capital adequacy; domestic domestic overall domesticsolvency institutions institutions institutions institutions ratio in EMU member states (in %) 25% 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 20% 15% 10% 8 10.7 11.3 11.4 12.3 13.1 12.8 15.9 16.3 16.7 18.3 13.7 in b) EU; consolidated data (in %) 2008 2011 2009 2012 2010 15.9 16.3 16.7 18.3 10 20 8 18 6 16 4 14 2 12 0 10 13.7 Figure 10: Tier 1 ratio in EMU member states (in %) 15.5 15.8 16.4 17.1 17.1 Source: ECB, Statistics on Consolidated Banking Data (Domestic banking groups and stand-alone banks), October 2013 11.8 12.8 13.0 13.0 14.4 Austria Belgium Cyprus Germany Estonia Spain Finland France Greece (GR) Ireland Italy Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Portugal Slovenia Slovakia 0% 15.5 15.8 16.4 17.1 17.1 9.5 9.6 10.9 11.2 11.2 11.6 5% 12.1 11.9 11.3 11.7 10.9 10.7 10% 11.8 12.8 13.0 13.0 14.4 15% 11.7 11.7 11.3 11.8 11.4 11.2 Austria 11.7 11.7 Belgium 11.3 Cyprus 11.8 11.4 Germany 11.2 Estonia 12.1 Spain 11.9 11.3 Finland 11.7 10.9 France 10.7 Greece (GR) 10.9 Ireland 11.2 11.2 Italy 11.6 Luxembourg 9.5 9.6Malta Netherlands 10.7 11.3 Portugal 11.4 Slovenia12.3 13.1 Slovakia 12.8 5% 16 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Jun. 2013 15 14 0% 13 12 11 10 9 8 7 16 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Jun. 2013 6 15 5 14 4 13 3 12 2 11 1 10 0 9 Banking Large Small Banks under 8 sector domestic domestic majority foreign 7 banks banks ownership 6 5 4 Source: 20 Bank of Slovenia 3 2008 2009 2010 2 2011 2012 18 1 16 0 Banking Large Small Banks under 14 sector domestic domestic majority foreign Figure 12: Capitalbanks adequacybanks by bank group ownership 12 13.1 13.6 13.5 14.6 20% 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 10% 11: Capital adequacy by bank group in a) Figure Slovenia; consolidated data (in %) 11.4 25% 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 20% 5% 4% 30% 2010 2011 2012 20% 13.1 13.6 13.5 14.6 14% 2010 2011 2012 11.4 16% Large domestic banks Medium domestic banks Small Banks under domestic majority foreign banks ownership Large domestic banks Medium domestic banks Small Banks under domestic majority foreign banks ownership 6 5% 4 2 0% Austria Belgium Cyprus Germany Estonia Spain Finland France Greece (GR) Ireland Italy Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Portugal Slovenia Slovakia 0 BV 10.7 11.3 11.4 12.3 13.1 12.8 Source: ECB, (SDW) 9.5 9.6 10.9 11.2 11.2 11.6 11.7 11.7 11.3 11.8 11.4 11.2 13 12 11 10 9 8 11/2013 7 6 12.1 11.9 11.3 11.7 10.9 10.7 Source: ECB, Statistics on Consolidated Banking Data 16 2008 2009 2011 2012 Jun. October 2013 (Domestic banking groups2010 and stand-alone banks), 15 201314 127 Figure 13: Tier 1 Capital Ratio by bank group in a) Slovenia; consolidated data (in %) 2011 2009 2012 2010 9.2 9.5 9.7 2012 Jun. 2013 2010 1.5 0.5 10.7 11.6 11.5 9.2 9.5 9.7 -1.0 1.5 7.7 7.7 9.0 8.8 8.9 9.4 8.7 8.9 8.2 8.8 9.2 9.1 -0.5 2.0 Banking sector Banking Slovenia sector EU USA 15.1 11.1 12.3 12.8 13.1 11.7 12.2 12.4 12.9 13.6 15.1 11.1 12.3 12.8 13.1 11.7 12.2 12.4 12.9 13.6 11.8 9.9 10.5 10.7 12.0 8.5 9.6 10.0 10.1 11.8 2012 Small domestic Banks under majority foreign Small domestic banks Banks under majority foreign ownership Slovenia EU USA Banking sector Medium sized domestic banks Slovenia EU USA 15.1 -2.0 5 Small domestic banks Banks under majority foreign ownership Medium sized domestic banks Small domestic banks Banks under majority foreign ownership -10 10 -20 0 2011 2012 2013 H1 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 H1 Figure 16: Return on equity (in %) Slovenia EU USA 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 H1 2010 2011 2012 2013 H1 -5 -10 -15 -20 Slovenia EU USA 2010 -5 15 -15 5 Medium sized domestic banks 2008 0 15.1 2012 2009 -0.5 Source: Bank of Slovenia, ECB, Statistics on Consolidated Banking Data (All domestic banks), October 2013 and 15 -1.0 Economic Research Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/), Quarterly, End of -1.5 10 Period, annualized data 11.1 12.3 12.8 13.1 11.7 12.2 12.4 12.9 13.6 2011 2008 0.0 11.1 12.3 12.8 13.1 11.8 8.5 9.6 10.0 10.1 2010 8.5 9.6 10.0 10.1 8.3 9.9 10.5 10.7 12.0 8.3 2009 11.7 12.2 12.4 12.9 13.6 9.9 10.5 10.7 12.0 2008 11.8 EU b); consolidated data (in %) -2.0 0.5 Source: ECB, (SDW) 1.5 0.0 Medium sized domestic 2011 Figure 15: Return on assetsownership banks banks (in %) 0.0 1.0 2.0 0.5 Banking sector 2010 Banks under majority foreign ownership -1.5 1.0 2 0 2.0 2009 Small domestic L O banks GA 1.0 0 7.7 7.7 8.7 8.9 8.2 8.8 9.2 9.1 2009 9.0 8.8 8.9 9.4 8.8 9.0 8.6 9.3 9.8 9.6 2011 2008 16 4 6 2.0 4 1.5 2 Jun. 2013 Banking Large Small Banks under 4 sector domestic domestic majority foreign 3 banks banks ownership 2 1 Source: Bank of Slovenia 0 20 Banking Large Small Banks under 2008 2010 2011 2012 sector 2009domestic domestic majority foreign 18 banks Ratio banks ownership Figure 14: Tier 1 Capital by bank group in 14 20 12 18 10 16 8 14 6 12 4 10 2 8 0 6 8 10.7 11.6 11.5 2008 8.8 9.0 8.6 9.3 9.8 9.6 16 15 14 13 12 11 16 10 15 9 14 8 13 7 12 6 11 5 10 4 9 3 8 2 7 1 6 0 5 10 2008 Large domestic A banks PRI 8.5 9.6 10.0 10.1 8 20 6 18 4 16 2 14 0 12 ISTIČN 8.3 10 Banking sector 9.9 10.5 10.7 12.0 STATISTICAL APPENDIX / S T12A T 8.3 1 16 0 14 Slovenia EU USA 2008 2009 Source: Bank of Slovenia, ECB, Statistics on Consolidated Banking Data (All domestic banks), October 2013 and Economic Research Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (http:// research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/), Quarterly, End of Period, annualized data 1.0 -0.5 0.5 -1.0 0.0 -1.5 -0.5 -2.0 -1.0 -1.5 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 H1 128 BV 11/2013 STATISTICAL APPENDIX / STATISTIČNA PRILOGA CORPORATE SECTOR INDICATORS Figure 1: Total pre-tax profit and loss of nonfinancial corporation in Slovenia in EUR billion Figure 3: Leverage by sector in Slovenia (in %) Source: AJPES, Bank of Slovenia 250 300 100 125 200 250 Industry Services Wholesale Industry and retail trade Overall Services Constructionand (right scale) Wholesale retail trade 150 200 100 150 50 100 2012 2012 2011 2011 2010 2010 2009 2009 2008 2008 Overall Construction (right scale) 2007 2007 2006 2006 2005 2005 2004 2004 2003 2003 0 2002 2002 0 25 0 50 0 Leverage is calculatedasaspercentage percentage debt-to-equity ratioratio Note: Note: Leverage is calculated debt-to-equity Source: AJPES, Bank Slovenia Source: AJPES, Bank of of Slovenia Figure 4: Ratio of non-current liabilities to EBITDA by sector in Slovenia Source: AJPES, Bank of Slovenia, Supreme Court Source: Ajpes, Bank of Slovenia Source: Ajpes, Bank of Slovenia 129 2012 2012 2011 2011 2010 2010 Source: Ajpes, Bank of Slovenia 2009 2009 Source: AJPES, Bank of Slovenia, Supreme Court 2008 2008 Aug. 13 0.5 0.0 2007 2007 Aug. 13 2006 2006 2011 Construction Industry Services Construction Wholesale and retail trade Industry Overall Services Wholesale and retail trade Overall 2005 2005 8.0 7.5 7.0 8.0 6.5 7.5 6.0 7.0 5.5 6.5 5.0 6.0 4.5 5.5 4.0 5.0 3.5 4.5 3.0 4.0 2.5 3.5 2.0 3.0 1.5 2.5 1.0 2.0 0.5 1.5 0.0 1.0 507 507 464 464 590 590 517 517 2012 0 Source: AJPES, Bank of Slovenia, Supreme Court 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 BV 11/2013 125 150 25 50 681 2010 300 350 2004 2004 2009 150 175 2003 2003 2008 350 400 2002 2002 0 100 88 64 100 200 88 64 200 300 175 200 2001 2001 300 400 400 450 50 75 242 242 199 199 436 400 500 587 500 600 200 225 Note: Leverage is calculated as percentage debt-to-equity ratio Source: AJPES, Bank of Slovenia 681 587 600 700 515 515 436 700 800 450 75 100 Figure 2: Number of bankrupcy proceedings initiated against firms in Slovenia 800 All corporates Non-financial corporations All corporates Non-financial corporations 225 2001 2001 2012 2012 2011 2011 2010 2010 2009 2009 Source: AJPES, Bank of Slovenia Source: AJPES, Bank of Slovenia 2008 2008 2007 2007 2006 2006 2005 2005 2004 2004 2003 2003 2002 2002 -2.5 -3.0 2001 2001 5.0 Total profit - loss 4.5 Total profit 4.0 5.0 Total loss 3.5 Total profit - loss 4.05 4.5 Total profit 3.0 4.0 Total loss 3.17 2.5 3.5 4.05 2.0 2.33 3.0 2.23 1.5 1.93 3.17 2.5 1.59 1.0 2.0 2.331.14 1.04 1.09 2.23 0.5 0.08 1.5 1.93 0.99 0.0 1.59 1.0 1.14 1.04 -0.5 0.5 -0.971.09 0.08 0.99 -1.0 0.0 -1.5 -0.5 -0.97 -2.0 -1.0 -2.5 -1.5 -3.0 -2.0